A Sentiment-Based Explanation of Forward Premium Puzzle

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Sentiment-Based Explanation of Forward Premium Puzzle"

Transcription

1 A Sentiment-Based Explanation of Forward Premium Puzzle Jianfeng Yu University of Minnesota Abstract This paper presents a sentiment-based explanation for forward premium puzzle. Agents over- or underestimate the growth rate of the economy. When domestic investor sentiment is higher than foreign sentiment, the interest rate at home is higher than foreign interest rate. At the same time, when agents prefer earlier resolution of uncertainty, the home currency is expected to appreciate due to the mean reversion of investor sentiment. Thus, the model can account for forward premium puzzle. This paper further empirically compares the sentimentbased explanation with those based on habit-formation and long-run risk. The evidence in the data strongly supports for a sentiment-based explanation. Surplus ratio predicts changes in exchange rates, but with an opposite sign as implied by the model. Consumption volatility has very weak power to predict returns on foreign exchange. By contrast, investor sentiment has significant power to predict both exchange rate changes and returns on foreign exchange (relative to U.S. dollar) across 19 industrial countries. In addition, forecasts of exchange rates based on sentiment easily beat random walk forecasts - with a smaller mean square error than that of random walk forecasts for 18 out of 19 industrial countries at a 6-month horizon. JEL Classification: G12, F31, G14, G15, Keywords: investor sentiment, forward premium puzzle, long-run risk, habit-formation First Draft: November I would like to thank Terry Odean and Stavros Panageas for comments. All errors are my own. jianfeng@umn.edu Address: Department of Finance, Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN Phone: (612)

2 1 Introduction There have been extensive literature examining the impact of investor irrationality on the stock market. Previous studies document that investor sentiment has most influence on the stocks which are hard to value and hard to arbitrage (e.g. Baker and Wurgler (2006)). The current paper explores the role of investor sentiment in another major market, the foreign exchange market. According to the uncovered interest rate parity (UIP), the expected change in exchange rates (foreign price of domestic currency) should equal the interest rate differential between foreign and domestic risk-free rate. Therefore, the regression coefficient of future changes in exchange rates on interest rate differentials should equals one. However, Fama (1984) and subsequent studies consistently find a negative coefficient in such regressions. That is, a raise in foreign interest rate forecasts an appreciation of foreign currency. This is referred as forward premium puzzle in the literature. The forward premium puzzle has inspired a vast empirical and theoretical work dissecting this puzzle. In this paper, I depart from rational expectation. The agents can be optimistic or pessimistic about the economic fundamental. In particular, the agent over- or underestimate the mean growth rate of consumption endowment. When the domestic agent is optimistic (i.e., the investor sentiment is high at home), the interest rate at home is higher than foreign interest rate. At the same time, the home currency is expected to depreciate because of the mean reversion of investor sentiment. As a results, through the channel of investor sentiment, the model can account for forward premium puzzle. In a complete market, the logarithm changes in exchange rates, measured in unit of foreign goods per domestic goods, equals the difference between the (log) stochastic discount factors for domestic and foreign countries. With preferences on early resolution of uncertainty, the pricing kernel is negatively related to the return on consumption claim. When sentiment is high, the consumption claim is over valued. As a result, the return on consumption claim is expected to be low due to the mean-reverting feature of investor sentiment. All together, high investor sentiment in domestic country leads to a higher future spot exchange rate. Given the positive relation between riskfree rate and investor sentiment, the model implies a negative association between interest rate differentials and exchange rate changes, i.e., the forward premium puzzle. Intuitively, in response to a rise in domestic investor sentiment, the equilibrium foreign price of the domestic currency drops immediately, so that relative to the new level today, the domestic currency is expected to appreciate tomorrow. At the same time, an increase in domestic sentiment raises the yields on domestic bonds and decreases the interest rate differentials between foreign and domestic countries. All together, when domestic sentiment is relatively high, an appreciation of the domestic currency is expected, and at the same time push down the interest rate differentials. This can qualitatively account for 2

3 the violation of the UIP condition in the data. The external habit-formation model and long-run risk model are two major workhorses in asset pricing. Verdelhan (2009) proposes an explanation of the forward premium puzzle based on habit-formation and Bansal and Shaliastovich (2009) provides an explanation based on long-run risk. I empirically compare the sentiment-based explanation with those based on habit-formation and long-run risk. In particular, I take the models one step further by investigating directly the mechanisms generating the forward premium puzzle. In habit-based model, a) the interest rate differential (between foreign and domestic countries) is negatively associated with surplus ratio in domestic country, b) changes in future exchange rates are positively correlated with home surplus ratio, and c) returns on foreign exchange is negatively associated with home surplus ratio. In longrun risk model, the three implications are a) the interest rate differential is positively associated with the volatility of consumption in domestic country, b) changes in future exchange rates are negatively correlated with home consumption volatility, and c) returns on foreign exchange is positively associated with home consumption volatility. However, the evidence in the data indicates that a) the interest rate differential is positively associated with surplus ratio in domestic country, and positively associated with the volatility of consumption in domestic country. b) changes in future exchange rates are negatively correlated with home surplus ratio and uncorrelated with home consumption volatility and c) returns on foreign exchange is positively associated with home surplus ratio and insignificantly associated with home consumption volatility. By contrast, investor sentiment has significant power to predict changes in exchange rates (relative to U.S. dollar) across 19 industrial countries. In addition, investor sentiment predicts returns on foreign exchange, even after controlling for forward premium and other predictors. Specifically, in a dataset with bilateral exchange rates between 19 industrial countries and the U.S., I show that foreign currencies appreciate significantly in subsequent months if the current U.S. investor sentiment is low. The results are strikingly consistent across all the 19 industrial countries in post Bretton-Woods periods. It is well known that forward premium (i.e. the interest rate differential) strongly predicts returns on foreign exchange. This paper documents that investor sentiment significantly improves the predictability of returns on foreign exchange. The R 2 of a regression which both forward premium and investor sentiment are included is more than doubled for 13 out of 19 countries compared with that of a regression in which forward premium is the only predictor. Meese and Rogoff (1983) show that macroeconomic variables have low power of forecasting exchange rate out of sample especially at short horizons (one year or less), though some of them can predict exchange rates in sample. While subsequent studies find evidence of exchange 3

4 rate predictability with macroeconomic variables, most results remain fragile or quantitatively moderate. 1 However, this paper finds strong evidence that investor sentiment forecasts exchange rates out of samples. At a 6-month horizon, out-of-sample forecasts based on investor sentiment have smaller mean squared errors than that of the random walk forecasts for 18 out of 19 exchange rates. The evidence of expectation-driven fluctuations in the foreign exchange market has policy implication that is absent in the stock market. The exchange rate differs from other asset prices in that exchange rate movements can change the relative prices of imports and exports when prices are fixed in the exporter s currency in the short run. A major benefit of exchange rate flexibility is that it facilitates the adjustment of the relative price in response to a country specific real shock (Friedman, 1953). However, Devereux and Engel (2007) argue that the expectation-driven exchange rate fluctuations may conflict with this conventional argument for the flexible exchange rate regime. If exchange rate movements are mainly driven by changes of expectations, rather than current demand and supply conditions in goods market, exchange rate fluctuations in this case may cause price distortions in the goods market rather than facilitating price adjustments in response to country specific real shocks. This is especially true when exchange rates are driven by irrational changes of expectations as documented in this paper. The model has implication on the role of investor sentiment in bond yield as well. When investor sentiment is high on the stock market, investors want to borrow to invest in the stock market. Through this channel, they drive up interest rate. As a result, a lower bond yield is expected in the future when investor sentiment finally return to its steady state. This paper empirically documents that, indeed, investor sentiment affects stock market and bond market hand in hand. In particular, high investor sentiment significantly predicts a negative change in bond yields. The contribution of this paper is twofold. First, this paper presents a sentiment-based model which can account for forward premium puzzle. Compared with the explanations based on leading asset pricing models, I find strong direct support for the sentiment channel in the data. Instead, there is only weak empirical evidence on the other two channels. Second, this paper document that investor sentiment has substantial predictive power in both currency and bond markets. Therefore, this study suggests that investor sentiment is a pervasive predictor in various asset markets and provide a natural out-of-sample support for the important role of investor sentiment in stock market noticed by previous studies. There is considerable earlier work on forward premium puzzle. Apart from Bansal and Shaliastovich (2009) and Verdelhan (2009) mentioned above, numerous studies attempt to explain 1 For instance, see Mark (1995), Groen (2000), Mark and Sul (2001), Kilian and Taylor (2003), Faust, Rogers, and Wright (2003), Molodtsova and Papell (2009), Wang and Wu (2008) among others. See Cheung, Chinn and Pascual (2005) for a recent comprehensive study. 4

5 this puzzle under rational expectations. Notable recent papers include Alvarez, Atkeson, and Kehoe (2009) in a segmented market, Bacchetta and Van Wincoop (2009) in a rational inattention framework, Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2007) with microstructure frictions, Colacito and Croce (2005) in a Bansal and Yaron (2004) long-run risk setting, Farhi and Gabaix (2008) in a Rietz (1988) rare disaster framework, and Lustig and Verdelhan (2007) in a cross-sectional analysis of foreign exchange portfolios. Earlier equilibrium-model based efforts to explain the forward premium puzzle include Backus, Gregory, and Telmer (1993) and Bekaert (1996). A number of earlier papers have provided insightful analysis on the role of investor irrationality in foreign exchange markets. An early application of irrationality to currency markets is provided by Frankel and Froot (1990). Mark and Wu (1998) develop a model in the noise trading setting of DeLong, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990): traders overweigh the forward premium when predicting future changes in the exchange rate. Gourinchas and Tornell (2004) provide an explanation base upon a distortion in investors beliefs about the dynamics of the forward premium. Han, Hirshleifer and Wang (2007) offer an explanation based on investor overconfidence. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the sentiment-based model. Section 3 compares the sentiment-based explanation with that based on habit-formation and longrun risk. Section 4 presents the results on the role of investor sentiment in foreign exchange market. Finally, Section 5 concludes. 2 A Model with Investor Sentiment In this section, I present a simple model of exchange rate with investor sentiment. The model is specified such that it is observationally equivalent with the Bansal-Yaron economy. As a result, the model is very tractable. In the current model, a separate pure exchange economy for the home country and the foreign country are specified. Consumption in the two countries is exogenously given To highlight the role of investor sentiment on forward premium puzzle, the model is abstract from money and inflation, and heterogenous belief is the only deviation from a standard two country model with recursive preferences. The model relies on investor sentiment alone to reproduce forward premium puzzle where financial markets are complete. 2.1 Preferences and Consumption Dynamics Assume that consumption stream, C t, follows a geometric Brownian motion under objective probability belief P : dc t C t = µdt + σdb t 5

6 If the agent has belief ˆP. By Girsanov theorem, there exists a process xt such that d ˆP dp t = ( t exp 0 x sds 1 ) t 2 0 x2 sds. Hence, in the agent s perception, dc t C t = (µ + x t ) dt + σd ˆB t where ˆB t is a standard Brownian motion. Therefore, under the perception of the agent, the growth rate of consumption is µ+x t rather than µ. As a result, x t can be interpreted as investor sentiment. When x t is positive, the agent is optimistic, vise versa. The origin of the sentiment, x t, is not modeled. It could be derived from learning with overconfidence (e.g., Scheinkman and Xiong (2003), and Xiong and Yan (2009)). Modeling the origin of sentiment do not add any economic insight for the purpose of this study, and it only complicates the analysis. Therefore, the sentiment process is specified exogenously. For easier presentation, I consider a discrete-time economy with infinite horizons developed by Bansal and Yaron. However, the interpretation on the state variable, x t, is different here. For simplicity, I assume that the true consumption growth rate, g t log (C t ) log (C t 1 ), is an i.i.d. process. However, the representative agent in the economy is sentimental and has a subjective belief which is different with the objective belief. Under his subjective belief, the mean growth rate of the economy, x t, is time-varying and the dynamics of the consumption growth is the following 2, g t+1 = µ g + x t + σ g η t+1 (1) In Bansal and Yaron (2004), x t is the true expected consumption growth rate. However, in this paper, the true consumption growth is assumed to be i.i.d., for simplicity, and x t measures investor sentiment. The investors preferences over uncertain consumption stream C t can be described by the Epstein-Zin recursive utlity function (e.g. Epstein and Zin (1989)) [ U t = (1 δ) C 1 γ θ t + δ (Êt U 1 γ t+1 ) 1 ] θ 1 γ θ, where Ê t ( ) is the expectation under the agent s subject belief conditional information up to time t, the parameter 0 < δ < 1 is the time discount factor, γ 0 is the risk-aversion parameter, ψ 0 is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution (IES) parameter, and the parameter θ = 1 γ. The 1 1 ψ sign is θ is determined by the values of risk aversion and IES. When risk aversion is larger than the reciprocal of the IES, the agent prefers early resolution of uncertainty of consumption path. Hence, 2 An alternative assumption is that the true expected growth rate is the same as Bansal and Yaron (2004). On top of that, there is a misperception process. This way, the model has two state variables, and the model can match more moments of the data. However, it does not add more intuition for the purpose here. 6

7 these preferences allow for agent s preference for the timing of the resolution of uncertainty. As in long-run risk model of Bansal and Yaron (2004), I assume that the agent prefers early resolution of uncertainty. 2.2 The Stochastic Discount Factor As shown in Epstein and Zin (1989), the logarithm of the intertemporal marginal rate of substitution (IMRS) is given by log (m t+1 ) = θ log δ θ ψ g t+1 + (θ 1) r a,t+1 (2) where r a,t+1 is the logarithm of the gross return on as asset that delivers aggregare consumption as its dividends each period. For any continuous return r t+1 = log (R t+1 ), including the one on wealth portfolio Ê t [exp (m t+1 + r t+1 )] = 1 (3) As shown below, with log-linear approximation, the return on wealth is solved explicitly by replacing r t+1 with r a,t+1 in equation (3). Hence, the IMRS is obtained explicitly. 2.3 Foreign Exchange Market A foreign country is introduced into the model. A similar setup is used in Colacito and Croce (2005) and Bansal and Shaliastovich (2009). For tractability, complete symmetry is imposed and all the model parameters are identical across countries. Under the foreign agent s subjective belief, mean growth rate of the foreign economy, x t, is time-varying and the dynamics of the consumption growth, g t, is the following, g t+1 = µ g + x t + σ gη t+1 The discount factor used to price assets denominated in foreign currency is given by, log ( m ) θ t+1 = θ log δ ψ g t+1 + (θ 1) ra,t+1 (4) the where the preference parameter are assumed to be the same at home and foreign countries, ra,t+1 is the logarithm of return on wealth. Let E t be the level of spot rate at the end of month t for the foreign country and it is defined as the foreign price per U.S. dollar. For notational convenience, denote e t = log(e t ). Under frictionless complete market, the exchange rate e t are linked to domestic and foreign discount factors m t and 7

8 m t by the following equation 3 e t+1 e t = log m t+1 log m t+1 (5) To understand the relation between investor sentiment and exchange rate, more structure on the pricing kernels is needed. Recall that the pricing kernel is given by log(m t+1 ) = θ log δ θ ψ g t+1 + (θ 1) r a,t+1 (6) When domestic sentiment is temporarily high at time t, the claim on consumption is over-valued currently. Therefore, the expected return on wealth is low since sentiment eventually returns to its long-run mean. This effect should be stronger at longer horizons since investor sentiment is persistent. Notice that θ 1 < 0 when risk aversion and IES are larger than 1, the expected value of domestic discount factor m t+1 is relatively high. From the above equation (5) and (6), holding else equal, the value of e t+1 e t is expected to be high at time t. That is, a high investor sentiment predicts an appreciation of U.S. dollar after controlling for other factor which might influence exchange rates. These arguments lead to the following prediction: Prediction 1: Domestic investor sentiment S t is positively associated with exchange rate changes, e t+1 e t. That is, high domestic sentiment forecasts an appreciation of domestic currency. Prediction 1 holds under very general conditions. No assumption needs to made on the dynamics of investor sentiment except the mean-reverting feature. I can go one step further by calculating the exactly relation between exchange rate changes and investor sentiment under this simple economy. To this end, I assume AR(1) processes for investor sentiment in both domestic and foreign countries: x t+1 = ρx t + ϕ e σ g ε t+1 x t+1 = ρx t + ϕ e σ g ε t+1 To solve for the unobserved wealth-to-consumption ratio in the model, I substitute r a,t+1 into the above Euler equation. From Campbell-Shiller log-linear approximation, r a,t+1 κ 0 + κ 1 z t+1 z t + g t+1, (7) z t A 0 + A 1 x t, (8) 3 Here, the agents at home and foreign have the same belief although their beliefs can be wrong. See Backus, Foresi, and Telmer (2001) for a rigorous argument. Among others, Backus, Foresi, and Telmer (2001) and Brandt, Cochrane and Santa-Clara (2006) exploit this equation to relate the dynamics of the exchange rate to the dynamics of the domestic and foreign discount factors. 8

9 where A 0 and A 1 are constants. Substituting equation (7) and (8) back into the Euler equation (3), it yields A 1 = 1 1 ψ 1 κ 1 ρ. Therefore, given the equilibrium solution to the IMRS, I can write down the solution to exchange rate changes in the following way: ( e t+1 e t = γgt+1 γg t+1 + γ 1 ) (x t x ( t ) + (θ 1) A 1 κ 1 ϕ e σ e εt+1 ε ) t+1 ψ Taking the conditional expectation, it yields the following key implication on the predictive ability of investor sentiment on exchange rate changes: E t (e t+1 e t ) = (9) ( γ 1 ) (x t x t ) (10) ψ Here, E t ( ) is the expectation under the objective belief. Notice that when the agent prefers earlier resolution of consumption uncertainty, γ 1 ψ > 0. Hence, as long as the domestic sentiment x t and foreign sentiment x f t are not perfectly correlation, there is a positive relation between domestic investor sentiment and expected exchange rate changes. The return on foreign exchange is defined as the excess return of a domestic investor who borrows at riskfree rate (in logs), r f,t, at home, converts them to a foreign currency, lends at foreign risk-free rate (in logs), rf,t, and then converts his earnings back to domestic currency. Hence, in logs, the return on foreign exchange, rx F X t is given by r F X t+1 = r f,t r f,t + e t e t+1. (11) The interest rate differentials are r f,t r f,t = 1 ψ ( ) x t x f t (12) Taking together, it leads to, ( ) ) E t r F X t+1 = γ (x t x f t (13) The above argument leads to the following two predictions: Prediction 2: Interest rate differentials are negatively associated with domestic investor sentiment x t, and positively associated with foreign investor sentiment, x t. Prediction 3: Returns on foreign exchange is negatively associated with domestic investor sentiment x t, and positively associated with foreign investor sentiment, x t. 9

10 Notice that in true Bansal-Yaron economy where x t is the expected growth rate under true belief, the expected returns on foreign exchange is a constant and independent of x t. This is because that in equation (9), the expected value of g t+1 is x t, rather than a constant, which is the case in the economy under objective belief. It follows from equation (10), (12) and (13) that E t (e t+1 e t ) = (1 ψγ) (r f,t r ) f,t ( ) ( ) E t r F X t+1 = γψ r f,t r f,t (14) (15) Equation (14) and (15) are the key results from the model. From equation (14), the UIP coefficient is 1 ψγ, which is negative as long as the agent prefers an earlier resolution of uncertainty. From equation (15), the regression coefficient of returns on foreign exchange on forward premium is γψ, which is larger than one when the agent prefers an earlier resolution of uncertainty. These are consistent with the empirically findings of Fama (1984). Therefore, this simple model with investor sentiment can generate forward premium puzzle. Intuitively, in response to a rise in domestic investor sentiment, the equilibrium foreign price of the domestic currency drops immediately, so that relative to the new level today, the domestic currency is expected to appreciate tomorrow due to the mean reversion in investor sentiment, and the dollar return on investments abroad is expected to be low as well. At the same time, a higher domestic sentiment raises the yields on domestic bonds and decreases the interest rate differentials between foreign and domestic countries. All together, when domestic sentiment is relatively high, an appreciation of the domestic currency and a lower return on foreign exchange are expected, and at the same time the interest rate differential is pushed down. Thus it results in a negative coefficient in UIP regressions. The model also has implications on the role of investor sentiment in bond yield and returns on consumption claim. In particular, in the model, the riskfree rate is given by ( ) r f,t = log Et m d t+1 = C ψ x t (16) where C 1 is a proper constant. Indeed, in the data, the correlation between real interest rate and investor sentiment is 27%. As a result, the following key implication on the predictive ability of 10

11 investor sentiment on bond yield changes is obtained: E t (r f,t+1 r f,t ) = 1 ψ (ρ 1) x t (17) This leads to the following prediction of the model: Prediction 4: There is a negative relation between investor sentiment and changes on bond yields. As it will become clear later, Section 4 provides strong evidence to support prediction 1-4. So far, the results are for real exchange rates and interest rate. The results can be extended for nominal terms by modeling inflation process. The implications on the role of investor sentiment on exchange rate remains the same. The results are omitted here for brevity. In the empirical test, following the literature, I focus on nominal terms, and use real exchange rates as robustness checks. 3 Comparison with Habit-Formation and Long-run Risk Explanations Within the class of rational, representative-agents frameworks, two workable and influential models are the external-habit model of Campbell and Cochrane (1999) and the long run risk model of Bansal and Yaron (2004). Previous studies show that these two models can account for a set of asset pricing puzzle, such as high equity premium, low risk free rate, high volatility of stock return, low volatility of riskfree rate, the failure of expectation hypothesis, and the forward premium puzzle. In particular, Verdelhan (2009) proposes an explanation of the forward premium puzzle based on habit-formation and Bansal and Shaliastovich (2009) provides an explanation based on long-run risk. Both models can successfully account for the failure of UIP. Before documenting empirically the role of investor sentiment on foreign exchange market, I directly compare the channels in sentiment-based model with the the channels in these two models. The key state variables in habit formation based explanation, in the long-run risk based explanation, and in the sentiment-based explanation are the surplus ratio, sp t, the time-varying consumption volatility, σ gt, and the investor sentiment S t, respectively. For these three explanations, they all work in the following manner: The interest rate differential is approximately a linear function of some state variable, (i.e., surplus ratio, consumption volatility or investor sentiment), at the same time, the expected changes in exchange rates and the expected return on foreign exchange are also approximately a linear function of the same state variable. If the coefficients on the state variable of interest rate differentials and expected changes in exchange rate are opposite, then the model yields a negative coefficient in UIP regression. To see which 11

12 explanation is more relevant empirically. I take one step further by examining the relation between the state variable and the interest rate differential, changes in exchange rates, and returns on foreign exchange. With consumption data, surplus ratio and consumption volatility can be constructed. Baker and Wurgler (2006) create investor sentiment index, and the university of Michigan provides consumer sentiment data as well. Therefore, the three models can be tested directly by linking surplus ratio, consumption volatility, and investor sentiment to changes in exchange rates and returns on foreign exchange. Below, I provide a brief review on the key mechanisms in these three models. For habit-formation model by Verdelhan (2009), the relation between the interest rate differential and expected changes in spot rate and the expected returns on foreign exchange are given by E t (e t+1 e t ) = γ 1 φ B E t ( r F X t+1 ) = γ 2 σ 2 g 2B ( r f,t r f,t ) ( r f,t r f,t ) (18) (19) where sp t and sp t are the surplus ratio in home country and foreign country, respectively, φ < 1 is the habit persistence, σ g is the constant consumption volatility in the habit model, constant B is a proper constant determined by preference parameters and consumption volatility,and γ is the risk aversion. Hence, to generate a negative coefficient in UIP regression, Verdelhan (2009) requires B < 0. However, the key mechanisms for the model to account for forward premium puzzle are the following three equations: r f,t r f,t = B (sp t sp t ) (20) E t (e t+1 e t ) = γ (1 φ) (sp t sp t ) (21) ( ) γ E t r F X 2 σg 2 t+1 = (sp t sp t ) (22) 2 Notice that B < 0, γ (1 φ) > 0, and γ2 σ 2 g 2 > 0. As a results, the habit-formation model implies that interest rate differentials are negatively correlated with domestic surplus ratio, changes in exchange rate are positively related to domestic surplus ratio, and the return on foreign exchange is negatively associated with surplus ratio. For long-run risk model by Bansal and Shaliastovich (2009), the relation between the interest rate differential and expected changes in spot rate and the expected returns on foreign exchange 12

13 are given by E t (e t+1 e t ) = m x (x t x t ) + ( 1 2 m gs γ + γ 1 ψ ( ) E t r F X ψγ 2 ( ) t+1 = r γψ + γ 1 f,t r f,t ) ( rf,t r ( f,t) + mxs σ 2 xt σxt 2 ) (23) (24) where m x = 1 ψ, m gs = 1 2 ( γ 1 ) (γ 1), m xs = 1 ( γ 1 ) ( ) 2 κ1 (γ 1). ψ 2 ψ 1 κ 1 ρ For the parameter values in the long-run risk model, m x, m gs, and m xs are all negative. Thus, the UIP regression coefficient is negative under proper parameter values. However, the mechanisms behind the failure of UIP are the following three equations identifying the relation between consumption volatility, σ gt, and interest rate differential, expected changes in spot rate, and the expected returns on foreign exchange: rf,t r f,t = 1 ( γ + γ 1 ) (σ 2 gt σ 2 ) gt 2 ψ E t (e t+1 e t ) = m x (x t x ( t ) + m gs σ 2 gt σgt 2 ) ( + mxs σ 2 xt σgt 2 ) ( ) E t r F X 1 ( t+1 = 2 γ2 σgt 2 σgt 2 ) ( ) For the parameter values in the long-run risk model, 1 2 γ + γ 1 ψ > 0, m gs < 0, and 1 2 γ2 > 0. Therefore, long-run risk model implies that interested rate differential is positively related to domestic consumption volatility, that changes in exchange rate are negatively related to domestic consumption volatility, and that the return on foreign exchange is positively related to domestic consumption volatility. Finally, for the sentiment-based explanation, (25) (26) (27) E t (e t+1 e t ) = (1 ψγ) (r f,t r ) f,t ( ) ( ) E t r F X t+1 = γψ r f,t r f,t (28) (29) The model can account for the forward premium puzzle when 1 < ψγ. Again, the key mechanisms 13

14 for this model are: rf,t r f,t = 1 ψ (x t x t ) (30) ( E t (e t+1 e t ) = γ 1 ) (x t x t ) (31) ψ E t ( r F X t+1 ) = γ (xt x t ) (32) As a result, the sentiment-based model implies that forward premium is negatively correlated with domestic sentiment, changes in exchange rate are positively related to domestic surplus ratio, and the return on foreign exchange is negatively associated with surplus ratio. In a nutshell, all the three models can generate forward premium puzzle with properly chosen parameter values. The sentiment-based model works through the channel of investor sentiment. The habit-formation model works through the channel of time-varying risk aversion (i.e. inversion of surplus ratio), while the long-run risk model functions through the channel of time-varying consumption volatility. With empirical measures on investor sentiment, surplus ratio, and consumption volatility, I can investigate these three channels directly. In particular, empirically tests are performed for equation (25), (26), (27), (20), (21), (22), (30), (31) and (32) in the next section. 4 Empirical Tests In this section, I first introduce notations on predictive variables; then I present the econometric models and the data used in this section. The empirical specifications are standard long-horizon predictive regressions (e.g. Fama and French (1988) and Hodrick (1992)). 4.1 Definition of Variables First, define changes in spot rate as e t = e t e t 1. and define E 52,t is the maximum spot rates in the past 52-weeks at the end of month t. Similarly, E min,t is defined as the historical minimum until the end of month t. Now two proxies for underand overreaction can be computed as 4 : 4 Both psychological and statistical evidence indicates that individuals tend to underreact to sporadic news (e.g. conservatism), such as quarterly earnings announcement, but overreact to a prolonged series of news, regardless good or bad (e.g. representativeness). See Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998) and Kanneman, Slovic, and Tversky (1982) for details. Li and Yu (2009) and Wang, Yu, and Yuan (2009) argue that nearness to the 52-week high captures the degree of underreaction to recent news, while nearness to the historical low capture the degree of overreaction to 14

15 x 52 = E t E 52,t, x max = E t E min,t Empirical studies find that macro fundamentals have very weak power predicting exchange rate changes. However, Wang, Yu, and Yuan (2009) show that x 52 and x min have strong power to predict exchange rate changes and returns on foreign exchange. Therefore x 52 and x min is used as control variables in predicting exchange rate changes. In empirical test that follows, the 3-month forward exchange rate F t is observed at the end of month t for a delivery at the end of month t + 3. Let f t = log(f t ). The 3-month forward premium is defined as fp t = f t e t. By covered interest parity, fp t = rf,t r f,t, where rf,t is the 3-month riskfree rate (from end of month t to the end of month t + 3) in foreign countries at the end of month t and r f,t the 3-month domestic riskfree rate the end of month t. The return on foreign exchange is therefore, r F X t+3 = f t e t+3. Finally, following Wachter (2006), surplus ratio is approximated by sp t = 40 j=1 φ j g t j. and following Bansal and Shaliastovich (2009), consumption volatility, σ gt, is measured as a 4.5 year sum of absolute residual from AR(3) projections of consumption growth rates. 4.2 Empirical Design The empirical specifications are standard long-horizon predictive regressions (e.g. Fama and French (1988) and Hodrick (1992)). All variables are monthly observed. Future spot rate changes and returns on foreign exchange rates are regressed onto investor sentiment, S t, surplus ratio, sp t, and consumption volatility, σ gt. The ratio of current spot rate to the 52-week high spot rate, x 52, and the ratio of current spot rate to historical minimum spot rate, x min are used as control variables in various regressions. Thereofore, the dependent variable is either log changes in foreign exchange rates, e t+h e t with different horizons or 3-month log returns on foreign exchange r F X t+3. The independent variables are investor sentiment, S t, surplus ratio, sp t, and consumption volatility, σ gt. prolonged extreme record. 15

16 For example, to examine the predictive ability of investor sentiment on changes in spot rates, the main regression is e t+h e t = α h + β 1,h x 52,t + β 2,h x min,t + β 3,h S t + ɛ t,t+h (33) The error term ɛ t,t+h is an element of the time t + h, and is autocorrelated due to overlapping observations when the forecast horizon h > 1. Both Newey and West (1987) standard errors and Hodrick (1992) standard errors are used to adjust for this autocorrelation and potential heteroscedasticity. The t-statistics resulting from both adjusted standard errors test the null hypothesis that a given slope coefficient equals zero. Hodrick (1992) t-statistics retain the correct size in small sample (e.g. Ang and Bekaert (2007). For small h, these two methods give a similar t-statistics. However, the difference can be substantial when forecast horizon h is large, such as 2- to 4-year. 4.3 Data The main analysis uses investor sentiment data from the website of Jeffrey Wurger. Michigan consumer sentiment index is also used for robustness checks. The monthly sentiment index spans from January 1966 to December 2005, a total of 40 years. Baker and Wurgler (2006) form a composite sentiment index that is the first principal component of six measures of investor sentiment. The principal component analysis filters out idiosyncratic noise in the six measures and captures their common component. The six measures are the number and the average first-day returns of IPOs, the dividend premium, the closed-end fund discount, the NYSE turnover, and the equity share in new issues. The monthly sentiment data spans from 1966m1 to 2005m12. Annual sentiment measure is used for robustness checks as well, and the results, omitted for brevity, are very similar with the results reported here. The dataset on foreign exchange includes monthly spot and 3-month forward exchange rates between the US dollar and currencies in 19 industrial countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, and the UK. Data sample is between 1973m1 and 2009m08 for most countries and may vary in some countries due to the data availability. Monthly CPI for these 19 countries and U.S.A. from 1973m1-2009m8 is obtained from IMF. Annual real consumption per capita from is obtained from OECD. Spot exchange rates are from the Federal Reserve and 3-month forward exchange rates are from the International Financial Statistics (IFS). The spot and forward exchange rates are used to calculate interest rate differentials between the US dollar and other currencies. For several 16

17 countries, part of the forward exchange rates are missing in the IFS. In this case, the forward rate is obtained from Bloomberg, or calculated from the 3-month interest rate obtained from G-10 dataset. The choice of the data source is dictated by the availability of the data. Finally, I obtain monthly prices for one to five year zero-coupon bonds from June, 1952 to December 2008 from CRSP. 4.4 Summary Statistics Investor sentiment is standardized with mean zero and standard deviation one. Table 1 reports the summary statistics for monthly changes on spot rates ( e t ), the ratio of current spot rate to the 52-week high spot rate, x 52, and the ratio of current spot rate to historical minimum spot rate, x min. The means and standard deviations of variables are on a percent basis. The autocorrelation for x 52 and x min is the annualized autocorrelation. The monthly volatility of changes in spot rate is about 3% for most of the countries, which is consistent with previous studies. The autocorrelation of changes on spot rates is very low, which suggests that spot rates behave like a random walk. Nearness to the 52-week high, x 52, is close to one, and moderately volatile, the autocorrelation is reasonably low. However, nearness to the historical low is much more volatile and very persistent. On average, it is as persistent as the traditional predictors, dividend yield, in stock market. The last two column reports the correlation between nearness to the 52-week high and investor sentiment and the correlation between nearness to the historical low and investor sentiment. The correlation between nearness to the historical low and investor sentiment is about 50% across 19 countries. It is therefore important to control for nearness to the historical low in the predictive regression. From Table 1, the currencies of Japan, Swiss, Austria, Germany, and Netherlands appreciate on average against U.S. dollar from 1973 to (Denmark and Belgium also appreciate slightly against U.S. dollar in this period). Table 2 shows that exactly these currencies have lower interests than that in U.S. during this period (or equivalently a negative forward premium). This implies that the expectation hypothesis in currency markets seems hold on average or in the long-run. Table 2 also indicates that the countries with a low average interest rate also yield a negative return on foreign exchange. This implies that sorting on interest rate differential can yield a significant spread (e.g., Hustig and Verdelhan (2007)). The volatility of returns on foreign exchange is much more volatile than forward premium, consistent with the finding with Fama (1984). 4.5 Comparison of Three Models This section provides empirical results on the comparison of the three explanations. In particular, statistical tests are performed for equation (25), (26), (27), (20), (21), (22), (30), (31) and (32). 17

18 According to Section 3, interested rate differential (i.e. forward premium) is positively related to domestic consumption volatility, negatively correlated with domestic surplus ratio, and negatively correlated with domestic sentiment. The last three columns of Table 2 show that this is exactly the opposite for habit-based explanation. There is strong support for both long-run risk based and sentiment-based explanation. For example, the correlation between forward premium and domestic sentiment is negative for all the 19 countries, consistent with the prediction 2 in Section 2. Similarly, according to Section 3, returns on foreign exchange are positively related to domestic consumption volatility, negatively correlated with domestic surplus ratio, and negatively correlated with domestic sentiment. Table 4 shows that surplus ratio is strongly positively correlated with future changes in exchange rates, the opposite of that of the habit model. The results from Table 4 is consistent with the sentiment-based explanation. For long-run risk model, consumption volatility has little power to predict returns on foreign exchange and the signs of the coefficients flip across countries. Here, I focus on 1-year changes on exchange rate rather than one-month changes. All the three state variables are persistent, hence it is easier to identified their predictability in longer horizons. Finally, according to Section 3, changes in exchange rates are negatively related to domestic consumption volatility, positively correlated with domestic surplus ratio, and positively correlated with domestic sentiment. Table 3 shows that surplus ratio is negatively correlated with future changes in exchange rates, the opposite of the implications from the habit model. Again, the results from Table 3 is consistent with the sentiment-based explanation. For long-run risk model, consumption volatility has very weak power to predict changes in exchange rates and the sign flips across countries. The data for U.S. consumption is long, hence the surplus ratio and consumption volatility can be more precisely estimated. Thus, up to this point, the analysis is based on nominal exchange rate and US consumption data only. To test the models directly, real exchange rates and foreign consumption data are needed. The longest available annual real per capita consumption data from (obtained from OECD) is used to construct surplus ratio and consumption volatility for all the 20 countries. Annual surplus ratio is defined as the smoothed average of the past 10-year consumption growth. Annual consumption volatility is defined as a 3 year sum of absolute residuals from AR(3) projections of consumption growth rates. I then convert the annual observation to monthly observation by assigning the value at the end of this year to each month in the following year. Panel A of Table 5 reports the forecast of changes in real exchange rates by surplus ratio. It is seen that the predictive power of the surplus ratio is again the opposite with that implied by the model. The model implies a positive relation between domestic surplus ratio and changes 18

19 in exchange rate, but the data suggest the opposite. The model also implies a negative relation between foreign surplus ratio and changes in exchange rate, but the evidence from the data is mixed. Panel B of Table 5 reports the forecast of changes in real exchange rates by consumption volatility. The empirical results indicate that the predictive power of consumption volatility is very weak and the sign flips across 19 countries. Table 6 reports results from the predictive regressions of 3-month returns on foreign exchange on surplus ratios and consumption volatility. The results confirms the findings from regression of changes in spot rates on surplus ratio and consumption volatility in Table 5. These results are very similar with the analysis based on U.S. consumption data alone and nominal exchange rates, which is of course expected given the low correlation between U.S. consumption and foreign consumption. In a nutshell, the empirical evidence in this section provides strong support for the sentiment channel. The habit-based explanation has difficulty reconciling the evidence in this section given the exactly opposite results with the predictions from the model. For long-run risk model, the support is at most modest for the time-varying consumption volatility channel. 4.6 Forecasting Changes in Exchange Rates by Sentiment Previous subsection provides support for the sentiment-based explanation. Although in the simple model presented in Section 2, there is an exact relation between forward premium. In more realistic setting with additional shocks, this won t hold. Therefore, investor sentiment may contain information which is not captured by forward premium. In subsequent analysis, I empirically explore in more detail on the predictive ability of investor sentiment in currency markets. Because a majority of foreign exchange transaction involves U.S. dollar (about 86%), U.S. dollar is used as domestic currency. Table 7 reports results from the monthly overlapping predictive regression of changes in exchange rates on investor sentiment together with control variables, for nearness to the 52-week high and nearness to the historical low 5. The forecast horizons are 1- month, 3-month, 12-month, 24-month, and 48-month. For each regression, this table reports the slopes, the adjusted R 2, and two sets of t-statistics: t-statistics calculated from standard errors corrected for autocorrelations per Newey and West (1987) and t-statistics calculated from standard errors adjusted for the use of overlapping observations in long-horizon regression per Hodrick (1992). Noticeably, investor sentiment serves as a statistically significant predictor of exchange rate changes across all the 19 countries at most horizons less than 2-year. It becomes less significant at a very long horizon, such as a 4-year horizon. In addition, the predictive power of nearness to the 52-week high is stronger at shorter horizons, while the predictive power of nearness to the historical low is 5 The is a concern that the autocorrelation of nearness to the historical low is very high. I replaced nearness to the historical low with nearness to 5-year low and the results are very similar. The persistence of nearness to the 5-year low is much lower. These results are omitted for brevity and available upon request. 19

20 stronger at longer horizons, typically at 2-3 years (as measured by Hodrick (1992) t-statistics). These results confirm prediction 1 in foreign exchange market. One striking feature of the results is the consistency across the 19 industrial countries. Adding investor sentiment into the predictive regression in generally produce twice as high R 2 as that with only nearness to the 52-week high and the historical low. Together, these three predictors can account for about 40% of variation in exchange rate changes at one-year horizon. Given the fact that it is very hard to predict exchange rate, this is an intriguing result. Traditional macroeconomic variable have very limited power to predict exchange rate changes, especially at horizons less than 1 year. By contrast, investor sentiment, which are motivated by traders behavioral biases, has significant predictive power at both short and longer horizons. The results are especially interesting because foreign exchange market are dominated by professional investors and is regard as the most efficient market in the world. In summary, this section documents a robust empirical fact that investor sentiment positively predicts changes in future spot rates. The predictive power of investor sentiment is very robust across 19 industrial countries. 4.7 Forecasting Returns on Foreign Exchange by Sentiment Forward premium predicts the future returns on foreign exchange (e.g. Fama(1984), Hansen and Hodrick (1980)). Prediction 3 states that investor sentiment serve as a contrarian predictor of returns on foreign exchange. This subsection empirically tests this prediction by controlling known predictors. In Table 8, returns on foreign exchange are first regressed on 3-month forward premium. This table confirms the finding from previous studies on the predictive ability of forward premium. The high values of Newey-West t-statistics indicate that forward premium is indeed a significant predictor of returns on foreign exchange. In the second predictive regression, investor sentiment, S t, x 52, and x min are also included into the regression. The results show that investor sentiment is a statistically significant predictor of returns on foreign exchange. The economic significance of the predictability is rather large. A one-standard-deviation increase in investor sentiment is associated with about 8% decrease in annualized future returns on foreign exchange. In addition, nearness to the 52-week high significantly negatively predicts the return on foreign exchange while nearness to historical high is significantly positively associated with the future returns on foreign exchange. This is of course, consistent with the negative predictive power of nearness to the historical low and the positive power of nearness to the 52-week high on changes on future spot rates. Finally, the interaction between forward premium and investor sentiment is generally positive and significant for 7 out of 19 countries. This indicates that forward premium has 20

A Long-Run Risks Explanation of Predictability Puzzles in Bond and Currency Markets

A Long-Run Risks Explanation of Predictability Puzzles in Bond and Currency Markets A Long-Run Risks Explanation of Predictability Puzzles in Bond and Currency Markets Ravi Bansal Ivan Shaliastovich June 008 Bansal (email: ravi.bansal@duke.edu) is affiliated with the Fuqua School of Business,

More information

The Share of Systematic Variation in Bilateral Exchange Rates

The Share of Systematic Variation in Bilateral Exchange Rates The Share of Systematic Variation in Bilateral Exchange Rates Adrien Verdelhan MIT Sloan and NBER March 2013 This Paper (I/II) Two variables account for 20% to 90% of the monthly exchange rate movements

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles : A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles, JF (2004) Presented by: Esben Hedegaard NYUStern October 12, 2009 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Long-Run Risk Solving the 3 Data and Calibration Results

More information

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets Andrey Ermolov Columbia Business School April 24, 2014 1 / 41 Stylized Facts about Bond Markets US Fact 1: Upward Sloping Real Yield Curve In US, real long

More information

International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences

International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences p. 1/3 International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences Riccardo Colacito Prepared for Tom Sargent s PhD class (Part 1) Roadmap p. 2/3 Today International asset pricing (exchange

More information

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS 1 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS Lars Peter Hansen Bendheim Lectures, Princeton University 2 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS ABSTRACT Expectations and uncertainty about growth rates that

More information

Risks For The Long Run And The Real Exchange Rate

Risks For The Long Run And The Real Exchange Rate Riccardo Colacito, Mariano M. Croce Overview International Equity Premium Puzzle Model with long-run risks Calibration Exercises Estimation Attempts & Proposed Extensions Discussion International Equity

More information

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Pricing Unexpected Growth Fluctuations Lars Peter Hansen 1 2007 Nemmers Lecture, Northwestern University 1 Based in part joint work with John Heaton, Nan Li,

More information

Volatility Risk Pass-Through

Volatility Risk Pass-Through Volatility Risk Pass-Through Ric Colacito Max Croce Yang Liu Ivan Shaliastovich 1 / 18 Main Question Uncertainty in a one-country setting: Sizeable impact of volatility risks on growth and asset prices

More information

A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective

A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective Ravi Bansal Dana Kiku Amir Yaron November 14, 2007 Abstract Asset return and cash flow predictability is of considerable

More information

Common Risk Factors in Currency Markets

Common Risk Factors in Currency Markets Common Risk Factors in Currency Markets Hanno Lustig, Nick Roussanov and Adrien Verdelhan UCLA, Wharton and BU CEPR / SNB - Zurich, September 28 Summary Example Subprime Mortgage Crisis: Currency Portfolios.1

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1 Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Philippe Bacchetta Eric van Wincoop January 10, 007 1 Prepared for the May 007 issue of the American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings.

More information

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Liuren Wu Baruch College, City University of New York Joint work with Jian Hua 6th Annual Conference of the Society for Financial Econometrics June 12-14,

More information

If Exchange Rates Are Random Walks Then Almost Everything We Say About Monetary Policy Is Wrong

If Exchange Rates Are Random Walks Then Almost Everything We Say About Monetary Policy Is Wrong If Exchange Rates Are Random Walks Then Almost Everything We Say About Monetary Policy Is Wrong Fernando Alvarez, Andrew Atkeson, and Patrick J. Kehoe* The key question asked by standard monetary models

More information

Currency Risk Factors in a Recursive Multi-Country Economy

Currency Risk Factors in a Recursive Multi-Country Economy Currency Risk Factors in a Recursive Multi-Country Economy R. Colacito M.M. Croce F. Gavazzoni R. Ready NBER SI - International Asset Pricing Boston July 8, 2015 Motivation The literature has identified

More information

An Empirical Evaluation of the Long-Run Risks Model for Asset Prices

An Empirical Evaluation of the Long-Run Risks Model for Asset Prices An Empirical Evaluation of the Long-Run Risks Model for Asset Prices Ravi Bansal Dana Kiku Amir Yaron November 11, 2011 Abstract We provide an empirical evaluation of the Long-Run Risks (LRR) model, and

More information

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( ) Lecture 5 Predictability Traditional Views of Market Efficiency (1960-1970) CAPM is a good measure of risk Returns are close to unpredictable (a) Stock, bond and foreign exchange changes are not predictable

More information

Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing. Abstract

Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing. Abstract Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing Alex Lebedinsky Western Kentucky University Abstract In this note, I conduct an empirical investigation of the affine stochastic

More information

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings J Econ Finan (2010) 34:23 29 DOI 10.1007/s12197-008-9070-2 Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings Faruk Balli Rosmy J. Louis Mohammad Osman Published online: 24 December 2008 Springer Science + Business

More information

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration Takashi Kano Hitotsubashi University @HIAS, IER, AJRC Joint Workshop Frontiers in Macroeconomics and Macroeconometrics November 3-4, 2017

More information

Real and Nominal Puzzles of the Uncovered Interest Parity

Real and Nominal Puzzles of the Uncovered Interest Parity Real and Nominal Puzzles of the Uncovered Interest Parity Shigeru Iwata and Danai Tanamee Department of Economics University of Kansas July 2010 Abstract Examining cross-country data, Bansal and Dahlquist

More information

Global Currency Hedging

Global Currency Hedging Global Currency Hedging JOHN Y. CAMPBELL, KARINE SERFATY-DE MEDEIROS, and LUIS M. VICEIRA ABSTRACT Over the period 1975 to 2005, the U.S. dollar (particularly in relation to the Canadian dollar), the euro,

More information

Risks for the Long Run and the Real Exchange Rate

Risks for the Long Run and the Real Exchange Rate Risks for the Long Run and the Real Exchange Rate Riccardo Colacito - NYU and UNC Kenan-Flagler Mariano M. Croce - NYU Risks for the Long Run and the Real Exchange Rate, UCLA, 2.22.06 p. 1/29 Set the stage

More information

An Empirical Evaluation of the Long-Run Risks Model for Asset Prices

An Empirical Evaluation of the Long-Run Risks Model for Asset Prices Critical Finance Review, 2012,1:183 221 An Empirical Evaluation of the Long-Run Risks Model for Asset Prices Ravi Bansal 1,DanaKiku 2 and Amir Yaron 3 1 Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, and NBER;

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Bryan Kelly NYU Stern and Chicago Booth Outline Introduction An Economic Framework Econometric Methodology Empirical Findings Conclusions Tail Risk

More information

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Badrinath Kottimukkalur * January 2018 Abstract This paper provides an arbitrage based explanation for the puzzling negative

More information

ESSAYS ON ASSET PRICING PUZZLES

ESSAYS ON ASSET PRICING PUZZLES ESSAYS ON ASSET PRICING PUZZLES by FEDERICO GAVAZZONI Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY at the Carnegie Mellon University David A. Tepper School

More information

Long-Run Risk, the Wealth-Consumption Ratio, and the Temporal Pricing of Risk

Long-Run Risk, the Wealth-Consumption Ratio, and the Temporal Pricing of Risk Long-Run Risk, the Wealth-Consumption Ratio, and the Temporal Pricing of Risk By Ralph S.J. Koijen, Hanno Lustig, Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh and Adrien Verdelhan Representative agent consumption-based asset

More information

Explaining International Business Cycle Synchronization: Recursive Preferences and the Terms of Trade Channel

Explaining International Business Cycle Synchronization: Recursive Preferences and the Terms of Trade Channel 1 Explaining International Business Cycle Synchronization: Recursive Preferences and the Terms of Trade Channel Robert Kollmann Université Libre de Bruxelles & CEPR World business cycle : High cross-country

More information

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach Identifying : A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach Frank Schorfheide University of Pennsylvania CEPR and NBER Dongho Song University of Pennsylvania Amir Yaron University of Pennsylvania NBER February 12,

More information

The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks

The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks Glenn D. Rudebusch Eric T. Swanson Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial

More information

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Nicolas Coeurdacier (SciencesPo & CEPR) Helene Rey (LBS & NBER & CEPR) Pablo Winant (PSE) Barcelona June 2013 Coeurdacier, Rey, Winant Financial Integration...

More information

Short- and Long-Run Business Conditions and Expected Returns

Short- and Long-Run Business Conditions and Expected Returns Short- and Long-Run Business Conditions and Expected Returns by * Qi Liu Libin Tao Weixing Wu Jianfeng Yu January 21, 2014 Abstract Numerous studies argue that the market risk premium is associated with

More information

Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008)

Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008) Backus, Routledge, & Zin Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008) Asset pricing with Kreps-Porteus preferences, starting with theoretical results from Epstein

More information

If Exchange Rates Are Random Walks, Then Almost Everything We Say About Monetary Policy Is Wrong

If Exchange Rates Are Random Walks, Then Almost Everything We Say About Monetary Policy Is Wrong If Exchange Rates Are Random Walks, Then Almost Everything We Say About Monetary Policy Is Wrong By Fernando Alvarez, Andrew Atkeson, and Patrick J. Kehoe* The key question asked of standard monetary models

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations?

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations? What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations? Bernard Dumas INSEAD, Wharton, CEPR, NBER Alexander Kurshev London Business School Raman Uppal London Business School,

More information

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in Durable Consumption Wei Yang 1 This draft: October 2009 1 William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Rochester, Rochester,

More information

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Jerry Tsai University of Oxford Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania December 12, 2014 and NBER A The iid model This section

More information

Diverse Beliefs and Time Variability of Asset Risk Premia

Diverse Beliefs and Time Variability of Asset Risk Premia Diverse and Risk The Diverse and Time Variability of M. Kurz, Stanford University M. Motolese, Catholic University of Milan August 10, 2009 Individual State of SITE Summer 2009 Workshop, Stanford University

More information

Long Run Risks and Financial Markets

Long Run Risks and Financial Markets Long Run Risks and Financial Markets Ravi Bansal December 2006 Bansal (email: ravi.bansal@duke.edu) is affiliated with the Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, Durham, NC 27708. I thank Dana Kiku,

More information

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Giancarlo Corsetti Luca Dedola Sylvain Leduc CREST, May 2008 The International Consumption Correlations Puzzle

More information

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns Ravi Jagannathan Northwestern University and NBER Binying Liu Northwestern University September 30, 2015 Abstract We develop a model for dividend

More information

The Shape of the Term Structures

The Shape of the Term Structures The Shape of the Term Structures Michael Hasler Mariana Khapko November 16, 2018 Abstract Empirical findings show that the term structures of dividend strip risk premium and volatility are downward sloping,

More information

Introduction... 2 Theory & Literature... 2 Data:... 6 Hypothesis:... 9 Time plan... 9 References:... 10

Introduction... 2 Theory & Literature... 2 Data:... 6 Hypothesis:... 9 Time plan... 9 References:... 10 Introduction... 2 Theory & Literature... 2 Data:... 6 Hypothesis:... 9 Time plan... 9 References:... 10 Introduction Exchange rate prediction in a turbulent world market is as interesting as it is challenging.

More information

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model Glenn D. Rudebusch Eric T. Swanson Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco John Taylor s Contributions to Monetary Theory and Policy Federal

More information

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Philippe Bacchetta Study Center Gerzensee University of Lausanne Swiss Finance Institute & CEPR Eric van Wincoop University of Virginia NBER January

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

A Consumption-Based Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates

A Consumption-Based Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates A Consumption-Based Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania and NBER January 20, 2005 I thank Andrew Abel, Andrew Ang, Ravi Bansal, Michael Brandt, Geert

More information

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence Journal of Money, Investment and Banking ISSN 1450-288X Issue 5 (2008) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2008 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New

More information

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , JPE 1996 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 16, 2009 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction Motivation Contribution 2 Assumptions Equilibrium 3 Mechanism Empirical Implications of Idiosyncratic

More information

Is there a significant connection between commodity prices and exchange rates?

Is there a significant connection between commodity prices and exchange rates? Is there a significant connection between commodity prices and exchange rates? Preliminary Thesis Report Study programme: MSc in Business w/ Major in Finance Supervisor: Håkon Tretvoll Table of content

More information

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHANNES KEPLER UNIVERSITY LINZ Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison by Burkhard Raunig and Johann Scharler* Working Paper

More information

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )] Problem set 1 Answers: 1. (a) The first order conditions are with 1+ 1so 0 ( ) [ 0 ( +1 )] [( +1 )] ( +1 ) Consumption follows a random walk. This is approximately true in many nonlinear models. Now we

More information

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns Ravi Jagannathan Northwestern University, and NBER, ISB, SAIF Binying Liu Northwestern University September 28, 2016 Abstract We show that,

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Noise Traders, Exchange Rate Disconnect Puzzle, and the Tobin Tax

Noise Traders, Exchange Rate Disconnect Puzzle, and the Tobin Tax Noise Traders, Exchange Rate Disconnect Puzzle, and the Tobin Tax September 2008 Abstract This paper proposes a framework to explain why the nominal and real exchange rates are highly volatile and seem

More information

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Mitsuru Katagiri International Monetary Fund October 24, 2017 @Keio University 1 / 42 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities - The models we studied earlier include only real variables and relative prices. We now extend these models to have

More information

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Persistent than You Think October 19th, 2009 Introduction: Habit Preferences Habit preferences: can generate a higher equity premium for a given curvature

More information

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns Ravi Jagannathan Northwestern University and NBER Binying Liu Northwestern University April 14, 2016 Abstract We show that, in a perfect and

More information

Prospect Theory and Asset Prices

Prospect Theory and Asset Prices Prospect Theory and Asset Prices Presenting Barberies - Huang - Santos s paper Attila Lindner January 2009 Attila Lindner (CEU) Prospect Theory and Asset Prices January 2009 1 / 17 Presentation Outline

More information

The Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets

The Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets The Financial Review 41 (2006) 565--587 The Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets Hui Guo Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Abstract We investigate the risk-return relation in international

More information

From the perspective of theoretical

From the perspective of theoretical Long-Run Risks and Financial Markets Ravi Bansal The recently developed long-run risks asset pricing model shows that concerns about long-run expected growth and time-varying uncertainty (i.e., volatility)

More information

Skewness in Expected Macro Fundamentals and the Predictability of Equity Returns: Evidence and Theory

Skewness in Expected Macro Fundamentals and the Predictability of Equity Returns: Evidence and Theory Skewness in Expected Macro Fundamentals and the Predictability of Equity Returns: Evidence and Theory Ric Colacito, Eric Ghysels, Jinghan Meng, and Wasin Siwasarit 1 / 26 Introduction Long-Run Risks Model:

More information

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model Hui Guo a, Christopher J. Neely b * a College of Business, University of Cincinnati, 48

More information

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis A. Buss B. Dumas R. Uppal G. Vilkov INSEAD INSEAD, CEPR, NBER Edhec, CEPR Goethe U. Frankfurt

More information

Ambiguity Aversion: Implications for the Uncovered Interest Rate Parity Puzzle

Ambiguity Aversion: Implications for the Uncovered Interest Rate Parity Puzzle Ambiguity Aversion: Implications for the Uncovered Interest Rate Parity Puzzle Cosmin L. Ilut Duke University First version: October 2008 Revised version: March 2010 Abstract High-interest-rate currencies

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 202A DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 203 D. Romer FORCES LIMITING THE EXTENT TO WHICH SOPHISTICATED INVESTORS ARE WILLING TO MAKE TRADES THAT MOVE ASSET PRICES BACK TOWARD

More information

Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns. Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen

Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns. Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen Outline Introduction Equity premium puzzle Recent contribution Contribution of this paper Long-Run Risk Model

More information

Risks For the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks For the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles Risks For the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles Ravi Bansal and Amir Yaron ABSTRACT We model consumption and dividend growth rates as containing (i) a small long-run predictable

More information

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing /49 Introduction We present models of asset pricing where investors preferences are subject to psychological biases or where investors

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LIX, NO. 4 AUGUST 004 Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles RAVI BANSAL and AMIR YARON ABSTRACT We model consumption and dividend growth rates

More information

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences Petr Zemčík CERGE-EI April 2005 1 Mean Reversion Equity returns display negative serial correlation at horizons longer than one year.

More information

Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule. Bank of Canada Conference on Fixed Income Markets

Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule. Bank of Canada Conference on Fixed Income Markets Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule Michael Gallmeyer (Texas A&M) Francisco Palomino (Michigan) Burton Hollifield (Carnegie Mellon) Stanley Zin (Carnegie Mellon) Bank of Canada Conference on Fixed

More information

Variation in Liquidity and Costly Arbitrage

Variation in Liquidity and Costly Arbitrage and Costly Arbitrage Badrinath Kottimukkalur * December 2018 Abstract This paper explores the relationship between the variation in liquidity and arbitrage activity. A model shows that arbitrageurs will

More information

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Ralph S.J. Koijen, Hanno Lustig, and Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh University of Chicago, UCLA & NBER, and NYU, NBER & CEPR UC Berkeley, September 10, 2009 Unified Stochastic

More information

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners Bahmani-Oskooee and Ratha, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 1-13 1 The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee and Artatrana Ratha

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Long Run Labor Income Risk

Long Run Labor Income Risk Long Run Labor Income Risk Robert F. Dittmar Francisco Palomino November 00 Department of Finance, Stephen Ross School of Business, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 4809, email: rdittmar@umich.edu

More information

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam Optimal Financial Education Avanidhar Subrahmanyam Motivation The notion that irrational investors may be prevalent in financial markets has taken on increased impetus in recent years. For example, Daniel

More information

If Exchange Rates Are Random Walks, Then Almost Everything We Say about Monetary Policy is Wrong

If Exchange Rates Are Random Walks, Then Almost Everything We Say about Monetary Policy is Wrong Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 388 March 2007 If Exchange Rates Are Random Walks, Then Almost Everything We Say about Monetary Policy is Wrong Fernando Alvarez University

More information

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns October 30, 2017 Abstract We present a latent variable model of dividends that predicts, out-of-sample, 39.5% to 41.3% of the variation in

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries Davide Furceri University of Palermo Georgios Karras Uniersity of Illinois at Chicago Abstract The main purpose of this

More information

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning Tongbin Zhang Univeristat Autonoma de Barcelona and Barcelona GSE April 2016 Tongbin Zhang (Institute) Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning April 2016 1 / 31

More information

Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle

Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle Robert F. Stambaugh, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania and NBER Jianfeng Yu, Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy This online appendix is divided into four sections. In section A we perform pairwise tests aiming at disentangling

More information

A Long-Run Risks Explanation of Predictability Puzzles in Bond and Currency Markets

A Long-Run Risks Explanation of Predictability Puzzles in Bond and Currency Markets A Long-Run Risks Explanation of Predictability Puzzles in Bond and Currency Markets Ravi Bansal Ivan Shaliastovich August 2011 Bansal (email: ravi.bansal@duke.edu) is affiliated with the Fuqua School of

More information

Discussion of "Real Exchange Rate, Real Interest Rates and the Risk Premium" by Charles Engel

Discussion of Real Exchange Rate, Real Interest Rates and the Risk Premium by Charles Engel Discussion of "Real Exchange Rate, Real Interest Rates and the Risk Premium" by Charles Engel Roland Straub European Central Bank Global Research Forum, Frankfurt, 17/12/2012 What is the paper about? 1/18

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: From factor models to asset pricing Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Solution to exercise 1 of problem

More information

Financial Ampli cation of Foreign Exchange Risk Premia 1

Financial Ampli cation of Foreign Exchange Risk Premia 1 Financial Ampli cation of Foreign Exchange Risk Premia 1 Tobias Adrian, Erkko Etula, Jan Groen Federal Reserve Bank of New York Brussels, July 23-24, 2010 Conference on Advances in International Macroeconomics

More information

Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates

Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates Martin Eichenbaum Ben Johannsen Sergio Rebelo Disclaimer: The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect

More information

Online Appendix: Conditional Risk Premia in Currency Markets and. Other Asset Classes. Martin Lettau, Matteo Maggiori, Michael Weber.

Online Appendix: Conditional Risk Premia in Currency Markets and. Other Asset Classes. Martin Lettau, Matteo Maggiori, Michael Weber. Online Appendix: Conditional Risk Premia in Currency Markets and Other Asset Classes Martin Lettau, Matteo Maggiori, Michael Weber. Not for Publication We include in this appendix a number of details and

More information