Arbitrage and Its Physical Limits

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Arbitrage and Its Physical Limits"

Transcription

1 Arbitrage and Its Physical Limits Louis H. Ederington Price College of Business, University of Oklahoma Chitru S. Fernando Price College of Business, University of Oklahoma Kateryna V. Holland Krannert School of Management, Purdue University Scott C. Linn Price College of Business, University of Oklahoma January 15, 2017 Abstract We examine how physical constraints limit arbitrage by studying the effect of crude oil storage constraints on arbitrage activity in the U.S. crude oil market. We document both temporary and long-term violations of the no-arbitrage conditions that are robustly attributable to storage capacity constraints. When crude oil storage levels are well below available storage capacity, temporary violations of the upper no-arbitrage bound occur but tend to be eliminated within a few days. However, as the amount of oil in storage approaches the capacity limit, the price adjustment process slows and violations of the upper no-arbitrage limit persist. We find evidence of temporary, but not long-term, violations of the lower no-arbitrage futures pricing bound, with the latter being consistent with our observation that there were no periods of stockout conditions during our sample period. We also find that arbitrage was limited by financial constraints over our sample period. However, the evidence in support of physical constraints impeding arbitrage is independently strong and remains robust when we control for the effect of financial constraints. Our results are also robust to the use of different measures of physical constraints. Our evidence further indicates that arbitrage normally impacts the spot price more than the futures price. Our findings highlight the importance of accounting for physical arbitrage limits in the pricing of commodity futures. We also contribute to the Theory of Storage literature by highlighting the consequences for prices when inventories approach storage capacity limits. JEL Classifications: law of one price, limits to arbitrage, commodity markets, oil futures markets, oil storage, physical constraints, cash-and-carry arbitrage. Keywords: G13, G18, Q41. Author contact information: Ederington: lederington@ou.edu, (405) ; Fernando: cfernando@ou.edu, (405) ; Holland: khollan@purdue.edu; (765) ; Linn: slinn@ou.edu (405) We thank Bruce Bawks, John Conti, Thomas Lee, Yongjia Li, Anthony May, Glen Sweetnam, John Zyren, and seminar participants at the U.S. Energy Information Administration, and the Second IEA IEF OPEC Workshop on the interactions between physical and financial energy markets for valuable discussions and comments. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the U.S. Department of Energy -- Energy Information Administration and the University of Oklahoma Office of the Vice President for Research. We also thank Moody s Analytics for making the company s EDF (Expected Default Frequency) data available to us and to Sue Zhang and Robert Tran for their gracious help in assembling the data. The views expressed in this paper reflect the opinions of the authors only, and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Energy Information Administration or the U.S. Department of Energy. The authors are solely responsible for all errors and omissions.

2 Arbitrage and Its Physical Limits Abstract We examine how physical constraints limit arbitrage by studying the effect of crude oil storage constraints on arbitrage activity in the U.S. crude oil market. We document both temporary and long-term violations of the no-arbitrage conditions that are robustly attributable to storage capacity constraints. When crude oil storage levels are well below available storage capacity, temporary violations of the upper no-arbitrage bound occur but tend to be eliminated within a few days. However, as the amount of oil in storage approaches the capacity limit, the price adjustment process slows and violations of the upper no-arbitrage limit persist. We find evidence of temporary, but not long-term, violations of the lower noarbitrage futures pricing bound, with the latter being consistent with our observation that there were no periods of stock-out conditions during our sample period. We also find that arbitrage was limited by financial constraints over our sample period. However, the evidence in support of physical constraints impeding arbitrage is independently strong and remains robust when we control for the effect of financial constraints. Our results are also robust to the use of different measures of physical constraints. Our evidence further indicates that arbitrage normally impacts the spot price more than the futures price. Our findings highlight the importance of accounting for physical arbitrage limits in the pricing of commodity futures. We also contribute to the Theory of Storage literature by highlighting the consequences for prices when inventories approach storage capacity limits. JEL Classifications: law of one price, limits to arbitrage, commodity markets, oil futures markets, oil storage, physical constraints, cash-and-carry arbitrage. Keywords: G13, G18, Q41. 2

3 Arbitrage and Its Physical Limits contango would have to widen much more to signal real storage distress. Spencer Jakab, Wall Street Journal, December 2, Introduction While the Law of One Price (LOP) is one of the most powerful concepts in the financial economics tool chest, a number of recent papers explore the financial limits to the arbitrage that enforces LOP, and the implications of these limits for asset pricing. 1 Physical limits, specifically limits on the availability of either inventory or storage capacity, are potentially equally important in the arbitrage pricing relationship for financial assets whose value is derived from the value of commodities. 2 While several recent studies have examined the role of financial limits to arbitrage in the pricing of commodity derivatives, 3 the potential effect of physical limits has not been empirically studied. In this paper, we address this gap in the literature by studying the effect of physical storage limits on arbitrage activity in the U.S. crude oil market. We specifically focus on the futures physical delivery hub at Cushing, Oklahoma, which is also the major storage center in the U.S. for crude oil. We draw inferences through an examination of the behavior of the spread between futures and spot prices for West Texas Intermediate (WTI) crude oil. In commodity markets, if the price of a commodity for future delivery exceeds the price for near-term delivery by more than the carrying (including storage) and transaction costs, arbitrageurs should be able to make a riskless profit by simultaneously executing contracts to buy in the spot market and sell in the forward market, while storing the commodity over the interim period. Exploitation of such an arbitrage opportunity, commonly referred to as cash-and-carry arbitrage, results in the now familiar relation between futures and spot prices derived from the Theory of Storage. 4 More precisely, cash-and-carry 1 See, for example, Shleifer and Vishny (1997), Gromb and Vayanos (2002), Mitchell, Pulvino and Stafford (2002), Hong and Stein (2003), Gabaix, Krishnamurthy, and Vigneron (2007), Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), Etula (2013), and Acharya, Lochstoer, and Ramadorai (2013). 2 See Routledge, Seppi, and Spatt (2000) and Gorton, Hayashi, and Rouwenhorst (2013). 3 See, for example, Mou (2010), Hong and Yogo (2012), Etula (2013), Acharya, Lochstoer, and Ramadorai (2013), and Cheng, Kirilenko, and Xiong (2015). 4 Kaldor (1939), Working (1949), Brennan (1958), Deaton and Laroque (1992), and Routledge, Seppi, and Spatt (2000). 3

4 arbitrage should place an upper limit on the spread between the price for near-term delivery, the spot price, 5 and the price for longer-term delivery, henceforth the futures price. Likewise, the possibility of reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage, which involves a short sale in the spot market covered by a purchase in the forward market, should set a lower limit on the futures-spot spread. In many commodity markets, however, storage capacity is limited -- especially at the delivery location for the futures contract. Once all available storage facilities are full (or, in the case of reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage, the available inventory is depleted), the corresponding arbitrage described above is no longer possible and the noarbitrage limits on the futures-spot spread should no longer hold. In a classical cash-and-carry arbitrage transaction involving a physical commodity at a spot-futures market hub like the WTI Cushing hub, the arbitrageur will execute three simultaneous transactions: (1) purchase the commodity in the spot market; (2) sell a corresponding quantity of the commodity in the futures market; and (3) contract to store the commodity at the hub until the futures transaction is closed out or settled. The ability to execute this trade depends on the availability of storage space at the hub. 6 If storage capacity or inventory is not immediately available, violations of the no-arbitrage condition may persist until storage becomes available. Storage contracts are typically over-the-counter agreements and thus may require some time to arrange. Moreover, they have elements of counterparty risk, such as force majeure and physical delivery default that are not present in purely financial arbitrage trades. These elements may discourage or delay the actions necessary to implement the arbitrage trades. If delayed, spreads above the no-arbitrage limit may persist until storage can be arranged. Consequently, the physical limits to executing an arbitrage may contribute to the persistence of futures-spot spread no-arbitrage violations above and beyond the limits imposed by financial constraints. 5 As discussed below, contracts in the crude-oil market are normally for delivery over a month since (unlike for commodities like gold) immediate spot delivery of large quantities of oil is very difficult and expensive. For futures contracts held to physical delivery, the CME group allows one calendar month for the oil to be delivered to the Cushing hub. Hence the quoted spot prices are normally forward or futures prices for delivery over the nearest calendar month. Contracts for immediate delivery are rare and typically for small quantities that can be moved by tanker truck. Despite the absence of immediate spot delivery in this market, we keep with convention by using the term spot price to refer to the settlement price for near-term-delivery contracts. 6 In a reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage transaction, the arbitrageur will simultaneously (1) borrow and sell the commodity in the spot market; and (2) purchase a corresponding quantity of the commodity in the futures market. The ability to execute this contract depends on the availability of inventory at the hub that can be borrowed. 4

5 We find evidence of both short- and long-term violations of the no-arbitrage conditions in the U.S. crude oil futures market at the WTI Cushing hub. Consistent with the argument that often storage cannot be arranged immediately, we find evidence of numerous temporary violations of the no-arbitrage upper bound. When storage levels are well below capacity, these temporary violations tend to be eliminated quickly, i.e., within a couple of days. However, as the amount of oil stored approaches the available capacity, the adjustment process takes longer and violations of the upper no-arbitrage limit persist for longer than a few days. In contrast, we observe only temporary violations of the no-arbitrage lower bound indicating the absence of persistent physical limits on reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage. Our finding for reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage is consistent with the absence of any periods of inventory stock-out conditions during our sample period, with crude oil inventory in storage never dropping below 30% of available storage capacity. Our evidence further indicates that the spot price adjusts more than the futures price in bringing the spread back within the noarbitrage bounds, which again points to physical arbitrage limits being a major factor determining the mispricing of the futures-spot spread. Testing for violations of the no-arbitrage conditions is complicated because we are unable to exactly identify the no-arbitrage limits at each point in time since (as discussed below) historical data on storage and transaction costs are not available. Hence, we test for evidence of cash-and-carry and reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage by examining the behavior of the futures-spot spread. We find evidence of both cash-and-carry arbitrage and reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage normally operating to return the futures-spot spread to within noarbitrage bounds. When the futures-spot spread is positive on day t-2 and rises further on day t-1 (and storage capacity is not exhausted), there is a strong tendency for the spread to fall on day t which is what we would expect if the further rise in the spread on day t-1 sets off cashand-carry arbitrage. This reversal tendency is stronger when the spread on day t-2 is high than when it is positive but low. This is again what we would expect since the further rise on day t-1 is more likely to raise the spread above the upper no-arbitrage bound if the spread is already very high. Likewise, if the spread on day t-2 is negative and the spread declines further on day t-1, there is a strong tendency for the spread to rise or reverse on day t. Again, this is what one would expect if the further decline in the spread on day t-1 triggers reverse 5

6 cash-and-carry arbitrage and this reversal tendency is stronger the more negative is the spread on day t-2. Both of these spread reversal tendencies are stronger when spread volatility is high. In contrast, if the level of the spread on day t-2 and the change on day t-1 are of opposite sign, making it less likely that the change in the spread on day t-1 carried it outside the no-arbitrage bound, the spread changes on days t-1 and t are basically uncorrelated. While normally a further rise in the spread on day t-1 from an already high level on day t-2 tends to be reversed on day t, this is not the case when oil inventories are close to capacity, which indicates that the lack of available storage space hinders the cash-and-carry arbitrage which would normally operate to pull the spread back down on day t. On the other hand, as alluded to previously, we find no evidence that reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage is impeded by low inventories. We also examine possible financial limits to arbitrage in the WTI crude oil market concurrently with measures of physical limits to arbitrage. The importance of financial limits to arbitrage in the oil market is highlighted by Acharya, Lochstoer, and Ramadorai (2013). 7 Those authors document the effect on futures and spot prices when producers hedging demand in the futures market is not fully met due to broker-dealer capital constraints. We also present evidence that arbitrage was restricted by financial constraints over our sample period. However, the evidence in support of physical constraints impeding arbitrage is considerably stronger and remains robust when we control for the effect of the financial constraint measures we examine. While Acharya, Lochstoer, and Ramadorai (2013) emphasize the importance of an inventory stock-out in giving rise to commodity sector default risk, there is no significant oil inventory stock-out that occurs in the period of our study. In contrast, our study highlights the role played by the unavailability of storage capacity due to high inventory levels as the cause of a decoupling between the futures and spot market in oil, an event that occurs several times during our sample period. Therefore, our study builds on the existing literature on the financial limits to arbitrage in commodity markets by also establishing the importance of the physical limits to arbitrage in these markets. We therefore provide a more complete picture of the role that limits to 7 Birge, Hortacsu, and Mercadal (2016) show that financial constraints impede arbitrage in electricity markets. 6

7 arbitrage, both physical limits as well as financial limits, play in the pricing of commodity futures. We contribute to the literature on the Theory of Storage by examining the effect of inventory storage capacity limits. The existing literature has focused on the effect of stockouts when inventories are very low with little or no attention to the possible pricing effects when inventories are very high and storage capacity becomes limited or is exhausted. For instance, Routledge, Seppi, and Spatt (2000), who explore the consequences of the nonnegativity inventory constraint for forward and futures prices, write, Inventory can always be added to keep current spot prices from being too low relative to expected future spot prices. We contribute to this literature by exploring the price consequences when inventories approach storage capacity limits so that additional inventory cannot be added. Modeling inventories as buffers to supply and demand shocks, Deaton and Laroque (1992) show that the increase in the risk of an inventory stock-out when inventories are low carries through to an increase in expected future spot price volatility. Routledge, Seppi, and Spatt (2000) extend the Deaton and Laroque (1992) model by including a forward market and show that inventory stock-outs can break the arbitrage link between the spot and forward markets. Similarly, we show that when storage capacity is limited or exhausted, the commodity s spot price will also be decoupled from the forward price. Therefore, in the case of both inventory stockouts and full storage situations, the arbitrage pricing relation between forward and spot prices will break down. Additionally, consistent with the Theory of Storage, we find that when inventories are neither very high nor very low, arbitrage restores the futures-spot spread to its no-arbitrage bounds following temporary violations. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In the next section, we discuss arbitrage and storage in the crude oil market and develop our primary hypotheses. The data is described and basic results are presented in section 3, where we test for how the market responds to temporary violations of the no-arbitrage limits and present evidence that violations of the upper limit persist as storage approaches full capacity. In section 4, we explore how reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage enforces the lower no-arbitrage limit on the spread and whether this spread enforcing arbitrage is hindered when available oil inventories are low. In section 5, we expand the analysis to consider financial as well as physical limits 7

8 to arbitrage. In section 6, we examine how spot and futures prices change due to arbitrage and ask whether arbitrage impacts primarily the spot price, primarily the futures price, or both. Various robustness checks are presented in section 7, and section 8 concludes. 2. Oil market arbitrage and storage 2.1. No arbitrage spread conditions in the oil market Consider the limits that arbitrage places on the futures-spot and futures-futures spreads at the crude oil futures contract delivery/pricing hub assuming that storage is available for lease at the hub location. 8 Let Pt,t+v designate the price at time t for delivery at time t+v and Pt,t+s represent the time t price for delivery at time t+s where s>v. If t+v is the first available delivery time, Pt,t+v may be referred to as the spot price and Pt,t+s-Pt,t+v as the futures-spot spread. We will follow that convention here. Since large quantities of crude oil cannot be delivered instantaneously, virtually all physical delivery contracts in the crude oil market, including spot contracts, are contracts for delivery over a future period of time generally one month (Kaminski, 2012). For futures contracts held to physical delivery, the CME group allows one calendar month for the oil to be delivered to the Cushing hub. For example, suppose the current month is June. The three-month futures contract will be the contract that, if held to expiration, will result in physical delivery of crude oil commencing September 1 and ending on or before September 30. Similarly, delivery on the two-month futures contract will occur from August In the case of the spot contract traded in the month of June, physical delivery of crude oil will commence July 1 and end on or before July 31. Hence by convention the quoted spot prices in the crude oil market are typically prices for delivery over the nearest forward calendar month. 9 Contracts that stipulate physical delivery over shorter periods, including immediate physical delivery, are rare and typically for small quantities that can be moved by tanker truck. 8 More generally, storage may also be available at remote locations, in which case the availability of such remote storage will be determined by both storage and transportation constraints. 9 The CME group stipulates several methods by which the buyer can opt to receive physical delivery. At the buyer's option, delivery can be made by: (1) by inter-facility transfer ("pumpover") into a designated pipeline or storage facility with access to seller's incoming pipeline or storage facility; (2) by in-line (or in-system) transfer, or book-out of title to the buyer; or (3) if the seller agrees to such transfer and if the facility used by the seller allows for such transfer, without physical movement of product, by in-tank transfer of title to the buyer. Especially with the third option, physical delivery will effectively be instantaneous and subject only to the provision that the buyer has acquired the right to store oil in the tank/s used previously by the seller. 8

9 Let SCt,t+v,t+s represent the present value as of time t of the cost of storing one unit of the commodity from time t+v to t+s including transaction costs on the futures trades. 10 Let CVt,t+v,t+s designate the (assumed known) present value as of time t of the convenience yield from holding physical units of the commodity from time t+v to t+s. If Pt,t+s > [Pt,t+v + SCt,t+v.t+s CVt,t+v,t+s](1+rt,t+v,t+s) where rt,t+v,t+s is the interest rate from t+v to t+s, arbitrageurs can earn a riskless profit by simultaneously: (1) buying the near-term contract Pt,t+v, (2) shorting the longer term contract Pt,t+s, and (3) assuming storage capacity is available, arranging for storage from t+v to t+s. 11 An implicit assumption is that funding of the transaction is not constrained, which we will relax in the analysis presented in section 5. As arbitrageurs transact to capture the riskless profit, Pt,t+v should rise and Pt,t+s fall until Pt,t+s [Pt,t+v + SCt,t+v.t+s CVt,t+v,t+s](1+rt,t+v,t+s). Hence this arbitrage should ensure that: [Pt,t+s -Pt,t+v] [Pt,t+vrt,t+v,t+s + (SCt,t+v.t+s CVt,t+v,t+s)(1+rt,t+v,t+s)] (1) Ederington, Fernando, Holland, Lee, and Linn (2016) provide strong evidence in support of this arbitrage relationship for U.S. crude oil futures at the Cushing delivery point. Assuming trades and storage can be contracted the instant violations of equation 1 are observed, violations of equation 1 should be fleeting and only observable in high frequency data. However, if storage takes time to arrange (as explored in section 2.2 below), violations of equation 1 could arise but be temporary. If storage cannot be arranged immediately, a trader pursuing riskless arbitrage would need to wait to arbitrage the mispricing between the spot and futures contracts until storage becomes available. 12 In the latter case, the spread may continue to exceed the no-arbitrage upper bound in equation 1 until sufficient storage capacity becomes available. Assuming storage can be arranged, any temporary violation of 10 For ease of exposition, we disregard the possibility of storage at a location away from the hub, in which case any transportation costs between the delivery points for the t+v and t+s contracts need to be added to the transaction costs. 11 This trade is not completely riskless if the convenience yield is uncertain. For pedagogical simplicity we allow future storage costs to be uncertain but treat the convenience yield as uncertain but effect of uncertainty regarding either is basically the same. Nonetheless, risk cannot be completely eliminated due to physical and financial performance risk. 12 Speculators could execute a naked speculative transaction involving only the spot and futures trades, hoping that storage can be arranged in the future on terms that would not eliminate arbitrage profit. However, such transactions are not riskless. Ederington et al. (2016) show that most cash-and-carry arbitrage transactions in this market tend to be riskless. 9

10 equation 1 should be followed by a fall in the spread as arbitrage trades take place. 13 However if storage is at capacity, violations of equation 1 can persist. Our treatment of SCt,t+v.t+s in equation 1 warrants clarification. We recognize that both SCt,t+v.t+s and CVt,t+v,t+s are endogenous. In particular, as discussed below, SCt,t+v.t+s will tend to rise and CVt,t+v,t+s will tend to fall as inventories increase. Thus, it could be argued that if storage cannot be arranged immediately, the cost of storage is effectively infinite so that equation 1 always holds but this is void of any predictive content. To obtain predictive hypotheses, when we refer to equation 1 being violated, we are treating SCt,t+v.t+s as the cost of storage when it can be arranged. We next examine the no-arbitrage lower bound. Consider a trader who holds the commodity in inventory. If Pt,t+s < [Pt,t+v + SCSt,t+v.t+s CVt,t+v,t+s](1+rt,t+v,t+s) where SCSt,t+v,t+s is the saving on storage costs by not storing oil from t+v to t+s minus transaction costs, the trader can profit by simultaneously: (1) selling the oil for delivery at time t+v at Pt,t+v and (2) purchasing for delivery at time t+s for Pt,t+s. This frees up storage from time t+v to t+s. If alternative uses for the storage can be arranged immediately or SCSt,t+v,t+s is known, this arbitrage is riskless and arbitrage should ensure that: [Pt,t+s -Pt,t+v] [Pt,t+vrt,t+v,t+s + (SCSt,t+v.t+s CVt,t+v,t+s)(1+rt,t+v,t+s)] (2) Note that this lower bound on the spread may be either positive or negative. 14 If alternative storage uses cannot be arranged immediately and SCSt,t+v,t+s is uncertain, this trade is risky unless the trades are delayed until alternative uses for the storage have been arranged. Therefore, it is possible that inequality (2) is violated temporarily. If inventories are depleted so that there is no oil to sell for delivery at time t+v, then the violation of equation 2 may persist longer. 13 Additionally, temporary violations of arbitrage bounds could occur because of inattentive traders (Duffie, 2010) or lack of sufficient financial traders in the market, which is also inhabited by physical traders who have traditionally dominated the market. 14 In commodity futures market analyses, it is sometimes assumed that (1) transaction costs are negligible, and (2) any storage costs can be completely recaptured if the storage is not used so that SCS t,t+v,t+s = SC t,t+v,t+s and hence [P t,t+s -P t,t+v] = [P t,t+vr t,t+v,t+s + (SC t,t+v.t+s CV t,t+v,t+s)(1+r t,t+v,t+s)]. However we argue in section 2.2 below that in commodity markets, and crude oil in particular, SCS t,t+v,t+s is generally less than SC t,t+v,t+s either because transaction costs are not negligible or because storage costs cannot be totally recouped if the storage is unused. Hence there is normally a gap between the upper and lower spread limits in equations 1 and 2. 10

11 2.2. Storage and storage costs If oil is purchased for delivery at time t+s and sold for delivery at time t+v in a cashand-carry arbitrage, storage must be arranged for the time period between t+s and t+v. Since the availability and cost of storage are important to our analysis, it is helpful to summarize relevant characteristics of crude oil storage. Once produced, crude oil may be stored in tank farms, underground caverns, refineries, and pipelines, or off-shore in tankers. Particularly important for our purpose are storage levels and costs at the pricing point and delivery hub for the WTI futures contract, which is in Cushing, Oklahoma. Ederington et al. (2016) find that most arbitrage in the WTI crude oil market entails Cushing oil inventories. The U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA) estimates the working capacity of tank farms in the U.S. at million barrels as of September 2015 of which 73 million barrels, or 18.0%, are at Cushing, making it the largest oil storage facility in the world (EIA, 2015, ). Cushing, labeled the pipeline capital of the world, is connected to crude oil production facilities and oil refineries throughout the United States through an extensive pipeline network. Oil is stored in Cushing for operational, arbitrage, and speculative purposes. While anecdotal and media reports appear from time to time about investment banks and other oil traders leasing storage at Cushing for arbitrage and speculative purposes (see, for example, Leff, 2015), hard data is unavailable. However according to the EIA, in spring 2015 approximately 80% of the storage at Cushing was leased by the owner-operators to others while the percentage leased to others at other tank farms in the U.S. was only about 29%. Storage away from Cushing entails additional transportation costs or additional risk to arbitrage using crude oil futures since the delivery point for the NYMEX oil futures contract is Cushing. 15 This suggests that much of the storage at Cushing is leased for arbitrage or speculative purposes. Storage capacity at Cushing has grown considerably over the last decade. The EIA reports that working capacity increased from 46.0 million barrels in September 2010 to 71.4 million in March Capacity figures prior to 2010 are unavailable but the maximum held in storage prior to January 2006 was only 22.8 million barrels. The business media commonly attribute at least 15 Nonetheless, the press has published articles describing crude oil being stored on floating tankers in conjunction with arbitrage trades (See, for example, Kent and Kantchev, 2015). However, a precise time series of tanker storage data is not available. 11

12 some of this storage construction to demand for storage by WTI futures traders (see, for example, Blas, 2015, and Kaufman, 2015). Storage contracts at Cushing and elsewhere are typically over-the-counter and thus may require some time to arrange. 16 Moreover, they have counterparty risk, force majeure and physical delivery risk elements that are not present in purely financial arbitrage trades, which may discourage or delay the actions necessary to implement the arbitrage trades. If delayed, spreads above the no-arbitrage limit may persist until storage can be arranged. 17 Unfortunately, historical figures for the storage cost measures SCt,t+v,t+s and SCSt,t+v,t+s are unavailable so we cannot directly test for violations of equations 1 and 2. Instead, as explained below, we test for indirect evidence of violations and consequent market corrections by examining changes in the futures-spot spread. Average crude oil storage costs at Cushing are commonly estimated around $0.40 to $0.50 per barrel per month but reportedly vary considerably depending on capacity utilization. 18 If a trader wants to execute an arbitrage transaction but has not yet leased storage capacity, the cost to him is the storage cost per barrel stated in the new lease. If a trader has already leased storage, what matters to him in considering a particular arbitrage possibility is the storage unit s opportunity cost, which will vary with capacity utilization and quite possibly across individual traders. Consider, for instance, a trader who has leased storage capacity for a year at $0.50 a barrel/month. After the lease is signed, the $0.50 becomes a sunk cost and what then matters is the marginal opportunity cost of using the storage capacity. Depending on whether it is possible to re-lease the unused storage capacity, this marginal opportunity cost may vary from zero to the re-lease rate. Moreover the unused storage has an option value. If the trader institutes a cash and carry arbitrage as soon as the spread widens sufficiently to make the arbitrage profitable and hence fills his storage units to capacity, he loses the option to conduct the arbitrage on even more favorable terms in the future if spreads should widen 16 The CME has recently launched an oil storage futures contract at the Louisiana Offshore Port but not as yet for storage at Cushing. 17 Faced with an apparently profitable futures-spot spread that exceeds expected storage costs, some traders may trade the futures and spot immediately. In doing so, they accept the risk that storage cannot be arranged or will be more expensive than anticipated and the trade will remain a speculation unless and until the exposure is covered in the physical market. 18 Private communication with a company specializing in oil and petroleum product storage confirms that the typical price has been about $.50/barrel per month but that the cost increases whenever the market is in contango, suggesting those are periods in which demand for storage capacity is high. 12

13 further. Thus, in this case, SCt,t+v,t+s is hard to measure and may vary across traders but undoubtedly varies positively with capacity utilization. While storage costs likely vary positively with capacity utilization, the convenience yield likely varies inversely as Einloth (2009), Gorton, Hayashi, and Rouwenhorst (2013) and others point out, reinforcing the tendency for the upper no-arbitrage bound in equation 1 to vary positively with capacity utilization levels. Gorton, Hayashi, and Rouwenhorst (2013) argue that the convenience yield in commodity futures should vary inversely with inventory levels since low inventory levels increase price volatility. Consistent with this, using data for 33 commodity markets, they find that: 1) the cash-futures basis is an inverse function of inventory levels, and 2) returns to a strategy of holding long futures positions are positive and inversely correlated with inventory levels. Turning to reverse-cash-and-carry arbitrage, the storage cost savings if the trader draws down his inventory, SCSt,t+v,t+s, depend on whether the storage tank can be re-leased or used for other purposes since he will pay the storage cost per barrel of leased capacity whether he has oil stored or not. If it cannot be re-leased, SCSt,t+v,t+s is zero. Since we hypothesize that arbitrage possibilities are limited by available storage capacity and that storage costs vary directly with capacity utilization, we need measures of both actual storage levels and storage capacity at Cushing. Since the EIA began reporting actual weekly Cushing storage levels in April 2004, our data period begins April 5, The EIA began surveying and reporting storage capacity figures semi-annually in September Since the EIA s capacity figures cover only the latter third of our data period and only estimate shell and working capacity, not effective capacity, we use as our primary proxy for effective capacity a measure based on historical peaks in actual storage. In Figure 1, we chart Cushing estimated working storage capacity levels and actual storage levels from April 2004 to April 2015 on a logarithmic scale. ***Insert Figure 1 about here*** Searching for the lowest number of peaks or inflection points for a linear spline 19 Prior to that time the Cushing figures were lumped into those for the Midwest region. 20 The EIA reports both shell capacity and working capacity where the latter lower figure adjusts for the fact that oil at the bottom of the tank is not obtainable and that the tanks cannot be filled to the very top. Both the EIA and others stress that the unknown effective capacity is less than either figure since some space is required for effective operation. 13

14 function, which bounds all observed storage levels with inflection points at the chosen peaks, yields the linear spline with peaks at 4/18/2005, 2/2/2009, 1/4/2013, and 4/3/2015 shown as the solid blue line in Figure 1 where we also graph actual storage levels. We use this log linear function as our initial and primary proxy for computing effective storage capacity. In section 7, we also use the EIA measures of working capacity for the October 2010 April 2015 sub-period for which these figures are available Storage and spreads Initial evidence According to the analysis in section 2.l, large positive spreads between the prices of contracts for longer-term and near-term delivery should only persist when storage levels approach capacity so that arbitrageurs find it difficult or impossible to arrange storage. Initial evidence on this is presented in Figure 2 where we chart 10-day moving averages of both capacity utilization and the futures-spot spread. ***Insert Figure 2 about here*** Capacity utilization is measured as the ratio of the actual level of crude oil stocks as reported by the EIA to the proxy for effective storage capacity described in section 2.2. The futures-spot spread in Figure 2 is measured as the difference between the price of the second and nearby futures contracts. As predicted, Figure 2 shows that large positive futures-spot spreads are generally associated with high levels of capacity utilization Hypotheses While Figure 2 indicates that high futures-spot spreads are generally associated with high levels of capacity utilization, this does not necessarily indicate that physical limits to arbitrage were a constraint since other factors could account for the correlation in Figure 2. For instance, an unexpected short-term decline in the demand for crude oil which is not expected to persist could lead to both an increase in crude oil inventories and a disproportionate decline in the spot price, and therefore an increase in the spread. For further evidence on the effect of arbitrage and its limits, we analyze the behavior of the futures-spot spread across time. Ideally, if we could observe the storage cost and convenience yield terms, SCt,t+v,t+s, SCSt,t+v,t+s, and CVt,t+v,t+s, in equations 1 and 2, we could 14

15 explore how they change as storage levels approach capacity and test for violations of equations 1 and 2. However, as explained in section 2.2 those data are unobservable. Consequently, we test for arbitrage and its limits based on the behavior of the futures-spot spread. Consider the implications of the analysis in section 2.1 for the behavior of the futuresspot spread. As long as the futures-spot spread is between the upper bound defined by equation 1 and the lower bound defined by equation 2, arbitrage should not occur. In this case, if markets are weak form efficient and news arrives randomly, the change in the spread one day should be independent of previous spread changes. However, if a change in the spread in period t-1 carries the spread above the no-arbitrage bound, this should set off arbitrage in which arbitrageurs buy for delivery in the near-term and sell for delivery in the longer-term resulting in a decline in the spread in period t. Likewise, a fall in the spread below the no-arbitrage upper bound in period t-1 should set off arbitrage that raises the spread in period t. Thus, we expect successive changes in the spread to be uncorrelated within the upper and lower no-arbitrage bounds and negatively correlated outside the noarbitrage bounds. Testing for evidence of arbitrage based on spread autocorrelations is complicated by the fact that we cannot observe storage costs, transaction costs, the convenience yield, or the storage cost savings when storage levels are reduced, and so we cannot compute the upper and lower no-arbitrage bounds. However, we expect storage costs to vary directly and the convenience yield to vary inversely with storage capacity utilization and thus, the upper bound should rise as capacity utilization rises. In addition, for given values of the noarbitrage bounds, the likelihood that a change in the spread leads to a violation of the upper or lower bounds should depend on the sign and size of both the change in the spread and its 15

16 prior level. 21 For instance, suppose the period t-1 change in the spread is positive. In this case, it is more likely that it crosses the upper bound and thus leads to a fall in the spread in period t if the spread level at the beginning of period t-1 is positive and high than if the spread at the beginning of period t-1 is negative or low. Likewise, a given decline in the spread in period t-1 is more likely to cross the lower bound, and thus lead to a rise in period t, if the spread at the beginning of period t is already negative or low. This leads to our first hypothesis: H1: If there are no limits to arbitrage, an increase (decrease) in the futures-spot spread should be more likely to lead to arbitrage and a subsequent fall (rise) in the spread if the spread is already high (low). It is not clear a priori whether we should observe this predicted autocorrelation pattern in weekly, daily, hourly, or higher frequency data. If the arbitrage can be arranged almost instantaneously, then we should observe these patterns only in high frequency data if at all. However, we have argued above in sections 2.1 and 2.2 that, when the spread rises above the upper bound, risk or the inability to arrange storage may lead arbitrageurs to delay going long in the near-term contract and shorting the longer-term contract until they can contract for storage. Thus it may take hours or days until the spread change reverses. We test for arbitrage patterns in daily data. We have argued above that there are likely physical limits to arbitrage. When storage is near capacity, both storage costs and the lead time required to contract storage will likely increase. Given these difficulties in storage contracting when storage is near capacity, a 21 To see this, suppose the upper bound is fixed and equal to U. Suppose also that at t-1 the actual spread equals A. The distance to U therefore equals U-A. The narrower the gap the smaller is the required change in the spread before the upper bound is breached. Assume arbitrage opportunities arrive randomly (that is the change in the spread arrives randomly each period) and that the size of the change is a drawing from a stationary distribution with mean 0 and constant variance. The probability that U will be breached given U and A equals the probability that the change will exceed U-A. To illustrate, suppose the change in the spread is a drawing 2 U A from a N(0, ) distribution. Therefore, the probability that the change will breach U equals Pr z, which is increasing in A since U is fixed. Conditional on the change equaling an arbitrary value P, the probability evaluated at t-1 equals Pr U A P z 16 which is increasing in P given U and A.

17 spread change reversing arbitrage is less likely, implying lower first-order autocorrelation. This leads to our second hypothesis: H2: When storage levels are at or near capacity, cash-and-carry arbitrage is more costly or difficult, thus if the futures-spot spread is positive and high, a further increase in the spread is less likely to be followed by arbitrage and a reversal in the spread. Similarly, if there is an inventory stockout or if inventories are at the minimum required for operational purposes, reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage, in which arbitrageurs sell from inventory in the spot market, cannot occur, leading to our third hypothesis: H3: When tradeable inventory levels are at or near zero, reverse cash-and-carry arbitrage is more costly or difficult, thus if the futures-spot spread is negative and low, a further decrease in the spread is less likely to be followed by arbitrage and a reversal in the spread. 3. Results 3.1. Data description and initial evidence. While futures and spot price data are available from 1983, our data period begins in April 2004 when the EIA began reporting crude oil stock levels at Cushing. We examine daily prices of NYMEX WTI crude oil futures contracts from April through May 6, 2015 obtained from the website of the Energy Information Administration. Descriptive statistics for the futures-spot spread measured as the difference between the prices of the second and nearby contracts are presented in Table 1 for both the level and daily changes in the spread. ***Insert Table 1 about here*** Interestingly, while Schwartz (1997) and Routledge, Seppi, and Spatt (2000) argue that in this market backwardation should be more common than contango, the market actually tended to be in contango over much of this period with the spread averaging $0.52, as shown in Panel A. The spread was positive on 76.5% of the observed days. With a standard deviation of $0.39, daily changes in the spread were fairly large. 17

18 Partial autocorrelations out to a four-day lag are reported in Panel B for both the spread and its components. Several patterns are worth noting. First, consistent with our arbitrage argument, there is evidence of fairly strong mean reversion with a first order autocorrelation of between changes on successive days. Clearly, there is a tendency for increases and decreases in the spread to be partially reversed on subsequent days. In the absence of arbitrage, this would seem to violate weak-form efficiency. Second, the spread displays considerably more mean reversion than either of its two components. The first order autocorrelation for the futures and spot price changes are only and respectively. This indicates that the mean reversion of the spread is not simply a reflection of mean reversion in the spot and futures prices due to some other cause such as bid-ask bounce. Third, while the first-order autocorrelation in spread changes is clearly the largest, there is also evidence of negative partial correlation at lags of two and three days. As we discussed above, it is unclear a priori how long it would take arbitrageurs to contract storage and thus how quickly arbitrage should reverse violations of the no-arbitrage bounds. If indeed the mean reversion observed in the spread is due to arbitrage, this indicates that most of the reversal takes place in one day but that full reversal may take several days Testing for evidence of arbitrage activity and physical limits to arbitrage According to the arbitrage hypothesis, mean reversion in the spread should be observed only when the change in the spread crosses the no-arbitrage bounds and then only if arranging the arbitrage transactions occurs with a lag. As long as the spread is fluctuating within the no-arbitrage bounds, weak form efficiency implies that there should be little, if any, autocorrelation. As discussed above, testing is complicated by the difficulty in measuring the no-arbitrage bounds. However, as we argued in section 2.4 and H1, an increase in the spread in period t-1 is more likely to cross the no-arbitrage upper bound, and thus lead to mean reversion in period t, if the spread is already positive and high than if it is negative or low. Likewise, a negative change in the spread is more likely to cross the noarbitrage lower bound leading to mean reversion if the spread is already low. To test this, we examine variations of a simple regression ΔSPt = β0 + β1δspt-1+et, The estimated β 1 = which is significant at the 1% level based on Newey-West standard errors. 18

19 where ΔSPt = SPt SPt-1 and SPt = Ft St with Ft being the futures price on day t and St being the spot price. We consider several variations. First, we divide the sample into (1) cases when the change in the spread and the beginning spread have the same sign and (2) cases when they have different signs. We define DSamet-1 =1 if ΔSPt-1*SPt-2 >0 and =0 otherwise. Thus DSamet-1 =1 if a positive spread at time t-2 is followed by a further increase in the spread at time t-1 or if a negative spread at time t-2 is followed by a further decrease at time t-1, i.e. if the spread at time t-2 and the change in day t-1 have the same sign. We define DDifft-1 =1-DSamet-1. Thus DDifft-1=1 if ΔSPt-1*SPt-2 <=0, i.e., if the spread change on day t- 1 is opposite in sign to the spread on day t-2. As reported in Table 2 DDifft-1=1 is slightly more common than DSamet-1=1 since it includes the cases when ΔSPt-1 or SPt-2 are zero. ***Insert Table 2 about here*** Second, we separate those cases when the change in the spread (at time t-1) and the beginning spread (at time t-2) have the same sign into two groups: contango, where both signs are positive (so that the upper bound might be violated) and backwardations, where both signs are negative (or zero) (so that the lower bound might be violated). DPost-1=1 if SPt-2>0 and ΔSPt-1>0 and zero otherwise and DNegt-1=1 if SPt-2<0 and ΔSPt-1<0 and zero otherwise. Table 2 shows that during our sample period DPos is more common than DNeg. Third, given that the spread is positive and in contango for 76.5% of the observations in our sample, we further divide the set when a positive spread is followed by a further increase in the spread into: (1) those cases when the time t-2 spread is positive but less than $0.50 and (2) those cases when the time t-2 spread is positive and greater than $0.50. We choose $0.50 since this is a common estimate of storage costs and since the median spread is $0.45. Specifically, we take cases where the spread is positive (SPt-2>0) and the change in spread is positive (ΔSPt-1>0) and define DPosLowt-1=1 if the spread is between 0 and $0.50, 0<SPt-2<=0.50, and zero otherwise and DPosHight-1=1 if the spread is above $0.5 (SPt-2>0.5) and zero otherwise. Fourth, we consider instances of contango where the spread is more likely to provide opportunities for arbitrage (positive, increasing and above $0.50) but storage capacity is exhausted. To test this, we define the dummy variable DCap_Utilt=1 if the ratio of actual Cushing storage levels announced by the EIA for that week divided by our estimate of 19

Oxford Energy Comment March 2009

Oxford Energy Comment March 2009 Oxford Energy Comment March 2009 Reinforcing Feedbacks, Time Spreads and Oil Prices By Bassam Fattouh 1 1. Introduction One of the very interesting features in the recent behaviour of crude oil prices

More information

Can LOOP Ever Be a Gulf Coast Cushing? Part 2 Searching for a sour crude benchmark.

Can LOOP Ever Be a Gulf Coast Cushing? Part 2 Searching for a sour crude benchmark. ? Can LOOP Ever Be a Gulf Coast Cushing? Part 2 Searching for a sour crude benchmark. Morningstar Commodities Research 10 April 2017 Sandy Fielden Director, Oil and Products Research +1 512 431-8044 sandy.fielden@morningstar.com

More information

United States Petroleum January 28, 2017

United States Petroleum January 28, 2017 United States Petroleum January 28, 2017 Background U.S. petroleum, crude and refined, transitions from a negative seasonal trend in late December to positive seasonal trend in late January and early February.

More information

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks Li Jing and Henry Thompson 2010 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/20654/ MPRA Paper No. 20654, posted 13. February

More information

Commodity convenience yield and risk premium determination: The case of the U.S. natural gas market

Commodity convenience yield and risk premium determination: The case of the U.S. natural gas market Energy Economics 28 (2006) 523 534 www.elsevier.com/locate/eneco Commodity convenience yield and risk premium determination: The case of the U.S. natural gas market Song Zan Chiou Wei a,1,2, Zhen Zhu b,c,

More information

Speculative Floating Oil

Speculative Floating Oil Speculative Floating Oil A. Kirilenko 1 A. Kruglova 2 1 Centre for Global Finance and Technology Imperial College Business School 2 MIT Center for Finance and Policy 1 Eastern Conference on Mathematical

More information

A GLOSSARY OF FINANCIAL TERMS MICHAEL J. SHARPE, MATHEMATICS DEPARTMENT, UCSD

A GLOSSARY OF FINANCIAL TERMS MICHAEL J. SHARPE, MATHEMATICS DEPARTMENT, UCSD A GLOSSARY OF FINANCIAL TERMS MICHAEL J. SHARPE, MATHEMATICS DEPARTMENT, UCSD 1. INTRODUCTION This document lays out some of the basic definitions of terms used in financial markets. First of all, the

More information

ROLL RELATED RETURN IN THE S&P GSCI EXCESS RETURN INDEX DI HU

ROLL RELATED RETURN IN THE S&P GSCI EXCESS RETURN INDEX DI HU ROLL RELATED RETURN IN THE S&P GSCI EXCESS RETURN INDEX BY DI HU THESIS Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Agricultural and Applied Economics in

More information

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks Jing Li* and Henry Thompson** This paper investigates the trend in the monthly real price of oil between 1990 and 2008 with a generalized autoregressive conditional

More information

THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET

THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET 1. The Structure of the Market The foreign exchange market is an example of a speculative auction market that has the same "commodity" traded virtually continuously around the

More information

Modelling the Global Price of Oil: Is there any Role for the Oil Futures-spot Spread?

Modelling the Global Price of Oil: Is there any Role for the Oil Futures-spot Spread? Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Papers 3-13-218 Modelling the Global Price of Oil: Is there any Role for the Oil Futures-spot Spread? Daniele Valenti University of Milan, Department of Economics,

More information

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data Nicolas Parent, Financial Markets Department It is now widely recognized that greater transparency facilitates the

More information

February Working Paper Modelling the Global Price of Oil: Is there any Role for the Oil Futures-spot Spread?

February Working Paper Modelling the Global Price of Oil: Is there any Role for the Oil Futures-spot Spread? February 218 Working Paper 6.218 Modelling the Global Price of Oil: Is there any Role for the Oil Futures-spot Spread? Daniele Valenti Economic Theory Series Editor: Matteo Manera Modelling the Global

More information

(Refer Slide Time: 1:20)

(Refer Slide Time: 1:20) Commodity Derivatives and Risk Management. Professor Prabina Rajib. Vinod Gupta School of Management. Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur. Lecture-08. Pricing and Valuation of Futures Contract (continued).

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

PROFESSIONAL INTERESTS

PROFESSIONAL INTERESTS KATERYNA V. HOLLAND Purdue University, Krannert Graduate School of Management Office: KRAN 522 403 W. State Street khollan@purdue.edu West Lafayette, IN 47907-2056 ACADEMIC EXPERIENCE Purdue University,

More information

Development of a Market Benchmark Price for AgMAS Performance Evaluations. Darrel L. Good, Scott H. Irwin, and Thomas E. Jackson

Development of a Market Benchmark Price for AgMAS Performance Evaluations. Darrel L. Good, Scott H. Irwin, and Thomas E. Jackson Development of a Market Benchmark Price for AgMAS Performance Evaluations by Darrel L. Good, Scott H. Irwin, and Thomas E. Jackson Development of a Market Benchmark Price for AgMAS Performance Evaluations

More information

Financial Derivatives Section 1

Financial Derivatives Section 1 Financial Derivatives Section 1 Forwards & Futures Michail Anthropelos anthropel@unipi.gr http://web.xrh.unipi.gr/faculty/anthropelos/ University of Piraeus Spring 2018 M. Anthropelos (Un. of Piraeus)

More information

Forward and Futures Contracts

Forward and Futures Contracts FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 Forward and Futures Contracts These notes explore forward and futures contracts, what they are and how they are used. We will learn how to price forward contracts

More information

The Fundamentals of Commodity Futures Returns

The Fundamentals of Commodity Futures Returns The Fundamentals of Commodity Futures Returns Gary B. Gorton The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania and National Bureau of Economic Research gorton@wharton.upenn.edu Fumio Hayashi University of

More information

Volatility Trade Design

Volatility Trade Design Volatility Trade Design J. Scott Chaput* Louis H. Ederington** May 2002 * Assistant Professor of Finance ** Oklahoma Bankers Professor of Finance University of Otago Michael F. Price College of Business

More information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Critical Finance Review, 2016, 5: 165 175 Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Kent Daniel Sheridan Titman 1 Columbia Business School, Columbia University, New York,

More information

LIQUIDITY EXTERNALITIES OF CONVERTIBLE BOND ISSUANCE IN CANADA

LIQUIDITY EXTERNALITIES OF CONVERTIBLE BOND ISSUANCE IN CANADA LIQUIDITY EXTERNALITIES OF CONVERTIBLE BOND ISSUANCE IN CANADA by Brandon Lam BBA, Simon Fraser University, 2009 and Ming Xin Li BA, University of Prince Edward Island, 2008 THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL

More information

Performance of Statistical Arbitrage in Future Markets

Performance of Statistical Arbitrage in Future Markets Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 12-2017 Performance of Statistical Arbitrage in Future Markets Shijie Sheng Follow this and additional works

More information

18. Forwards and Futures

18. Forwards and Futures 18. Forwards and Futures This is the first of a series of three lectures intended to bring the money view into contact with the finance view of the world. We are going to talk first about interest rate

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps

Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps A derivative asset is any asset whose payoff, price or value depends on the payoff, price or value of another asset. The underlying or primitive asset may be almost

More information

J. V. Bruni and Company 1528 North Tejon Street Colorado Springs, CO (719) or (800)

J. V. Bruni and Company 1528 North Tejon Street Colorado Springs, CO (719) or (800) J. V. Bruni and Company 1528 North Tejon Street Colorado Springs, CO 80907 (719) 575-9880 or (800) 748-3409 Retirement Nest Eggs... Withdrawal Rates and Fund Sustainability An Updated and Expanded Analysis

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Pairs trading: opportunities in oil. 28th January 2009 Anthony Grech Research Analyst IG Index

Pairs trading: opportunities in oil. 28th January 2009 Anthony Grech Research Analyst IG Index Pairs trading: opportunities in oil 28th January 2009 Anthony Grech Research Analyst IG Index Pairs trading: opportunities in oil 01 Pairs trading: opportunities in oil Co-relating the price ratio between

More information

Demand Effects and Speculation in Oil Markets: Theory and Evidence

Demand Effects and Speculation in Oil Markets: Theory and Evidence Demand Effects and Speculation in Oil Markets: Theory and Evidence Eyal Dvir (BC) and Ken Rogoff (Harvard) IMF - OxCarre Conference, March 2013 Introduction Is there a long-run stable relationship between

More information

Practice Set #1: Forward pricing & hedging.

Practice Set #1: Forward pricing & hedging. Derivatives (3 credits) Professor Michel Robe What to do with this practice set? Practice Set #1: Forward pricing & hedging To help students with the material, eight practice sets with solutions shall

More information

Chapter 2: BASICS OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES

Chapter 2: BASICS OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES Chapter 2: BASICS OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES 2.1 DISCOUNT FACTORS 2.1.1 Discount Factors across Maturities 2.1.2 Discount Factors over Time 2.1 DISCOUNT FACTORS The discount factor between two dates, t

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 2 Summer 1994 INTEREST RATE PARITY IN TIMES OF TURBULENCE: THE ISSUE REVISITED

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 2 Summer 1994 INTEREST RATE PARITY IN TIMES OF TURBULENCE: THE ISSUE REVISITED Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 2 Summer 1994 INTEREST RATE PARITY IN TIMES OF TURBULENCE: THE ISSUE REVISITED Nada Boulos * and Peggy E. Swanson * Abstract Empirical studies

More information

Examples of Derivative Securities: Futures Contracts

Examples of Derivative Securities: Futures Contracts Finance Derivative Securities Lecture 1 Introduction to Derivatives Examples of Derivative Securities: Futures Contracts Agreement made today to: Buy 5000 bushels of wheat @ US$4.50/bushel on December

More information

Click here to visit our website : ClearHedging

Click here to visit our website : ClearHedging March 16, 2017 On Wednesday, the front month WTI future settled at $48.86. This was a decline of 2.8% since last Wednesday, but above its low of the week at $47.09. The Forward curve was little changed

More information

Limits to Arbitrage and Hedging: Evidence from Commodity Markets

Limits to Arbitrage and Hedging: Evidence from Commodity Markets Limits to Arbitrage and Hedging: Evidence from Commodity Markets Viral Acharya, Lars Lochstoer, and Tarun Ramadorai Viral Acharya, Lars Lochstoer, and Tarun Ramadorai () 1 / 44 Motivation: Limits-to-arbitrage

More information

PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3

PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3 PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3 Stress testing operational risk for capital planning and capital adequacy PART 2: Monday, March 18th, 2013, New York Presenter: Alexander Cavallo, NORTHERN TRUST 1 Disclaimer

More information

CHAPTER 1 Introduction to Derivative Instruments

CHAPTER 1 Introduction to Derivative Instruments CHAPTER 1 Introduction to Derivative Instruments In the past decades, we have witnessed the revolution in the trading of financial derivative securities in financial markets around the world. A derivative

More information

Commodity Market Interest and Asset Return. Predictability

Commodity Market Interest and Asset Return. Predictability Commodity Market Interest and Asset Return Predictability Harrison Hong Motohiro Yogo March 25, 2010 Abstract We establish several new findings on the relation between open interest in commodity markets

More information

BANK OF CANADA RENEWAL OF BACKGROUND INFORMATION THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET. May 2001

BANK OF CANADA RENEWAL OF BACKGROUND INFORMATION THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET. May 2001 BANK OF CANADA May RENEWAL OF THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET BACKGROUND INFORMATION Bank of Canada Wellington Street Ottawa, Ontario KA G9 78 ISBN: --89- Printed in Canada on recycled paper B A N K O F C

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

Appendix to Supplement: What Determines Prices in the Futures and Options Markets?

Appendix to Supplement: What Determines Prices in the Futures and Options Markets? Appendix to Supplement: What Determines Prices in the Futures and Options Markets? 0 ne probably does need to be a rocket scientist to figure out the latest wrinkles in the pricing formulas used by professionals

More information

RISK DISCLOSURE STATEMENT FOR SECURITY FUTURES CONTRACTS

RISK DISCLOSURE STATEMENT FOR SECURITY FUTURES CONTRACTS RISK DISCLOSURE STATEMENT FOR SECURITY FUTURES CONTRACTS This disclosure statement discusses the characteristics and risks of standardized security futures contracts traded on regulated U.S. exchanges.

More information

Economics 430 Handout on Rational Expectations: Part I. Review of Statistics: Notation and Definitions

Economics 430 Handout on Rational Expectations: Part I. Review of Statistics: Notation and Definitions Economics 430 Chris Georges Handout on Rational Expectations: Part I Review of Statistics: Notation and Definitions Consider two random variables X and Y defined over m distinct possible events. Event

More information

OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 5: Forwards, Futures, and Futures Options

OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 5: Forwards, Futures, and Futures Options OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 5: Forwards, Futures, and Futures Options Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis Spot (cash) market Forward contract Futures contract Options on futures Copyright

More information

Candlestick Signals and Option Trades (Part 3, advanced) Hour One

Candlestick Signals and Option Trades (Part 3, advanced) Hour One Candlestick Signals and Option Trades (Part 3, advanced) Hour One 1. Hedges, long and short A hedge is any strategy designed to reduce or eliminate market risk. This applies to equity positions and the

More information

Determining Exchange Rates. Determining Exchange Rates

Determining Exchange Rates. Determining Exchange Rates Determining Exchange Rates Determining Exchange Rates Chapter Objectives To explain how exchange rate movements are measured; To explain how the equilibrium exchange rate is determined; and To examine

More information

Weekly Options on Stock Pinning

Weekly Options on Stock Pinning Weekly Options on Stock Pinning Ge Zhang, William Patterson University Haiyang Chen, Marshall University Francis Cai, William Patterson University Abstract In this paper we analyze the stock pinning effect

More information

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s As part of its monetary policy strategy, the ECB regularly monitors the development of a wide range of indicators and assesses their implications

More information

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis The main goal of Chapter 8 was to describe business cycles by presenting the business cycle facts. This and the following three

More information

The Oil Market s Mixed Price Signals

The Oil Market s Mixed Price Signals May The Oil ket s Mixed Price Signals OXFORD ENERGY COMMENT Bassam Fattouh Jan 02, Jan 09, Jan 16, Jan 23, Jan 30, 06, 13, 20, 27, 06, 13, 20, 27, 03, 10, 17, 24, May 01, May 08, Recent movements in oil

More information

University of Siegen

University of Siegen University of Siegen Faculty of Economic Disciplines, Department of economics Univ. Prof. Dr. Jan Franke-Viebach Seminar Risk and Finance Summer Semester 2008 Topic 4: Hedging with currency futures Name

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE FUNDAMENTALS OF COMMODITY FUTURES RETURNS. Gary B. Gorton Fumio Hayashi K. Geert Rouwenhorst

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE FUNDAMENTALS OF COMMODITY FUTURES RETURNS. Gary B. Gorton Fumio Hayashi K. Geert Rouwenhorst NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE FUNDAMENTALS OF COMMODITY FUTURES RETURNS Gary B. Gorton Fumio Hayashi K. Geert Rouwenhorst Working Paper 13249 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13249 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

IASB Exposure Drafts Financial Instruments: Classification and Measurement and Fair Value Measurement. London, September 10 th, 2009

IASB Exposure Drafts Financial Instruments: Classification and Measurement and Fair Value Measurement. London, September 10 th, 2009 International Accounting Standards Board First Floor 30 Cannon Street, EC4M 6XH United Kingdom Submitted via www.iasb.org IASB Exposure Drafts Financial Instruments: Classification and Measurement and

More information

Calmer Markets Suggest Crude Price Consensus Speculators burned by lower volatility.

Calmer Markets Suggest Crude Price Consensus Speculators burned by lower volatility. ? Calmer Markets Suggest Crude Price Consensus Speculators burned by lower volatility. Morningstar Commodities Research 14 August 217 Sandy Fielden Director, Oil and Products Research +1 512 431-844 sandy.fielden@morningstar.com

More information

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance.

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. RESEARCH STATEMENT Heather Tookes, May 2013 OVERVIEW My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. Much of my work focuses on understanding the ways in which capital market

More information

Answers to Selected Problems

Answers to Selected Problems Answers to Selected Problems Problem 1.11. he farmer can short 3 contracts that have 3 months to maturity. If the price of cattle falls, the gain on the futures contract will offset the loss on the sale

More information

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS 1 NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS Options are contracts used to insure against or speculate/take a view on uncertainty about the future prices of a wide range

More information

How surprising are returns in 2008? A review of hedge fund risks

How surprising are returns in 2008? A review of hedge fund risks How surprising are returns in 8? A review of hedge fund risks Melvyn Teo Abstract Many investors, expecting absolute returns, were shocked by the dismal performance of various hedge fund investment strategies

More information

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998) 219 239 Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Anup Agrawal*, Charles R. Knoeber College of Management, North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC

More information

Six Guidelines to Effectively Manage Your Commodity Risk

Six Guidelines to Effectively Manage Your Commodity Risk Six Guidelines to Effectively Manage Your Commodity Risk By Moazzam Khoja, CFA, SunGard Kiodex Introduction: Commodity and Energy Markets 1. Do not be fooled by mean reversion. There is a lot of recent

More information

The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting

The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting Christopher Ragan* An essential part of the Bank of Canada s inflation-control strategy is a flexible exchange rate that is free to adjust to various

More information

No-Arbitrage and Cointegration

No-Arbitrage and Cointegration Università di Pavia No-Arbitrage and Cointegration Eduardo Rossi Introduction Stochastic trends are prevalent in financial data. Two or more assets might share the same stochastic trend: they are cointegrated.

More information

PRODUCT INNOVATION, CLEARING, AND COMPETITION AMONG U.S. DERIVATIVES EXCHANGES *

PRODUCT INNOVATION, CLEARING, AND COMPETITION AMONG U.S. DERIVATIVES EXCHANGES * PRODUCT INNOVATION, CLEARING, AND COMPETITION AMONG U.S. DERIVATIVES EXCHANGES * Michael Gorham Abstract Futures traders are attracted to market liquidity the ability to buy and sell without the transaction

More information

Lecture Notes on. Liquidity and Asset Pricing. by Lasse Heje Pedersen

Lecture Notes on. Liquidity and Asset Pricing. by Lasse Heje Pedersen Lecture Notes on Liquidity and Asset Pricing by Lasse Heje Pedersen Current Version: January 17, 2005 Copyright Lasse Heje Pedersen c Not for Distribution Stern School of Business, New York University,

More information

THE NEW EURO AREA YIELD CURVES

THE NEW EURO AREA YIELD CURVES THE NEW EURO AREA YIELD CURVES Yield describe the relationship between the residual maturity of fi nancial instruments and their associated interest rates. This article describes the various ways of presenting

More information

Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility. David A. Hsieh. Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC (919)

Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility. David A. Hsieh. Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC (919) Estimating the Dynamics of Volatility by David A. Hsieh Fuqua School of Business Duke University Durham, NC 27706 (919)-660-7779 October 1993 Prepared for the Conference on Financial Innovations: 20 Years

More information

Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach

Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach John T. Harvey Professor of Economics Department of Economics Box 98510 Texas Christian University Fort Worth, Texas 7619 (817)57-730 j.harvey@tcu.edu

More information

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy This online appendix is divided into four sections. In section A we perform pairwise tests aiming at disentangling

More information

Discussion of. Commodity Price Movements in a General Equilibrium Model of Storage. David M. Arsenau and Sylvain Leduc

Discussion of. Commodity Price Movements in a General Equilibrium Model of Storage. David M. Arsenau and Sylvain Leduc Discussion of Commodity Price Movements in a General Equilibrium Model of Storage David M. Arsenau and Sylvain Leduc by Raf Wouters (NBB) "Policy Responses to Commodity Price Movements", 6-7 April 2012,

More information

Copula-Based Pairs Trading Strategy

Copula-Based Pairs Trading Strategy Copula-Based Pairs Trading Strategy Wenjun Xie and Yuan Wu Division of Banking and Finance, Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore ABSTRACT Pairs trading is a technique that

More information

Day-of-the-Week Trading Patterns of Individual and Institutional Investors

Day-of-the-Week Trading Patterns of Individual and Institutional Investors Day-of-the-Week Trading Patterns of Individual and Instutional Investors Hoang H. Nguyen, Universy of Baltimore Joel N. Morse, Universy of Baltimore 1 Keywords: Day-of-the-week effect; Trading volume-instutional

More information

Portfolio Rebalancing:

Portfolio Rebalancing: Portfolio Rebalancing: A Guide For Institutional Investors May 2012 PREPARED BY Nat Kellogg, CFA Associate Director of Research Eric Przybylinski, CAIA Senior Research Analyst Abstract Failure to rebalance

More information

A Pedagogical Note on the Derivation of Option Profit Lines

A Pedagogical Note on the Derivation of Option Profit Lines JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE EDUCATION Volume2 Number2 Winter 2003 16 A Pedagogical Note on the Derivation of Option Profit Lines Hassan Shirvani and Barry Wilbratte Abstract This paper presents a

More information

Futures and Forward Contracts

Futures and Forward Contracts Haipeng Xing Department of Applied Mathematics and Statistics Outline 1 Forward contracts Forward contracts and their payoffs Valuing forward contracts 2 Futures contracts Futures contracts and their prices

More information

Implications of Low Inflation Rates for Monetary Policy

Implications of Low Inflation Rates for Monetary Policy Implications of Low Inflation Rates for Monetary Policy Eric S. Rosengren President & Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Washington and Lee University s H. Parker Willis Lecture in

More information

Rising public debt-to-gdp can harm economic growth

Rising public debt-to-gdp can harm economic growth Rising public debt-to-gdp can harm economic growth by Alexander Chudik, Kamiar Mohaddes, M. Hashem Pesaran, and Mehdi Raissi Abstract: The debt-growth relationship is complex, varying across countries

More information

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Zhangkai Huang * and Xingzhong Xu Guanghua School of Management Peking University Abstract Unlike in other countries, negotiated block shares have

More information

HEDGING WITH FUTURES AND BASIS

HEDGING WITH FUTURES AND BASIS Futures & Options 1 Introduction The more producer know about the markets, the better equipped producer will be, based on current market conditions and your specific objectives, to decide whether to use

More information

The Characteristics of Stock Market Volatility. By Daniel R Wessels. June 2006

The Characteristics of Stock Market Volatility. By Daniel R Wessels. June 2006 The Characteristics of Stock Market Volatility By Daniel R Wessels June 2006 Available at: www.indexinvestor.co.za 1. Introduction Stock market volatility is synonymous with the uncertainty how macroeconomic

More information

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS. EXAM FM SAMPLE QUESTIONS Financial Economics

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS. EXAM FM SAMPLE QUESTIONS Financial Economics SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES EXAM FM FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS EXAM FM SAMPLE QUESTIONS Financial Economics June 2014 changes Questions 1-30 are from the prior version of this document. They have been edited to conform

More information

Distant Speculators and Asset Bubbles in the Housing Market

Distant Speculators and Asset Bubbles in the Housing Market Distant Speculators and Asset Bubbles in the Housing Market NBER Housing Crisis Executive Summary Alex Chinco Chris Mayer September 4, 2012 How do bubbles form? Beginning with the work of Black (1986)

More information

CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY

CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY Chapter Overview This chapter has two major parts: the introduction to the principles of market efficiency and a review of the empirical evidence on efficiency

More information

A Proposed Fuel Price Stabilization Mechanism through the Use of Financial Derivatives

A Proposed Fuel Price Stabilization Mechanism through the Use of Financial Derivatives Inter-American Development Bank Infrastructure and Environment Sector Energy Division INE/ENE A Proposed Fuel Price Stabilization Mechanism through the Use of Financial Derivatives TECHNICAL NOTES No.

More information

Welcome to NYMEX WTI Light Sweet Crude Oil Futures

Welcome to NYMEX WTI Light Sweet Crude Oil Futures Welcome to NYMEX WTI Light Sweet Crude Oil Futures Product Overview Looking to take part in today s active oil markets? Consider NYMEX WTI Light Sweet Crude Oil futures (ticker symbol CL). NYMEX WTI is

More information

Dealing with Downside Risk in Energy Markets: Futures versus Exchange-Traded Funds. Panit Arunanondchai

Dealing with Downside Risk in Energy Markets: Futures versus Exchange-Traded Funds. Panit Arunanondchai Dealing with Downside Risk in Energy Markets: Futures versus Exchange-Traded Funds Panit Arunanondchai Ph.D. Candidate in Agribusiness and Managerial Economics Department of Agricultural Economics, Texas

More information

Correlation vs. Trends in Portfolio Management: A Common Misinterpretation

Correlation vs. Trends in Portfolio Management: A Common Misinterpretation Correlation vs. rends in Portfolio Management: A Common Misinterpretation Francois-Serge Lhabitant * Abstract: wo common beliefs in finance are that (i) a high positive correlation signals assets moving

More information

OSCILLATORS. TradeSmart Education Center

OSCILLATORS. TradeSmart Education Center OSCILLATORS TradeSmart Education Center TABLE OF CONTENTS Oscillators Bollinger Bands... Commodity Channel Index.. Fast Stochastic... KST (Short term, Intermediate term, Long term) MACD... Momentum Relative

More information

APPENDIX SUMMARIZING NARRATIVE EVIDENCE ON FEDERAL RESERVE INTENTIONS FOR THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE. Christina D. Romer David H.

APPENDIX SUMMARIZING NARRATIVE EVIDENCE ON FEDERAL RESERVE INTENTIONS FOR THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE. Christina D. Romer David H. APPENDIX SUMMARIZING NARRATIVE EVIDENCE ON FEDERAL RESERVE INTENTIONS FOR THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE Christina D. Romer David H. Romer To accompany A New Measure of Monetary Shocks: Derivation and Implications,

More information

I N F O R M A T I O N. regarding the financial instruments subject to the investment services carried out by Deltastock and the risks involved

I N F O R M A T I O N. regarding the financial instruments subject to the investment services carried out by Deltastock and the risks involved I N F O R M A T I O N regarding the financial instruments subject to the investment services carried out by Deltastock and the risks involved I. GENERAL PROVISIONS 1. This Information regarding the financial

More information

Financial Markets I The Stock, Bond, and Money Markets Every economy must solve the basic problems of production and distribution of goods and

Financial Markets I The Stock, Bond, and Money Markets Every economy must solve the basic problems of production and distribution of goods and Financial Markets I The Stock, Bond, and Money Markets Every economy must solve the basic problems of production and distribution of goods and services. Financial markets perform an important function

More information

The Impact of Institutional Investors on the Monday Seasonal*

The Impact of Institutional Investors on the Monday Seasonal* Su Han Chan Department of Finance, California State University-Fullerton Wai-Kin Leung Faculty of Business Administration, Chinese University of Hong Kong Ko Wang Department of Finance, California State

More information

12 Bounds. on Option Prices. Answers to Questions and Problems

12 Bounds. on Option Prices. Answers to Questions and Problems 12 Bounds on Option Prices 90 Answers to Questions and Problems 1. What is the maximum theoretical value for a call? Under what conditions does a call reach this maximum value? Explain. The highest price

More information

EC Grain Pricing Alternatives

EC Grain Pricing Alternatives University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Historical Materials from University of Nebraska- Lincoln Extension Extension 1977 EC77-868 Grain Pricing Alternatives Lynn

More information

Introduction. This module examines:

Introduction. This module examines: Introduction Financial Instruments - Futures and Options Price risk management requires identifying risk through a risk assessment process, and managing risk exposure through physical or financial hedging

More information

Positioning Analysis in Commodity Markets: Bridging Fundamental and Technical Analysis

Positioning Analysis in Commodity Markets: Bridging Fundamental and Technical Analysis J.P. Morgan Center for Commodities at the University of Colorado Denver Business School Positioning Analysis in Commodity Markets: Bridging Fundamental and Technical Analysis Mark Keenan Managing Director,

More information

Types of Forex analysis

Types of Forex analysis Types of Forex analysis There are two principal and confronting schools in Forex analysis - the fundamentalists and technicians. Both are supposed to be right. Sometimes technicians are more successful,

More information

Country Risk Components, the Cost of Capital, and Returns in Emerging Markets

Country Risk Components, the Cost of Capital, and Returns in Emerging Markets Country Risk Components, the Cost of Capital, and Returns in Emerging Markets Campbell R. Harvey a,b a Duke University, Durham, NC 778 b National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA Abstract This

More information

Modelling Energy Forward Curves

Modelling Energy Forward Curves Modelling Energy Forward Curves Svetlana Borovkova Free University of Amsterdam (VU Amsterdam) Typeset by FoilTEX 1 Energy markets Pre-198s: regulated energy markets 198s: deregulation of oil and natural

More information