Volatility-of-Volatility Risk in Asset Pricing

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Volatility-of-Volatility Risk in Asset Pricing"

Transcription

1 Volatility-of-Volatility Risk in Asset Pricing Te-Feng Chen, Tarun Chordia, San-Lin Chung, and Ji-Chai Lin * November 2017 Abstract This paper develops a general equilibrium model in an endowment economy with time-varying uncertainty and provides empirical support for an outcome of the model that the market volatilityof-volatility (VOV) predicts market returns. A second outcome is an asset pricing model that incorporates the market, the market volatility and VOV as a pricing factors. The differential longshort quintile portfolio return amounts to 72 basis points per month when sorting on the VOV beta. The risk premium on VOV is robust across different testing strategies and different test assets. Market risk and volatility risk are not priced in constant beta models but consistent with theory, the conditional factor loadings on both the market risk and volatility risk are priced. The pricing impact of VOV strengthens during market crashes while that of market volatility obtains during normal times. JEL Classification: G14; G12; Contacts Chen Chordia Chung Lin Voice: Fax: tfchen@polyu.edu.hk Tarun.Chordia@emory.edu chungsl@ntu.edu.tw jclin@polyu.edu.hk Address: HK Polytechnic Goizueta Business School National Taiwan HK Polytechnic University Emory University University University Kowloon, Hong Kong Atlanta, GA Taipei, Taiwan Kowloon, Hong Kong * We thank seminar participants at Hong Kong Polytechnic University.

2 Volatility-of-Volatility Risk in Asset Pricing Abstract This paper develops a general equilibrium model in an endowment economy with time-varying uncertainty and provides empirical support for an outcome of the model that the market volatilityof-volatility (VOV) predicts market returns. A second outcome is an asset pricing model that incorporates the market, the market volatility and VOV as a pricing factors. The differential longshort quintile portfolio return amounts to 72 basis points per month when sorting on the VOV beta. The risk premium on VOV is robust across different testing strategies and different test assets. Market risk and volatility risk are not priced in constant beta models but consistent with theory, the conditional factor loadings on both the market risk and volatility risk are priced. The pricing impact of VOV strengthens during market crashes while that of market volatility obtains during normal times. JEL classification: G12, G13, E4 1

3 1. Introduction Turmoil in financial markets while episodic has become more frequent, leading to higher uncertainty in markets. 1 In order to capture the dynamics of market uncertainty, Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) build a general equilibrium model for a representative investor with Epstein and Zin (1989) preferences and introduce the volatility-of-volatility (VOV) as an additional source of uncertainty. Their model shows that VOV drives the time-varying variance risk premium and its ability to predict stock market returns. This paper develops a macroeconomic model that synthesizes the seminal long-run risk model of Bansal and Yaron (2004) and the variance-of-variance model of Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009). We solve the macro-finance model explicitly and derive the equilibrium aggregate asset prices. The model establishes that an increase in VOV reflects higher uncertainty about market volatility, and raises the market risk premium, implying an immediate price decline and higher future returns. Further, VOV drives the contemporaneous covariance between market returns and market volatility (denoted CVRV). CVRV is time-varying and becomes more negative as VOV increases. Further, VOV and CVRV contain similar information for predicting market returns. We use aggregate asset prices to characterize the macroeconomic risks, and transform the underlying macro-based model to a market-based three-factor asset pricing model. The marketbased model has distinct advantages: (i) Financial data provide useful information because asset prices tell us how market participants value risks; and (ii) Markets disseminate financial data in a timely fashion. In the asset pricing model, the expected return of security i is determined by three sources of risks: (i) the covariance with market returns, ov,,, ; (ii) the covariance 1 As Mr. Olivier Blanchard, IMF s chief economist, points out in The Economist in January 2009, Crises feed uncertainty. And uncertainty affects behaviour, which feeds the crisis. 1

4 with the market variance, ov,,,, where, ar, ; and, (iii) the covariance with the variance of market variance, ov,,,, where, ar,. The first risk is the market risk of the classical capital asset pricing model (CAPM; Sharpe, 1964; Lintner, 1965). The second risk corresponds to the volatility risk of Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006). The last risk, which is the main focus of our paper, is the volatility-ofvolatility, VOV, risk. While the aggregate volatility risk is proxied by the volatility index, VIX, obtained from the Chicago Board of Options Exchange (CBOE), we measure VOV using high frequency S&P 500 index option data. We first convert the tick-by-tick options data to equally spaced five-minute observations and then use the model-free methodology (see Carr and Madan 1998, Britten-Jones and Neuberger 2000, Bakshi, Kapadia, and Madan, 2003, and Jiang and Tian 2005) to estimate the market variance implied by index option prices for each five-minute interval. For each day, we estimate VOV by calculating the realized bipower variance from a series of five-minute model-free implied market variance within the day. The bipower variation, introduced by Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard (2004), delivers a consistent estimator solely for the continuous component of VOV while excluding the jump component. 2 In other words, our empirical results are not affected by the potential jump risk embedded in volatility as shown by Pan (2002), Eraker (2008), and Drechsler and Yaron (2011). Empirically, VOV strongly affects the market return-volatility covariance (CVRV), and, moreover, VOV and, to a lesser extent, CVRV predict market returns. VOV predicts market returns even after controlling for the variance risk premium and jump risk, as documented by Bollerslev, 2 Measures of realized jump based on the difference between realized variation and bipower variation have been proposed by Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard (2004), Huang and Tauchen (2005), and Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold (2007). 2

5 Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) and Drechsler and Yaron (2011), respectively. Thus, consistent with our model, VOV is a state variable that drives the time-varying market risk premium. The next question is whether VOV is a priced factor in the cross-section of asset returns. We test the three-factor asset pricing model using stock returns on NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ listed stocks over the period from 1996 to The main finding is that VOV is indeed priced in the cross-section of stock returns with a return differential of -72 basis points per month across quintile portfolios sorted on the VOV beta. The portfolio returns decrease with the VOV beta because the market return decreases with VOV and so a stock whose return increases with VOV i.e., a positive VOV beta, will provide a hedge against VOV risk and thus earn lower returns than a stock with a negative VOV beta. The risk premium on VOV is robust in Fama-MacBeth (1973) regressions when the test assets are 25 portfolios formed using independent quintile sorts on the VOV beta and the VIX beta as well as when using individual stocks as test assets. The VOV premium is robust in the presence of the Fama and French (1993) and the Carhart (1997) factors (SMB, HML and UMD) as well as the market skewness and the market kurtosis factor of Chang, Christoffersen, and Jacobs (2013) and the jump factor of Cremers, Halling and Weinbaum (2015). Moreover, the VOV premium remains robust in the presence of the firm level characteristics including firm size, the book-to-market ratio, past returns, the Amihud (2002) illiquidity, the implied-realized volatility spread (IVOL-TVOL) and the call-put implied volatility spread (CIVOL- PIVOL) of Bali and Hovakimian (2009) and Yan (2011). The unconditional VIX beta and the MKT beta are not priced in our sample. However, consistent with the theoretical model, the conditional component of the factor loadings of both, VIX and the MKT, are priced. While Ang et al. (2006) and Adrian and Rosenberg (2008) show that market volatility is a priced factor, Chang, Christoffersen, and Jacobs (2013) find mixed results. 3

6 Interestingly, we find that all the three risks (MKT, VIX, VOV) in the asset pricing model are significantly priced during normal times when we remove the observations with large market declines from our sample. However, during crash periods (with extreme negative market returns), the price of VOV risk becomes even more significant while the premiums on MKT and VIX have the wrong sign. The positive premium on VIX during market turmoil combined with the negative premium during normal periods, results in an overall VIX premium that is indistinguishable from zero. The results imply that market turmoil strengthens investors demand for compensation for VOV risk. Our study is related to several strands of the literature. Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) use the variance risk premium as an indirect measure of VOV to predict stock market returns. However, Drechsler and Yaron (2011) show that jump shocks can capture the size and predictive power of the variance risk premium. Further, Drechsler (2013) shows that model uncertainty also has a large impact on the variance risk premium, helping explain its power to predict stock returns. Unlike these studies, we focus directly on VOV. We empirically construct a VOV measure that excludes jumps to show that it is a determinant of the variance risk premium and that it can predict stock market returns. Moreover, we provide new evidence that VOV risk is important for pricing the cross-section of stock returns. Our paper is also related to the pricing model with higher moments of the market return as risk factors, as proposed by Chang, Christoffersen, and Jacobs (2013). They find that market skewness is a priced risk factor in the cross section of stock returns. Both our paper and their work extend Ang et al. (2006) to extract implied moments from index option prices. Our results are robust to the inclusion of the market skewness factor as well as the jump factor of Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum (2015). In fact, we find that VOV risk subsumes the pricing power of the higher 4

7 moment and jump betas documented in the literature. Our findings imply that, in the spirit of the Merton (1973) ICAPM, the time-varying VOV seems better in capturing shifts in the investment opportunity set than the time-varying market skewness and jumps. Finally, Baltussen, Van Bekkum, and Van Der Grient (2013) show evidence that an ambiguity measure based on firm-level historical volatility of option-implied volatility (vol-of-vol) is associated with future stock returns, which is inconsistent with the rational pricing of uncertainty. Our study complements theirs as we show that our VOV measure is in supportive of the rational pricing of VOV risk. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section describes the economic dynamics and develops our market-based three-factor model for the empirical implementation. Section 3 constructs the measure of market volatility-of-volatility. Section 4 describes the data, presents the summary statistics, and provides evidence for the VOV s predictability on future stock market returns. In section 5, we show empirical evidence on the pricing of VOV risk in the crosssectional stock returns and investigate the VOV risk-return tradeoff during market turmoil. Finally, section 6 contains our concluding remarks. 2. An asset pricing model with VOV risk This section develops an asset pricing model with volatility-of-volatility (VOV) risk starting with a macroeconomic model that incorporates the seminal long-run risk model of Bansal and Yaron (2004) and the variance-of-variance model of Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009). We solve the macro-finance model explicitly and derive the equilibrium aggregate asset prices. Then, we use the properties of aggregate asset prices to characterize the macroeconomic risks and develop a market-based three-factor model for the cross-sectional asset prices Economic dynamics and the equilibrium market risk premium 5

8 The setting of our model is a discrete-time endowment economy. The dynamics of the consumption growth rate,, and the dividend growth rate,,, are governed by the following processes:,,,,,,,,,,, (1) where,,,,,,,,, ~ 0,1, represents the long-run consumption growth, is the time-varying economic uncertainty, and is the economic volatility-ofvolatility, which is the conditional variance of the economic uncertainty. These features of the long-run risk and the time-varying economic uncertainty have been proposed by Bansal and Yaron (2004), while the additional feature of economic volatility-of-volatility has been introduced by Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009). The representative agent is assumed to have recursive preferences of Epstein and Zin (1989). Thus, the logarithm of the Intertemporal Marginal Rate of Substitution (IMRS) is log 1,, where, is the return on consumption claim, is the time discount factor, is the riskaversion parameter, is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution (IES) parameter, and 1 1 1/. With 1, and 1, 0. Based on Campbell and Shiller s (1988) approximation,,, where is the logarithm of price consumption ratio, which in equilibrium is an affine function of the state variables, i.e.. 3 Substituting the equilibrium consumption return,,, into the 3 The equilibrium solutions are: / 0, / 6 0, and 0.

9 IMRS, the innovation in the pricing kernel is,,,,, (2) where 0, 1 0, 1 0, 1 0. The underlying parameters drive the prices for short-run risk ( ), long-run risk ( ), volatility risk ( ), and volatility of volatility risk ( ). An analogous expression holds for the stock market return,,,,,,,, where, is the log price dividend ratio, which in equilibrium is an affine function of the state variables,,,,,,. 4 Since, 0, we have, 0,, 0, and, 0. The innovation in market return can be expressed as,,,,,,,,,, where,,, 0,,,, 0, and,,, 0. The conditional variance of market return is readily calculated as, ar,,,,, and the process for innovations in market variance is,,,,,,, where,, and,,. Thus, innovations in market variance are related to both the economic volatility shock and the economic volatility-of-volatility shock. It follows that the market volatility-of-volatility (i.e., the conditional variance of market variance) is, ar,,,, and the process for its innovations is,,,,, where,,. Note that, in our model, innovations to the market volatility-of-volatility are solely determined by economic variance of variance shocks with a scaling factor,,. Thus, the volatility of market VOV (i.e., the conditional variance of variance 4 The solutions are:, /,,,.,, and,.,, where,,, and,,. 7,

10 of market variance),, ar,,, is constant in our model. It is straightforward now to derive the equity premium on the market portfolio. In the following proposition, the expected market return is determined by the covariance risks with respect to three sources of risks in the pricing kernel. Proposition 1: The risk premium for the market,,,, is governed by three covariance risks as follows:,, 0.5 ar, ov,, ov,, ov,, ov,,,,,. (3) The first two terms in (3)represent the long-run risk premium and the volatility risk premium, which are the same as in Bansal and Yaron (2004), while the last one represents the volatility-ofvolatility risk premium, as in Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) Market return-volatility covariance and future return predictability The contemporaneous market return and market volatility tend to be negatively correlated, which is commonly referred to as the leverage effect in the literature (e.g. Black, 1976; Christie, 1982; among others). This covariance could also be understood as the volatility risk for the aggregate market under ICAPM (Ang et al., 2006). The model endogenously generates a timevarying contemporaneous correlation between the market return and the market volatility as well as a negative contemporaneous correlation between the market return and the volatility-ofvolatility. Straightforward calculations yield the following proposition. Proposition 2: The market return is negatively correlated with both the market volatility and the 5 Since we do not assume the square root process for the volatility-of-volatility as Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) do, the volatility risk in the resulting equity premium does not confound with the volatility-of-volatility risk. 8

11 market volatility-of-volatility, as shown below:, ov,,,,,,, 0, ov,,,,, 0. (4) The contemporaneous covariance between the market return and the market volatility is timevarying and driven by the volatility-of-volatility. By contrast, the contemporaneous covariance between the market return and the volatility-of-volatility is constant. In the absence of the time-varying economic volatility-of-volatility i.e., when is constant and =0, the second term of, is zero, resulting in a less negative value. Thus, the economic volatility-of-volatility amplifies the impact of volatility on returns. Moreover, driven by, the volatility risk for the aggregate market is time-varying and provides information about future market returns since the time-varying market risk premium from (3) is driven by as well. Further, the market volatility-of-volatility (, ), which varies directly with the economic volatility-of-volatility ( ), possesses similar information about future market returns. The following proposition summarizes market return predictability of, through the channel of the underlying economic volatility-of-volatility ( ). Proposition 3. With the presence of time-varying economic volatility-of-volatility ( ), the projection coefficient for the predictive regression of market returns on, is negative, i.e.,,,,, with 0. The projection coefficient for predictive regression of market returns on, is positive, i.e.,,,,, with 0. Specifically, the projection coefficients are:,,,,,,,,,,, 0,,, 0. (5) 9

12 The negative association between the future market return and the volatility risk for the market and a positive association between the future market return and the market volatility-ofvolatility are consistent with the feedback effect through the time-varying risk premium documented in the literature (see, e.g. Campbell and Hentschel 1992; Bekaert and Wu 2000; Wu 2001; Bollerslev, Sizova, and Tauchen, 2012; among others). When increases,, also increases (and, decreases), which leads investors to demand a higher risk premium, resulting in a negative contemporaneous market return due to a higher discount rate pushing the price lower, and leading to a higher future return to compensate for the increased risk. Furthermore, Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) show that the variance risk premium (VRP), which is the proxy for the economic volatility-of-volatility,, in their equilibrium model, can predict the future market return. However, Drechsler and Yaron (2011), challenge the role of in Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou, since the jump risk premium could be an alternative state variable that contributes to both the variance risk premium and the market return predictability. Thus, instead of using VRP, an indirect measure used by Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou to proxy for, we will use the direct measure - market volatility-of-volatility (,. Further, we will isolate the jump component of, from the continuous component and use only the latter A market-based three-factor model for pricing individual stocks Based on the sources of risk in (1), we assume that the innovation in stock return i is 6,,,,,,,,,. Given the pricing kernel in (2), the expected stock return can be written as,, 0.5 ar,,,,. (6) The expected stock return is determined by three sources of economic risks: economic long-run 6 We have not included the risk of consumption growth as the empirical support for it is weak. 10

13 risk (, ), economic volatility risk (,, and economic volatility-of-volatility risk (, ). The following proposition provides the risk premium in terms of market risks. Proposition 4: The risk premium for stock i,,,, is governed by,, 0.5 ar, ov,,, ov,,, ov,,,, (7) where,,,,,,. (8),, The proof of the above proposition uses the properties of the aggregate asset prices to characterize the macroeconomic risks in (6). In equilibrium, the market volatility-of-volatility risk, which is the return covariance with respect to the variance of market variance, is solely determined by the economic volatility-of-volatility risk (, ), i.e., ov,,,,,. Also, the return sensitivities with respect to the market variance and with respect to the market return provide additional information for the economic volatility risk and the long-run risk; that is, ov,,,,,,,, and ov,,,,,,,,,. Substituting out the economic risks in (6), results in the market-based three-factor model for individual stock excess returns in (7). Thus, the expected return on stock i is determined by three sources of risks related to aggregate asset prices. The first term measures the market risk of classical capital asset pricing model (CAPM; Sharpe, 1964; Lintner, 1965). The second term corresponds to the aggregate volatility risk in Ang et al. (2006). The last term, which is the main focus of this paper, measures the aggregate volatility of volatility risk. The resulting three risk premiums in our market-based model,,, and, are related to the three economic risk premiums through a linear transformation. 11

14 The market-based model developed in this paper has several advantages. Financial data provides useful information because asset prices tell us how market participants value risks. Moreover, financial data conveys information to investors in a timely fashion. Further, the marketbased risk factors are easier to estimate. For instance,, is easier to estimate than. Also, the empirical design of our model is compatible with a large literature of multi-factor models for explaining cross-sectional stock returns (see, for instance, Fama and French, 1993, 2015; Ang et al., 2006; Maio and Santa-Clara, 2012; Hou, Xue and Zhang, 2015; among others). 3. Estimating the variance of market variance To test the proposed market-based three-factor model, we need three risk factors the market return, the market variance, and the variance of market variance. For the first two factors, we use the CRSP value-weighted market index and the CBOE VIX index, respectively. The VIX index has been used as a proxy for the market variance by Ang et al., (2006), Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009), and Chang, Christoffersen, and Jacobs (2013) among others. We estimate the variance of market variance by calculating the realized bipower variation from five-minute modelfree implied market variances, using the high-frequency S&P 500 index option data as follows. First, we extract the model-free implied variance, using the spanning methodology proposed by Carr and Madan (2001), Bakshi and Madan (2000), Bakshi, Kapadia, and Madan (2003), and Jiang and Tian (2005). Bakshi, Kapadia, and Madan (2003) show that the price of a -maturity _ return variance contract, Q e, Log, which is the discounted conditional expectation of the square of market return under the risk-neutral measure, and can be spanned by a collection of out-of-money call options and out-of-money put options, i.e., 12

15 _ 2 1 log ; 2 1 log ;, where ; and ; are the prices of European calls and puts at time written on the underlying stock with strike price and expiration date at τ. The conditional variance of market return can be calculated by e _,, where satisfies the riskneutral valuation relationship, which is related to the first four risk-neutral moments of market returns as described in equation (39) of Bakshi, Kapadia, and Madan (2003). Next, we use the model-free realized bipower variance, introduced by Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard (2004), to estimate the variance of market variance. Define the intraday stock return as, log log, 1,...,, where M is number of five minute intervals per trading day. Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard (2004) provide two measures of realized variation; the first one is the realized variance, the bipower variance,, (9),, and the second one is,,. Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold (2002) show that the realized variance converges to the integrated variance plus the jump contributions, i.e.,, where is the number of return jumps in day t+1 and, is the squared jump size. Moreover, Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard (2004) show that. In other words, the bipower variance provides a consistent estimator of the realized variance but solely for the diffusion part. Our measure for the variance of market variance is estimated from five-minute model-free implied variances. The intraday model-free implied variances,, 1,...,, are calculated using equation (9). Since the process of market variance is a (semi-)martingale, we 13

16 apply the bipower variance formula on the changes in annualized model-free implied variances and obtain a measure for the variance of market variance: Δ 2 1,, (10) where Δ,. Similarly, we estimate diffusion part of the covariance between the market return and the market variance, CVRV, using the bipower covariation formula of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard (2008): 1 4 Δ Δ (11) Based on these measures, our empirical results will not be affected by volatility jumps (or the return jumps embedded in the volatility). 4. Data and descriptive statistics 4.1. Data To calculate implied volatility, we use the tick-by-tick quote data for the S&P 500 index (SPX) options from CBOE s Market Data Report (MDR) tapes over the time period from January 1996 to December The underlying SPX prices are also available on the tapes. Daily data for equity options and S&P 500 index options are obtained from OptionMetrics. We use the Zero Curve file, which contains the zero-coupon interest rate curve and the Index Dividend file, which contains the dividend yield, from OptionMetrics. Daily and monthly stock return data are from the CRSP while intraday transactions data are from TAQ. Financial statement data are from the COMPUSTAT. Fama and French (1993) factors including their momentum factor, UMD, are obtained from the 14

17 online data library of Professor Ken French. 7 The VIX index is obtained from the CBOE website. 8 While we use the new VIX index to calculate the market variance risk premium as proposed by Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009), we also use the old VIX, which is based on the S&P 100 options and Black Scholes implied volatilities, as our volatility factor, following Ang et al. (2006). We use index option prices from the Option Price file to replicate the market skewness factor and the market kurtosis factor of Chang, Kristoffersen, and Jacobs (2013). We follow the literature (see Jiang and Tian 2005; Chang, Kristoffersen, and Jacobs 2013; among others) to filter out index option prices that violate arbitrage bounds. We eliminate all observations for which the ask price is lower than the bid price, the bid price is equal to zero, or the average of the bid and ask price is less than 3/8. We also eliminate in-the-money options (e.g. put options with K/S>1.03 and call options with K/S<1.03) because prior studies suggest that they are less liquid. We use the daily SPX low and high prices, downloaded from Yahoo Finance, 9 to filter out the MDR data that are outside the [low, high] interval. To compute the market volatility-of-volatility, we first partition the tick-by-tick S&P500 index options data into five-minute intervals. For each maturity within each interval, we linearly interpolate implied volatilities for a fine grid of one thousand moneyness levels (K/S) between 0.01% and 300%. For moneyness levels below or above the available moneyness level in the market, we use the implied volatility of the lowest or highest available strike price. The modelfree implied variance is estimated from (9), using out-of-money call and out-of-money put prices. Linearly interpolated maturities are used to obtain the estimate at a fixed 30-day horizon. Each day, the market volatility-of-volatility (VOV) is calculated by using the bipower variance formula of equation (10) with the 81 within-day five-minute annualized 30-day model-free implied variance

18 estimates covering the normal CBOE trading hours from 8:30 a.m. to 3:15 p.m. Central Time. We estimate the daily bipower covariance, CVRV, between the market return and the market variance using the intraday five-minute logarithmic return multiplied by 22 and the five-minute implied variance for S&P 500 index. Following Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009), we define the market variance risk premium (, ) as the difference between the ex-ante implied variance (, ) and the ex-post realized variance (, ), i.e.,,,. We focus on the 30-day variance risk premium. Market implied variance (, ) is the squared new VIX index divided by 12. The sum of the SPX five-minute squared logarithmic returns across the past 22 trading days is used to calculate the one-month market realized variance (, ). To implement our empirical model, we construct innovations in market moments. Following Ang et al. (2006), the innovation in market volatility (ΔVIX) is its first order difference, i.e.. Chang, Kristoffersen, and Jacobs (2013) indicate that while the first difference is appropriate for VIX, an ARMA(1,1) model is needed to remove the time-series dependence in the skewness and kurtosis factors. Following their approach, the innovations in market volatility-of-volatility (ΔVOV) is computed as the ARMA(1,1) model residual of the market volatility-of-volatility. Similarly, an ARMA(1,1) model is used to obtain the innovations in the bipower covariance, ΔCVRV Descriptive statistics Figure 1 plots the daily S&P 500 logarithmic return (rspx) and changes in market volatility (ΔVIX) over the time period from January 1996 to December There are clear spikes on the graph the Asian financial crisis in 1997, the LTCM crisis in 1998, September 11, 2001, the WorldCom and Enron bankruptcies in 2001 and 2002, the subprime loan crisis in 2007, the recent 16

19 financial crisis in 2008, the flash crash in 2010, the battle over the fiscal cliff in 2011 and 2013, and the recent sovereign debt crisis in Europe. Table 1 reports descriptive statistics for the daily factors used in this paper, including the four factors (MKT, SMB, HML, and UMD) of Fama and French (1993) and Carhart (1997), the market variance risk premium (VRP), the volatility index (VIX; Ang et al., 2006), our measure of variance of market variance (VOV), the market skewness factor (SKEW) and market kurtosis factor (KURT) of Chang, Kristoffersen, and Jacobs (2013), the zero beta straddle factor of Coval and Shumway (2001), and the options return volatility factor (VOL) and the options return jump factor (JUMP) of Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum (2015). In our sample, the mean of 30-day market variance risk premium (VRP) is 0.155%, which is slightly smaller than 0.183% in Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) sample. The mean VOV is 0.047%, and its standard deviation is 0.497%. The mean SKEW is and the mean KURT is , suggesting that the risk-neutral distribution of the market return is asymmetric and has fat tails. The mean delta-neutral straddle return (STR) is %; the mean delta-neutral, gammaneutral, vega positive straddle return (VOL) is %; the mean delta-neutral, vega-neutral, gamma positive straddle return (JUMP) is %. These sample estimates are consistent with the findings of Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum (2015) that the STR documented by Coval and Shumway (2001) is in large part due to the jump component (JUMP). Panel B reports the Spearman correlations between the daily factors, where the non-return based state variables are measured by their innovations. As expected, MKT is strongly negatively correlated with ΔVIX (-0.786), but much less with ΔVOV (-0.054). However, the correlation of MKT and ΔVOV increases to on days when the S&P 500 index declines by more than 1.91%, (the 5 th percentile value of daily rspx), while the correlation of MKT and ΔVIX increases to VRP is positively correlated with ΔVOV (0.140) and JUMP (0.090), consistent with Bollerslev, 17

20 Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) and Drechsler and Yaron (2011), respectively. ΔKURT and ΔSKEW are highly correlated at , which is comparable to the reported by Chang, Kristoffersen, and Jacobs (2013). Further, STR has a much higher correlation with JUMP (0.929) than that with VOL (0.263), which is similar to the findings reported by Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum (2015). Interestingly, ΔVOV has low correlations with ΔVIX (0.065), ΔSKEW (-0.006), ΔKURT (-0.016), STR (0.065), VOL (0.055), and JUMP (0.055), which suggests that the pricing power of VOV, if any, is unlikely to be due to these market moments proposed by previous studies. While ΔVOV has a low correlation with ΔVIX, VOV determines the market volatility risk. According Proposition 2, VOV dictates the extent to which the contemporaneous market return and market volatility covary. Indeed, the results of the following two simple regressions show that the daily bipower covariance, CVRV, between the market return and the market variance (using the intraday 5-min logarithmic return multiplied by 22 and the 5-min implied variance for S&P 500 index) is significantly and negatively related to VOV: , , The regression results suggest that the correlation between market returns and the market variance becomes more negative as VOV increases. Figure 2 depicts VOV and -CVRV (i.e., the negative of CVRV) over time. The two time-series strongly co-move together. Furthermore, the results of the following two simple regressions show that the market variance risk premium (VRP) is significantly and positively related to VOV and significantly and negatively related to CVRV , ,

21 The results are consistent with our model in which an increase in VOV makes the market more uncertain, and leads investors to demand a higher risk premium, resulting in a lower stock price and a negative contemporaneous market return. If VOV is indeed a determinant of the equity risk premium, the lower stock price now paves the way for a higher future return, which means that future stock returns are predictable by VOV. We examine this prediction in the next subsection VOV s predictability of future market returns Table 2 reports the results of the one-period return predictability regression of daily S&P 500 logarithmic returns (rspx) in excess of the risk-free rate (rf) on the lagged bipower covariance (CVRV), market volatility (VIX), variance of market variance (VOV), variance risk premium (VRP), market skewness (SKEW), market kurtosis (KURT), and jump risk (JUMP). We use robust Newey- West (1987) t-statistics with the optimal lags to account for autocorrelations. Panel A presents the regressions at a daily frequency. Consistent with Proposition 3, in columns [1] through [3], we find that VOV positively predicts one-period ahead daily market return in all of the specifications that include the aforementioned control variables (except for CVRV). Consistent with Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) and Drechsler and Yaron (2011), VRP significantly predicts future stock market returns. Nevertheless, VOV contains information about future stock market returns beyond that in VRP. Moreover, column [4] reports that CVRV negatively predicts one-period ahead daily market returns. That is, future market returns will be higher when the market return and the market variance are more negatively correlated (i.e., when VOV is higher). Thus, CVRV also impacts future market returns and this impact is driven by VOV. In column [5], we find that VOV and CVRV become less significant when both are in the regression model, suggesting that they contain similar information about future market returns. Since VOV is still marginally significant and CVRV is 19

22 insignificant in the regression, it suggests that VOV is the main driving force for the market return predictability of the covariance of the market return and the market variance. However, the market variance itself, as measured by VIX, is insignificant in all the specifications. Thus, while VIX is inversely correlated with the contemporaneous market return, it contains little information about future market returns. In Panel B of Table 2, we use the monthly S&P 500 logarithmic returns (rspx) in excess of the risk-free rate (rf) as the dependent variable, and the independent variables are sampled at the end of the previous month. We similarly find that VOV positively predicts one-period ahead monthly market returns in all of the specifications, except when CVRV is included as one of the independent variables. Overall, the test results support our proposition that VOV is an important determinant of the market risk premium, and a state variable that affects the aggregate asset prices. 5. VOV risk in the cross-sectional stock returns This section examines how VOV risk affects cross-sectional stock returns. Following Ang et al. (2006), we use daily returns to estimate betas each month t for each firm i listed on the NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ with more than 17 daily observations in a given month.,,,,,,. (12) We then use the pre-ranking betas obtained from the above regression in the previous month to form the test assets. Specifically, we independently sort the pre-ranking betas,, and,, each into quintile portfolios to obtain 25 (5x5) test portfolios. After portfolio formation, we calculate the value-weighted daily and monthly stock returns for each portfolio. Using these 25 portfolio test assets, we test our proposition that, holding other things constant, the expected return on portfolio p is determined by its three systematic risks implied by our proposed model, 20

23 ,,,, (13) where,,,, and, are the post-ranking betas obtained from the following time series regression estimated over the entire sample period,,,,,,,. (14) In addition, since our theoretical model (see Proposition 4) results in factor loadings that are related to time-varying volatility and time-varying volatility-of-volatility, we follow Avramov and Chordia (2006) to estimate a conditional beta model as follows,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,, (15) Thus, the expected return on portfolio p is determined by,,,,,,,,,,,,. (16) The above specification facilitates the identification of two time-varying systematic risks,,,,,,,, and,,,,,, which not only nest the constant betas of, and, examined by Ang et al. (2006) but also incorporate the time-varying betas of,,,,,, and,, implied by our theoretical model. 5.1.Portfolios results We first use the, and, sorted portfolios to test how portfolio returns vary with their post-ranking VIX betas and VOV betas and report the results in Table 3. Specifically, we sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on,, from the lowest (quintile 1) to the highest (quintile 5), and also independently sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on,. For each of the quintile portfolios sorted on,, we average across the five, portfolios that intersect 21

24 with the, portfolio, resulting in, quintile portfolios controlling for,. A similar approach yields, quintile portfolios controlling for,. We expect the portfolio returns to decrease with VOV beta for the following reason. Proposition 2 shows that the market return decreases with VOV and so a stock whose return increases with VOV i.e., a positive, will provide a hedge against the VOV risk, thus earning a lower return than a stock with a negative,. Panel A of Table 3 reports that controlling for,, the quintile 5 stocks (whose returns co-move more positively with VOV beta) have lower average returns than the quintile 1 stocks with a negative VOV beta, by 72 basis points per month (t-statistic = -2.25). Controlling for Fama-French (1993) and Carhart (1997) four factor model, the 5-1 long-short portfolio yields a significant alpha of percent per month with a t-statistic of The test results suggest that VOV risk is priced independent of volatility risk and the widely used factors market, size, B/M, and momentum factors. The post-ranking beta,,, lines up with the pre-ranking beta,, and increases from quintile 1 to the quintile 5 portfolio. The, -sorted 5-1 long-short portfolio has a significant positive post-ranking, of 0.18 (t=2.26), an insignificant, of 0.01 (t=0.23) and an insignificant, of 0.01 (t=0.23). Furthermore, it is clear that the post ranking betas are timevarying. Consistent with Proposition 4, we find that, varies with the market variance and the VOV and, varies with VOV. 10 In terms of the firm characteristics, the quintile 5 firms are the larger more liquid firms and have lower past month returns as compared to the quintile 1 firms. Controlling for,, we also find that the return difference between stocks with high volatility risk and stocks with low volatility risk is significantly negative, at percent per 10 Proposition 4 actually shows that, varies with the economic volatility and the economic volatility of volatility but these are in turn related to market volatility and VOV. 22

25 month with a t-statistic of The, -sorted 5-1 long-short portfolio has significant positive post-ranking, of 0.10 (t=3.97) as well as significant, of 0.24 (t=4.49) and significant, of 0.03 (t=1.89). The negative impact of, on the cross-section of stock returns is also consistent with our model and with the results in Ang et al. (2006). Proposition 2 shows that the market return and variance are negatively correlated. Thus, a stock whose return is positively correlated with the market variance will provide a hedge and earn negative returns. Note that the, -sorted portfolios are accompanied by dispersed post-ranking factor loadings with respect to not only the VIX factor but also the MKT and the VOV factors. Further, unlike in the case of the, -sorted portfolios, the betas are no longer time-varying. In terms of the firm characteristics, the quintile 5 firms are smaller than the quintile 1 firms Controlling for firm characteristics, high moment risks, and jump risk We now check whether our results are robust to other competing systematic risks and also firm characteristics. Table 4 presents results on, -sorted portfolios, controlling for market capitalization (Size), book-to-market ratio (B/M), past 11-month returns (RET_2_12), past onemonth return (RET_1) and Amihud s illiquidity (ILLIQ). We also control for other competing systematic risks including the Chang, Christoffersen, and Jacobs (2013) market skewness risk (, ) and market kurtosis risk (, ), the Coval and Shumway (2001) volatility risk with respect to the zero beta straddle factor (, ), the Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum (2015) volatility risk (, ) and jump risk (, ), and the Kelly and Jiang (2014) return tail risk (, ). As before, we independently sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on, and on the other factors or characteristics. We then average the returns across the, portfolios. Panel A of Table 4 presents the post-ranking portfolio alphas for, quintile portfolios controlling for the firm characteristics and other potential sources of systematic risk. The Fama- 23

26 French (1993) and Carhart (1997) four factor alpha of the 5-1 long short portfolio remains significant at percent (t=-1.94) after controlling for Size; at percent (t=-2.48) after controlling for B/M; at percent (t= -2.08) after controlling for RET_2_12; at percent (t=-2.16) after controlling for RET_1; and at percent (t=-1.98) after controlling for ILLIQ. Thus, the lower returns on higher, stocks are not driven by the well-known firm characteristics that impact the cross-section of stock returns. Panel A further shows that the four-factor alpha of the 5-1 long short portfolio sorted by, also remains significant after controlling for the competing systematic risks. Specifically, the alpha is percent (t=-2.34) after controlling for, ; percent (t=-2.14) after controlling for, ; percent (t=-2.35) after controlling for, ; percent (t=-2.40) after controlling for, ; percent (t=-2.75) after controlling for, ; and percent (t=-2.37) after controlling for,. Again, the results imply that the lower returns on higher, stocks are not likely due to the existing high-moment risks, jump risk, or tail risk. Table 4 also presents results for the quintile portfolios sorted on each of the competing systematic risks. Panel C controls for,, while Panel B does not. Panel B shows that, in our sample period, only, and, are significantly priced, with their four factor 5-1 alphas at (t=-2.50) and at (t=-1.65), respectively. Controlling for,, as shown in Panel C, the four factor 5-1 alpha for, remains significantly negative at (t = -2.13), but the four factor 5-1 alpha for, is no longer significant. This indicates that a substantial part of the jump risk premium is due to VOV risk. In summary, the return differential associated with, cannot be explained by either firm characteristics or other competing systematic risks. On the other hand, while, and, are the only two other competing systematic risks that carry significant return differentials in our sample period, and moreover, subsumes the pricing effect of,. 24

27 5.3. Cross-Sectional Regressions We now run Fama-MacBeth (1973) regressions to estimate the risk premium on VOV risk while controlling for the other risk factors including the Fama-French and Carhart factors (SMB, HML, and UMD), the Chang, Christoffersen, and Jacobs (2013) market skewness factor (ΔSKEW) and market kurtosis factor (ΔKURT), and the Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum (2015) jump factor (JUMP). Our main set of test assets are the 25 portfolios formed on intersection of, and, quintile portfolios. Since, and, are the only two other competing systematic risks that carry significant return differentials in our sample period as shown in Table 4, we also form 125 (5x5x5) portfolios by sorting on,, β,, and, and yet another set of 25 portfolios by sorting on, and,. For each portfolio, we use the postformation daily value-weighted returns to obtain the post-formation factor loadings. We then run the cross-sectional regressions to estimate the premiums. Robust Newey and West (1987) standard errors with six lags that account for autocorrelations are used. Panel A of Table 5 presents the constant beta results while Panel B presents results for the time-varying betas. In column [1] of Panel A, the estimated price for VOV beta,, is (t = -2.51), implying that investors are willing to accept a lower return to the tune of 3.35% on their investments for a unit increase in VOV beta. To apply this price of VOV risk to the 5-1 hedge portfolio in Table 3, a VOV beta difference of 0.18 between quintile portfolio 5 and quintile portfolio 1 contributes 0.60 percent lower (i.e., =-0.60) per month to the hedge portfolio s expected return, which accounts for about 83% of the hedge portfolio s return of % per month. Column [2] shows that adding other risks to the regressions does not materially change the risk premium on VOV. In fact, none of the other risk factors are significant. In column [3] where we use the 125 portfolios independently sorted on,,,, and,, we 25

28 find that the estimate of is significantly negative at with a t-statistic of -6.51, but the estimates of and are insignificant with t-statistics of 0.30 and -0.54, respectively. Further, in column [4] where we use the 25 portfolios independently sorted on, and,, we similarly find that the estimate of remains significantly negative at with a t-statistic of -1.98, but the estimate of is insignificant with a t-statistic of Thus, VOV risk is robust in the presence of other risk factors and with different test assets. In contrast, while the estimated price of VIX risk,, is significant at (t =-1.84) in column [1], it becomes insignificant when Fama-French-Carhart factors and other higher moment factors are included as shown in columns [2], [3], and [4]. This suggests that VOV risk has stronger pricing power than VIX risk. In Panel B, we estimate the time-varying beta model of equation (15), using VIX and the VOV as conditioning variables. The risk premium estimates are obtained for the expected return in equation (16), which gives the estimates of premiums,,,,,,,,, and. As with the constant beta results in Panel A, we find that is significant across all different combinations of risk factors. In addition, as reported in column [6],,,,, and, are significant suggesting that betas are indeed time-varying as suggested by Proposition 4. Even with all the other factors in columns [8],,, and, are still marginally significant consistent with the time-varying factor loadings as per our theoretical model. Overall, VOV risk is a surprisingly robust pricing factor! 5.4. Firm-level Fama-MacBeth regressions Thus far, we have used various portfolio approaches to show that VOV risk is priced. In this section, we further examine whether the pricing of VOV risk is robust to the firm-level analysis. Using individual stocks as test assets may avoid potentially spurious results that could arise when 26

29 the test portfolios exhibit a factor structure (Lewellen, Nagel, and Shanken, 2010). Furthermore, Lo and MacKinlay (1990) argue that portfolio sorts could lead to data snooping biases. In addition, a stock-level analysis allows us to control for important firm characteristics. Specifically, we run the following cross-sectional regression:,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,, (17) where the dependent variable is the monthly individual excess stock return. We use the 25 portfolios formed on intersection of, quintile portfolios and, quintile portfolios and, following the methodology of Fama and French (1992), we assign each of the 25 portfolio-level post-ranking beta estimates to the individual stocks within the portfolio at that time. Small stocks ranked in the first decile based on NYSE breakpoints are excluded from the sample. For stock i that belongs to portfolio p at time t,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,, and,, are the post-ranking betas from the time-series regression (15). Thus, not only do we estimate time-varying betas, the individual stock betas can also vary over time because the portfolio compositions can change each month. We also report the time-constant betas results using the post-ranking betas,,,,,, and,, from the time-series regression (14). One again, we use Newey and West (1987) standard errors with six lags., denotes a set of firm characteristic variables that consist of Size, B/M, RET_1, RET_2_12, and ILLIQ. We also check whether our results are robust to existing well-known volatility spreads that affect cross-sectional stock returns. We construct the implied-realized volatility spread (IVOL-TVOL), which, as described in Bali and Hovakimian (2009), is defined as the average of implied volatilities of at-the-money call and put options minus the total volatility calculated using daily returns in the previous month; the call-put implied volatility spread (CIVOL- 27

30 PIVOL), which, as described in Bali and Hovakimian (2009) and Yan (2011), is defined as the atthe-money call option implied volatility minus the at-the-money put option implied volatility. Since we extract the volatility data from OptionMetrics Volatility Surface file as in Yan (2011), we choose the 30-day maturity put and call options with deltas equal to -0.5 and 0.5, respectively. Thus,, denotes a set of volatility characteristic variables that include IVOL- TVOL, and CIVOL-PIVOL. Table 6 presents the results from the firm-level Fama-MacBeth regressions. Panel A presents the constant beta results while Panel B presents the conditional beta results. Column [1] of Panel A shows that while is insignificant, is significantly negative at (t=-5.10) and the risk premium of VOV at the firm level is close to that estimated from the portfolio approach, as reported in Table 5. Controlling for IVOL-TVOL and CIVOL-PIVOL, the estimate of remains significantly negative at -3.10, with a t-statistic of -4.19, as shown in column [2]. In Panel B, we find that remains significantly negative at -1.11(t=-1.89) controlling for firm characteristics as shown in column [3] and at (t=-1.98) further controlling for volatility characteristics as shown in column [4]. In addition, consistent with previous findings,,, and, are significant with t-statistics of 4.08 and -4.40, as reported in column [3], respectively and 2.60 and -2.87, as reported in column [4], respectively. Thus, once again, consistent with our theoretical model, we find evidence for time variation in the betas. The firm characteristics - illiquidity, firm size, the past one month return, the realized volatility spread, and the call-put implied volatility spread are all significant with signs that are consistent with the prior literature. Overall, the firm-level evidence confirms our results that VOV is a priced risk factor. 28

31 5.5. Market crash and volatility risk In contrast to the results in Ang et al. (2006), Tables 5 and 6 show that the risk premium on the volatility (VIX) betas is essentially zero. To better understand why VOV risk is priced but volatility risk is not, we investigate the performance of the 25 portfolios independently sorted on, and, during the normal periods and crash periods. Table 7 presents the Fama MacBeth (1973) factor premiums during the market crash period and the normal period for our time-constant and time-varying beta models. In Panel A, Crash is equal to one if the monthly market factor (MKT) is below %, its time-series mean minus three times standard deviation; and zero otherwise; Normal is defined by 1-Crash. The results are similar when we define Crash differently in Panels B (MKT is lower than the time-series mean minus twice the standard deviation) and C (MKT is lower than the 5 th percentile value). During normal times, when we remove the observations on the days with extreme market downturns, Panel A of Table 7 shows that is significantly positive at 1.97 with a t-statistic of 1.70, is significantly negative at with a t-statistic of -1.88, and is significantly negative at with a t-statistic of When we consider the time-varying beta, as shown in column [2],,,,,, and, are significant, but and become insignificant. In contrast, during crash periods with extreme market downturns, as shown in columns [3] and [4], becomes even more negative while becomes significantly negative and becomes significantly positive. Thus, while large market declines reverse the risk-return tradeoff for the market risk and volatility risk, the market turmoil strengthens investors demand for compensation for VOV risk. This implies that volatility risk in asset pricing, as proposed by 29

32 Ang et al. (2006), has a negative premium during normal times but when combined with the positive premium during crash periods, the overall premium is zero in Tables 5 and Time-varying volatility risk In this section, we examine the risk premiums of the time-constant and the time-varying volatility risk. Table 8 reports the performance of portfolios sorted on the pre-ranking, and,, using the time-varying beta model of,,,,,,,,,,,,. (18) We first sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on,, from the lowest (quintile 1) to the highest (quintile 5), and within each quintile we further sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on,,. Portfolios are rebalanced monthly and are value weighted. In Panel A, each of the quintile portfolios sorted on,, is then averaged over the five portfolios intersected with the quintile portfolios sorted on,, resulting in,, quintile portfolios controlling for,. In Panel B, similar approach yields, quintile portfolios controlling for,,. The results show that, stocks with high,, (quintile 5) have a lower average return than stocks with more negative,, (quintile 1) by 0.42 percent per month with a t-statistic of Controlling for Fama-French (1993) and Carhart (1997) four factor model, the 5-1 long-short portfolio yields a significant alpha of percent per month with a t-statistic of In contrast, the 5-1 longshort portfolio sorted on, only produces insignificant differentials in stock returns, at 0.10 percent per month with a t-statistic of The results confirm the previous findings that while the constant volatility risk premium has limited explanatory power, the time-varying volatility risk (conditional on VOV) is priced in the cross-section of stock returns. 6. Conclusion 30

33 This paper extends Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) to study the asset pricing implications of the volatility-of-volatility (VOV), and contributes to the literature along two dimensions. First, we establish that VOV is an important determinant of the market risk premium by showing that VOV dictates the negative covariance between the contemporaneous market return and market volatility and that it predicts future market returns. Second, we develop a market-based three-factor model in which the market (MKT) risk, market volatility (VIX) risk, and market VOV risk determine the cross-section of asset returns. We find that VOV risk is robustly priced and that stocks with more negative VOV betas have significantly higher future stock returns, even after we account for the exposures to the Fama- French (1993) and Carhart(1997) factors, the market skewness and kurtosis factors, the jump risk factor, as well as firm characteristics. While, the unconditional VIX beta and the MKT beta are not priced in our sample, consistent with the theoretical model, the conditional component of the factor loadings of both, VIX and the MKT, are priced. All the three risks (MKT, VIX, VOV) in the asset pricing model are significantly priced during normal times when we remove the observations with large market declines from our sample. However, during crash periods, the price of VOV risk becomes even more significant while the premiums on MKT and VIX have the wrong sign. The positive premium on VIX during market turmoil combined with the negative premium during normal periods, results in an overall VIX premium that is indistinguishable from zero. The results imply that market turmoil strengthens investors demand for compensation for VOV risk. 31

34 References Adrian, T., and Rosenberg, J., 2008, Stock returns and volatility: Pricing the short-run and longrun components of market risk, Journal of Finance 63, Amihud, Y., 2002, Illiquidity and stock returns: Cross-section and time-series effects, Journal of Financial Markets 5, Andersen, T. G., T. Bollerslev, and F. X. Diebold Roughing it up: Including jump components in the measurement, modeling, and forecasting of return volatility. Review of Economics and Statistics 89: Ang, A. R. J. Hodrick, Y. Xing, and X. Zhang, The cross-section of volatility and expected returns. Journal of Finance 61: Avramov, D., and T. Chordia, 2006, Asset Pricing Models and Financial Market Anomalies. Review of Financial Studies 19, Bakshi, G., and D. Madan A theory of volatility spread. Management Science 52: Bakshi, G., N. Kapadia, and D. Madan, Stock return characteristics, skew laws, and the differential pricing of individual equity options. Review of Financial Studies 16: Bali, T. and A. Hovakimian, 2009, Volatility spreads and expected stock returns, Management Science, 55: Baltussen, G., S. Van Bekkum, and B. Van Der Grient, Unknown unknowns: Vol-of-vol and the cross-section of stock returns. AFA 2013 San Diego Meetings Paper. Bansal, R., and A. Yaron Risks for the long run: A potential resolution of asset pricing puzzles. Journal of Finance 59: Barndorff-Nielsen, O., and N. Shephard Power and bipower variation with stochastic volatility and jumps. Journal of Financial Econometrics 2:

35 Bekaert, G., and G. Wu Asymmetric volatility and risk in equity markets. Review of Financial Studies 13: Black, F., Studies of stock price volatility changes. Proceedings of the 1976 Meetings of the American Statistical Association, Business and Economical Statistics Section, Bollerslev, T., N. Sizova, and G. Tauchen, Volatility in equilibrium: Asymmetries and dynamic dependencies. Review of Finance 16: Bollerslev, T., G. Tauchen, and H. Zhou, Expected stock returns and variance risk premia. Review of Financial Studies 22: Bollerslev, T., and V. Todorov, Tails, fears, and risk premia. Journal of Finance 66: Britten-Jones, M., and A. Neuberger Option prices, implied price processes, and stochastic volatility. Journal of Finance 55: Campbell, J. Y., and L. Hentschel, 1992, No news is good news: An asymmetric model of changing volatility in stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics, 31, Campbell, J. Y., and R. J. Shiller, The dividend-price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. Review of Financial Studies 1: Carr, P., and D. Madan Towards a theory of volatility trading. In R. Jarrow (ed.), Volatility: New Estimation Techniques for Pricing Derivatives, chap. 29, pp London: Risk Books. Carr, P., and L. Wu Variance risk premia. Review of Financial Studies 22: Chang, B. Y., P. Christoffersen, and K. Jacobs, Market skewness risk and the cross section of stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics 107: Christie, A. A., The stochastic behavior of common stock variances Value, leverage and interest rate effects. Journal of Financial Economics 10:

36 Coval, J., and T. Shumway, 2001, Expected option returns, Journal of Finance 56, Cremers, M., M. Halling, D. Weibaum, 2015, Aggregate jump and volatility risk in the crosssection of stock returns, Journal of Finance 70: Drechsler, I., and A. Yaron, What's vol got to do with it. Review of Financial Studies 24: Drechsler, I., Uncertainty, time varying fear, and asset prices. Journal of Finance 68: Epstein, L.G., and S. E. Zin, Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: A theoretical framework. Econometrica 57: Eraker, B Affine general equilibrium models. Management Science 54: Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1992, The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance 47, Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1993, Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 33, Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 2015, A five-factor asset pricing model, Journal of Financial Economics 116, Fama, E. F., and J. D. MacBeth, 1973, Risk return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests, Journal of Political Economy 71, Hou, K., C. Xue, and L. Zhang, 2015, Digesting anomalies: An investment approach, Review of Financial Studies 28, Huang, X., and G. Tauchen The relative contribution of jumps to total price variance. Journal of Financial Econometrics 3:

37 Jiang, G., and Y. Tian Model-free implied volatility and its information content. Review of Financial Studies 18: Kelly, B., H. Jiang Tail risk and asset prices. Review of Financial Studies 27, Linter, J The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics 47: Lewellen, J., S. Nagel, and J. Shanken A skeptical appraisal of asset pricing tests. Journal of Financial Economics 96: Maio, P., and P. Santa-Clara, Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM. Journal of Financial Economics 106: Merton, R. C., An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica 41: Pan, J., The jump-risk premia implicit in options: Evidence from an integrated time-series study. Journal of Financial Economics 63: Sharpe, W. F., Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance 19: Wu, G., The determinants of asymmetric volatility. Review of Financial Studies 14, Yan, S., Jump risk, stock returns, and slope of implied volatility smile. Journal of Financial Economics 99:

38 Table 1: Properties of the daily factors We report summary statistics and Spearman correlations for the daily factors, including the four factors (MKT, SMB, HML, and UMD) of Fama and French (1993) and Carhart (1997), the market variance risk premium (VRP), the VIX index, our measure of variance of market variance (VOV), the bipower covariance (multiplied by 22) between the intraday five-minute logarithmic return and the five-minute implied variance for S&P 500 index (CVRV), the market skewness factor (SKEW) and market kurtosis factor (KURT) of Chang, Christoffersen, and Jacobs (2013), the zero beta straddle factor of Coval and Shumway (2001), and the options return volatility factor (VOL) and the options return jump factor (JUMP) of Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum (2015). ΔVIX is the first difference of VIX; ΔCVRV, ΔVOV, ΔSKEW, and ΔKURT are the residuals from fitting an ARMA(1,1) regression using VOV, SKEW, and KURT, respectively. The sample period is from January 1996 to December Panel A: Summary statistics MKT SMB HML UMD VRP VIX CVRV VOV SKEW KURT STR VOL JUMP (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) Mean Median Std.Dev Panel B: Spearman correlation MKT SMB HML UMD VRP ΔVIX ΔCVRV ΔVOV ΔSKEW ΔKURT STR VOL JUMP MKT SMB HML UMD VRP ΔVIX ΔCVRV ΔVOV ΔSKEW ΔKURT STR VOL JUMP

39 Table 2: CVRV, VOV, and future stock returns This table reports the estimates of the one-period return predictability regression using the logarithmic returns on the S&P 500 index (rspx) in excess of the risk-free rate (rf) on the lagged bipower covariance (multiplied by 22), between the intraday five-minute logarithmic return and the five-minute implied variance for S&P 500 index (CVRV), market volatility (VIX), variance of market variance (VOV), variance risk premium (VRP), market skewness (SKEW), market kurtosis (KURT), and jump risk (JUMP). The dependent variable in Panel A is the daily rspx-rf multiplied by 22. In Panel B, the dependent variable is the monthly rspx-rf and the independent variables are sampled at the end of the month. Robust Newey and West (1987) t-statistics are reported in parentheses. The sample period is from January 1996 to December Panel A: Dependent variable= daily rspx-rf (t) [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] Intercept (-0.29) (-0.46) (0.36) (0.99) (-0.16) VIX (t-1) (0.29) (-0.63) (-0.61) (-1.12) (0.16) VOV (t-1) (2.10) (2.05) (2.05) (1.66) CVRV (t-1) (-1.91) (-0.28) VRP (t-1) (3.75) (3.83) (3.72) SKEW (t-1) (1.56) (1.74) KURT (t-1) (1.43) (1.33) JUMP (t-1) (0.70) (0.62) rspx-rf (t-1) (-3.29) (-2.14) (-2.05) (-1.77) (-3.26) Adj. R Panel B: Dependent variable= monthly rspx-rf (t) [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] Intercept (0.06) (-0.12) (0.33) (0.67) (0.04) VIX (t-1) (0.13) (-0.70) (-0.87) (-1.39) (0.20) VOV (t-1) (2.73) (2.02) (1.92) (1.52) CVRV (t-1) (-2.25) (0.10) VRP (t-1) (4.14) (3.83) (4.97) SKEW (t-1) (-0.19) (-0.08) KURT (t-1) (-0.56) (-0.48) JUMP (t-1) (0.29) (0.12) rspx-rf (t-1) (1.39) (1.02) (1.17) (1.35) (1.34) Adj. R

40 Table 3: Two-way sorted portfolios on, and, At the end of each month, we run the following regression for each stock using daily returns:,,,,,,. We sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on,, from the lowest (quintile 1) to the highest (quintile 5), and independently sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on,. Portfolios are rebalanced monthly and are value weighted. In Panel A, each of the quintile portfolios sorted on, is then averaged over the five portfolios intersected with the quintile portfolios sorted on,, resulting in, quintile portfolios controlling for,. In Panel B, similar approach yields, quintile portfolios controlling for,. The column 5-1 refers to the hedge portfolio that longs portfolio 5 and shorts portfolio 1. Using the post-formation daily portfolio returns, we estimate the post-formation factor loadings for each portfolio separately from the following time-series regressions,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,, where,,,,,,,,,,,,,, and,, =,. Using the post-formation monthly portfolio returns, we compute the excess returns and the risk-adjusted returns of each portfolio with respect to Fama-French and Carhart four factors (MKT, SMB, HML, and UMD). Robust Newey West (1987) t-statistics are in parentheses. The sample period is from January 1996 to December Portfolios ranking t-stat Panel A: Performance of, sorted portfolio, controlling for, Excess return (-2.25) α-capm (-2.16) α-ff (-2.33) α-ffc (-2.79) Post-ranking factor loadings, (0.23), (0.23), (2.26) Post-ranking time-varying factor loadings, (4.93),, (-1.95),, (-2.00), (3.67),, (-1.90), (2.08) Pre-formation firm characteristics Size($b) (4.01) B/M (-1.38) RET_2_ (-0.10) RET_ (-5.68) ILLIQ(10 6 ) (-1.65) 38

41 Table 3 (continued.) Portfolios ranking t-stat Panel B: Performance of, sorted portfolio, controlling for, Excess return (-1.77) α-capm (-2.59) α-ff (-2.78) α-ffc (-2.58) Post-ranking factor loadings, (4.49), (3.97), (1.89) Post-ranking time varying factor loadings, (0.26),, (-0.42),, (1.53), (-0.40),, (1.64), (2.21) Pre-formation firm characteristics Size($b) (-4.33) B/M (0.94) RET_2_ (0.57) RET_ (1.14) ILLIQ(10 6 ) (-1.41) 39

42 Table 4: Two-way sorted portfolios on, and control variables This table shows performance of portfolios sorted on,, with controlling market capitalization (Size), book-tomarket ratio (B/M), past 11-month returns (RET_2_12), past one-month return (RET_1), and Amihud s illiquidity (ILLIQ), Chang, Christoffersen, and Jacobs s (2013) market skewness risk (, ) and market kurtosis risk (, ), Coval and Shumway s (2001) volatility risk with respect to the zero beta straddle factor (, ), Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum s (2015) volatility risk (, ) and jump risk (, ), and Kelly and Jiang s (2014) return tail risk (, ), respectively. We sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on,, from the lowest (quintile 1) to the highest (quintile 5), and independently sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on each control variable. Portfolios are rebalanced monthly and are value weighted. Panel A presents the results for, quintile portfolios controlling for the quintile portfolios sorted on each control variable. The results for the quintile portfolios sorted on each of the competing systematic risks without and with controlling for, quintile portfolios are presented in Panel B and in Panel C, respectively. The column 5-1 refers to the hedge portfolio that longs portfolio 5 and shorts portfolio 1. Using the post-formation monthly portfolio returns, we compute the risk-adjusted returns of each portfolio with respect to Fama-French and Carhart four factors (MKT, SMB, HML, and UMD). Robust Newey West (1987) t-statistics are in parentheses. The sample period is from January 1996 to December Portfolios ranking Control variables t-stat Panel A: Performance of, sorted portfolio, controlling for each control variable Size (-1.94) B/M (-2.48) RET_2_ (-2.08) RET_ (-2.16) ILLIQ (-1.98), (-2.34), (-2.14), (-2.35), (-2.40), (-2.75), (-2.37) 40

43 Table 4 (continued.) Portfolios ranking Control variables t-stat Panel B: Performance of each control variable sorted portfolio, (-2.50), (1.11), (-1.01), (0.76), (-1.65), (1.44) Panel C: Performance of each control variable sorted portfolio, controlling for,, (-2.13), (0.71), (-0.96), (0.90), (-1.53), (1.30) 41

44 Table 5: Fama-MacBeth regressions This table presents the Fama MacBeth (1973) factor premiums for the volatility-of-volatility factor (ΔVOV), with controlling for the market factor (MKT), the volatility factor (ΔVIX), Fama-French and Carhart factors (SMB, HML, and UMD), Chang, Christoffersen, and Jacobs s (2013) market skewness factor (ΔSKEW) and market kurtosis factor (ΔKURT), and Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum s (2015) jump factor (JUMP). We estimate the first stage return betas using the daily full-sample post-formation value-weighted returns. Then, we regress the cross-sectional monthly portfolio returns on daily return betas from the first stage, using Fama MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regression. In Panel A, the testing model is,,, where,,,, and, are the post-ranking betas from the time-series regression of,,,,,,. In Panel B, the testing model is,,,,,,,,,,,,, where the post-ranking betas are from,,,,,,,,, where,,,,,,,, and,,,,, Three sets of test portfolios are considered. In columns [1], [2], and [5] through [8], the test portfolios are the 25 portfolios independently sorted on, and,. Column [3] uses the 125 portfolios independently sorted on,,,, and,. Column [4] uses the 25 portfolios independently sorted on, and,. Portfolios are rebalanced monthly and are value weighted. Robust Newey West (1987) t-statistics that account for autocorrelations are in parentheses. The sample period is from January 1996 to December Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions Panel A: Constant beta models Panel B: Time-varying beta models Test portfolios,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,, [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] Intercept (-1.08) 0.30 (0.23) (-1.87) 2.42 (1.58) 1.04 (1.39) (-0.54) 2.36 (2.19) 0.25 (0.18), 1.84 (1.60) 0.33 (0.24) 2.95 (2.59) (-1.16) (-0.45) 1.22 (1.02) (-1.51) 0.34 (0.23), (-1.84) (-0.96) 0.44 (0.22) 5.14 (1.12) 1.31 (0.41) (-1.12) 3.06 (0.92) (-0.71), (-2.51) (-2.84) (-6.51) (-1.98) (-2.54) (-2.59) (-2.87) (-2.77),, 0.90 (1.82) 0.61 (1.24),, 0.13 (1.85) 0.14 (1.72),, (-1.87) (-1.73), (-0.58) (-1.74) 1.69 (1.40) (-0.54) (-0.50), (-0.26) (-0.72) 1.38 (1.54) 0.16 (0.33) (-0.08), (-0.95) (-0.16) 0.83 (0.87) (-2.13) (-0.31), 1.79 (1.09) 0.03 (0.30) 2.19 (1.29) 1.71 (1.06) 1.88 (1.12), (-0.72) (-0.54) (-1.31) (-1.22) (-0.75), (-0.10) 4.24 (0.40) (0.77) (0.79) (-0.37) Adj. R

45 Table 6: Firm-level Fama-MacBeth regressions This table reports the results for the firm-level Fama-MacBeth regressions. We run the following cross-sectional regression:,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,, where the dependent variable is the monthly individual stock returns; We use the 25 portfolios formed on intersection of, quintile portfolios and, quintile portfolios and, following the methodology of Fama and French (1992), we assign each of the 25 portfolio-level post-ranking beta estimates to the individual stocks within the portfolio at that time. Small stocks ranked in the first decile based on NYSE breakpoints are excluded. In Panel A, for stock i that belongs to portfolio p at time t,,,,,,, and,, are the post-ranking betas from the time-series regression of,,,,,, ; In Panel B,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,, and,, are from regression of,,,,,,,,,,,,,., consists of Size, B/M, RET_2_12, RET_1, and ILLIQ;, includes the impliedrealized volatility spread (IVOL-TVOL) and the call-put implied volatility spread (CIVOL-PIVOL). Robust Newey and West (1987) t-statistics that account for autocorrelations are reported in parentheses. The sample period is from January 1996 to December Fama-MacBeth regressions: individual stocks Panel A: Constant beta models Panel B: Time-varying beta models [1] [2] [3] [4] Intercept (-0.96) 0.56 (0.44) (-0.01) 1.45 (1.15) Log(Size($b)) (-4.95) (-3.02) (-4.92) (-2.98) Log(B/M) 0.11 (0.96) 0.10 (0.77) 0.11 (0.95) 0.10 (0.78) RET_2_ (0.99) 0.20 (0.56) 0.35 (1.02) 0.21 (0.57) RET_ (-2.80) (-2.12) (-2.77) (-2.12) ILLIQ(10 6 ) 0.49 (2.46) 2.91 (3.08) 0.50 (2.51) 2.93 (3.09), 1.96 (1.65) 0.37 (0.28) 0.93 (0.77) (-0.35), 0.08 (0.02) 4.25 (0.91) 2.57 (0.66) 5.81 (1.28), (-4.33) (-4.19) (-1.89) (-1.98),, 0.23 (0.50) (-0.73),, 0.20 (4.08) 0.16 (2.60),, (-4.40) (-2.87) IVOL-TVOL 0.76 (3.72) 0.76 (3.71) CIVOL-PIVOL 4.05 (6.63) 4.01 (6.66) Adj. R No. obs 570, , , ,187

46 Table 7: Market crash and factor premiums This table presents the Fama MacBeth (1973) factor premiums during the market crash period and the normal period for the market factor (MKT), the volatility factor (ΔVIX), and the volatility-of-volatility factor (ΔVOV). The test portfolios are the 25 portfolios independently sorted on, and, and the portfolios are rebalanced monthly and value weighted. Crash is equal to one if the monthly market factor (MKT) is below %, its time-series mean minus three times standard deviation; and zero otherwise; Normal is defined by 1-Crash. Using the post-formation daily portfolio returns, we compute the risk exposures with respect to our constant beta model and time-varying beta model. Then we regress the cross-sectional monthly portfolio returns on betas from the first stage, using Fama MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regression. The constant beta model is,,, where the post-ranking betas are from the time-series regression of,,,,,,. The time-varying beta model is,,,,,,,,,,,,, where the postranking betas are from,,,,,,,,, where,,,,,,,, and,,,,,. We report the estimates of factor premiums using the Normal periods in columns [1] and [2] and using the Crash periods in columns [3] and [4]. Robust Newey and West (1987) t-statistics that account for autocorrelations are reported in parentheses. The sample period is from January 1996 to December Normal periods Crash periods [1] [2] [3] [4] Panel A: Crash(t) =1 if MKT(t) <-13.10% (Mean-3*SD of MKT) Intercept (-1.07) (-0.56) (-6.04) 3.79 (1.16), 1.97 (1.70) 1.40 (1.17) (-80.10) (-5.45), (-1.88) (-1.21) (2.74) (7.35), (-2.47) (-2.57) (-1.96) (-4.20),, 0.94 (1.87) (-4.68),, 0.13 (1.83) 0.41 (0.53),, (-1.84) (-0.62) Adj. R

47 Table 7 (continued.) Normal periods Crash periods [1] [2] [3] [4] Panel B: Crash(t) =1 if MKT(t)< -8.54% (Mean- 2*SD of MKT) Intercept (-1.36) (-0.98) 9.23 (1.70) (3.01), 2.60 (2.17) 2.16 (1.81) (-4.03) (-5.80), (-2.17) (-1.54) (1.66) (1.90), (-2.39) (-2.47) (-3.10) (-2.16),, 1.12 (2.16) (-2.29),, 0.14 (1.71) 0.04 (0.06),, (-1.69) (-0.30) Adj. R Panel C: Crash(t) =1 if MKT(t)< (5 th percentile of MKT) Intercept (-1.20) (-0.86) 1.43 (0.22) 7.14 (1.04), 2.55 (2.17) 2.19 (1.83) (-1.82) (-2.56), (-2.06) (-1.43) (0.65) (1.02), (-2.28) (-2.43) (-2.85) (-1.73),, 1.07 (2.12) (-0.92),, 0.13 (1.58) 0.20 (0.40),, (-1.54) (-0.71) Adj. R

48 Table 8: Performance of portfolios formed on, and,, At the end of each month, we run the following regression for each stock using daily returns:,,,,,,,,,,,,. We first sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on,, from the lowest (quintile 1) to the highest (quintile 5), and within each quintile we further sort stocks into quintile portfolios based on,,. Portfolios are rebalanced monthly and are value weighted. In Panel A, each of the quintile portfolios sorted on,, is then averaged over the five portfolios intersected with the quintile portfolios sorted on,, resulting in,, quintile portfolios controlling for,. In Panel B, similar approach yields, quintile portfolios controlling for,,. The column 5-1 refers to the hedge portfolio that longs portfolio 5 and shorts portfolio 1. Using the post-formation monthly portfolio returns, we compute the excess returns and the risk-adjusted returns of each portfolio with respect to Fama-French and Carhart four factors (MKT, SMB, HML, and UMD). Robust Newey West (1987) t-statistics are in parentheses. The sample period is from January 1996 to December Portfolios ranking t-stat Panel A: Performance of,, sorted portfolio, controlling for, Excess return (-2.35) α-capm (-3.09) α-ff (-3.01) α-ffc (-2.87) Panel B: Performance of, sorted portfolio, controlling for,, Excess return (0.54) α-capm (0.48) α-ff (0.27) α-ffc (-0.33) 46

49 Figure 1. Daily market returns (rspx) and market volatility (VIX). We plot daily market returns (rspx) and changes in market volatility (ΔVIX) over the time period from January 1996 through December

50 Figure 2 Daily market covariance between return and variance (CVRV), and market volatility-of-volatility (VOV). We plot daily minus market covariance between return and variance (-CVRV) and market volatility-ofvolatility (VOV) over the time period from January 1996 through December We partition the tick-by-tick S&P500 index options data into five-minute intervals, and then we estimate the model-free implied variance for each interval. For each day, we use the bipower variation formula on the five-minute based annualized 30-day model-free implied variance estimates within the day, resulting in our daily measure of market volatility-of-volatility (VOV). We estimate the covariance between the market return and the market variance (CVRV) using the bipower covariation formula on the five-minute based S&P500 index returns and the five-minute based annualized 30-day model-free implied variance within the day. 48

Volatility-of-Volatility Risk in Asset Pricing

Volatility-of-Volatility Risk in Asset Pricing Volatility-of-Volatility Risk in Asset Pricing Te-Feng Chen San-Lin Chung Ji-Chai Lin tfchen@polyu.edu.hk chungsl@ntu.edu.tw jclin@polyu.edu.hk Abstract: Exploring the equilibrium model of Bollerslev et

More information

Volatility-of-Volatility Risk and Asset Prices

Volatility-of-Volatility Risk and Asset Prices olatility-of-olatility Risk and Asset Prices Te-Feng Chen National Taiwan University, Taipei, Taiwan Tel: (+886) 2-3366-1100 Email: d94723008@ntu.edu.tw San-Lin Chung National Taiwan University, Taipei,

More information

Volatility Jump Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns. Yu Li University of Houston. September 29, 2017

Volatility Jump Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns. Yu Li University of Houston. September 29, 2017 Volatility Jump Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Yu Li University of Houston September 29, 2017 Abstract Jumps in aggregate volatility has been established as an important factor affecting the

More information

In Search of Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk. in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns*

In Search of Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk. in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns* In Search of Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns* Martijn Cremers a Yale School of Management Michael Halling b University of Utah David Weinbaum c Syracuse University

More information

Portfolio Management Using Option Data

Portfolio Management Using Option Data Portfolio Management Using Option Data Peter Christoffersen Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto, Copenhagen Business School, and CREATES, University of Aarhus 2 nd Lecture on Friday 1 Overview

More information

Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXX, NO. 2 APRIL 2015 Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns MARTIJN CREMERS, MICHAEL HALLING, and DAVID WEINBAUM ABSTRACT We examine the pricing

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

Asymmetric Effects of Volatility Risk on Stock Returns: Evidence from VIX and VIX Futures

Asymmetric Effects of Volatility Risk on Stock Returns: Evidence from VIX and VIX Futures Asymmetric Effects of Volatility Risk on Stock Returns: Evidence from VIX and VIX Futures Xi Fu * Matteo Sandri Mark B. Shackleton Lancaster University Lancaster University Lancaster University Abstract

More information

This paper investigates whether realized and implied volatilities of individual stocks can predict the crosssectional

This paper investigates whether realized and implied volatilities of individual stocks can predict the crosssectional MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Vol. 55, No. 11, November 2009, pp. 1797 1812 issn 0025-1909 eissn 1526-5501 09 5511 1797 informs doi 10.1287/mnsc.1090.1063 2009 INFORMS Volatility Spreads and Expected Stock Returns

More information

Moment risk premia and the cross-section of stock returns in the European stock market

Moment risk premia and the cross-section of stock returns in the European stock market Moment risk premia and the cross-section of stock returns in the European stock market 10 January 2018 Elyas Elyasiani, a Luca Gambarelli, b Silvia Muzzioli c a Fox School of Business, Temple University,

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

In Search of Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns*

In Search of Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns* In Search of Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns* Martijn Cremers a Yale School of Management Michael Halling b University of Utah David Weinbaum c Syracuse University

More information

Asubstantial portion of the academic

Asubstantial portion of the academic The Decline of Informed Trading in the Equity and Options Markets Charles Cao, David Gempesaw, and Timothy Simin Charles Cao is the Smeal Chair Professor of Finance in the Smeal College of Business at

More information

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Itamar Drechsler Alan Moreira Alexi Savov Wharton Rochester NYU Chicago November 2018 1 Liquidity and Volatility 1. Liquidity creation - makes it cheaper to pledge

More information

Variance Premium, Downside Risk, and Expected Stock Returns

Variance Premium, Downside Risk, and Expected Stock Returns Variance Premium, Downside Risk, and Expected Stock Returns Bruno Feunou Bank of Canada Roméo Tédongap ESSEC Business School Ricardo Lopez Aliouchkin Syracuse University Lai Xu Syracuse University We thank

More information

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Itamar Drechsler, NYU and NBER Alan Moreira, Rochester Alexi Savov, NYU and NBER JHU Carey Finance Conference June, 2018 1 Liquidity and Volatility 1. Liquidity creation

More information

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix 1 Tercile Portfolios The main body of the paper presents results from quintile RNS-sorted portfolios. Here,

More information

Asset Pricing Implications of the Volatility Term Structure. Chen Xie

Asset Pricing Implications of the Volatility Term Structure. Chen Xie Asset Pricing Implications of the Volatility Term Structure Chen Xie Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy under the Executive Committee in the Graduate

More information

University of California Berkeley

University of California Berkeley University of California Berkeley A Comment on The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns : The Statistical Significance of FVIX is Driven by a Single Outlier Robert M. Anderson Stephen W. Bianchi

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

Option Markets and Stock Return. Predictability

Option Markets and Stock Return. Predictability Option Markets and Stock Return Predictability Danjue Shang Oct, 2015 Abstract I investigate the information content in the implied volatility spread: the spread in implied volatilities between a pair

More information

VOLATILITY RISK PREMIA BETAS

VOLATILITY RISK PREMIA BETAS VOLATILITY RISK PREMIA BETAS Ana González-Urteaga Universidad Pública de Navarra Gonzalo Rubio Universidad CEU Cardenal Herrera Abstract This paper analyzes the cross-sectional and time-series behavior

More information

Explaining individual firm credit default swap spreads with equity volatility and jump risks

Explaining individual firm credit default swap spreads with equity volatility and jump risks Explaining individual firm credit default swap spreads with equity volatility and jump risks By Y B Zhang (Fitch), H Zhou (Federal Reserve Board) and H Zhu (BIS) Presenter: Kostas Tsatsaronis Bank for

More information

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 2/28/2012 Abstract We

More information

Economic Uncertainty and the Cross-Section of Hedge Fund Returns

Economic Uncertainty and the Cross-Section of Hedge Fund Returns Economic Uncertainty and the Cross-Section of Hedge Fund Returns Turan Bali, Georgetown University Stephen Brown, New York University Mustafa Caglayan, Ozyegin University Introduction Knight (1921) draws

More information

Volatility Uncertainty and the Cross-Section of Option Returns *

Volatility Uncertainty and the Cross-Section of Option Returns * Volatility Uncertainty and the Cross-Section of Option Returns * [May 13, 2018] Jie Cao The Chinese University of Hong Kong E-mail: jiecao@cuhk.edu.hk Aurelio Vasquez ITAM E-mail: aurelio.vasquez@itam.mx

More information

Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners

Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners A Model: Who Gains and Who Loses When Divergence-of-Opinion is Resolved? In the baseline model, the pessimist s gain or loss is equal to her shorting demand times

More information

Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns

Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns Wei Huang, Qianqiu Liu, S.Ghon Rhee and Liang Zhang Shidler College of Business University of Hawaii at Manoa 2404 Maile Way Honolulu, Hawaii,

More information

Betting against Beta or Demand for Lottery

Betting against Beta or Demand for Lottery Turan G. Bali 1 Stephen J. Brown 2 Scott Murray 3 Yi Tang 4 1 McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University 2 Stern School of Business, New York University 3 College of Business Administration, University

More information

Is Liquidity the Trigger for Stock Returns? A Double Take and the Role of Investors Risk Aversion

Is Liquidity the Trigger for Stock Returns? A Double Take and the Role of Investors Risk Aversion Is Liquidity the Trigger for Stock Returns? A Double Take and the Role of Investors Risk Aversion Jian Chen a, Taufiq Choudhry b, Jing-Ming Kuo c,* and Qingjing Zhang d a Fujian Key Laboratory of Statistical

More information

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs John L. Glascock 1 University of Connecticut Ran Lu-Andrews 2 California Lutheran University (This version: August 2016) Abstract The traditional

More information

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru i Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2012 ii Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru (B.Sc National University

More information

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly Online Appendix Section I provides details of the calculation of the variables used in the paper. Section II examines the robustness of the beta anomaly.

More information

Cross section of option returns and idiosyncratic stock volatility

Cross section of option returns and idiosyncratic stock volatility Cross section of option returns and idiosyncratic stock volatility Jie Cao and Bing Han, Abstract This paper presents a robust new finding that delta-hedged equity option return decreases monotonically

More information

Explaining Stock Returns with Intraday Jumps

Explaining Stock Returns with Intraday Jumps Explaining Stock Returns with Intraday Jumps Diego Amaya HEC Montreal Aurelio Vasquez ITAM January 14, 2011 Abstract The presence of jumps in stock prices is widely accepted. In this paper, we explore

More information

Volatility as investment - crash protection with calendar spreads of variance swaps

Volatility as investment - crash protection with calendar spreads of variance swaps Journal of Applied Operational Research (2014) 6(4), 243 254 Tadbir Operational Research Group Ltd. All rights reserved. www.tadbir.ca ISSN 1735-8523 (Print), ISSN 1927-0089 (Online) Volatility as investment

More information

Volatility Uncertainty and the Cross-Section of Option Returns *

Volatility Uncertainty and the Cross-Section of Option Returns * Volatility Uncertainty and the Cross-Section of Option Returns * [March 15 2018, Preliminary Draft] Jie Cao The Chinese University of Hong Kong E-mail: jiecao@cuhk.edu.hk Aurelio Vasquez ITAM E-mail: aurelio.vasquez@itam.mx

More information

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Itamar Drechsler Alan Moreira Alexi Savov New York University and NBER University of Rochester March, 2018 Motivation 1. A key function of the financial sector is

More information

Informed Options Trading on the Implied Volatility Surface: A Cross-sectional Approach

Informed Options Trading on the Implied Volatility Surface: A Cross-sectional Approach Informed Options Trading on the Implied Volatility Surface: A Cross-sectional Approach This version: November 15, 2016 Abstract This paper investigates the cross-sectional implication of informed options

More information

Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns

Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns Thanos Verousis a and Nikolaos Voukelatos b a Newcastle University Business School, Newcastle University b Kent Business School, University of Kent Abstract

More information

Market Efficiency and Idiosyncratic Volatility in Vietnam

Market Efficiency and Idiosyncratic Volatility in Vietnam International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 10, No. 6; 2015 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Market Efficiency and Idiosyncratic Volatility

More information

The Market Price of Risk of the Volatility Term Structure

The Market Price of Risk of the Volatility Term Structure The Market Price of Risk of the Volatility Term Structure George Dotsis Preliminary and Incomplete This Draft: 07/09/09 Abstract In this paper I examine the market price of risk of the volatility term

More information

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Badrinath Kottimukkalur * January 2018 Abstract This paper provides an arbitrage based explanation for the puzzling negative

More information

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Bryan Kelly NYU Stern and Chicago Booth Outline Introduction An Economic Framework Econometric Methodology Empirical Findings Conclusions Tail Risk

More information

Common Risk Factors in the Cross-Section of Corporate Bond Returns

Common Risk Factors in the Cross-Section of Corporate Bond Returns Common Risk Factors in the Cross-Section of Corporate Bond Returns Online Appendix Section A.1 discusses the results from orthogonalized risk characteristics. Section A.2 reports the results for the downside

More information

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor In this online appendix, we provide a comparative static analysis of the theoretical model as well as further robustness checks on the trend factor.

More information

Illiquidity Premia in the Equity Options Market

Illiquidity Premia in the Equity Options Market Illiquidity Premia in the Equity Options Market Peter Christoffersen University of Toronto Kris Jacobs University of Houston Ruslan Goyenko McGill University and UofT Mehdi Karoui OMERS 26 February 2014

More information

The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns

The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns Andrew Ang Columbia University, USC and NBER Robert J. Hodrick Columbia University and NBER Yuhang Xing Rice University Xiaoyan Zhang Cornell University

More information

Dissecting the Market Pricing of Return Volatility

Dissecting the Market Pricing of Return Volatility Dissecting the Market Pricing of Return Volatility Torben G. Andersen Kellogg School, Northwestern University, NBER and CREATES Oleg Bondarenko University of Illinois at Chicago Measuring Dependence in

More information

Credit Default Swaps, Options and Systematic Risk

Credit Default Swaps, Options and Systematic Risk Credit Default Swaps, Options and Systematic Risk Christian Dorion, Redouane Elkamhi and Jan Ericsson Very preliminary and incomplete May 15, 2009 Abstract We study the impact of systematic risk on the

More information

Expected Stock Returns and Variance Risk Premia (joint paper with Hao Zhou)

Expected Stock Returns and Variance Risk Premia (joint paper with Hao Zhou) Expected Stock Returns and Variance Risk Premia (joint paper with Hao Zhou) Tim Bollerslev Duke University NBER and CREATES Cass Business School December 8, 2007 Much recent work on so-called model-free

More information

Are Idiosyncratic Skewness and Idiosyncratic Kurtosis Priced?

Are Idiosyncratic Skewness and Idiosyncratic Kurtosis Priced? Are Idiosyncratic Skewness and Idiosyncratic Kurtosis Priced? Xu Cao MSc in Management (Finance) Goodman School of Business, Brock University St. Catharines, Ontario 2015 Table of Contents List of Tables...

More information

Internet Appendix. Table A1: Determinants of VOIB

Internet Appendix. Table A1: Determinants of VOIB Internet Appendix Table A1: Determinants of VOIB Each month, we regress VOIB on firm size and proxies for N, v δ, and v z. OIB_SHR is the monthly order imbalance defined as (B S)/(B+S), where B (S) is

More information

Risk-managed 52-week high industry momentum, momentum crashes, and hedging macroeconomic risk

Risk-managed 52-week high industry momentum, momentum crashes, and hedging macroeconomic risk Risk-managed 52-week high industry momentum, momentum crashes, and hedging macroeconomic risk Klaus Grobys¹ This draft: January 23, 2017 Abstract This is the first study that investigates the profitability

More information

Predicting the Equity Premium with Implied Volatility Spreads

Predicting the Equity Premium with Implied Volatility Spreads Predicting the Equity Premium with Implied Volatility Spreads Charles Cao, Timothy Simin, and Han Xiao Department of Finance, Smeal College of Business, Penn State University Department of Economics, Penn

More information

Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options

Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options Mobina Shafaati Abstract This study analyzes the impact of volatility on the prices of individual equity options. Using the daily

More information

Cross Sectional Asset Pricing Tests: Ex Ante versus Ex Post Approaches

Cross Sectional Asset Pricing Tests: Ex Ante versus Ex Post Approaches Cross Sectional Asset Pricing Tests: Ex Ante versus Ex Post Approaches Mahmoud Botshekan Smurfit School of Business, University College Dublin, Ireland mahmoud.botshekan@ucd.ie, +353-1-716-8976 John Cotter

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Volatility-of-Volatility Risk

Volatility-of-Volatility Risk Volatility-of-Volatility Risk Darien Huang Ivan Shaliastovich Preliminary - Please Do Not Cite or Distribute January 2014 Abstract We show that time-varying volatility-of-volatility is a separate and significant

More information

Implied Funding Liquidity

Implied Funding Liquidity Implied Funding Liquidity Minh Nguyen Yuanyu Yang Newcastle University Business School 3 April 2017 1 / 17 Outline 1 Background 2 Summary 3 Implied Funding Liquidity Measure 4 Data 5 Empirical Results

More information

Internet Appendix for The Joint Cross Section of Stocks and Options *

Internet Appendix for The Joint Cross Section of Stocks and Options * Internet Appendix for The Joint Cross Section of Stocks and Options * To save space in the paper, additional results are reported and discussed in this Internet Appendix. Section I investigates whether

More information

Stocks with Extreme Past Returns: Lotteries or Insurance?

Stocks with Extreme Past Returns: Lotteries or Insurance? Stocks with Extreme Past Returns: Lotteries or Insurance? Alexander Barinov Terry College of Business University of Georgia June 14, 2013 Alexander Barinov (UGA) Stocks with Extreme Past Returns June 14,

More information

The pricing of volatility risk across asset classes. and the Fama-French factors

The pricing of volatility risk across asset classes. and the Fama-French factors The pricing of volatility risk across asset classes and the Fama-French factors Zhi Da and Ernst Schaumburg, Version: May 6, 29 Abstract In the Merton (1973) ICAPM, state variables that capture the evolution

More information

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Christian Julliard and Anisha Ghosh Working Paper 2008 P t d b J L i f NYU A t P i i Presented by Jason Levine for NYU Asset Pricing Seminar, Fall 2009

More information

Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns

Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2014 Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns Courtney D. Winn Utah State University Follow this

More information

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1.1 WHAT IS VOLATILITY? It is useful to start with an explanation of what volatility is, at least for the purpose of clarifying the scope of this book. Volatility

More information

This Appendix presents the results of variable selection tests, the results of the 14-factor

This Appendix presents the results of variable selection tests, the results of the 14-factor Internet Appendix This Appendix presents the results of variable selection tests, the results of the 14-factor model that further controls for the aggregate volatility and jump risk factors of Cremers,

More information

Is Stock Return Predictability of Option-implied Skewness Affected by the Market State?

Is Stock Return Predictability of Option-implied Skewness Affected by the Market State? Is Stock Return Predictability of Option-implied Skewness Affected by the Market State? Heewoo Park and Tongsuk Kim * Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology 2016 ABSTRACT We use Bakshi, Kapadia,

More information

Does market liquidity explain the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle in the Chinese stock market?

Does market liquidity explain the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle in the Chinese stock market? Does market liquidity explain the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle in the Chinese stock market? Xiaoxing Liu Guangping Shi Southeast University, China Bin Shi Acadian-Asset Management Disclosure The views

More information

Does Idiosyncratic Volatility Proxy for Risk Exposure?

Does Idiosyncratic Volatility Proxy for Risk Exposure? Does Idiosyncratic Volatility Proxy for Risk Exposure? Zhanhui Chen Nanyang Technological University Ralitsa Petkova Purdue University We decompose aggregate market variance into an average correlation

More information

Understanding and Trading the Term. Structure of Volatility

Understanding and Trading the Term. Structure of Volatility Understanding and Trading the Term Structure of Volatility Jim Campasano and Matthew Linn July 27, 2017 Abstract We study the dynamics of equity option implied volatility. We show that the dynamics depend

More information

Optimal Portfolio Allocation with Option-Implied Moments: A Forward-Looking Approach

Optimal Portfolio Allocation with Option-Implied Moments: A Forward-Looking Approach Optimal Portfolio Allocation with Option-Implied Moments: A Forward-Looking Approach Tzu-Ying Chen National Taiwan University, Taipei, Taiwan Tel: (+886) 2-3366-1100 Email: d99723002@ntu.edu.tw San-Lin

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FUNDAMENTALLY, MOMENTUM IS FUNDAMENTAL MOMENTUM. Robert Novy-Marx. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FUNDAMENTALLY, MOMENTUM IS FUNDAMENTAL MOMENTUM. Robert Novy-Marx. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FUNDAMENTALLY, MOMENTUM IS FUNDAMENTAL MOMENTUM Robert Novy-Marx Working Paper 20984 http://www.nber.org/papers/w20984 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty?

Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty? Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty? Alexander Barinov Terry College of Business University of Georgia E-mail: abarinov@terry.uga.edu http://abarinov.myweb.uga.edu/ This version: July 2009 Abstract The

More information

Lecture 4: Forecasting with option implied information

Lecture 4: Forecasting with option implied information Lecture 4: Forecasting with option implied information Prof. Massimo Guidolin Advanced Financial Econometrics III Winter/Spring 2016 Overview A two-step approach Black-Scholes single-factor model Heston

More information

High Idiosyncratic Volatility and Low Returns. Andrew Ang Columbia University and NBER. Q Group October 2007, Scottsdale AZ

High Idiosyncratic Volatility and Low Returns. Andrew Ang Columbia University and NBER. Q Group October 2007, Scottsdale AZ High Idiosyncratic Volatility and Low Returns Andrew Ang Columbia University and NBER Q Group October 2007, Scottsdale AZ Monday October 15, 2007 References The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Understanding Stock Return Predictability Hui Guo and Robert Savickas Working Paper 2006-019B http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2006/2006-019.pdf

More information

Realization Utility: Explaining Volatility and Skewness Preferences

Realization Utility: Explaining Volatility and Skewness Preferences Realization Utility: Explaining Volatility and Skewness Preferences Min Kyeong Kwon * and Tong Suk Kim March 16, 2014 ABSTRACT Using the realization utility model with a jump process, we find three implications

More information

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2015 Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis Seth E. Williams Utah State University

More information

Idiosyncratic volatility and stock returns: evidence from Colombia. Introduction and literature review

Idiosyncratic volatility and stock returns: evidence from Colombia. Introduction and literature review Idiosyncratic volatility and stock returns: evidence from Colombia Abstract. The purpose of this paper is to examine the association between idiosyncratic volatility and stock returns in Colombia from

More information

Bear Beta. First version: June 2016 This version: November Abstract

Bear Beta. First version: June 2016 This version: November Abstract Bear Beta Zhongjin Lu Scott Murray First version: June 2016 This version: November 2016 Abstract We construct an Arrow-Debreu state-contingent security AD Bear that pays off $1 in bad market states and

More information

How does the market variance risk premium vary over time? Evidence from S&P 500 variance swap investment returns

How does the market variance risk premium vary over time? Evidence from S&P 500 variance swap investment returns How does the market variance risk premium vary over time? Evidence from S&P 500 variance swap investment returns Eirini Konstantinidi and George Skiadopoulos December 31, 2013 Abstract We explore whether

More information

Firm specific uncertainty around earnings announcements and the cross section of stock returns

Firm specific uncertainty around earnings announcements and the cross section of stock returns Firm specific uncertainty around earnings announcements and the cross section of stock returns Sergey Gelman International College of Economics and Finance & Laboratory of Financial Economics Higher School

More information

Making Better Use of Option Prices to Predict Stock Returns

Making Better Use of Option Prices to Predict Stock Returns Making Better Use of Option Prices to Predict Stock Returns Dmitriy Muravyev Aurelio Vasquez Wenzhi Wang Boston College ITAM Boston College [Preliminary draft, please do not cite or circulate] December

More information

Essays on the Term Structure of Volatility and Option Returns

Essays on the Term Structure of Volatility and Option Returns University of Massachusetts Amherst ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst Doctoral Dissertations Dissertations and Theses 2018 Essays on the Term Structure of Volatility and Option Returns Vincent Campasano Follow

More information

VIX Fear of What? October 13, Research Note. Summary. Introduction

VIX Fear of What? October 13, Research Note. Summary. Introduction Research Note October 13, 2016 VIX Fear of What? by David J. Hait Summary The widely touted fear gauge is less about what might happen, and more about what already has happened. The VIX, while promoted

More information

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Yuhang Xing Rice University This version: July 25, 2006 1 I thank Andrew Ang, Geert Bekaert, John Donaldson, and Maria Vassalou

More information

Market and Non-market Variance Risk in Individual Stock Returns

Market and Non-market Variance Risk in Individual Stock Returns Market and Non-market Variance Risk in Individual Stock Returns Sungjune Pyun National University of Singapore This Draft: January 2018 ABSTRACT This paper shows that the price and quantity of variance

More information

On the Ex-Ante Cross-Sectional Relation Between Risk and Return Using Option-Implied Information

On the Ex-Ante Cross-Sectional Relation Between Risk and Return Using Option-Implied Information On the Ex-Ante Cross-Sectional Relation Between Risk and Return Using Option-Implied Information Ren-Raw Chen * Dongcheol Kim ** Durga Panda *** This draft: December 2009 Abstract: This paper examines

More information

Continuous Beta, Discontinuous Beta, and the Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns

Continuous Beta, Discontinuous Beta, and the Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns Continuous Beta, Discontinuous Beta, and the Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns Sophia Zhengzi Li Job Market Paper This Version: January 15, 2013 Abstract Aggregate stock market returns are naturally

More information

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Addendum Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara This version: February 01 1 Hanken School of Economics. E-mail: paulofmaio@gmail.com. Nova School of Business

More information

What explains the distress risk puzzle: death or glory?

What explains the distress risk puzzle: death or glory? What explains the distress risk puzzle: death or glory? Jennifer Conrad*, Nishad Kapadia +, and Yuhang Xing + This draft: March 2012 Abstract Campbell, Hilscher, and Szilagyi (2008) show that firms with

More information

Topics in financial econometrics

Topics in financial econometrics Topics in financial econometrics NES Research Project Proposal for 2011-2012 May 12, 2011 Project leaders: Stanislav Anatolyev, Professor, New Economic School http://www.nes.ru/ sanatoly Stanislav Khrapov,

More information

Option-Implied Correlations, Factor Models, and Market Risk

Option-Implied Correlations, Factor Models, and Market Risk Option-Implied Correlations, Factor Models, and Market Risk Adrian Buss Lorenzo Schönleber Grigory Vilkov INSEAD Frankfurt School Frankfurt School of Finance & Management of Finance & Management 17th November

More information

Université de Montréal. Rapport de recherche. Empirical Analysis of Jumps Contribution to Volatility Forecasting Using High Frequency Data

Université de Montréal. Rapport de recherche. Empirical Analysis of Jumps Contribution to Volatility Forecasting Using High Frequency Data Université de Montréal Rapport de recherche Empirical Analysis of Jumps Contribution to Volatility Forecasting Using High Frequency Data Rédigé par : Imhof, Adolfo Dirigé par : Kalnina, Ilze Département

More information

Is Trading What Makes Prices Informative? Evidence from Option Markets

Is Trading What Makes Prices Informative? Evidence from Option Markets Is Trading What Makes Prices Informative? Evidence from Option Markets Danjue Shang November 30, 2016 Abstract I investigate the information content in the implied volatility spread, which is the spread

More information

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns?

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? University of Miami School of Business Stan Stilger, Alex Kostakis and Ser-Huang Poon MBS 23rd March 2015, Miami Alex Kostakis (MBS)

More information

Global Journal of Finance and Banking Issues Vol. 5. No Manu Sharma & Rajnish Aggarwal PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS OF HEDGE FUND INDICES

Global Journal of Finance and Banking Issues Vol. 5. No Manu Sharma & Rajnish Aggarwal PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS OF HEDGE FUND INDICES PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS OF HEDGE FUND INDICES Dr. Manu Sharma 1 Panjab University, India E-mail: manumba2000@yahoo.com Rajnish Aggarwal 2 Panjab University, India Email: aggarwalrajnish@gmail.com Abstract

More information