Multivariate Shrinkage for Optimal Portfolio Weights

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Multivariate Shrinkage for Optimal Portfolio Weights"

Transcription

1 Multivariate Shrinkage for Optimal Portfolio Weights Vasyl Golosnoy a and Yarema Okhrin b,1 a Institute of Statistics and Econometrics, University of Kiel, Kiel, Germany b Department of Statistics, University of Frankfurt (Oder), Frankfurt (Oder), Germany Abstract The improvement of portfolio selection by means of multivariate shrinkage estimator for the optimal portfolio weights is a subject of this paper. The estimated classical Markowitz weights are shrunk to the vector of current portfolio weights, which is chosen as a shrinkage target. Assuming log asset returns to be Gaussian and i.i.d., the explicit solutions are derived for the optimal shrinkage intensity. The obtained theoretical results are compared with competing approaches within an extensive Monte Carlo simulation study and applied in an empirical example. JEL Classification: C13, C44, G11, G15. Keywords: portfolio optimization, shrinkage estimation, multivariate shrinkage. 1 Corresponding author. address: okhrin@uni-ffo.de, Phone:

2 1 Introduction The classical Markowitz s (1952) portfolio optimization, directly implemented in practice, often fails, despite its methodological appeal. The tendency to maximize the effects of errors in the input assumptions (cf. Michaud, 1989) seems to be the major problem of the classical analysis. Especially dramatic influence on the portfolio allocations is caused by estimation errors in the expected asset returns (cf. Merton, 1980, Best and Grauer, 1991). This paper is concerned with improving the results of Markowitz procedure by applying the shrinkage methodology for incorporating estimation uncertainty directly into investor s utility function. The portfolio selection can be improved by including some additional information into asset allocation procedure. Predictability of asset returns is captured by factor models (for overview see Ferson, 1995, Keim and Hawawini, 1995) by using exogenous variables for forecasting future outcomes. The exogenous variables in factor models is a source of conditional information, that should be included into portfolio optimization. The papers of Brennan, Schwartz and Lagnado (1997), Campbell and Viceira (1999), Brandt (1999), Barberis (2000), Ferson and Siegel (2001) etc. investigate portfolio problem for predictable returns. Another possibility to improve portfolio selection is to modify not the model of returns but the selection procedure itself by diminishing the undesirable effects of estimation uncertainty. Several approaches are developed for improving asset allocation procedure. Frost and Savarino (1988), Michaud (1989, 1998), Grauer and Shen (2000), Jagannathan and Ma (2003), Garlappi, Uppal and Wang (2003) suggest to constrain the portfolio weights in the portfolio optimization problem. Michaud (1998), Scherer (2002) use the resampling from the estimated distribution. They estimate the moments from the historical data, simulate paths of returns using these moments, calculate weights for each path and average over these weights. Klein and Bawa (1976), Jorion (1986), Frost and Savarino (1986), Kandel and Stambaugh (1996), Kan and Zhou (2004) advocate different types of Bayesian methods for portfolio selection. Jorion (1986) and Ledoit and Wolf (2003a,b) propose different types of shrinkage estimators by optimizing the trade-off between the classical estimation procedures and some shrinkage target. Here we introduce a multivariate shrinkage estimator for the optimal portfolio weights. Since the seminal paper of James and Stein (1961) the methodology of shrinkage estimation was further developed among others by Efron and Morris (1975), Berger (1982), Berger and Berliner (1984), George (1986a,b) and Longford (1999). The idea to improve the estimation procedure by shrinking has already been applied in portfolio analysis for estimation of the mean vector by Jorion (1986) and of the covariance matrix by Ledoit 2

3 and Wolf (2003a,b). However, these estimators are in some sense artificial, because there is no objective information what should be used as a shrinkage target. To the contrary, there is a natural shrinkage target for the optimal portfolio weights. This is the fractions of assets in the current portfolio composition. The main idea lies in using the shrinkage factors for linear weighting of the current portfolio weights, held by the investor, and the classical Markowitz estimated optimal portfolio weights, based on the estimated vector of means and covariance matrix. In case of large uncertainty about the estimated optimal weights the investor should stay close to his current holdings, if the uncertainty is reduced the investor should move in the direction of the estimated optimal portfolio weights. The usage of natural shrinkage for the optimal weights brings several advantages compared to the traditional estimation. First, the obtained shrinkage factors are optimal with respect to the investor s utility function to the contrary to the shrinkage estimators of Jorion (1986) and Ledoit and Wolf (2003a,b). The latter are optimal with respect to a quadratic loss criterion, that is not directly related to the investor s utility. The proposed shrinkage estimation procedure incorporates the variance of the classical estimated optimal portfolio weights. That means the estimation risk is also included into portfolio optimization. Additionally, because the current holdings are used as a shrinkage target, the shrinkage optimal weights impose smaller amount of wealth traded during portfolio revision compared to the Markowitz procedure, thus the proportional transaction costs are lower compared to the classical estimator. The explicit solutions for the optimal shrinkage factors for the portfolio problem with and without riskless asset are the main results of the paper. The optimal shrinkage factors are the function of the number of previous returns n, used for the estimation of the distribution parameters. If n reducing the variance of the estimators to zero, the optimal policy is to move far in the direction of the estimated optimal weights, for the small values of n the investor stays not far from the current vector of portfolio weights. The proposed shrinkage methodology is compared with competing approaches in terms of expected utility. The obtained solutions are analyzed both in a simulation study and in a study with empirical data. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The multivariate shrinkage estimator for the optimal portfolio weights is introduced in Section 2. The explicit solutions for the optimal shrinkage intensity are given in Section 3. The competing approaches are compared analytically in Section 4 and analyzed in the simulation and the empirical study in Sections 5 and 6, respectively. Section 7 concludes the paper. 3

4 2 Shrinkage for the Optimal Weights The considered single-period investor aims to maximize the expected utility of the endperiod wealth. Here and further we assume a multivariate normal distribution for risky assets logarithmic returns. Thus the portfolio problem is equivalent to the expected utility maximization based on the portfolio return r p (cf. Huang and Litzenberger, 1988) max w E U( r p), (1) where w is a vector of selected portfolio weights of risky assets. The classical Markowitz (1952) optimal weights are the function of the unknown moments of returns, that are replaced by the sample vector of means and of the sample covariance matrix, i.e. ˆµ = n 1 t i=t n+1 x i and ˆΣ = (n 1) 1 t i=t n+1 (x i ˆµ)(x i ˆµ), where x i denotes the vector of historical asset returns at time point i. The solution of the portfolio problem is given by the estimated portfolio weights as a function of sample moments and the form of utility function. Unfortunately, the practical application of the Markowitz (1952) approach often leads to unsatisfactory results. Michaud (1989) provides an overview of reasons for this evidence. The main one is caused by estimation errors in the input parameters (cf. Merton, 1980, Best and Grauer, 1991). Here we propose the strategy improvement based on the multivariate shrinkage estimator for the optimal portfolio weight. The idea to use shrinkage methods in the portfolio theory is not a new one. It is initially suggested by Jorion (1986) with the aim to improve the estimator of the expected asset returns. The approach of Jorion (1986) is based on the observation of Stein (1955), that the maximum likelihood estimator for the expected return is inadmissible relative to a quadratic loss function. To the contrary, James-Stein shrinkage estimator (cf. James and Stein, 1961), constructed as a linear weighting of the sample estimator and some arbitrary chosen vector of constants, has lower risk than the sample mean and is admissible in terms of quadratic loss function. Ledoit and Wolf (2003a) extend the approach of Jorion (1986) by using a shrinkage methodology for improving the estimator of the covariance matrix. Their improved estimator is a weighted sum of the sample covariance matrix and of the covariance matrix from the single index model. While the sample covariance matrix is unbiased but has a lot of estimation error, the covariance matrix from the one factor model has comparatively little estimation error but is a biased one. The estimator of Ledoit and Wolf (2003a) is constructed in order to find an optimal balance between the estimation error and bias. 4

5 Both Jorion (1986) and Ledoit and Wolf (2003a) show that their estimator improves the portfolio performance in terms of expected utility. A natural extension of the shrinkage approach is to develop a multivariate shrinkage estimator directly to the optimal portfolio weights. We suggest a shrinkage estimator for the optimal portfolio weights of risky assets in the following form ŵ = û a + c (1 a), (2) where a is a vector of shrinkage factors, c is a vector of portfolio weights currently hold by the investor in his portfolio, û is a vector of optimal portfolio weights estimated from the classical Markowitz procedure, denotes element by element multiplication (Hadamard product), 1 is a vector of ones of corresponding dimension. The multivariate shrinkage can be seen as an extension of the single shrinkage approach (cf. George, 1986a, Longford, 1999), allowing individual trade-off between the true information and estimation risk for each single asset. The proposed shrinkage estimator for the portfolio weights can be justified in the following way. Before portfolio decision, the investor holds the vector of the current portfolio weights c. Then in some black box procedure based on the previous information he obtains the estimator for the vector of the optimal portfolio weights û, that can be seen as a realization of random variables. Now the investor faces the question to what extent he should trust the estimated optimal weights and move away from his current portfolio holdings. The answer to this question is the optimal shrinkage intensity a that maximizes the expected utility of the end-period portfolio return. The asset allocation problem (1) can now be written by max E U( r p ), (3) a where the portfolio weights ŵ are given by equation (2). The maximization problem (3) can be interpreted as follows. The classical Markowitz approach uses so-called two step procedure. First the distribution parameters are estimated, then the estimated parameters are substituted into portfolio optimization task as if they were not the estimators but the true values. Our approach extends the classical procedure one step further. The estimated optimal weights û are treated as a function of a realization of random vectors of returns and are substituted into maximization problem (3). Then the optimal shrinkage intensity a is determined. The investor maximizes the expected utility and takes into account the additional risk, caused by the estimation of the classical optimal weights û. Thus our approach includes the estimation risk into portfolio decision problem. On the one hand the introduction of individual shrinkage factors for each portfolio weight will obviously increase the expected utility. However, on the other hand this also increases 5

6 substantially the number of parameters in the model and leads to a rise in the general estimation error. The trade-off between the number of parameters and estimation precision is a long standing problem in statistical theory and the shrinkage estimation is not an exception. On the contrary to the case discussed above, another extreme is to assume that the only shrinkage factor is equal for all portfolio weights. This approach is advocated by Ledoit and Wolf (2003a,b) for the shrinkage estimation of covariance matrices. In this simplified framework the estimator of the portfolio weights in (2) reduces to and the expected utility maximization is given by ŵ s = a s û + (1 a s )c (4) max a s E U( r p ). (5) Since this special case is of importance in practical applications, we derive all results separately for a single and different shrinkage coefficients. 3 The Optimal Shrinkage Factors The investor chooses the optimal portfolio weights w by maximizing the expected utility function. Here we consider the investor with the quadratic utility function with the risk aversion coefficient γ > 0 given by EU = E( r p ) γ 2 V ar( r p). We assume in this paper that the log returns are i.i.d. with r t N k (µ, Σ) for future returns and x t N k (µ, Σ) for past returns, where N k (, ) stands for k-dimensional Gaussian distribution. Now we consider separately the cases with and without riskless asset in the portfolio. 3.1 Riskless asset is present The investor allocates his wealth among k risky and one riskless asset. The portfolio return is expressed by r p = w r + (1 w 1)r f, then the portfolio optimization problem is given by max w w (µ r f 1) γ 2 w Σw, (6) where r f is a riskless rate of return. The classical solution of this problem is represented by tangency portfolio weights u M with the unknown parameters usually replaced by their 6

7 sample counterparts, i.e. u M = γ 1 Σ 1 (µ r f 1) and û M = γ 1 ˆΣ 1 (ˆµ r f 1). Okhrin and Schmid (2003) derive the first two moments of the estimated optimal portfolio weights under normality assumption for log returns, E(û M ) and Cov(û M ) = Ω M. The formulas of Okhrin and Schmid (2003) are provided in Appendix A. Next we use these results to derive expressions and properties of the shrinkage factors. Taking into account the form of the utility function in (6), the optimization problem in (3) can be rewritten with respect to the weighting factors a in the following way max a M E(ŵ M(r r f 1)) γ 2 V ar(ŵ M(r r f 1)), (7) where ŵ M = (û M c) a M + c. The solution of this portfolio problem is given in the next Theorem. Theorem 1. Assume that the {x t } is a sequence of independent and normally distributed k-dimensional random vectors with the mean µ and the covariance matrix Σ. Then the solution of the maximization problem (7) is given by where a M = Q 1 M ((E(û M) c) Σ (u M c)), Q M = Ω M (Σ + (µ r f 1)(µ r f 1) ) + Σ (E(û M ) c)(e(û M ) c). The first term in the matrix Q M reflects the uncertainty in the two step estimation procedure. Small sample size leads to larger uncertainty about the estimated portfolio weights û M, i.e. the covariance matrix Ω M has a greater impact on the matrix Q M. This, consequently, implies smaller values of the optimal shrinkage coefficients and higher tendency to preserve current portfolio composition. The opposite situation is observed for large samples. In this case the investor is more certain about the model parameters and should tend to the optimal weights of Markowitz. These ideas are formalized in the next corollary, which provides results on the limiting behavior of the optimal shrinkage coefficients a M. Corollary 1. a) If the estimation risk is reduced to zero by setting n, the optimal shrinkage factors a M from Theorem 1 are given by lim n a M = 1. b) If the variance of the estimator of the optimal portfolio weights is infinite, i.e. n < k+5, the optimal shrinkage factors a M from Theorem 1 are given by a M = 0 for n < k

8 In the case of single shrinkage coefficient the optimization problem is given by max E(ŵ a M,s M,s(r r f 1)) γ 2 V ar(ŵ M,s(r r f 1)), (8) where ŵ M,s = a M,s (û M c) + c. The next corollary establishes the optimal shrinkage factors in this case. Corollary 2. Let x t follow the multivariate normal distribution with parameters µ and Σ. Then the solution of (8) is given by a M,s = (E(û M ) c) Σ(u M c) tr [ (Σ + (µ r f 1)(µ r f 1) )Ω M ] + (E(ûM ) c) Σ(E(û M ) c). The proof of the corollary follows along the lines of the proof of Theorem 1 by using the properties of Hadamard product and setting a M = a M,s 1. Similar statement as in Corollary 1 can also be proved in the case of a single shrinkage coefficient. When the optimal different shrinkage coefficients a M expected utility, it is not crucial if some elements of the vector a M from zero to one. coefficient. It appears that a M,s lead to the increase of investor s lie outside the interval However, this issue is important in the case of a single shrinkage portfolio is higher then on the current portfolio, i.e. 1 if the expected excess return on the tangency a M,s 1 if E(û M)(µ r f 1) c (µ r f 1) > 0. The proof of this statement follows along the lines of the proof of Corollary 5. Concerning the lower bound, note that the numerator is not exactly a quadratic form, because the estimator û is upward biased. Therefore we can always find such values of the parameters that the numerator of a M,s and consequently a M,s, are negative. James and Stein (1961) solve this problem by restricting the optimal shrinkage factor from below by zero, i.e. a JS = max{0, a }. In our case, the asymptotic unbiasedness of the estimator û makes the probability of a M,s the restriction a M,s < 0 negligible small for reasonable choices of n. Concerning 1, the condition provided above is sufficient, but not a necessary condition and in practice the inequality will be fulfilled for a wide range of parameters. 3.2 No Riskless Asset Here we analyze the portfolio problem without riskless asset. The portfolio return in this case is given by r p = w r. The asset allocation problem with k risky assets in the portfolio and quadratic utility is max w w µ γ 2 w Σw s.t. w 1 = 1. 8

9 The classical Markowitz solution of this problem is given by u Q = Σ Σ Rµ γ where R = Σ 1 Σ 1 11 Σ 1 1 Σ 1 1. Okhrin and Schmid (2003) derive the first two moments of the estimated weights û Q under normality assumption for log returns, given by E(û Q ) and Cov(û Q ) = Ω Q. The formulas are provided in Appendix A. Now we remark that in the absence of the riskless asset in the portfolio as well as in case when the riskless asset is present the vector of current weights c does not need to sum up to one. It may sum up to one in case of portfolio revision, but, for example, in the case of initial investment it is summed up to zero. We state the portfolio optimization problem with the restriction that the vector of current portfolio weights sums up to a number 1 υ = c 1 with υ [0; 1]. Then the maximization of the expected utility in case of portfolio revision can be expressed by max a Q E(ŵ Qr) γ 2 V ar(ŵ Qr), s.t. a Q(E(û Q ) c) = υ, (9) where ŵ Q = a Q (û Q c) + c. The solution of this problem is given in the following Theorem. Theorem 2. Assume that {x t } is a sequence of independent and normally distributed k- dimensional random vectors with the mean µ and the covariance matrix Σ. The solution of the stated above maximization problem (9) is given by a Q = Q 1 ( ) Q (E(û Q ) c) (µ γσc ξ1), γ where ξ = (E(û Q) c) Q 1 Q ((E(û Q) c) (µ γσc)) γυ (E(û Q ) c) Q 1 Q (E(û, Q) c) Q Q = Ω Q (Σ + µµ ) + Σ (E(û Q ) c)(e(û Q ) c). The covariance matrix Ω Q of the estimated portfolio weights plays here a similar role in reflecting the uncertainty in the estimated model parameters as in the case of tangency portfolio. Next we provide a corollary similar to Corollary 1 about the limiting behavior of the shrinkage factors a Q. Corollary 3. a) If the estimation risk is reduced to zero by using n, the optimal shrinkage factors a Q are given by lim n a Q = 1. 9

10 b) If the variance of the estimator of the optimal portfolio weights is infinite, i.e. n < k+4, the optimal shrinkage factors a Q are given by a Q = 0 for n < k + 4. The expected quadratic utility maximization that we solve in the case of single shrinkage factor is given by the following unconstrained maximization problem max a Q,s E(ŵ Q,sr) γ 2 V ar(ŵ Q,sr), (10) where ŵ Q,s = a Q,s (û Q c) + c. Note that the restriction ŵ Q,s 1 = 1 is fulfilled for all values of a Q,s if and only if û Q 1 = 1 and c 1 = 1. This implies that υ = 0. The next corollary establishes the solution of this optimization problem, the proof is similar to the proof of Corollary 2. Corollary 4. Let x t follow the multivariate normal distribution with the parameters µ and Σ. Then the solution of (10) is given by a Q,s = (E(û Q ) c) Σ(γ 1 Σ 1 µ c) tr [ (Σ + µµ )Ω Q ] + (E(ûQ ) c) Σ(E(û Q ) c). We can provide exact conditions, which guarantee that the single shrinkage coefficient takes the values between zero and one for the portfolio problem considered in this subsection. Corollary 5. It holds that a Q,s [0, 1] if the expected return on the quadratic utility optimal portfolio is higher then on the current portfolio and if the variance of the current portfolio is higher than the variance of the global minimum variance portfolio, i.e. a Q,s [0, 1] if the following two conditions hold (E(û Q ) c) µ > 0, c Σc 1 1 Σ 1 1 > 0. Similarly to the case of the problem with a riskless asset the condition provided here are sufficient, but not necessary conditions and the shrinkage coefficient belongs to the unit interval for large variety of other parameter constellations. As earlier the restrictions for the different shrinkage coefficients are not crucial. The shrinkage estimators obtained in this section are the functions of the unknown distribution parameters. By calculating the optimal shrinkage intensities the unknown true values are replaced by their estimated counterparts. Next we discuss the consequences of estimation of the shrinkage coefficients as well as the impact of different portfolio selection techniques on the investor s utility. 10

11 4 Comparison of Different Portfolio Rules Here we compare the portfolio performance of the shrinkage strategies with the performance of the classical Markowitz procedure. The performance is measured by the expected utility of portfolio return. The strategies to compare are (1) Markowitz allocation with known moments (µ, Σ); (2) Markowitz allocation with estimated moments (ˆµ, ˆΣ); (3a,b) single different shrinkage strategies with estimated moments but known optimal shrinkage intensities; (4a,b) single and different shrinkage strategies with estimated moments as well as estimated optimal shrinkage intensities. We show analytically that the expected utility of natural shrinkage strategies with estimated moments but known optimal shrinkage intensities are bounded above by the Markowitz allocation with full certainty and below by the Markowitz allocation with estimated moments. The estimation of the optimal shrinkage intensities leads to the reduction of the expected utility compared with the knowledge of the optimal shrinkage intensities. However, as it is shown later in the simulation study, the expected utility in case of estimated shrinkages is still bounded below by the expected utility from the Markowitz allocation with estimated moments. Relationship between expected utilities from the single and different shrinkage strategies in the case of estimated intensities needs further investigation. As earlier, we consider the portfolio allocation both in presence and absence of the riskless asset. 4.1 Riskless asset is present When the distribution of returns is known with certainty, the Markowitz expected utility is given by EU 1 = (µ r f1) Σ 1 (µ r f 1) 2γ + r f. We derive in Appendix C the Markowitz expected utility for the case of estimated moments of returns, given by EU 2 = n2 2nk 4n + 2k + 3 2γ(n k 2) 2 (µ r f 1) Σ 1 (µ r f 1) γ 2 tr ( Ω M (Σ + (µ r f 1)(µ r f 1) ) ) + r f with Ω M = Cov(û M ). The difference between the expected utilities with true and estimated parameters in Markowitz approach is given by 12 = EU 1 EU 2 = (k + 1)2 (µ r f 1) Σ 1 (µ r f 1) 2γ(n k 2) 2 + γ 2 tr ( Ω M (Σ + (µ r f 1)(µ r f 1) ) ). 11

12 Of course, 12 > 0 because Ω M and Σ are positive definite. If the natural shrinkage coefficients are known with certainty, the expected utility of different shrinkage strategy is given by EU 3b = E(ŵ M(r r f 1)) γ 2 V ar(ŵ M(r r f 1)) + r f with ŵ M = û M a M + (1 a M ) c. The expected utility from different shrinkage EU 3b EU 1, because EU 1 is a theoretically attainable maximum. The expected utility from single shrinkage EU 3a EU 3b because the single shrinkage approach can be seen as constrained optimization compared to the different shrinkage approach. On the other hand EU 3a EU 2, because EU 3a results from seeking for the maximum with respect to a M,s where EU 3a = EU 2 for a M,s = 1. Thus the expected utility of the shrinkage strategy with certain shrinkage coefficient is bounded by EU 1 EU 3b EU 3a EU 2. The comparison of the expected shrinkage utility with estimated shrinkage parameters is done in section Simulation Study. 4.2 Riskless asset is absent If the distribution parameters (µ, Σ) are known with certainty, the Markowitz expected utility is given by EU 1 = µ Rµ 2γ + µ Σ 1 1 γ/2. 1 Σ 1 1 We show in Appendix C, that the expected utility with uncertain parameters is given by EU 2 = (n 1)(n 2k 1) µ Rµ + µ Σ 1 1 γ/2 γ (n k 1) 2 2γ 1 Σ tr(ω QΣ), where Ω Q = Cov(û Q ). The difference between the expected utilities with true and estimated parameters in Markowitz approach is given by 12 = EU 1 EU 2 = k 2 µ Rµ + γ (n k 1) 2 2γ 2 tr(ω QΣ) 0, because Ω Q is positive semidefinite and Σ is positive definite. If the natural shrinkage coefficient is known with certainty, the expected utility of shrinkage strategy is given by EU 3b = E(ŵ Qr) γ 2 V ar(ŵ Qr) with ŵ Q = û Q a Q + (1 a Q ) c. Similar to the arguments provided in the previous subsection we can establish the following relationship EU 1 EU 3b EU 3a EU 2. 12

13 5 Simulation Study We clarify the obtained results within the simulation study. For the illustrative purposes we consider here the case of three risky and one riskless asset in the portfolio. Later, in the empirical study, we apply the methodology to the portfolio that consists of k = 10 risky assets. The study is designed as follows. The log risky asset returns are multivariate normal and i.i.d. and generated on the monthly basis, i.e. 12x t N(µ, Σ). The annualized distribution parameters of the model are given by.05 µ =.07, Σ = , the annualized riskless rate is r f =.02 and the risk aversion coefficient is taken from the set γ {10, 25}. If the distribution parameters of asset returns were certain, the corresponding optimal weights for the risky asset would be given by u M = (.12,.31,.32). We consider shrinkage strategies with k = 3 different shrinkage factors as well as with a single shrinkage factor. In case of no uncertainty about the true values of the distribution parameters the true optimal shrinkage factors (a M,s, a M ) as well as the optimal shrinkage weights of the risky asset w M are the functions of current portfolio holdings c and of the number of past returns n, used for the estimation. The shrinkage optimal weights w M, the shrinkage factors a M,s and a M, the classical optimal weights u M and the current weights c are plotted on the following Figures for different values of the risk aversion coefficient γ and for the distribution parameters, given above. Figures 1 about here. Because the true distribution parameters are unknown, they should be estimated. Using the sample estimators for the distribution parameters, we run a simulation study in order to compare the classical Markowitz portfolio strategy with the proposed shrinkage strategies. The simulation study is designed in the following way. A path of previous returns is generated every replication, the sample estimates for distribution parameters ˆµ and ˆΣ, optimal shrinkage factors (â M,s, â M ) and optimal portfolio weights û M, ŵ M are calculated from this path using n previous monthly returns. In the classical portfolio strategy the wealth is invested in proportions û M and 1 û M1 for risky and riskless assets, respectively. In the shrinkage portfolio strategy the wealth is invested in proportions ŵ M and 1 ŵ M 1. Following Ledoit and Wolf (2003a,b), the holding period of the portfolio investor is taken 13

14 to be one year (12 month). Then the expected utility is calculated for the classical and shrinkage strategies with and without knowledge of the exact distribution parameters. The study is done for the values of c 2 = u M,2, c 3 = u M,3, c 1 {.50,.49,...,.99, 1.0} and n {24, 60, 120}, the risk aversion coefficient is taken from the set γ {10, 25}. The expected utility is plotted on the following Figures for all considered portfolio strategies. The number of replications is chosen to be 10 5 for all cases. Figures 2 about here. The benchmark strategy with the knowledge of the true distribution parameters is clearly the best one and brings the investor the highest expected utility. The classical strategy with the estimated parameters is always the worst one. When the exact shrinkage intensities are known, the different shrinkage strategy dominates its single shrinkage counterpart. Concerning the case of unknown optimal shrinkage intensities the relationship between single and different shrinkage utilities changes depending on the distance between c 1 and u M,1. If c 1 is in the small neighborhood of u M,1 then the single shrinkage approach dominates, otherwise the different shrinkage approach is better. Next we apply the proposed methodology to the real financial data. 6 Empirical Results In this section we present the empirical evidence on the performance of shrinkage estimators defined in Section 3. The proposed estimators with single and different shrinkage factors are compared with the classical Markowitz (1952) sample estimator, with the Bayes-Stein estimator of Jorion (1986) as well as the estimator of Ledoit and Wolf (2003a,b) in terms of quadratic utility function. The investment strategy is constructed in the following way. First n previous monthly returns are used for the estimation of the distribution parameters ˆµ and ˆΣ. Then the classical Markowitz û Q, Jorion ĵr, Ledoit and Wolf ˆ lw as well as the single shrinkage ŵq,s and different shrinkage ŵ Q optimal weights are calculated based on the estimated parameters. The investor allocates his wealth accordingly to the estimated optimal weights for all compared strategies and holds the portfolio during the holding period. The length of the holding period s takes the values from 6 to 24 months. Thus, at the investment date t the in-sample period lasts from t n + 1 to t, the out-of-sample period goes from t + 1 to t + s. The quantities of interest are the out-of-sample mean and variance of the portfolio return, that are required for calculation of the expected utility. The expected utility is considered for the investor with the risk aversion coefficient γ {5, 10, 20, 35, 50, 100}. 14

15 The empirical study is conducted based on the MSCI monthly data set for the period Dec Apr 2004, totally 413 observations. The prices are taken for the last trading day of the month. The investor allocates his wealth among k = 10 developed financial markets, namely UK, Germany, France, the Netherlands, USA, Canada, Japan, Italy, Spain, Switzerland. The country MSCI indexes are denominated in US$, the dividends are cumulated. The MSCI World Index over the same period is chosen to be the proxy for the market index in the single factor model. The expected utilities are calculated for the different values of risk aversion coefficient γ, different holding periods s = {6, 7,..., 24} month with n {30, 31,..., 150} previous months, used for the estimation. The competing strategies are ranked from 5 (highest) to 1 (lowest) rank for each given s, γ and n. The ranks over different n {30, 31,..., 150} are averaged, the averaged ranks are plotted on Figure 3. Figure 3 about here. Based on the performed study we report the following empirical findings. The average ranking of alternative strategies strongly depends on the investor s risk aversion coefficient. For small γ < 10 the role of portfolio variance in the utility function is minor, the expected portfolio return dominates the investor s choice. The strategy of Jorion is clearly the best one for these values of γ. The different shrinkages strategy is the second best, the single shrinkage strategy is the third best. The strategy of Ledoit and Wolf dominates the approach of Markowitz for small investment horizon s, but starting approximately from 12 months is the worst one. The role of the portfolio variance increases with the increase of the investor s risk aversion. For γ {20, 35} the strategy of different shrinkages is the best one, the single shrinkage strategy is the second best. The strategy of Jorion occupies the third position, Ledoit and Wolf s strategy has position four for s < 12 months and position five otherwise. The investor with large risk aversion, i.e. γ > 50 is interested primarily in the minimization of the portfolio variance and neglects potential losses in the portfolio return. For such investors the different shrinkages strategy is again the best choice, the second best choice is the single shrinkage strategy. The strategy of Ledoit and Wolf has the third position approximately for s < 12 months, while for s > 12 the third position is occupied by the classical Markowitz strategy. The strategy of Jorion is almost everywhere the worst one for such choice of γ. Summarizing, we can conclude that the strategy with different shrinkages is the best one for almost for all γ s except the case of small risk aversion coefficients, while the single shrinkage strategy is the second best choice. The strategy of Jorion is preferable for small 15

16 γ, while the strategy of Ledoit performs well (third best) only for large γ s and investment horizon smaller than s < 1 year. 7 Summary The multivariate shrinkage for the optimal portfolio weights is developed in this paper. This development extends the univariate shrinkage estimators for the means (Jorion, 1986) and for the covariance matrix (Ledoit and Wolf, 2003a,b) proposed earlier in the context of portfolio selection. The idea lies in shrinking the Markowitz optimal weights for risky assets to the investor s current portfolio holdings. We propose two different estimators: one with single shrinkage coefficient and another one with different shrinkage coefficients. The shrinkage estimation uses the trade-off in terms of expected utility between the estimation uncertainty and the information about the true optimal weights that is contained in the classical estimator. If the information contained in the estimated Markowitz optimal weights is reliable, the investor should move more in the direction of the estimated weights. Alternatively, the investor moves not far from his current portfolio holdings if the information is not trusty enough. The main results of the paper are presented in Section 3. We develop analytically the explicit solutions for the optimal shrinkage intensity for both proposed estimators in case of k risky assets as well as in case of k risky and one riskless asset for the single period investor with the quadratic utility function. We also provide useful corollaries about the limiting behavior of the optimal shrinkage factors. The application of the shrinkage estimators for the portfolio weights shows their superiority over the classical Markowitz strategy in the simulation study. As a rule, the strategy with different shrinkage factors outperforms the single shrinkage factor strategy. The shrinkage strategies beat their Markowitz counterpart even for the estimated optimal shrinkage factors. We compare proposed shrinkage strategies in the empirical study with the classical Markowitz strategy, the Bayes-Stein strategy of Jorion (1986) and strategy of Ledoit and Wolf (2003a,b). The strategy with different shrinkage coefficients is the best one, while the single shrinkage strategy is the second best for all risk aversion coefficients γ except γ < 10. However, it should be noted that the shrinkage strategy requires input of additional information (vector of current portfolio holdings) compared to the competing approaches. 16

17 8 Appendix 8.1 Appendix A Riskless asset is present Okhrin and Schmid (2003) derive the first two moments of the optimal portfolio weights under normality assumption for log returns, when the usual sample estimators are used for the moments E(û M ) = γ 1 n 1 n k 2 Σ 1 (µ r f 1) [ n 2 Cov(û M ) = γ 2 z 1 n Σ 1 + (µ r f 1) Σ 1 (µ r f 1) Σ 1 n k + n k 2 Σ 1 (µ r f 1)(µ r f 1) Σ 1], with z 1 = (n 1) 2 /(n k 1)(n k 2)(n k 4) Riskless asset is absent Okhrin and Schmid (2003) derive the first two moments of the estimated weights û under normality assumption for log returns, given by E(û Q ) = Σ Σ n 1 n k 1 γ 1 Rµ. Cov(û Q ) = + 1 R (n k 1) 1 Σ q 1 γ 2 Rµµ R + q 2 γ 2 µ RµR 1 (n ) 1)2 (q γ q 2 (k 1) + n (n k 1) 2 R with q 1 = (n 1) 2 (n k + 1) (n k)(n k 1) 2 (n k 3), q 2 = (n 1) 2 (n k)(n k 1)(n k 3). 17

18 8.2 Appendix B Proof of Theorem 1 In order to proof the theorem it is necessary to solve the maximization problem, given by MEU = max a M E(ŵ M(r r f 1)) γ 2 V ar(ŵ M(r r f 1)), (11) where ŵ M = (û M c) a M + c and û M and r are independent by construction. Let Φ = Σ + (µ r f 1)(µ r f 1). Using properties of Hadamard product (cf. Zhang, 1999) and Theorem 3.2b.1 of Mathai and Provost (1992) it follows that E(ŵ M(r r f 1)) = a M((E(û M ) c) (µ r f 1)) + c (µ r f 1), E(ŵ M(r r f 1)) 2 = E ( ŵ MΦŵ M ) = E ( (a M û M ) Φ(a M û M ) + 2(a M û M ) Φ((1 a M ) c) + ((1 a M ) c) Φ((1 a M ) c) ) = a M(Φ E(û M û M))a M + 2a M(Φ E(û M 1 ))c 2a M(Φ E(û M c ))a M + a M(Φ E(cc ))a M 2a M(Φ E(c1 ))c + c Φc = a M[ Φ E(ûM û M) + 2Φ E(û M c ) + Φ (cc ) ] a M + 2a M[ Φ E(ûM 1 ) Φ (cc ) ] c + c Φc. Setting components together leads to the following optimization problem where MEU = max a M a M((E(û M ) c) (µ r f 1 γσc)) γ 2 a MQ M a M, Q M = Ω M Σ + Ω M ((µ r f 1)(µ r f 1) ) + ((E(û M ) c)(e(û M ) c) ) Σ. The first derivative of the objective function with respect to the vector a M is set to zero, then the solution of the maximization problem is given by ( ( )) µ a M = Q 1 rf 1 M (E(û M ) c) Σc. γ Note that Ω M Σ is positive definite, since Σ and Ω M are positive definite. Therefore Q M is positive definite as well, since the rest two terms in the expression for Q M are nonnegative definite. This implies that a M is a valid solution of the maximization problem. 18

19 8.2.2 Proof of Corollary 1 In order to prove the first part of the corollary, we take the limit ( ( )) µ lim n a M = lim Q 1 rf 1 n M (E(û M ) c) Σc. (12) γ Note that the estimator û M is asymptotically unbiased and consistent. This implies that lim n E(û M ) = u M and lim n Ω M = 0 k k and leads to the following limit of a M lim n a M = ( (u M c)(u M c) Σ ) 1 ( (um c) Σ(u M c) ). Let D denotes a diagonal matrix with the main diagonal equal to u M c. Then lim n a M = ( DΣD ) 1 DΣ(uM c) = D 1 Σ 1 D 1 DΣ(u M c) = D 1 (u M c) = 1 and this proves the first statement of the corollary. The second part of the corollary is proven with the observation, that all the elements of the matrix Q M are equal to infinity for n < k + 5. Then all the elements of the matrix Q 1 M are equal to zeros, thus a M = 0 for n < k + 5 follows immediately Proof of Theorem 2 The utility function is derived in this case similarly as for the tangency portfolio, however due to the constraint on the shrinkage coefficients the proof is based on solving the following Lagrange maximization problem max a a Q Q( (E(ûQ ) c) µ ) + c µ γ [ a 2 Q (Ω Q Σ + (µµ ) Ω Q +(E(û Q ) c)(e(û Q ) c) Σ) a Q + 2a ( Q (E(ûQ ) c) Σc ) + c Σc ] w.r.t. a Q(E(û Q ) c) = υ. (13) After setting the first derivatives with respect to the shrinkage factors a Q and Lagrangian coefficient λ to zero the system of two equation is solved. The resulting solution is given by a Q = Q 1 Q γ ( ( (E(û Q ) c) µ Σc (E(û Q) c) Q 1 Q ((E(û )) Q) c) (µ Σc)) γυ (E(û Q ) c) Q 1 Q (E(û 1 Q) c) where Q Q = Ω Q Σ + (µµ ) Ω Q + ((E(û Q ) c)(e(û Q ) c) ) Σ. The validity of the solution is motivated in a similar manner as in Theorem 1. 19

20 8.2.4 Proof of Corollary 5 Since the first term in the denominator of a Q,s is positive, we conclude that a Q,s (E(û Q) c) (µ γσc) γ(e(û Q ) c) Σ(E(û Q ) c). Substitution of the expression for E(û Q ) leads to a Q,s ( 1 Σ 1 1 Σ 1 1 γ 1 d 1 µ R c )(µ γσc) ( ( ) 1 γ Σ 1 1 Σ 1 1 γ 1 d 1 µ R c )Σ 1 Σ 1 1 Σ 1 1 γ 1 d 1 µ R c ( ) = 1 (1 + d 1 ) Σ 1 1 Σ 1 1 µ c + γ 1 d 1 µ 1 Rµ γ 1 Σ 1 1 γc Σc ( ) d 2 1 Σ Σ 1 1 µ c + γ 1 d 2 1µ 1 Rµ γ 1 Σ 1 1 γc Σc = I II To derive an economically sensible restriction on the portfolio characteristics we consider [ 1 Σ 1 µ ] I II = (1 d 1 ) 1 Σ γ 1 d 1 µ Rµ c µ = (1 d 1 ) [ E(u r) E(c r) ]. Since 1 d 1 < 0, then I II < 0 and consequently a s < 1, if E(u Q r) E(c r) > 0, i.e. if the expected return on the quadratic utility optimal portfolio is higher than on the current. Taking into account this assumption, c Σc 1/1 Σ 1 1 suffices to guarantee that a Q,s > 0, i.e. if the variance of the current portfolio is higher than the variance of the global minimum variance portfolio then a Q,s > 0. The asymptotic properties of a Q,s can be proved in the same way as for the different shrinkage coefficients. 8.3 Appendix C Derivation if the expected utility We consider here the situation when the riskless asset is present. The expected utility is given by EU 2 = E(û M ) (µ r f 1) γ 2 ( E(û M (r r f 1)(r r f 1) û M ) (E(û M ) (µ r f 1)) 2) + r f. Using the expression for expected optimal weights E(û M ) we consider E(û M(r r f 1)(r r f 1) û M ) = tr ( Ω M (Σ + (µ r f 1)(µ r f 1) ) ) + + z2 γ 2 ( (µ rf 1) Σ 1 (µ r f 1) + [(µ r f 1) Σ 1 (µ r f 1)] 2) 20

21 with z = (n 1)/(n k 2). Taking into account that E(û M ) (µ r f 1) = z γ (µ r f1) Σ 1 (µ r f 1), we obtain ) EU 2 = (z z2 (µ rf 1) Σ 1 (µ r f 1) γ 2 γ 2 tr (Ω M(Σ + (µ r f 1)(µ r f 1) )) + r f. The expected utility in case of no riskless asset is derived by analogy. References [1] Barberis, N., 2000, Investing for the long run when returns are predictable, Journal of Finance 55, [2] Berger, J., 1982, Selecting a minimax estimator of a multivariate normal mean, The Annals of Statistics 10, [3] Berger, J. and L.M. Berliner, 1984, Bayesian input in Stein-estimation and a new minimax empirical bayes estimator, Journal of Econometrics 25, [4] Best, M. and R. Grauer, 1991, On the sensitivity of mean-variance-efficient portfolios to changes in asset means: some analytical and computational results, Review of Financial Studies 4, [5] Brandt, M.W., 1999, Estimating portfolio and consumption choice: a conditional Euler equations approach, Journal of Finance 54, [6] Brennan, M.J., Schwartz, E.S. and R. Lagnado, 1997, Strategic asset allocation, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 21, [7] Campbell, J.Y. and L.M. Viceira, 1999, Consumption and portfolio decisions when expected returns are time varying, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, [8] Efron, B. and C. Morris, 1975, Data analysis using Stein s estimator and its generalizations, Journal of the American Statistical Association 70, [9] Ferson, W., 1995, Theory and empirical testing of asset pricing models, in R. Jarrow, V. Maksimovic and W. Ziemba eds. Handbools in Operation Research and Management Science, Vol. 9 Finance, Amsterdam, Elsevier. [10] Ferson, W. and A. Siegel, 2001, The efficient use of conditional infermation in portfolios, Journal of Finance 56,

22 [11] Frost, P. and E. Savarino, 1986, An empirical Bayes approach to efficient portfolio selection, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 21, [12] Frost, P. and E. Savarino, 1988, For better performance constrain: constrain portfolio weights, Journal of Portfolio Management, Fall [13] George, E.I., 1986a, Combining minimax shrinkage estimators, Journal of the American Statistical Association 81, [14] George, E.I., 1986b, Minimax multiple shrinkage estimation, The Annals of Statistics 14, [15] Garlappi, L., Uppal, R. and T. Wang, Portfolkio selection with parameter and model uncertainty, Working Paper, November [16] Grauer, R. and F. Shen, 2000, Do constraints improve portfolio performance? Journal of Banking and Finance 24, [17] Huang, C. and R.H. Litzenberger, 1988, Foundations for financial economics, New York, Elsevier. [18] Jagannathan, R. and T. Ma, 2003, Risk reduction in large portfolios: why imposing the wrong constraints helps, Journal of Finance 58, [19] James, W. and C. Stein, 1961, Estimation with quadratic loss, Proceedings of the 4th Berkeley Symposium on Mathmatical Statistics and Probability 1, Berkeley, University of Calif. Press, [20] Jorion, P., 1986, Bayes-Stein estimation for portfolio analysis, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 21, [21] Kan, R. and G. Zhou, 2004, Optimal estimation for economics gains: portfolio choice with parameter uncertainty, Working Paper, May [22] Kandel, S. and R. Stambaugh, 1996, On the predictability of stock returns: an asset allocation perspective, Journal of Finance 51, [23] Keim, D. and G. Hawawini, 1995, On the predictability of common stock returns: world-wide evidence, in R. Jarrow, V. Maksimovic and W. Ziemba eds. Handbools in Operation Research and Management Science, Vol. 9 Finance, Amsterdam, Elsevier. [24] Klein, R. and V. Bawa, 1976, The effect of estimation risk on optimal portofolio choice, Journal of Financial Economics 3,

23 [25] Ledoit, O. and M. Wolf, 2003a, Improved estimation of the covariance matrix of stock returns with an application to portfolio selection, Journal of Empirical Finance 10, [26] Ledoit, O. and M. Wolf, 2003b, A well-conditioned estimator for large-dimensional covariance matrices, Journal of Multivariate Analysis 88(2), [27] Longford, N.T., 1999, Multivariate shrinkage estimation of small area means and proposrtions, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Serie B 162, [28] Markowitz, H., 1952, Portfolio selection, Journal of Finance 7, [29] Mathai, A.M. and S.B. Provost, 1992, Quadratic forms in random variables, New York, Marcel Dekker. [30] Merton, R.C., 1980, On estimating the expected return on the market, Journal of Financial Economics 8, [31] Michaud, R.O., 1989, The Markowitz optimization enigma: is optimized optimal? Financial Analyst Journal 45(1), [32] Michaud, R.O., 1998, Efficient Asset Management, Boston, Massachusetts, Harvard Business School Press. [33] Okhrin, Y. and W. Schmid, 2005, Distributional properties of optimal portfolio weights. Forthcoming in Journal of Econometrics. [34] Scherer, B., 2002, Portfolio resampling: review and critique, Financial Analyst Journal 58, [35] Stein, C., 1955, Inadmissability of the usual estimator for the mean of a multivariate normal distribution. Proc. 3rd Berkeley Symp. Math. Statist. Prob. 1, [36] Zhang, F., 1999, Matrix Theory: Basic Results and Techniques, New York, Springer. 23

24 Figure 1: 24

25 Figure 2: 25

26 Figure 3: 26

27 Figure 1: The true optimal (black solid), true shrinkage (black dashed for single and black dashed-dotted for different shrinkage coefficients), current (dotted) portfolio weights of the first asset as well as optimal shrinkage coefficients (grey dashed for single and grey dasheddotted for different shrinkage coefficients) as a function of the current weight c 1. c 2 and c 3 are set equal to the true portfolio weights. Model parameters are given in Section 5. Left column corresponds to γ = 10, right column to γ = 25. n {24, 60, 120}. Figure 2: The expected utility for the true optimal (black solid), estimated optimal (grey solid), true shrinkage (black dashed for single and black dashed-dotted for different shrinkage coefficients), estimated shrinkage (grey dashed for single and grey dashed-dotted for different shrinkage coefficients), current (dotted) utilities as a function of the current weight c 1. c 2 and c 3 are set equal to the true portfolio weights. Model parameters are given in Section 5. Left column corresponds to γ = 10, right column to γ = 25. n {24, 60, 120}. Figure 3: The averaged over n [30, 150] ranks of expected utilities for competing strategies: (1) Markowitz strategy (solid black), (2) Jorion strategy (solid grey), (3) Ledoit and Wolf strategy (dotted), (4) single shrinkage strategy (dashed), (5) different shrinkage strategy (dashed-dotted) as a function investment horizon s (months), for the risk aversion coefficients γ {5, 10, 20, 35, 50, 100} (from left to right, from top to bottom). Design of the study is described in Section 6. 27

Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty

Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty George Photiou Lincoln College University of Oxford A dissertation submitted in partial fulfilment for

More information

Portfolio Selection with Mental Accounts and Estimation Risk

Portfolio Selection with Mental Accounts and Estimation Risk Portfolio Selection with Mental Accounts and Estimation Risk Gordon J. Alexander Alexandre M. Baptista Shu Yan University of Minnesota The George Washington University Oklahoma State University April 23,

More information

How inefficient are simple asset-allocation strategies?

How inefficient are simple asset-allocation strategies? How inefficient are simple asset-allocation strategies? Victor DeMiguel London Business School Lorenzo Garlappi U. of Texas at Austin Raman Uppal London Business School; CEPR March 2005 Motivation Ancient

More information

On Portfolio Optimization: Imposing the Right Constraints

On Portfolio Optimization: Imposing the Right Constraints On Portfolio Optimization: Imposing the Right Constraints Patrick Behr Andre Güttler Felix Miebs June 1, 2010 Abstract We develop a shrinkage theory based framework for determining optimal portfolio weight

More information

Asset Allocation and Risk Assessment with Gross Exposure Constraints

Asset Allocation and Risk Assessment with Gross Exposure Constraints Asset Allocation and Risk Assessment with Gross Exposure Constraints Forrest Zhang Bendheim Center for Finance Princeton University A joint work with Jianqing Fan and Ke Yu, Princeton Princeton University

More information

The Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios

The Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios The Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios Apostolos Kourtis First version: June 6 2014 This version: January 23 2016 Abstract Investors often adopt mean-variance efficient portfolios for achieving

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Mean Variance Portfolio Theory

Mean Variance Portfolio Theory Chapter 1 Mean Variance Portfolio Theory This book is about portfolio construction and risk analysis in the real-world context where optimization is done with constraints and penalties specified by the

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

A RIDGE REGRESSION ESTIMATION APPROACH WHEN MULTICOLLINEARITY IS PRESENT

A RIDGE REGRESSION ESTIMATION APPROACH WHEN MULTICOLLINEARITY IS PRESENT Fundamental Journal of Applied Sciences Vol. 1, Issue 1, 016, Pages 19-3 This paper is available online at http://www.frdint.com/ Published online February 18, 016 A RIDGE REGRESSION ESTIMATION APPROACH

More information

Optimal Estimation for Economic Gains: Portfolio Choice with Parameter Uncertainty

Optimal Estimation for Economic Gains: Portfolio Choice with Parameter Uncertainty Optimal Estimation for Economic Gains: Portfolio Choice with Parameter Uncertainty RAYMOND KAN and GUOFU ZHOU First draft: May 2003 This version: August 2004 Kan is from the University of Toronto and Zhou

More information

Testing Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance

Testing Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance Testing Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance Ekaterina Kazak 1 Winfried Pohlmeier 2 1 University of Konstanz, GSDS 2 University of Konstanz, CoFE, RCEA Econometric Research in Finance Workshop 2017 SGH

More information

Asset Selection Model Based on the VaR Adjusted High-Frequency Sharp Index

Asset Selection Model Based on the VaR Adjusted High-Frequency Sharp Index Management Science and Engineering Vol. 11, No. 1, 2017, pp. 67-75 DOI:10.3968/9412 ISSN 1913-0341 [Print] ISSN 1913-035X [Online] www.cscanada.net www.cscanada.org Asset Selection Model Based on the VaR

More information

Optimal weights for the MSCI North America index. Optimal weights for the MSCI Europe index

Optimal weights for the MSCI North America index. Optimal weights for the MSCI Europe index Portfolio construction with Bayesian GARCH forecasts Wolfgang Polasek and Momtchil Pojarliev Institute of Statistics and Econometrics University of Basel Holbeinstrasse 12 CH-4051 Basel email: Momtchil.Pojarliev@unibas.ch

More information

Turnover Minimization: A Versatile Shrinkage Portfolio Estimator

Turnover Minimization: A Versatile Shrinkage Portfolio Estimator Turnover Minimization: A Versatile Shrinkage Portfolio Estimator Chulwoo Han Abstract We develop a shrinkage model for portfolio choice. It places a layer on a conventional portfolio problem where the

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Quantitative Risk Management

Quantitative Risk Management Quantitative Risk Management Asset Allocation and Risk Management Martin B. Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Outline Review of Mean-Variance Analysis

More information

A Generalized Approach to Portfolio Optimization: Improving Performance By Constraining Portfolio Norms

A Generalized Approach to Portfolio Optimization: Improving Performance By Constraining Portfolio Norms A Generalized Approach to Portfolio Optimization: Improving Performance By Constraining Portfolio Norms Victor DeMiguel Lorenzo Garlappi Francisco J. Nogales Raman Uppal July 16, 2007 Abstract In this

More information

Robust Portfolio Rebalancing with Transaction Cost Penalty An Empirical Analysis

Robust Portfolio Rebalancing with Transaction Cost Penalty An Empirical Analysis August 2009 Robust Portfolio Rebalancing with Transaction Cost Penalty An Empirical Analysis Abstract The goal of this paper is to compare different techniques of reducing the sensitivity of optimal portfolios

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

Practical Portfolio Optimization

Practical Portfolio Optimization Practical Portfolio Optimization Victor DeMiguel Professor of Management Science and Operations London Business School Based on joint research with Lorenzo Garlappi Alberto Martin-Utrera Xiaoling Mei U

More information

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén PORTFOLIO THEORY Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Portfolio Theory Investments 1 / 60 Outline 1 Modern Portfolio Theory Introduction Mean-Variance

More information

Global Currency Hedging

Global Currency Hedging Global Currency Hedging JOHN Y. CAMPBELL, KARINE SERFATY-DE MEDEIROS, and LUIS M. VICEIRA ABSTRACT Over the period 1975 to 2005, the U.S. dollar (particularly in relation to the Canadian dollar), the euro,

More information

The out-of-sample performance of robust portfolio optimization

The out-of-sample performance of robust portfolio optimization The out-of-sample performance of robust portfolio optimization André Alves Portela Santos May 28 Abstract Robust optimization has been receiving increased attention in the recent few years due to the possibility

More information

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation 200 2 Ó Ó 4 4 Dec., 200 OR Transactions Vol.4 No.4 Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation Xie Yao Liang Zhi An 2 Abstract For one-period investors, fixed income securities

More information

Minimum Downside Volatility Indices

Minimum Downside Volatility Indices Minimum Downside Volatility Indices Timo Pfei er, Head of Research Lars Walter, Quantitative Research Analyst Daniel Wendelberger, Quantitative Research Analyst 18th July 2017 1 1 Introduction "Analyses

More information

Estimation risk modeling in portfolio selection: Implicit approach implementation

Estimation risk modeling in portfolio selection: Implicit approach implementation Journal of Finance and Investment Analysis, vol.1, no.3, 2012, 21-31 ISSN: 2241-0988 (print version), 2241-0996 (online) Scienpress Ltd, 2012 Estimation risk modeling in portfolio selection: Implicit approach

More information

Parameter Estimation Techniques, Optimization Frequency, and Equity Portfolio Return Enhancement*

Parameter Estimation Techniques, Optimization Frequency, and Equity Portfolio Return Enhancement* Parameter Estimation Techniques, Optimization Frequency, and Equity Portfolio Return Enhancement* By Glen A. Larsen, Jr. Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Indianapolis, IN 46202, USA, Glarsen@iupui.edu

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M VIALE I Markowitz-Tobin Mean-Variance Portfolio Analysis Assumption Mean-Variance preferences Markowitz 95 Quadratic utility function E [ w b w ] { = E [ w] b V ar w + E [ w] }

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

Optimal Versus Naive Diversification in Factor Models

Optimal Versus Naive Diversification in Factor Models Chapter 4 Optimal Versus Naive Diversification in Factor Models 4.1 Introduction Markowitz (1952) provides a solid framework for mean-variance based optimal portfolio selection. If, however, the true parameters

More information

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance analysis Prof. Massimo Guidolin Portfolio Management Second Term 2018 Outline and objectives Mean-variance and efficient frontiers: logical meaning o Guidolin-Pedio,

More information

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION SILAS A. IHEDIOHA 1, BRIGHT O. OSU 2 1 Department of Mathematics, Plateau State University, Bokkos, P. M. B. 2012, Jos,

More information

International Finance. Estimation Error. Campbell R. Harvey Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc.

International Finance. Estimation Error. Campbell R. Harvey Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc. International Finance Estimation Error Campbell R. Harvey Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc February 17, 2017 Motivation The Markowitz Mean Variance Efficiency is the

More information

The Dispersion Bias. Correcting a large source of error in minimum variance portfolios. Lisa Goldberg Alex Papanicolaou Alex Shkolnik 15 November 2017

The Dispersion Bias. Correcting a large source of error in minimum variance portfolios. Lisa Goldberg Alex Papanicolaou Alex Shkolnik 15 November 2017 The Dispersion Bias Correcting a large source of error in minimum variance portfolios Lisa Goldberg Alex Papanicolaou Alex Shkolnik 15 November 2017 Seminar in Statistics and Applied Probability University

More information

Performance of Portfolios Optimized with Estimation Error

Performance of Portfolios Optimized with Estimation Error Performance of Portfolios Optimized with Estimation Error Andrew F. Siegel Business School, University of Washington, Seattle, Washington 9895-3, asiegel@u.washington.edu Artemiza Woodgate Business School,

More information

Determination and Estimation of Risk Aversion Coefficients

Determination and Estimation of Risk Aversion Coefficients Mathematical Statistics Stockholm University Determination and Estimation of Risk Aversion Coefficients Taras Bodnar Yarema Okhrin Valdemar Vitlinskyy Taras Zabolotskyy Research Report 015:3 ISSN 1650-0377

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM

Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM Carlo Favero Favero () Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM 1 / 20 Econometric Modelling of Financial Returns Financial data are mostly observational data: they

More information

Forecast Risk Bias in Optimized Portfolios

Forecast Risk Bias in Optimized Portfolios Forecast Risk Bias in Optimized Portfolios March 2011 Presented to Qwafafew, Denver Chapter Jenn Bender, Jyh-Huei Lee, Dan Stefek, Jay Yao Portfolio Construction Portfolio construction is the process of

More information

Mathematics in Finance

Mathematics in Finance Mathematics in Finance Steven E. Shreve Department of Mathematical Sciences Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213 USA shreve@andrew.cmu.edu A Talk in the Series Probability in Science and Industry

More information

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods Prepared by Kevin Pei for The Fund @ Sprott Abstract: In this document, I will model and back test our portfolio with various proposed models. It goes without

More information

Volume 36, Issue 4. Joint aggregation over money and credit card services under risk

Volume 36, Issue 4. Joint aggregation over money and credit card services under risk Volume 36, Issue 4 Joint aggregation over money and credit card services under risk William A. Barnett University of Kansas and Center for Financial Stability Liting Su University of Kansas and Center

More information

Dynamic Asset Allocation for Hedging Downside Risk

Dynamic Asset Allocation for Hedging Downside Risk Dynamic Asset Allocation for Hedging Downside Risk Gerd Infanger Stanford University Department of Management Science and Engineering and Infanger Investment Technology, LLC October 2009 Gerd Infanger,

More information

Master s in Financial Engineering Foundations of Buy-Side Finance: Quantitative Risk and Portfolio Management. > Teaching > Courses

Master s in Financial Engineering Foundations of Buy-Side Finance: Quantitative Risk and Portfolio Management.  > Teaching > Courses Master s in Financial Engineering Foundations of Buy-Side Finance: Quantitative Risk and Portfolio Management www.symmys.com > Teaching > Courses Spring 2008, Monday 7:10 pm 9:30 pm, Room 303 Attilio Meucci

More information

APPLYING MULTIVARIATE

APPLYING MULTIVARIATE Swiss Society for Financial Market Research (pp. 201 211) MOMTCHIL POJARLIEV AND WOLFGANG POLASEK APPLYING MULTIVARIATE TIME SERIES FORECASTS FOR ACTIVE PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Momtchil Pojarliev, INVESCO

More information

Portfolio construction by volatility forecasts: Does the covariance structure matter?

Portfolio construction by volatility forecasts: Does the covariance structure matter? Portfolio construction by volatility forecasts: Does the covariance structure matter? Momtchil Pojarliev and Wolfgang Polasek INVESCO Asset Management, Bleichstrasse 60-62, D-60313 Frankfurt email: momtchil

More information

Optimal Portfolio Selection Under the Estimation Risk in Mean Return

Optimal Portfolio Selection Under the Estimation Risk in Mean Return Optimal Portfolio Selection Under the Estimation Risk in Mean Return by Lei Zhu A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in fulfillment of the thesis requirement for the degree of Master of Mathematics

More information

Estimation Risk Modeling in Optimal Portfolio Selection:

Estimation Risk Modeling in Optimal Portfolio Selection: Estimation Risk Modeling in Optimal Portfolio Selection: An Study from Emerging Markets By Sarayut Nathaphan Pornchai Chunhachinda 1 Agenda 2 Traditional efficient portfolio and its extension incorporating

More information

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Table of Contents Lecture 1... 7 1. State the objective of modern portfolio theory... 7 2. Define the return of an asset... 7 3. How is expected return defined?...

More information

Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples

Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples RolfPoulsen and Kourosh Marjani Rasmussen Abstract In the basic Markowitz and Merton models, a stock s weight in efficient portfolios goes up if its

More information

Does Naive Not Mean Optimal? The Case for the 1/N Strategy in Brazilian Equities

Does Naive Not Mean Optimal? The Case for the 1/N Strategy in Brazilian Equities Does Naive Not Mean Optimal? GV INVEST 05 The Case for the 1/N Strategy in Brazilian Equities December, 2016 Vinicius Esposito i The development of optimal approaches to portfolio construction has rendered

More information

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing Richard M. H. Suen University of Leicester 29 March 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/86499/ MPRA Paper

More information

The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement

The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement Richard Michaud, Robert Michaud, David Esch New Frontier Advisors Boston, MA 02110 Presented to: INSIGHTS 2016 fi360 National Conference April 6-8, 2016 San Diego,

More information

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes A Simple Martingale Method Approach Frank Thomas Seifried University of Kaiserslautern March 20, 2009 F. Seifried (Kaiserslautern) Deferred Capital

More information

MODELLING OPTIMAL HEDGE RATIO IN THE PRESENCE OF FUNDING RISK

MODELLING OPTIMAL HEDGE RATIO IN THE PRESENCE OF FUNDING RISK MODELLING OPTIMAL HEDGE RATIO IN THE PRESENCE O UNDING RISK Barbara Dömötör Department of inance Corvinus University of Budapest 193, Budapest, Hungary E-mail: barbara.domotor@uni-corvinus.hu KEYWORDS

More information

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching Science Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 2016; 4(6): 263-268 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/sjams doi: 10.11648/j.sjams.20160406.13 ISSN: 2376-9491 (Print); ISSN: 2376-9513 (Online)

More information

It s All in the Timing: Simple Active Portfolio Strategies that Outperform Naïve Diversification

It s All in the Timing: Simple Active Portfolio Strategies that Outperform Naïve Diversification It s All in the Timing: Simple Active Portfolio Strategies that Outperform Naïve Diversification Chris Kirby a, Barbara Ostdiek b a John E. Walker Department of Economics, Clemson University b Jesse H.

More information

Testing Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance

Testing Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance Testing Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance Ekaterina Kazak University of Konstanz, GSDS Winfried Pohlmeier University of Konstanz, CoFE, RCEA September 20, 2018 Abstract This paper studies the quality

More information

درس هفتم یادگیري ماشین. (Machine Learning) دانشگاه فردوسی مشهد دانشکده مهندسی رضا منصفی

درس هفتم یادگیري ماشین. (Machine Learning) دانشگاه فردوسی مشهد دانشکده مهندسی رضا منصفی یادگیري ماشین توزیع هاي نمونه و تخمین نقطه اي پارامترها Sampling Distributions and Point Estimation of Parameter (Machine Learning) دانشگاه فردوسی مشهد دانشکده مهندسی رضا منصفی درس هفتم 1 Outline Introduction

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE Proceedings of the 44th IEEE Conference on Decision and Control, and the European Control Conference 005 Seville, Spain, December 1-15, 005 WeA11.6 OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF

More information

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Fuzzy Optim Decis Making 217 16:221 234 DOI 117/s17-16-9246-8 No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Xiaoyu Ji 1 Hua Ke 2 Published online: 17 May 216 Springer

More information

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS SEPTEMBER 13, 2010 BASICS. Introduction

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS SEPTEMBER 13, 2010 BASICS. Introduction STOCASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODE: CANONICA APPICATIONS SEPTEMBER 3, 00 Introduction BASICS Consumption-Savings Framework So far only a deterministic analysis now introduce uncertainty Still an application

More information

FURTHER ASPECTS OF GAMBLING WITH THE KELLY CRITERION. We consider two aspects of gambling with the Kelly criterion. First, we show that for

FURTHER ASPECTS OF GAMBLING WITH THE KELLY CRITERION. We consider two aspects of gambling with the Kelly criterion. First, we show that for FURTHER ASPECTS OF GAMBLING WITH THE KELLY CRITERION RAVI PHATARFOD *, Monash University Abstract We consider two aspects of gambling with the Kelly criterion. First, we show that for a wide range of final

More information

Are Smart Beta indexes valid for hedge fund portfolio allocation?

Are Smart Beta indexes valid for hedge fund portfolio allocation? Are Smart Beta indexes valid for hedge fund portfolio allocation? Asmerilda Hitaj Giovanni Zambruno University of Milano Bicocca Second Young researchers meeting on BSDEs, Numerics and Finance July 2014

More information

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

Log-Robust Portfolio Management Log-Robust Portfolio Management Dr. Aurélie Thiele Lehigh University Joint work with Elcin Cetinkaya and Ban Kawas Research partially supported by the National Science Foundation Grant CMMI-0757983 Dr.

More information

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require Chapter 8 Markowitz Portfolio Theory 8.7 Investor Utility Functions People are always asked the question: would more money make you happier? The answer is usually yes. The next question is how much more

More information

Fast Convergence of Regress-later Series Estimators

Fast Convergence of Regress-later Series Estimators Fast Convergence of Regress-later Series Estimators New Thinking in Finance, London Eric Beutner, Antoon Pelsser, Janina Schweizer Maastricht University & Kleynen Consultants 12 February 2014 Beutner Pelsser

More information

Log-Normal Approximation of the Equity Premium in the Production Model

Log-Normal Approximation of the Equity Premium in the Production Model Log-Normal Approximation of the Equity Premium in the Production Model Burkhard Heer Alfred Maussner CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 3311 CATEGORY 12: EMPIRICAL AND THEORETICAL METHODS DECEMBER 2010 An electronic

More information

Decision theoretic estimation of the ratio of variances in a bivariate normal distribution 1

Decision theoretic estimation of the ratio of variances in a bivariate normal distribution 1 Decision theoretic estimation of the ratio of variances in a bivariate normal distribution 1 George Iliopoulos Department of Mathematics University of Patras 26500 Rio, Patras, Greece Abstract In this

More information

Non replication of options

Non replication of options Non replication of options Christos Kountzakis, Ioannis A Polyrakis and Foivos Xanthos June 30, 2008 Abstract In this paper we study the scarcity of replication of options in the two period model of financial

More information

Optimal rebalancing of portfolios with transaction costs assuming constant risk aversion

Optimal rebalancing of portfolios with transaction costs assuming constant risk aversion Optimal rebalancing of portfolios with transaction costs assuming constant risk aversion Lars Holden PhD, Managing director t: +47 22852672 Norwegian Computing Center, P. O. Box 114 Blindern, NO 0314 Oslo,

More information

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )] Problem set 1 Answers: 1. (a) The first order conditions are with 1+ 1so 0 ( ) [ 0 ( +1 )] [( +1 )] ( +1 ) Consumption follows a random walk. This is approximately true in many nonlinear models. Now we

More information

Robust Portfolio Optimization Using a Simple Factor Model

Robust Portfolio Optimization Using a Simple Factor Model Robust Portfolio Optimization Using a Simple Factor Model Chris Bemis, Xueying Hu, Weihua Lin, Somayes Moazeni, Li Wang, Ting Wang, Jingyan Zhang Abstract In this paper we examine the performance of a

More information

Robust Portfolio Optimization SOCP Formulations

Robust Portfolio Optimization SOCP Formulations 1 Robust Portfolio Optimization SOCP Formulations There has been a wealth of literature published in the last 1 years explaining and elaborating on what has become known as Robust portfolio optimization.

More information

Asymptotic methods in risk management. Advances in Financial Mathematics

Asymptotic methods in risk management. Advances in Financial Mathematics Asymptotic methods in risk management Peter Tankov Based on joint work with A. Gulisashvili Advances in Financial Mathematics Paris, January 7 10, 2014 Peter Tankov (Université Paris Diderot) Asymptotic

More information

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Hans U. Gerber and Gérard Pafumi Switzerland Abstract In the first part of the paper the surplus of a company is modelled by a Wiener process.

More information

Course information FN3142 Quantitative finance

Course information FN3142 Quantitative finance Course information 015 16 FN314 Quantitative finance This course is aimed at students interested in obtaining a thorough grounding in market finance and related empirical methods. Prerequisite If taken

More information

Portfolio Selection with Parameter and Model Uncertainty: A Multi-Prior Approach

Portfolio Selection with Parameter and Model Uncertainty: A Multi-Prior Approach Portfolio Selection with Parameter and Model Uncertainty: A Multi-Prior Approach Lorenzo Garlappi Raman Uppal Tan Wang April 2004 We gratefully acknowledge financial support from INQUIRE UK; this article

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

Bayes-Stein Estimators and International Real Estate Asset Allocation

Bayes-Stein Estimators and International Real Estate Asset Allocation Bayes-Stein Estimators and International Real Estate Asset Allocation Authors Simon Stevenson Abstract This article is the winner of the International Real Estate Investment/ Management manuscript prize

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall Financial mathematics

Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall Financial mathematics Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall 2014 Reduce the risk, one asset Let us warm up by doing an exercise. We consider an investment with σ 1 =

More information

Measuring Financial Risk using Extreme Value Theory: evidence from Pakistan

Measuring Financial Risk using Extreme Value Theory: evidence from Pakistan Measuring Financial Risk using Extreme Value Theory: evidence from Pakistan Dr. Abdul Qayyum and Faisal Nawaz Abstract The purpose of the paper is to show some methods of extreme value theory through analysis

More information

X ln( +1 ) +1 [0 ] Γ( )

X ln( +1 ) +1 [0 ] Γ( ) Problem Set #1 Due: 11 September 2014 Instructor: David Laibson Economics 2010c Problem 1 (Growth Model): Recall the growth model that we discussed in class. We expressed the sequence problem as ( 0 )=

More information

Dynamic Asset and Liability Management Models for Pension Systems

Dynamic Asset and Liability Management Models for Pension Systems Dynamic Asset and Liability Management Models for Pension Systems The Comparison between Multi-period Stochastic Programming Model and Stochastic Control Model Muneki Kawaguchi and Norio Hibiki June 1,

More information

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM Yan Zeng Version 1.0.2, last revised on 2012-05-30. Abstract A summary of mean variance analysis in portfolio management and capital asset pricing model. 1. Mean-Variance

More information

Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions, Modern Portfolio Theory

Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions, Modern Portfolio Theory Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions, Modern Portfolio Theory Shuoxun Hellen Zhang WISE & SOE XIAMEN UNIVERSITY April, 2015 1 / 95 Outline Modern portfolio theory The backward induction,

More information

Yale ICF Working Paper No First Draft: February 21, 1992 This Draft: June 29, Safety First Portfolio Insurance

Yale ICF Working Paper No First Draft: February 21, 1992 This Draft: June 29, Safety First Portfolio Insurance Yale ICF Working Paper No. 08 11 First Draft: February 21, 1992 This Draft: June 29, 1992 Safety First Portfolio Insurance William N. Goetzmann, International Center for Finance, Yale School of Management,

More information

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS FEBRUARY 19, 2013

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS FEBRUARY 19, 2013 STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS FEBRUARY 19, 2013 Model Structure EXPECTED UTILITY Preferences v(c 1, c 2 ) with all the usual properties Lifetime expected utility function

More information

EC316a: Advanced Scientific Computation, Fall Discrete time, continuous state dynamic models: solution methods

EC316a: Advanced Scientific Computation, Fall Discrete time, continuous state dynamic models: solution methods EC316a: Advanced Scientific Computation, Fall 2003 Notes Section 4 Discrete time, continuous state dynamic models: solution methods We consider now solution methods for discrete time models in which decisions

More information

A Simple, Adjustably Robust, Dynamic Portfolio Policy under Expected Return Ambiguity

A Simple, Adjustably Robust, Dynamic Portfolio Policy under Expected Return Ambiguity A Simple, Adjustably Robust, Dynamic Portfolio Policy under Expected Return Ambiguity Mustafa Ç. Pınar Department of Industrial Engineering Bilkent University 06800 Bilkent, Ankara, Turkey March 16, 2012

More information

Hedging Derivative Securities with VIX Derivatives: A Discrete-Time -Arbitrage Approach

Hedging Derivative Securities with VIX Derivatives: A Discrete-Time -Arbitrage Approach Hedging Derivative Securities with VIX Derivatives: A Discrete-Time -Arbitrage Approach Nelson Kian Leong Yap a, Kian Guan Lim b, Yibao Zhao c,* a Department of Mathematics, National University of Singapore

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Pacific Rim Real Estate Society (PRRES) Conference Bayes Stein Estimators & International Real Estate Allocation

Pacific Rim Real Estate Society (PRRES) Conference Bayes Stein Estimators & International Real Estate Allocation Pacific Rim Real Estate Society (PRRES) Conference 2000 Sydney, 23-27 January, 2000 Bayes Stein Estimators & International Real Estate Allocation Simon Stevenson Department of Banking & Finance, Graduate

More information