A Generalized Approach to Portfolio Optimization: Improving Performance By Constraining Portfolio Norms

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Generalized Approach to Portfolio Optimization: Improving Performance By Constraining Portfolio Norms"

Transcription

1 A Generalized Approach to Portfolio Optimization: Improving Performance By Constraining Portfolio Norms Victor DeMiguel Lorenzo Garlappi Francisco J. Nogales Raman Uppal July 16, 2007 Abstract In this paper, we provide a general framework for identifying portfolios that perform well out-of-sample even in the presence of estimation error. This general framework relies on solving the traditional minimum-variance problem (based on the sample covariance matrix) but subject to the additional constraint that the norm of the portfolio-weight vector be smaller than a given threshold. We show that our unifying framework nests as special cases the shrinkage approaches of Jagannathan and Ma (2003) and Ledoit and Wolf (2004b), and the 1/N portfolio studied in DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2007). We also use our general framework to propose several new portfolio strategies. For these new portfolios, we provide a moment-shrinkage interpretation and a Bayesian interpretation where the investor has a prior belief on portfolio weights rather than on moments of asset returns. Finally, we compare empirically (in terms of portfolio variance, Sharpe ratio, and turnover), the out-of-sample performance of the new portfolios we propose to nine strategies in the existing literature across five datasets. We find that the norm-constrained portfolios we propose have a lower variance and a higher Sharpe ratio than the portfolio strategies in Jagannathan and Ma (2003) and Ledoit and Wolf (2004b), the 1/N portfolio, and also other strategies in the literature such as factor portfolios and the parametric portfolios in Brandt, Santa-Clara, and Valkanov (2005). We wish to thank Vito Gala, Francisco Gomes, Garud Iyengar, Igor Makarov, Catalina Stefanescu, and Bruce Weber for comments and suggestions. DeMiguel and Uppal are from London Business School; Garlappi is from The University of Texas at Austin; Nogales is from the Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. 1

2 Contents 1 Introduction 3 2 Existing Approaches: Shrinking the Sample Covariance Matrix Base Case: The Shortsale-Unconstrained Minimum-Variance Portfolio The Shortsale-Constrained Minimum-Variance Portfolio Shrinking the Sample-Covariance Matrix Toward the Identity Matrix A Generalized Approach: Constraining the Portfolio Norms The General Norm-Constrained Minimum-Variance Portfolio First Particular Case: The 1-Norm-Constrained Portfolios Second Particular Case: The 2-Norm-Constrained Portfolios Third Particular Case: The Partial Minimum-Variance Portfolios Analytical Expression for the First Partial Minimum-Variance Portfolio Relation to the 2-Norm-Constrained Portfolios A Bayesian Interpretation of the Norm-Constrained Portfolios A Moment-Shrinkage Interpretation of the Norm-Constrained Portfolios Out-of-Sample Evaluation of the Proposed Portfolios 26 5 Conclusion 29 References 31 A Appendix: Details of the Partial Minimum-Variance Portfolios 34 A.1 Expressing the Minimum-Variance Problem Without the Adding-Up Constraint A.2 Applying the Conjugate-Gradient Method B Appendix: Proofs for All the Propositions 38 C Appendix: Details of Out-of-Sample Evaluation of Portfolios 45 C.1 Calibration of the Norm-Constrained Portfolios C.2 Description of the Portfolios Considered C.3 Description of the Empirical Datasets Considered C.4 Description of the Methodology Used to Evaluate Performance C.5 Discussion of the Out-of-Sample Performance Tables 56 Figures 62

3 1 Introduction Markowitz (1952) showed that an investor who cares only about the mean and variance of static portfolio returns should hold a portfolio on the efficient frontier. To implement these portfolios in practice, one needs to estimate the means and covariances of asset returns. Traditionally, the sample means and covariances have been used for this purpose. But due to estimation error, the portfolios that rely on the sample estimates typically perform poorly out of sample. 1 In this paper, we provide a general framework for determining portfolios with superior out-of-sample performance even in the presence of estimation error. This general framework relies on solving the traditional minimum-variance problem (based on the sample covariance matrix) but subject to the additional constraint that the norm of the portfolio-weight vector be smaller than a given threshold. It is well known that it is more difficult to estimate means than covariances of asset returns (see Merton (1980)), and also that errors in estimates of means have a larger impact on portfolio weights than errors in estimates of covariances. For this reason, recent research has focused on minimumvariance portfolios, which rely solely on estimates of covariances, and thus, are less vulnerable to estimation error than mean-variance portfolios. Indeed, the superiority of minimum-variance portfolios is demonstrated by extensive empirical evidence that shows that this portfolio usually performs better out of sample than any other mean-variance portfolio even when the Sharpe ratio or other performance measures that depend on both the portfolio mean and variance are used for evaluating performance. For example, Jagannathan and Ma (2003, p ) report: 2 1 For evidence of the poor performance of the Markowitz portfolio based on sample estimates of means and covariances, see Frost and Savarino (1986, 1988), Michaud (1989), Best and Grauer (1991), Chopra and Ziemba (1993), Broadie (1993), and Litterman (2003). DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2007) provide a comprehensive review of the performance of various methods to deal with the estimation error in means and covariances. These include the following. (i) The Bayesian approach with uninformed diffuse priors Barry (1974), Klein and Bawa (1976), and Bawa, Brown, and Klein (1979), with priors based on data Jobson, Korkie, and Ratti (1979) and Jorion (1985), with priors based on an asset-pricing model Pástor (2000), Pástor and Stambaugh (2000), Wang (2005) and Chevrier (2006), and with priors based on an asset-pricing model and the subjective views of an investor Black and Litterman (1990, 1992). (ii) Non-Bayesian approaches to estimation error, which include robust portfolio allocation rules Halldórsson and Tütüncü (2000), Goldfarb and Iyengar (2003), Tütüncü and Koenig (2003), and Garlappi, Uppal, and Wang (2006), and portfolio rules designed to optimally diversify across market and estimation risk Kan and Zhou (2005). (iii) Portfolios that exploit the moment restrictions imposed by the factor structure of returns MacKinlay and Pastor (2000). (iv) Parametric portfolios that exploit asset-specific information in the cross section of asset returns Brandt, Santa-Clara, and Valkanov (2005). 2 For additional evidence, see Jorion (1985, 1986, 1991) and DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2007). 3

4 The estimation error in the sample mean is so large nothing much is lost in ignoring the mean altogether when no further information about the population mean is available. For example, the global minimum variance portfolio has as large an out-of-sample Sharpe ratio as other efficient portfolio when past historical average returns are used as proxies for expected returns. In view of this we focus our attention on global minimum variance portfolios in this study. Just like Jagannathan and Ma (2003), we too focus on minimum-variance portfolios, even though the general framework we develop applies also to mean-variance portfolios. But even the performance of the minimum-variance portfolio depends crucially on the quality of the estimated covariances. Although the estimation error associated with the sample covariances is smaller than that for sample mean returns, it can still be substantial. In the literature, several approaches have been proposed to deal with the problem of estimating the large number of elements in the covariance matrix. One approach is to use higher-frequency data, say daily instead of monthly returns (see Jagannathan and Ma (2003)). A second approach is to impose some structure on the estimator of the covariance matrix; for instance, Chan, Karceski, and Lakonishok (1999) propose a variety of factor models, which reduce the number of parameters to be estimated, and therefore, mitigate the impact of estimation error. A third approach is suggested by Green and Hollifield (1992). They propose a two-step method if returns are generated by a single factor model. First, diversify over the set of high beta stocks and the set of low beta stocks separately; then, short the high beta portfolio and go long the low beta portfolio in oder to reduce the systematic risk. A fourth approach has been proposed by Ledoit and Wolf (2004b), who use as an estimator a weighted average of the sample covariance matrix and the identity matrix. This approach can be interpreted as a method that shrinks the sample covariance matrix toward the identity matrix. A fifth approach, which is often used in practice, is to impose shortsale constraints on the portfolio weights (see Frost and Savarino (1988) and Chopra (1993)). Jagannathan and Ma (2003) show that imposing a shortsale constraint when minimizing the portfolio variance is equivalent to shrinking the extreme elements of the covariance matrix. This simple remedy for dealing with estimation error performs very well. In fact, Jagannathan and Ma (2003, p. 1654) 4

5 find that the sample covariance matrix [with shortsale constraints] performs almost as well as those [covariance matrices] constructed using factor models, shrinkage estimators or daily returns. Finally, DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2007) demonstrate that even constraining shortsales may not mitigate completely the error in estimating the covariance matrix, and thus, an investor may be best off (in terms of Sharpe ratio, certainty-equivalent returns, and turnover) ignoring data on asset returns altogether and using the naive 1/N rule to allocate an equal proportion of wealth across each of the N assets. In this paper, we develop a new approach for determining the optimal portfolio weights in the presence of estimation error. Following the idea in Brandt (1999) and Britten-Jones (1999), we treat the weights rather than the moments of assets returns as the objects of interest to be estimated. So, rather than shrinking the moments of asset returns, we introduce the constraint that the norm of the portfolio-weight vector be smaller than a given threshold. The general framework we develop is then based on solving the traditional minimum-variance problem subject to this constraint on the norm of the portfolio-weight vector; that is, rather than shrinking the moments of asset returns, we require that the weights themselves be bounded. We base our analysis on the minimum-variance portfolio rather than the mean-variance portfolio because, as mentioned above, it is difficult to estimate expected returns precisely, and so portfolios that ignore sample mean returns often outperform portfolios relying on estimated means. 3 Our paper contributes to the literature on optimal portfolio choice in the presence of estimation error in several ways. One, we show that our framework nests as special cases the shrinkage approaches of Jagannathan and Ma (2003) and Ledoit and Wolf (2004b). In particular, we prove that if one solves the minimum-variance problem subject to the constraint that the sum of the absolute values of the weights (1-norm) be smaller than 1, then one retrieves the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance portfolio considered by Jagannathan and Ma (2003). If, on the other hand, one imposes the constraint that the sum of the squares of the portfolio weights (2-norm) be smaller than a given threshold, we prove that then one recovers the class of portfolios considered by Ledoit and 3 The norm constraints can be imposed also on the traditional mean-variance-portfolio problem, and our analysis extends in a straightforward manner to this case. As mentioned above, we focus on the minimum-variance problem because it performs better empirically due to the large error associated with estimating mean returns. For completeness, however, in our empirical work we consider as benchmarks both the classical Markowitz mean-variance portfolio and also the Bayesian mean-variance portfolio, as implemented in Jorion (1985). 5

6 Wolf (2004b). Finally, we show that if one imposes the constraint that the squared 2-norm of the portfolio-weight vector be smaller than 1/N, then one gets the 1/N portfolio studied in DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2007). Two, we use this general unifying framework to develop new portfolio strategies. For example, we show how the shortsale-constrained portfolio considered in Jagannathan and Ma (2003) can be generalized. In particular, we show that by imposing the constraint that the 1-norm of the portfolio-weight vector be smaller than a threshold that is strictly larger than 1, then we obtain a new class of shrinkage portfolios where we limit the total amount of shortselling in the portfolio, rather than limiting the shorting asset-by-asset, as in the traditional shortsale-constrained portfolio. To the best of our knowledge, this kind of portfolio has not been analyzed before in the academic literature, although it corresponds closely to the actual portfolio holdings allowed in personal margin accounts. Moreover, these portfolios have recently become quite popular among practitioners see the articles in The Economist (Buttonwood (2007)) and The New York Times (Hershey Jr. (2007)) that describe portfolios where investors are long 130% and short 30% of their wealth. More importantly, we use our general framework to also develop several new portfolio strategies. Specifically, we propose a different class of portfolios that we term partial minimum-variance portfolios. These portfolios are obtained by applying the classical conjugate-gradient method (see Nocedal and Wright (1999)) to solve the minimum-variance problem. We show that these portfolios may be interpreted as a discrete first-order approximation to the shrinkage portfolios proposed by Ledoit and Wolf (2004b). Three, we show how the norm-constrained portfolios we propose and also those proposed by Jagannathan and Ma (2003) and Ledoit and Wolf (2004b) can be interpreted as those of a Bayesian investor who has a certain prior belief on portfolio weights rather than moments of asset returns. Jorion (1986) also shows that the shrinkage estimators of mean returns he considers can be obtained by assuming the investor has a certain prior belief on the means of asset returns. Thus, the main difference between his approach and ours is that we assume a prior belief on the portfolio weights, as opposed to a prior belief on the means of the asset returns. 6

7 Four, our approach to minimum-variance portfolio selection is related also to a number of approaches proposed in the statistics and chemometrics literature to reduce estimation error in regression analysis. It is known in the literature that optimal portfolios weights in an unconstrained mean- or minimum-variance problem can be thought of as coefficients of an OLS regression (see, for example, Britten-Jones (1999)). It then follows that, in general, constrained weights are the outcome of similarly specified restricted regressions. In particular, the case where the 1-norm of the portfolio vector is constrained to be less than a certain threshold, is analogous to the statistical technique for regression analysis known as least absolute shrinkage and selection operator (lasso) (Tibshirani (1996)), the case where the 2-norm of the portfolio vector is constrained to be less than a certain threshold corresponds to the statistical technique known as ridge regression (Hoerl and Kennard (1970)), and the partial minimum-variance portfolio that we study, which is a discrete first-order approximation to the 2-norm-constrained minimum-variance portfolio, corresponds to the technique developed in chemometrics that is known as partial least squares (Wold (1975); Frank and Friedman (1993)). These regression techniques and the distribution theory associated with them have been used extensively in the statistics literature. By allowing a more general constrained structure in the construction of the portfolio weights and linking this to regression techniques, our paper provides a unified framework for understanding the existing methods proposed in the literature, and our analysis suggests new strategies that perform well out of sample. Five, the generalized framework allows one to calibrate the model using historical data in order to improve its out-of-sample performance. To demonstrate this, we show how the nonparametric technique known as cross validation can be used to estimate the optimal amount of shrinkage (the optimal value of the threshold on the portfolio norm) that minimizes the estimated out-of-sample variance; see Efron and Gong (1983) and Campbell, Lo, and MacKinley (1997, Section ) for discussions of cross validation. We also show how the time-series properties of portfolio returns (as opposed to individual security returns) that have been documented by Campbell, Lo, and MacKinley (1997) can be used to set the level of the constraint on the portfolio norm in order to improve the portfolio Sharpe ratio. 7

8 Finally, we compare empirically the out-of-sample performance of the three norm-constrained portfolios we propose to nine strategies in the existing literature for five different datasets. The portfolios we evaluate are listed in Table 1 and the datasets we consider are listed in Table 2. We compare performance along three dimensions: (i) out-of-sample portfolio variance, (ii) out-ofsample portfolio Sharpe ratio, 4 and (iii) portfolio turnover or trading volume. We find that the new portfolios we propose have a lower variance and a higher Sharpe ratio than those studied in Jagannathan and Ma (2003), Ledoit and Wolf (2004b), the 1/N portfolio evaluated in DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2007), and also other strategies proposed in the literature, including factor portfolios and the parametric portfolios in Brandt, Santa-Clara, and Valkanov (2005), which use firm-specific characteristics of the cross-section of stock returns. 5 Our work is related closely to Lauprete (2001), who also considers the 1- and 2-norm-constrained portfolios. 6 Our additional contribution is first to demonstrate that the 1- and 2-norm-constrained portfolios include as particular cases the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance portfolios considered by Jagannathan and Ma (2003), the shrinkage portfolios proposed by Ledoit and Wolf (2004b), and the 1/N portfolio. Second, we propose the partial minimum-variance portfolios and show that they are a discrete first-order approximation to the 2-norm-constrained portfolios. Third, we show how our general framework can be used to calibrate the portfolio strategies. Fourth, we provide comprehensive empirical results comparing the 1- and 2-norm-constrained portfolios, as well as the partial minimum-variance portfolios, to other portfolios from the literature. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the approaches considered in Jagannathan and Ma (2003) and Ledoit and Wolf (2004b), which shrink some or all of the elements of the sample covariance matrix. In Section 3, we propose our general approach, which shrinks the portfolio weights directly, and we show that it nests as special cases the approaches in Jagannathan and Ma (2003), Ledoit and Wolf (2004b), and the 1/N portfolio. We also give Bayesian and moment-shrinking interpretations of the proposed portfolios. In Section 4, we provide a brief 4 We consider the Sharpe ratio as a performance criterion because although none of the portfolios considered uses an estimate of the mean return, as argued above these portfolios tend to outperform those that take also mean returns into account. 5 Because the parametric portfolios in Brandt, Santa-Clara, and Valkanov (2005) rely on firm-specific characteristics they are not really comparable to the other portfolios we evaluate; however, we decided to include them in our empirical analysis because these portfolios achieve very high Sharpe ratios, and hence, are a very important benchmark. 6 See also, Lauprete, Samarov, and Welsch (2002) and Welsch and Zhou (2007). 8

9 discussion of the performance of the different portfolios on empirical data, with a more detailed discussion given in Appendix C. Section 5 concludes. Details of how to compute the partial minimum-variance portfolios are provided in Appendix A. Our main results are highlighted in propositions and proofs for all the propositions are collected in Appendix B. 2 Existing Approaches: Shrinking the Sample Covariance Matrix This section is divided into three parts. First, in Section 2.1, we describe the problem of identifying the minimum-variance portfolio in the absence of shortsale constraints. Then, we review two existing approaches for reducing the impact of the error in estimating the covariance matrix of asset returns. In Section 2.2, we describe the approach analyzed in Jagannathan and Ma (2003), in which shortsale constraints are imposed on the minimum-variance portfolio problem. In Section 2.3, we describe the method developed by Ledoit and Wolf (2004b). Both approaches can be interpreted as methods that shrink some or all of the elements of the sample covariance matrix to reduce the impact of estimation error. In Section 3 that follows, we show that these portfolios can also be interpreted as special cases of the general framework we develop, which shrinks directly the portfolio weights rather than the elements of the covariance matrix. 2.1 Base Case: The Shortsale-Unconstrained Minimum-Variance Portfolio In the absence of shortsale constraints, the minimum-variance portfolio is the solution to the following optimization problem: min w w ˆΣw, (1) s.t. w e = 1, (2) in which w R N is the vector of portfolio weights, ˆΣ R N N is the estimated covariance matrix, w ˆΣw is the variance of the portfolio return, e R N is the vector of ones, and the constraint w e = 1 ensures that the portfolio weights sum up to one. We denote the solution to this shortsaleunconstrained minimum-variance problem by w MINU. 9

10 2.2 The Shortsale-Constrained Minimum-Variance Portfolio Jagannathan and Ma (2003) study the effect of imposing shortsale constraints on the minimumvariance portfolio; that is, they consider the solution to the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance problem, min w w ˆΣw, (3) s.t. w e = 1, (4) w 0. (5) We denote the solution to the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance problem by w MINC. Jagannathan and Ma show that the solution to the shortsale-constrained problem coincides with the solution to the unconstrained problem in (1) (2) if the sample covariance matrix in (1) is replaced by the matrix ˆΣ JM = ˆΣ λe eλ, (6) in which λ R N is the vector of Lagrange multipliers for the shortsale constraint w 0 at the solution to the constrained problem (3) (5). Because λ 0, the matrix ˆΣ JM may be interpreted as the sample covariance matrix after shrinkage, because if the shortsale constraint corresponding to the i th asset is binding (w i = 0), then the sample covariance of this asset with any other asset is reduced by λ i, the magnitude of the Lagrange multiplier associated with its shortsale constraint. Figure 1 depicts the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance portfolio for the case with three risky assets. The three axes in the reference frame give the portfolio weights, w 1, w 2, and w 3, for the three risky assets. Two triangles are depicted in the figure. The larger triangle depicts the intersection of the plane formed by all portfolios whose weights sum up to one with the reference frame. The smaller triangle (colored) represents the set of portfolios whose weights are nonnegative and sum up to one; that is, the set of shortsale-constrained portfolios. The ellipses centered around the minimum-variance portfolio, w MINU, depict the iso-variance curves; that is, the curves formed by portfolios with equal variance. The shortsale-constrained minimum-variance portfolio is at the point where the colored triangle is tangent to the iso-variance curves. The figure also shows the 10

11 location of the 1/N portfolio, which can be interpreted as the portfolio that ignores both the mean returns and the covariances of returns. 2.3 Shrinking the Sample-Covariance Matrix Toward the Identity Matrix To reduce the effect of estimation error, Ledoit and Wolf (2004b) propose replacing the sample covariance matrix with a convex combination of the sample covariance matrix and the identity matrix. Concretely, they propose solving problem (1) (2), in which the matrix ˆΣ is replaced by the following matrix ˆΣ LW = ˆΣ + νi, (7) in which ν R is a positive constant, and I R N N is the identity matrix. Ledoit and Wolf also show how one can estimate the value of ν that minimizes the expected Frobenius norm of the difference between the matrix ˆΣ LW and the true covariance matrix. They show that this method can be interpreted as shrinking the sample covariance matrix toward the identity matrix. 7 Figure 2 depicts the Ledoit-Wolf portfolios for the case with three risky assets. The set of shortsale-constrained portfolios and the iso-variance curves are depicted as in Figure 1. The Ledoit and Wolf portfolios form a curve that joins the 1/N portfolio, which is the Ledoit and Wolf portfolio obtained if ν = in equation (7), with the minimum-variance portfolio equation w MINU, which is the Ledoit and Wolf portfolio obtained if ν = 0 in equation (7). 3 A Generalized Approach: Constraining the Portfolio Norms In this section, we propose a general class of portfolios that results from solving the traditional minimum-variance problem but subject to the additional constraint that the norm of the portfolioweight vector is smaller than a certain threshold δ. These portfolios can be viewed as resulting from shrinking the portfolio weights of the shortsale-unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio instead of shrinking the moments of asset returns. 7 Ledoit and Wolf (2004b) actually propose solving the minimum-variance problem in (1) (2) with the sample covariance matrix ˆΣ LW = 1 ˆΣ + ν I. Note that the portfolio weights that solve this problem are the same as 1+ν 1+ν the ones obtained from using the matrix ˆΣ LW = ˆΣ + νi. We focus on this second matrix because it is easier for our analytical purposes. 11

12 We start by describing the general class of portfolios in Section 3.1. Then, we consider three particular cases, which are motivated by the three methods used in the statistics literature to reduce estimation error in regression analysis: least absolute shrinkage and selection operator (lasso), ridge regression, and partial least squares. First, in Section 3.2, we consider the case where the 1-norm of the portfolio vector is constrained to be less than a certain threshold. Second, in Section 3.3, we consider the case where the 2-norm of the portfolio vector is constrained to be less than a certain threshold. Third, in Section 3.4, we study a portfolio that is a discrete first-order approximation to the 2-norm-constrained minimum-variance portfolio. We call this the partial minimum-variance portfolio. Finally, we provide two different interpretations of the normconstrained portfolios: in Section 3.5 we provide a Bayesian interpretation and in Section 3.6 we give a moment-shrinkage interpretation. 3.1 The General Norm-Constrained Minimum-Variance Portfolio We define the norm-constrained minimum-variance problem as the one that solves the traditional minimum-variance problem subject to the additional constraint that the norm of the portfolioweight vector is smaller than a certain threshold δ: min w w ˆΣw, (8) s.t. w e = 1, (9) w δ, (10) in which w is the norm of the portfolio-weight vector. We consider the 1-norm and the 2-norm, which are defined as: ( N ) 1/p w p = w i p, (11) i=1 for p = 1 and 2, respectively. We denote the solution to the general norm-constrained problem by w NC. 8 8 Observe that we take as the starting point of our analysis the minimum-variance portfolio problem rather than the mean-variance problem, even though we will evaluate performance in terms of the Sharpe ratio, which includes both the mean and variance of portfolio returns. As discussed in the introduction, the reason for starting with the minimum-variance portfolio is that it is difficult to estimate mean returns with much precision, and Jagannathan and Ma (2003) and DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2007) find empirically that the out-of-sample performance is better if 12

13 Note that the traditional shortsale-unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio, w MINU, is the solution to the norm-constrained problem with δ =. Consequently, if δ < w MINU, then the norm of the portfolio that solves problem (8) (10) must be strictly smaller than that of the unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio, w MINU. To highlight this result we state it in the following proposition. Proposition 1 For each δ < w MINU, the solution to the norm-constrained problem, w NC, satisfies the following inequality: w NC < w MINU. (12) Proposition 1 states that the norm-constrained minimum variance portfolio, w NC, is a shrinkage estimator of the shortsale-unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio, w MINU. Shrinkage estimators have been a popular method for reducing estimation error ever since their introduction by James and Stein (1961). The idea behind shrinkage estimators is that shrinking an unbiased estimator toward a deterministic target has a negative and a positive effect. 9 The negative effect is that the shrinkage introduces bias into the resulting estimator. The positive effect is that shrinking the estimator toward a deterministic target reduces the variance of the estimator. The challenge is to choose the amount of shrinkage that optimizes the tradeoff between bias and variance. We explain in Section C.1 how this can be done for the norm-constrained policies. 3.2 First Particular Case: The 1-Norm-Constrained Portfolios In this section, we consider the class of norm-constrained portfolios obtained by constraining the 1-norm of the portfolio-weight vector. The 1-norm is defined as the sum of the absolute values of one ignores estimates of mean returns and considers only the covariances between returns. If one wanted to consider the mean-variance portfolio problem with norm constraints, one would only need to replace the objective function in the problem defined in Equations (8) (10). Specifically, one needs to replace (8) with: maxw w T ˆµ t γ 2 wt ˆΣw, where γ is the investor s risk aversion parameter and µ is the R N vector of expected returns. With this change, our analysis would then apply to the mean-variance portfolio problem. We have implemented the resulting norm-constrained mean-variance portfolios and our empirical results (not reported) show that these portfolios do indeed achieve lower out-of-sample Sharpe ratios than the norm-constrained minimum-variance portfolios. 9 An estimator is unbiased if its expected value coincides with the parameter being estimated. 13

14 the portfolio weights w 1 = N i=1 w i. The resulting 1-norm-constrained portfolio problem is: min w w ˆΣw, (13) s.t. w e = 1, (14) N w i δ, (15) i=1 and we denote its solution by w NC1. The following proposition shows that for the case δ = 1, the solution to the 1-norm-constrained minimum-variance problem is the same as that for the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance portfolio analyzed by Jagannathan and Ma (2003). Proposition 2 The solution to the 1-norm-constrained problem (13) (15) with δ = 1 coincides with the solution to the shortsale-constrained problem (3) (5). A couple of comments are in order. First, note that Proposition 2 states that the shortsaleconstrained minimum-variance portfolio, which is studied in Jagannathan and Ma (2003), is a special case of the 1-norm-constrained minimum-variance portfolio for the threshold value of δ = 1. Then, by Proposition 1, we have that the shortsale-constrained portfolio can be interpreted as a portfolio resulting from shrinking the portfolio weights of the unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio. This interpretation is different from that given by Jagannathan and Ma (2003), who show that the shortsale-constrained portfolio can be interpreted as resulting from shrinking some of the coefficients of the sample covariance matrix. The interpretation we provide is useful because for an investor it is typically easier to think in terms of portfolio weights than the elements of the sample covariance matrix. Second, for threshold values of δ in (15) that are strictly larger than 1, our approach generates a class of portfolios that generalize the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance portfolio. To see this, note that the 1-norm can be rewritten as w 1 = N w i = w i w i, (16) i=1 i P(w) i N (w) 14

15 in which w i is the portfolio weight on the i th asset, P(w) is the set of asset indexes for which the corresponding portfolio weight is greater or equal than zero, P(w) = {i : w i 0}, and N (w) is the set of asset indexes for which the corresponding portfolio weight is negative, N (w) = {i : w i < 0}. Moreover, if the portfolio weights sum up to one (w e = 1), we have that w i = 1 w i. (17) i P(w) i N (w) From (16) and (17) we obtain w 1 = 1 2 w i. (18) i N (w) Equation (18) gives insight into the structure of this new class of portfolios. In particular, observe from (18) that imposing the constraint w 1 < δ for some δ > 1 is equivalent to assigning a shortsale budget; that is, a budget for the total amount of shortselling allowed in the portfolio. Indeed, using (18) we can rewrite the constraint in (15) on the 1-norm of the portfolio-weight vector as follows: i N (w) w i < δ 1 2, (19) in which the term i N (w) w i is the total proportion of wealth that is sold short and (δ 1)/2 is the shortsale budget. This shortsale budget can then be freely distributed among all of the assets. For instance, one could decide to short sell only one asset, and assign to this particular asset the weight of (δ 1)/2, or one could distribute the shortsale budget equally among a few of the assets. The w NC1 portfolio is different also from the generalized shortsale-constrained portfolio considered in DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2007), which is the minimum-variance portfolio subject to the constraint w ξe for some ξ > 0, which requires that the amount of shortselling allowed for each assets is exactly the same. In contrast, the 1-norm constraint allows the investor more flexibility about how to distribute the allowed shortsale budget across all of the assets. Figure 3 depicts the 1-norm-constrained portfolios for the case with three risky assets. The three axes in the reference frame give the portfolio weights for the three risky assets. Two triangles are depicted in the figure. The larger triangle depicts the intersection of the plane formed by all portfolios whose weights sum up to one with the reference frame. The smaller triangle (colored) 15

16 represents the set of portfolios whose weights are nonnegative and sum up to one; that is, the set of shortsale-constrained portfolios. The ellipses centered around the minimum-variance portfolio, w MINU, depict the iso-variance curves; that is, the curves formed by portfolios with equal variance. The hexagons represent the iso-1-norm curves; that is, the sets of portfolios with equal 1-norm, which are obtained from the intersection of the 2-dimensional plane formed by all portfolios whose weights sum to one with the cube describing the region of weights satisfying the 1-norm constraint. For each value of the threshold δ = {δ 1, δ 2,..., δ 5 }, the 1-norm-constrained minimum-variance portfolio is the point where the corresponding iso-1-norm hexagon is tangent to the iso-variance curve. The 1-norm-constrained portfolios corresponding to values of the threshold parameter δ ranging from 1 to w MINU 1 describe a curve that joins the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance portfolio, w MINC, with the shortsale-unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio, w MINU. 3.3 Second Particular Case: The 2-Norm-Constrained Portfolios We now consider the class of portfolios obtained by constraining the 2-norm of the vector of portfolio weights. The 2-norm is the traditional Euclidean norm in R N, obtained from (11) by setting p = 2, or, in matrix form, w 2 = (w w) 1/2. Note, however, that the solution to the minimum-variance problem with a constraint on the 2-norm w 2 < δ is the same as the solution to the problem with a constraint on the squared 2-norm w 2 2 < δ2. Because the squared 2-norm is easier to analyze than the 2-norm, we define the 2-norm-constrained minimum-variance portfolio problem as follows: min w w ˆΣw, (20) s.t. w e = 1, (21) N w 2 i δ, (22) i=1 and we denote the solution to this problem by w NC2. 16

17 To gain intuition about the 2-norm constrained minimum-variance portfolios, note that the constraint in (22) can be reformulated equivalently as follows: 10 N i=1 ( w i 1 ) 2 ( δ 1 ). (23) N N The reformulated constraint (23) demonstrates that imposing the 2-norm constraint on the portfolio weights in (22) is equivalent to imposing a constraint that the 2-norm of the difference between this portfolio and the 1/N portfolio is bounded by δ 1/N. Note also from (20), (21) and (23) that the 1/N portfolio is a special case of the 2-norm-constrained portfolio if we set δ = 1/N. The following proposition shows that the 2-norm constrained portfolio belongs to the class of unconstrained portfolios that would be obtained by using shrinkage techniques on the covariance matrix as in Ledoit and Wolf (2004b). Proposition 3 Provided ˆΣ is nonsingular, for each δ 1/N there exists a ν 0 such that the solution to problem (20) (22) is the solution to the minimum-variance problem in (1) (2) with the sample covariance matrix, ˆΣ, replaced by ˆΣ LW = ˆΣ + νi. Proposition 3 shows that the Ledoit and Wolf (2004b) portfolio can be interpreted as one that shrinks the portfolio weights. Again, this is a different interpretation than the one given in Ledoit and Wolf (2004b), in which the portfolio is viewed as one obtained from shrinking the sample covariance matrix toward the identity matrix. Ledoit and Wolf (2004a) consider other targets toward which to shrink the sample covariance matrix; for instance, the single-factor matrix and the constant correlation matrix. The 2-norm-constrained portfolios described above can be extended to generalize also these other approaches discussed in Ledoit and Wolf. To do this, one simply needs to replace the constraint w w δ 2 by the constraint w F w δ 2, where F is the target matrix. For expositional simplicity, we focus on the case where the target matrix is the identity. Figure 4 depicts the 2-norm-constrained portfolios for the case with three risky assets. The isovariance curves are depicted as in Figure 3. The circumferences centered on the equally-weighted 10 To understand why these two formulations are equivalent, observe that P N i=1 (wi 1/N)2 = P N i=1 w2 i + P N i=1 1/N 2 P N i=1 2wi/N = P N i=1 w2 i 1/N, where the last result follows from the fact that P N i=1 1/N 2 = 1/N and 2wi/N = 2/N. P N i=1 17

18 portfolio, 1/N, are the iso-2-norm curves; that is, the set of portfolios with the same 2-norm. We depict four iso-2-norm curves corresponding to four different threshold levels: δ 1, δ 2, δ 3, and δ 4. For a given threshold δ, the 2-norm-constrained portfolio is the point where the corresponding iso- 2-norm curve is tangent to an iso-variance curve. 11 For values of δ ranging from 1/N to w MINU 2 2, the 2-norm-constrained portfolios describe a smooth curve that joins the 1/N portfolio (for δ = 1/N) with the minimum-variance portfolio (for δ w MINU 2 2 ); this will be formally proven in Proposition 7. We now compare the 1-norm and the 2-norm portfolios in Figures 3 and 4, respectively. From Figure 3, observe that because the 1-norm level sets are shaped as hexagons, the 1-norm-constrained minimum-variance portfolios tend to be located at the vertices of these hexagons in Figure 3 it can be observed that this is the case for δ 1, δ 2, and δ 3. This implies that the 1-norm-constrained portfolios are likely to assign a zero weight to at least some of the assets. This phenomenon is well known for the case of the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance portfolio, which tends to assign a zero weight to a large subset of the total number of assets available for investment; for a discussion of this see, for instance, Jagannathan and Ma (2003). But Figure 3 shows that, although this phenomenon also takes place for the rest of the 1-norm-constrained portfolios with δ > 1, these portfolios will tend in general to invest in a higher number of assets than the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance portfolio. To see this, note that the vertices of the triangle (level set for δ = 1) correspond to portfolios that assign a zero weight to two out of the three assets, whereas the vertices of each hexagon (level sets for δ > 1) correspond to points where the weight on only one of the three assets is zero. Hence, we may expect the 1-norm-constrained portfolios with δ > 1 to invest in a larger number of assets than the shortsale-constrained minimum-variance portfolio. In contrast, the 2-norm-constrained portfolios will typically assign a non-zero (positive or negative) weight to all assets. Thus, in situations where the investor prefers a diversified portfolio that has some weight in all assets, the investor should use the 2-norm-constrained portfolios, while if the investor is interested in portfolios with investment in a smaller number of assets, then she should focus on the 1-norm-constrained portfolios. 11 To see why the solution must be at a tangency point of the two level sets, note that at a point where the two level sets cross each other, we can always find a point with smaller sample variance by moving along the level set for the portfolio norm. 18

19 This is consistent with the interpretation of the 1- and 2-norm portfolios given in the previous sections. Specifically, in Section 3.3 we showed that the 2-norm-constrained portfolio is the portfolio that minimizes the sample variance subject to the constraint that the square of the 2-norm of the difference with the 1/N portfolio is bounded by δ 1/N. Consequently, we would expect that the 2-norm constrained portfolios will, in general, remain relatively close to the 1/N portfolio, and thus, will assign a positive weight to all assets. Also, in Section 3.2 we showed that the 1-norm constrained portfolios are a generalization of the shortsale-constrained portfolios in which the total amount of shortselling on all assets must remain below a shortsale budget of (δ 1)/2. Therefore, we may expect the 1-norm constrained portfolios to have the well-known property of shortsaleconstrained minimum-variance portfolios, which tend to assign a weight different from zero to only a few of the assets. Summarizing, investors who believe that the optimal portfolio is close to the well-diversified 1/N portfolio, would want to use a 2-norm constraint when solving the minimumvariance problem to reduce estimation error. Investors who, on the other hand, believe the total amount of shortselling of the optimal portfolio should not exceed a given budget, would want to use a 1-norm constraint. 3.4 Third Particular Case: The Partial Minimum-Variance Portfolios In this section, we propose a class of portfolios that are obtained by applying the classical conjugategradient method (Nocedal and Wright (1999, Chapter 5)) to solve the minimum-variance problem. The conjugate gradient is an iterative method that, starting from an initial guess reaches the optimal solution, which is the shortsale-unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio, in N 1 successive steps, where N is the number of assets (in Appendix A we provide a detailed description of this algorithm). This method generates a sequence of portfolios, where the first portfolio is some initial guess (taken to be the 1/N portfolio in our implementation) and the terminal portfolio is the shortsale-unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio. We term each of the intermediate portfolios a partial minimum-variance portfolio. Even though the partial minimum-variance portfolios are not obtained by imposing explicitly a constraint on the norm of the minimum-variance portfolio, we show that the norm of the par- 19

20 tial minimum-variance portfolios is indeed smaller than the norm of the shortsale-unconstrained minimum-variance portfolios. Moreover, we also show that the partial minimum-variance portfolios can be viewed as a discrete first-order approximation to the 2-norm-constrained portfolios. For this reason, we consider the partial minimum-variance portfolios as a particular case of the norm-constrained portfolios. The partial minimum-variance portfolios are the counterpart in portfolio selection to the statistical technique of partial least squares for regression analysis, which has been shown to perform very well under certain conditions (see Wold (1975); Frank and Friedman (1993), and Friedman and Popescu (2004)). Our empirical analysis in Section 4 shows that the partial minimum-variance portfolios perform very well also on financial data and that they often outperform not just the portfolios in the existing literature but also the 1- and 2-norm-constrained portfolios described above. The partial minimum-variance portfolios form a set of N 1 portfolios that join the 1/N portfolio and the shortsale-unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio. Specifically, the first of these N 1 portfolios, which we term the first partial minimum-variance portfolio, is a weighted average of the 1/N portfolio and the so-called first conjugate portfolio. The term partial refers to the fact that the first partial minimum-variance portfolio minimizes the sample variance within the subset of portfolios formed by combinations of the 1/N portfolio and the first conjugate portfolio. This first conjugate portfolio is the zero-cost portfolio (i.e., a portfolio whose weights sum up to zero) that induces the maximum marginal decrease in the sample variance when combined with the 1/N portfolio. The second partial minimum-variance portfolio is then that combination of the first partial minimum-variance portfolio and the second conjugate portfolio that minimizes the sample variance, where the second conjugate portfolio is the zero-cost portfolio that, when combined with the first partial minimum-variance portfolio, induces the maximum marginal decrease in the sample portfolio variance, subject to the condition that it is conjugate with respect to the first conjugate portfolio; that is, subject to the condition that the first two conjugate portfolios are uncorrelated with respect to the sample covariance matrix. 20

21 By iterating this process N 1 times we generate a discrete set of N 1 portfolios (including the shortsale-unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio) that join the 1/N and the shortsaleunconstrained minimum-variance portfolios. Details of how to compute the partial minimumvariance portfolios are provided in Appendix A Analytical Expression for the First Partial Minimum-Variance Portfolio In this section, we provide an analytical expression for the first partial minimum-variance portfolio and use this to give some intuition for its properties. To do so, we first note that the gradient of the sample portfolio variance, w ˆΣw, with respect to the portfolio weight, w, is ) w (w ˆΣw = 2ˆΣw. (24) Moreover, this gradient evaluated at the starting 1/N portfolio is ( ) e/n w w ˆΣw = 2ˆΣ e N. (25) Hence, ˆΣe/N is the portfolio that when combined with the 1/N portfolio yields the largest marginal decrease in the portfolio sample variance. 12 But note that this portfolio is not a zero-cost portfolio; that is, its weights do not add up to zero in general. The properties of the gradient then imply that the first conjugate portfolio is simply the zero-cost portfolio that is closest (in 2-norm) to the portfolio ˆΣe/N. The properties of Euclidean spaces and some algebra then imply that the first conjugate portfolio, w CG1, is w CG1 = ) (I ee ˆΣ e N N, (26) because the matrix (I ee N ) is the projection matrix that projects any portfolio into the set of portfolios with zero-cost. The first partial minimum-variance portfolio is the combination of the 1/N portfolio and the first conjugate portfolio that minimizes the sample portfolio return variance; that is, the first partial 12 Note that any scalar multiple of the vector 2ˆΣe/N yields the largest marginal decrease in sample variance when combined with 1/N. For notational convenience, we use ˆΣe/N instead of 2ˆΣe/N. 21

22 minimum-variance portfolio is w P AR1 = e/n + α 0 w CG1, (27) in which α 0 is chosen to minimize the sample variance of the first partial minimum-variance portfolio. We now explain the intuition underlying this portfolio. First, in Proposition 4, we show that the i th component of the vector ˆΣ e N is the sample covariance of the return on the 1/N portfolio with the return on the i th risky asset. Proposition 4 The i th component of the vector ˆΣ e N is the sample covariance between the 1/N portfolio and the return on the i th risky asset. Then, in Proposition 5, we show that the i th component of the first conjugate portfolio is the negative of the deviation of this covariance from the average of the covariances between the 1/N portfolio and each of the individual assets. Proposition 5 Let σ ei be the covariance between the 1/N portfolio return and the i th risky asset return. Then, the i th component of the first conjugate portfolio, (w CG1 ) i, is (w CG1 ) i = ( σ ei 1 N N ) σ ej. (28) j=1 This result makes sense: the first conjugate portfolio is a zero-cost portfolio that assigns a positive weight to those assets whose covariance with the return of the 1/N portfolio is below average. As a result, given that α 0 > 0, the first partial minimum-variance portfolio assigns a weight larger than 1/N to those assets whose covariances with the 1/N portfolio are below average. This improves the diversification of the portfolio, and thus, decreases the portfolio variance. Also, note that the minimum-variance portfolio is the portfolio whose covariance with all other assets is equal to a constant (see Huang and Litzenberger (1988, Chapter 3, Proposition 12)). Thus, according to the interpretation above, the first partial minimum-variance portfolio should be closer to the shortsale-unconstrained minimum-variance portfolio than the 1/N portfolio. 22

Practical Portfolio Optimization

Practical Portfolio Optimization Practical Portfolio Optimization Victor DeMiguel Professor of Management Science and Operations London Business School Based on joint research with Lorenzo Garlappi Alberto Martin-Utrera Xiaoling Mei U

More information

Portfolio Selection with Robust Estimation

Portfolio Selection with Robust Estimation Submitted to Operations Research manuscript OPRE-2007-02-106 Portfolio Selection with Robust Estimation Victor DeMiguel Department of Management Science and Operations, London Business School 6 Sussex

More information

Data-Driven Portfolio Optimisation

Data-Driven Portfolio Optimisation Data-Driven Portfolio Optimisation Victor DeMiguel London Business School Based on joint research with Lorenzo Garlappi Alberto Martin-Utrera Xiaoling Mei U of British Columbia U Carlos III de Madrid U

More information

On Portfolio Optimization: Imposing the Right Constraints

On Portfolio Optimization: Imposing the Right Constraints On Portfolio Optimization: Imposing the Right Constraints Patrick Behr Andre Güttler Felix Miebs June 1, 2010 Abstract We develop a shrinkage theory based framework for determining optimal portfolio weight

More information

How inefficient are simple asset-allocation strategies?

How inefficient are simple asset-allocation strategies? How inefficient are simple asset-allocation strategies? Victor DeMiguel London Business School Lorenzo Garlappi U. of Texas at Austin Raman Uppal London Business School; CEPR March 2005 Motivation Ancient

More information

Portfolio Selection with Parameter and Model Uncertainty: A Multi-Prior Approach

Portfolio Selection with Parameter and Model Uncertainty: A Multi-Prior Approach Portfolio Selection with Parameter and Model Uncertainty: A Multi-Prior Approach Lorenzo Garlappi Raman Uppal Tan Wang April 2004 We gratefully acknowledge financial support from INQUIRE UK; this article

More information

The out-of-sample performance of robust portfolio optimization

The out-of-sample performance of robust portfolio optimization The out-of-sample performance of robust portfolio optimization André Alves Portela Santos May 28 Abstract Robust optimization has been receiving increased attention in the recent few years due to the possibility

More information

Optimal Portfolio Selection Under the Estimation Risk in Mean Return

Optimal Portfolio Selection Under the Estimation Risk in Mean Return Optimal Portfolio Selection Under the Estimation Risk in Mean Return by Lei Zhu A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in fulfillment of the thesis requirement for the degree of Master of Mathematics

More information

Does Naive Not Mean Optimal? The Case for the 1/N Strategy in Brazilian Equities

Does Naive Not Mean Optimal? The Case for the 1/N Strategy in Brazilian Equities Does Naive Not Mean Optimal? GV INVEST 05 The Case for the 1/N Strategy in Brazilian Equities December, 2016 Vinicius Esposito i The development of optimal approaches to portfolio construction has rendered

More information

It s All in the Timing: Simple Active Portfolio Strategies that Outperform Naïve Diversification

It s All in the Timing: Simple Active Portfolio Strategies that Outperform Naïve Diversification It s All in the Timing: Simple Active Portfolio Strategies that Outperform Naïve Diversification Chris Kirby a, Barbara Ostdiek b a John E. Walker Department of Economics, Clemson University b Jesse H.

More information

Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty

Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty George Photiou Lincoln College University of Oxford A dissertation submitted in partial fulfilment for

More information

Quantitative Risk Management

Quantitative Risk Management Quantitative Risk Management Asset Allocation and Risk Management Martin B. Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Outline Review of Mean-Variance Analysis

More information

Robust Portfolio Rebalancing with Transaction Cost Penalty An Empirical Analysis

Robust Portfolio Rebalancing with Transaction Cost Penalty An Empirical Analysis August 2009 Robust Portfolio Rebalancing with Transaction Cost Penalty An Empirical Analysis Abstract The goal of this paper is to compare different techniques of reducing the sensitivity of optimal portfolios

More information

Turnover Minimization: A Versatile Shrinkage Portfolio Estimator

Turnover Minimization: A Versatile Shrinkage Portfolio Estimator Turnover Minimization: A Versatile Shrinkage Portfolio Estimator Chulwoo Han Abstract We develop a shrinkage model for portfolio choice. It places a layer on a conventional portfolio problem where the

More information

Portfolio Selection with Mental Accounts and Estimation Risk

Portfolio Selection with Mental Accounts and Estimation Risk Portfolio Selection with Mental Accounts and Estimation Risk Gordon J. Alexander Alexandre M. Baptista Shu Yan University of Minnesota The George Washington University Oklahoma State University April 23,

More information

Asset Allocation and Risk Assessment with Gross Exposure Constraints

Asset Allocation and Risk Assessment with Gross Exposure Constraints Asset Allocation and Risk Assessment with Gross Exposure Constraints Forrest Zhang Bendheim Center for Finance Princeton University A joint work with Jianqing Fan and Ke Yu, Princeton Princeton University

More information

Parameter Uncertainty in Multiperiod Portfolio. Optimization with Transaction Costs

Parameter Uncertainty in Multiperiod Portfolio. Optimization with Transaction Costs Parameter Uncertainty in Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Transaction Costs Victor DeMiguel Alberto Martín-Utrera Francisco J. Nogales This version: November 4, 2015 DeMiguel is from London Business

More information

Optimal Versus Naive Diversification in Factor Models

Optimal Versus Naive Diversification in Factor Models Chapter 4 Optimal Versus Naive Diversification in Factor Models 4.1 Introduction Markowitz (1952) provides a solid framework for mean-variance based optimal portfolio selection. If, however, the true parameters

More information

Should you optimize your portfolio? On portfolio optimization: The optimized strategy versus the naïve and market strategy on the Swedish stock market

Should you optimize your portfolio? On portfolio optimization: The optimized strategy versus the naïve and market strategy on the Swedish stock market Uppsala University Fall 2013 Department of Business Studies On portfolio optimization: The optimized strategy versus the naïve and market strategy on the Swedish stock market Alan Ramilton* Abstract In

More information

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods Prepared by Kevin Pei for The Fund @ Sprott Abstract: In this document, I will model and back test our portfolio with various proposed models. It goes without

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

Estimation Risk Modeling in Optimal Portfolio Selection:

Estimation Risk Modeling in Optimal Portfolio Selection: Estimation Risk Modeling in Optimal Portfolio Selection: An Study from Emerging Markets By Sarayut Nathaphan Pornchai Chunhachinda 1 Agenda 2 Traditional efficient portfolio and its extension incorporating

More information

Is minimum-variance investing really worth the while? An analysis with robust performance inference

Is minimum-variance investing really worth the while? An analysis with robust performance inference Is minimum-variance investing really worth the while? An analysis with robust performance inference Patrick Behr André Güttler Felix Miebs. October 31, 2008 Department of Finance, Goethe-University Frankfurt,

More information

Optimal Portfolio Allocation with Option-Implied Moments: A Forward-Looking Approach

Optimal Portfolio Allocation with Option-Implied Moments: A Forward-Looking Approach Optimal Portfolio Allocation with Option-Implied Moments: A Forward-Looking Approach Tzu-Ying Chen National Taiwan University, Taipei, Taiwan Tel: (+886) 2-3366-1100 Email: d99723002@ntu.edu.tw San-Lin

More information

Asset Selection Model Based on the VaR Adjusted High-Frequency Sharp Index

Asset Selection Model Based on the VaR Adjusted High-Frequency Sharp Index Management Science and Engineering Vol. 11, No. 1, 2017, pp. 67-75 DOI:10.3968/9412 ISSN 1913-0341 [Print] ISSN 1913-035X [Online] www.cscanada.net www.cscanada.org Asset Selection Model Based on the VaR

More information

Aggregating Information for Optimal. Portfolio Weights

Aggregating Information for Optimal. Portfolio Weights Aggregating Information for Optimal Portfolio Weights Xiao Li December 1, 2018 Abstract I attempt to address an important issue of the portfolio allocation literature none of the allocation rules from

More information

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance analysis Prof. Massimo Guidolin Portfolio Management Second Term 2018 Outline and objectives Mean-variance and efficient frontiers: logical meaning o Guidolin-Pedio,

More information

Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Multiple Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs

Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Multiple Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Multiple Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs Xiaoling Mei School of Economics & Wang Yanan Institute for Study in Economics (WISE), Xiamen University Victor

More information

February 21, Purdue University Dept. of Electrical and Computer Engineering. Markowitz Portfolio Optimization. Benjamin Parsons.

February 21, Purdue University Dept. of Electrical and Computer Engineering. Markowitz Portfolio Optimization. Benjamin Parsons. Purdue University Dept. of Electrical and Computer Engineering February 21, 2012 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 Evaluate variations of portfolio optimization Bayes-Stein error estimation Bayes-Stein error estimation

More information

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM Yan Zeng Version 1.0.2, last revised on 2012-05-30. Abstract A summary of mean variance analysis in portfolio management and capital asset pricing model. 1. Mean-Variance

More information

Combination Approaches to Estimating Optimal Portfolios

Combination Approaches to Estimating Optimal Portfolios Combination Approaches to Estimating Optimal Portfolios Bradley S. Paye Jones Graduate School of Business, Rice University July 15, 2010 JEL Classification: G1, C13 Keywords: Combined estimators, shrinkage,

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

The Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios

The Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios The Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios Apostolos Kourtis First version: June 6 2014 This version: January 23 2016 Abstract Investors often adopt mean-variance efficient portfolios for achieving

More information

Penalized Least Squares for Optimal Sparse Portfolio Selection

Penalized Least Squares for Optimal Sparse Portfolio Selection Penalized Least Squares for Optimal Sparse Portfolio Selection Bjoern Fastrich, University of Giessen, Bjoern.Fastrich@wirtschaft.uni-giessen.de Sandra Paterlini, EBS Universität für Wirtschaft und Recht,

More information

MULTIPERIOD PORTFOLIO SELECTION WITH TRANSACTION AND MARKET-IMPACT COSTS

MULTIPERIOD PORTFOLIO SELECTION WITH TRANSACTION AND MARKET-IMPACT COSTS Working Paper 13-16 Statistics and Econometrics Series (15) May 2013 Departamento de Estadística Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Calle Madrid, 126 28903 Getafe (Spain) Fax (34) 91 624-98-48 MULTIPERIOD

More information

Parameter Estimation Techniques, Optimization Frequency, and Equity Portfolio Return Enhancement*

Parameter Estimation Techniques, Optimization Frequency, and Equity Portfolio Return Enhancement* Parameter Estimation Techniques, Optimization Frequency, and Equity Portfolio Return Enhancement* By Glen A. Larsen, Jr. Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Indianapolis, IN 46202, USA, Glarsen@iupui.edu

More information

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice Prof. Massimo Guidolin Portfolio Management Spring 2016 Overview The inputs of portfolio problems Using the single index model Multi-index models Portfolio

More information

Robust Portfolio Construction

Robust Portfolio Construction Robust Portfolio Construction Presentation to Workshop on Mixed Integer Programming University of Miami June 5-8, 2006 Sebastian Ceria Chief Executive Officer Axioma, Inc sceria@axiomainc.com Copyright

More information

Mechanics of minimum variance investment approach

Mechanics of minimum variance investment approach OSSIAM RESEARCH TEAM June, 09, 2011 WHITE PAPER 1 Mechanics of minimum variance investment approach Bruno Monnier and Ksenya Rulik June, 09, 2011 Abstract Bruno Monnier Quantitative analyst bruno.monnier@ossiam.com

More information

Correlation Ambiguity

Correlation Ambiguity Correlation Ambiguity Jun Liu University of California at San Diego Xudong Zeng Shanghai University of Finance and Economics This Version 2016.09.15 ABSTRACT Most papers on ambiguity aversion in the setting

More information

Black-Litterman Model

Black-Litterman Model Institute of Financial and Actuarial Mathematics at Vienna University of Technology Seminar paper Black-Litterman Model by: Tetyana Polovenko Supervisor: Associate Prof. Dipl.-Ing. Dr.techn. Stefan Gerhold

More information

On Mean Variance Portfolio Optimization: Improving Performance Through Better Use of Hedging Relations

On Mean Variance Portfolio Optimization: Improving Performance Through Better Use of Hedging Relations On Mean Variance Portfolio Optimization: Improving Performance Through Better Use of Hedging Relations Abstract In portfolio optimization, the inverse covariance matrix prescribes the hedge trades where

More information

Is the 1/n asset allocation strategy undervalued?

Is the 1/n asset allocation strategy undervalued? Bachelor Thesis Finance Is the 1/n asset allocation strategy undervalued? Author: W.J.A. Jacobs Student number: 855050 Supervisor: M. Nie University: Tilburg University Department: Finance Year: 2011 Abstract

More information

Multivariate Shrinkage for Optimal Portfolio Weights

Multivariate Shrinkage for Optimal Portfolio Weights Multivariate Shrinkage for Optimal Portfolio Weights Vasyl Golosnoy a and Yarema Okhrin b,1 a Institute of Statistics and Econometrics, University of Kiel, 24118 Kiel, Germany b Department of Statistics,

More information

Dynamic Smart Beta Investing Relative Risk Control and Tactical Bets, Making the Most of Smart Betas

Dynamic Smart Beta Investing Relative Risk Control and Tactical Bets, Making the Most of Smart Betas Dynamic Smart Beta Investing Relative Risk Control and Tactical Bets, Making the Most of Smart Betas Koris International June 2014 Emilien Audeguil Research & Development ORIAS n 13000579 (www.orias.fr).

More information

PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION: ANALYTICAL TECHNIQUES

PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION: ANALYTICAL TECHNIQUES PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION: ANALYTICAL TECHNIQUES Keith Brown, Ph.D., CFA November 22 nd, 2007 Overview of the Portfolio Optimization Process The preceding analysis demonstrates that it is possible for investors

More information

Testing Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance

Testing Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance Testing Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance Ekaterina Kazak 1 Winfried Pohlmeier 2 1 University of Konstanz, GSDS 2 University of Konstanz, CoFE, RCEA Econometric Research in Finance Workshop 2017 SGH

More information

Mean Variance Portfolio Theory

Mean Variance Portfolio Theory Chapter 1 Mean Variance Portfolio Theory This book is about portfolio construction and risk analysis in the real-world context where optimization is done with constraints and penalties specified by the

More information

Minimum Downside Volatility Indices

Minimum Downside Volatility Indices Minimum Downside Volatility Indices Timo Pfei er, Head of Research Lars Walter, Quantitative Research Analyst Daniel Wendelberger, Quantitative Research Analyst 18th July 2017 1 1 Introduction "Analyses

More information

Bloomberg. Portfolio Value-at-Risk. Sridhar Gollamudi & Bryan Weber. September 22, Version 1.0

Bloomberg. Portfolio Value-at-Risk. Sridhar Gollamudi & Bryan Weber. September 22, Version 1.0 Portfolio Value-at-Risk Sridhar Gollamudi & Bryan Weber September 22, 2011 Version 1.0 Table of Contents 1 Portfolio Value-at-Risk 2 2 Fundamental Factor Models 3 3 Valuation methodology 5 3.1 Linear factor

More information

Combining Portfolio Models *

Combining Portfolio Models * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 5-2, 433 455 (204) Combining Portfolio Models * Peter Schanbacher Department of Economics, University of Konstanz, Universitätsstraße 0, D-78464 Konstanz, Germany E-mail:

More information

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

Log-Robust Portfolio Management Log-Robust Portfolio Management Dr. Aurélie Thiele Lehigh University Joint work with Elcin Cetinkaya and Ban Kawas Research partially supported by the National Science Foundation Grant CMMI-0757983 Dr.

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: An Investment Process for Stock Selection Fall 2011/2012 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements December, 20 th, 17h-20h:

More information

SciBeta CoreShares South-Africa Multi-Beta Multi-Strategy Six-Factor EW

SciBeta CoreShares South-Africa Multi-Beta Multi-Strategy Six-Factor EW SciBeta CoreShares South-Africa Multi-Beta Multi-Strategy Six-Factor EW Table of Contents Introduction Methodological Terms Geographic Universe Definition: Emerging EMEA Construction: Multi-Beta Multi-Strategy

More information

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Table of Contents Lecture 1... 7 1. State the objective of modern portfolio theory... 7 2. Define the return of an asset... 7 3. How is expected return defined?...

More information

In terms of covariance the Markowitz portfolio optimisation problem is:

In terms of covariance the Markowitz portfolio optimisation problem is: Markowitz portfolio optimisation Solver To use Solver to solve the quadratic program associated with tracing out the efficient frontier (unconstrained efficient frontier UEF) in Markowitz portfolio optimisation

More information

Deciphering robust portfolios

Deciphering robust portfolios *Title Page (with authors and affiliations) Deciphering robust portfolios Woo Chang Kim a,*, Jang Ho Kim b, and Frank J. Fabozzi c Abstract Robust portfolio optimization has been developed to resolve the

More information

Robust Portfolio Optimization Using a Simple Factor Model

Robust Portfolio Optimization Using a Simple Factor Model Robust Portfolio Optimization Using a Simple Factor Model Chris Bemis, Xueying Hu, Weihua Lin, Somayes Moazeni, Li Wang, Ting Wang, Jingyan Zhang Abstract In this paper we examine the performance of a

More information

Passive and Active Currency Portfolio. Optimisation

Passive and Active Currency Portfolio. Optimisation Passive and Active Currency Portfolio Optimisation by Fei Zuo Submitted by Fei Zuo, to the University of Exeter as a thesis for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Finance, February 2016. This thesis

More information

Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Many Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs

Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Many Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Many Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs Victor DeMiguel Xiaoling Mei Francisco J. Nogales January 14, 2014 DeMiguel is from London Business School and can

More information

Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Many Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs

Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Many Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Many Risky Assets and General Transaction Costs Victor DeMiguel Xiaoling Mei Francisco J. Nogales May 6, 2014 DeMiguel is from London Business School and can be

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Introducing Expected Returns into Risk Parity Portfolios: A New Framework for Asset Allocation

Introducing Expected Returns into Risk Parity Portfolios: A New Framework for Asset Allocation Introducing Expected Returns into Risk Parity Portfolios: A New Framework for Asset Allocation Thierry Roncalli Research & Development Lyxor Asset Management, Paris thierry.roncalli@lyxor.com First Version:

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: From factor models to asset pricing Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Solution to exercise 1 of problem

More information

Are Smart Beta indexes valid for hedge fund portfolio allocation?

Are Smart Beta indexes valid for hedge fund portfolio allocation? Are Smart Beta indexes valid for hedge fund portfolio allocation? Asmerilda Hitaj Giovanni Zambruno University of Milano Bicocca Second Young researchers meeting on BSDEs, Numerics and Finance July 2014

More information

Reducing Estimation Risk in Mean-Variance Portfolios with Machine Learning

Reducing Estimation Risk in Mean-Variance Portfolios with Machine Learning Reducing Estimation Risk in Mean-Variance Portfolios with Machine Learning Daniel Kinn arxiv:184.1764v1 [q-fin.pm] 5 Apr 218 April 218 Abstract In portfolio analysis, the traditional approach of replacing

More information

Parameter Uncertainty in Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Transaction Costs

Parameter Uncertainty in Multiperiod Portfolio Optimization with Transaction Costs JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL AND QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS Vol. 50, No. 6, Dec. 2015, pp. 1443 1471 COPYRIGHT 2016, MICHAEL G. FOSTER SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, UNIVERSITY OF WASHINGTON, SEATTLE, WA 98195 doi:10.1017/s002210901500054x

More information

Dynamic Portfolio Strategies in the European Corporate Bond Market

Dynamic Portfolio Strategies in the European Corporate Bond Market Dynamic Portfolio Strategies in the European Corporate Bond Market Mary Pieterse-Bloem Willem F.C. Verschoor Zhaowen Qian and Remco C.J. Zwinkels December 2017 Abstract In this paper, we develop and implement

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Fall 2017 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2018 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

THE 1/n PENSION INVESTMENT PUZZLE

THE 1/n PENSION INVESTMENT PUZZLE Heath Windcliff* and Phelim P. Boyle ABSTRACT This paper examines the so-called 1/n investment puzzle that has been observed in defined contribution plans whereby some participants divide their contributions

More information

PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION

PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION Chapter 16 PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION Sebastian Ceria and Kartik Sivaramakrishnan a) INTRODUCTION Every portfolio manager faces the challenge of building portfolios that achieve an optimal tradeoff between

More information

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory 1. Introduction 2. Portfolio Basics 3. The Feasible Set 4. Portfolio Selection Rules 5. The Efficient Frontier 6. Indifference Curves 7. The Two-Asset Portfolio 8. Unrestriceted

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

A Bayesian Implementation of the Standard Optimal Hedging Model: Parameter Estimation Risk and Subjective Views

A Bayesian Implementation of the Standard Optimal Hedging Model: Parameter Estimation Risk and Subjective Views A Bayesian Implementation of the Standard Optimal Hedging Model: Parameter Estimation Risk and Subjective Views by Wei Shi and Scott H. Irwin May 23, 2005 Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the

More information

How Good is 1/n Portfolio?

How Good is 1/n Portfolio? How Good is 1/n Portfolio? at Hausdorff Research Institute for Mathematics May 28, 2013 Woo Chang Kim wkim@kaist.ac.kr Assistant Professor, ISysE, KAIST Along with Koray D. Simsek, and William T. Ziemba

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 2/28/2012 Abstract We

More information

The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement

The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement Richard Michaud, Robert Michaud, David Esch New Frontier Advisors Boston, MA 02110 Presented to: INSIGHTS 2016 fi360 National Conference April 6-8, 2016 San Diego,

More information

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance Chapter 8 Markowitz Portfolio Theory 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance The main question in portfolio theory is the following: Given an initial capital V (0), and opportunities (buy or sell) in N securities

More information

Introduction to Risk Parity and Budgeting

Introduction to Risk Parity and Budgeting Chapman & Hall/CRC FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS SERIES Introduction to Risk Parity and Budgeting Thierry Roncalli CRC Press Taylor &. Francis Group Boca Raton London New York CRC Press is an imprint of the Taylor

More information

Optimization 101. Dan dibartolomeo Webinar (from Boston) October 22, 2013

Optimization 101. Dan dibartolomeo Webinar (from Boston) October 22, 2013 Optimization 101 Dan dibartolomeo Webinar (from Boston) October 22, 2013 Outline of Today s Presentation The Mean-Variance Objective Function Optimization Methods, Strengths and Weaknesses Estimation Error

More information

Stock Return Serial Dependence and Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance

Stock Return Serial Dependence and Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance Stock Return Serial Dependence and Out-of-Sample Portfolio Performance Victor DeMiguel Francisco J. Nogales Raman Uppal May 31, 2010 DeMiguel and Uppal are from London Business School and can be contacted

More information

Foundations of Asset Pricing

Foundations of Asset Pricing Foundations of Asset Pricing C Preliminaries C Mean-Variance Portfolio Choice C Basic of the Capital Asset Pricing Model C Static Asset Pricing Models C Information and Asset Pricing C Valuation in Complete

More information

Estimation risk modeling in portfolio selection: Implicit approach implementation

Estimation risk modeling in portfolio selection: Implicit approach implementation Journal of Finance and Investment Analysis, vol.1, no.3, 2012, 21-31 ISSN: 2241-0988 (print version), 2241-0996 (online) Scienpress Ltd, 2012 Estimation risk modeling in portfolio selection: Implicit approach

More information

Risk-Based Investing & Asset Management Final Examination

Risk-Based Investing & Asset Management Final Examination Risk-Based Investing & Asset Management Final Examination Thierry Roncalli February 6 th 2015 Contents 1 Risk-based portfolios 2 2 Regularizing portfolio optimization 3 3 Smart beta 5 4 Factor investing

More information

Traditional Optimization is Not Optimal for Leverage-Averse Investors

Traditional Optimization is Not Optimal for Leverage-Averse Investors Posted SSRN 10/1/2013 Traditional Optimization is Not Optimal for Leverage-Averse Investors Bruce I. Jacobs and Kenneth N. Levy forthcoming The Journal of Portfolio Management, Winter 2014 Bruce I. Jacobs

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Optimization II: Model-Based Portfolio Management

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Optimization II: Model-Based Portfolio Management Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Optimization II: Model-Based Portfolio Management C. David Levermore University of Maryland, College Park Math 420: Mathematical Modeling January 26, 2012

More information

Chapter 2 Portfolio Management and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

Chapter 2 Portfolio Management and the Capital Asset Pricing Model Chapter 2 Portfolio Management and the Capital Asset Pricing Model In this chapter, we explore the issue of risk management in a portfolio of assets. The main issue is how to balance a portfolio, that

More information

How Good is the Out-of-Sample Performance of Optimized Portfolios?

How Good is the Out-of-Sample Performance of Optimized Portfolios? How Good is the Out-of-Sample Performance of Optimized Portfolios? An empirical comparison of optimal versus naive diversification Anders Bakke Supervisor Valeri Zakamouline This master s thesis is carried

More information

EXPLORING THE BENEFITS OF USING STOCK CHARACTERISTICS IN OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO STRATEGIES. Jonathan Fletcher. University of Strathclyde

EXPLORING THE BENEFITS OF USING STOCK CHARACTERISTICS IN OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO STRATEGIES. Jonathan Fletcher. University of Strathclyde EXPLORING THE BENEFITS OF USING STOCK CHARACTERISTICS IN OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO STRATEGIES Jonathan Fletcher University of Strathclyde Key words: Characteristics, Modelling Portfolio Weights, Mean-Variance

More information

Active allocation among a large set of stocks: How effective is the parametric rule? Abstract

Active allocation among a large set of stocks: How effective is the parametric rule? Abstract Active allocation among a large set of stocks: How effective is the parametric rule? Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 10/12/ 2011 Abstract In this study we measure

More information

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios Amit Goyal Goizueta Business School Emory University Ivo Welch Yale School of Management Yale Economics Department NBER December 16, 2003 Abstract This

More information

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region*

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region* Posted SSRN 08/31/01 Last Revised 10/15/01 Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region* Bruce I. Jacobs and Kenneth N. Levy * Previously entitled Leverage Aversion and Portfolio Optimality:

More information

Performance of risk-based asset allocation strategies

Performance of risk-based asset allocation strategies Performance of risk-based asset allocation strategies Copenhagen Business School 2015 Master s Thesis Cand.merc.(mat.) 01/07/2015 Authors: Simen Knutzen Jens Retterholt Supervisor: Martin Richter......................

More information

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem Chapter 8: CAPM 1. Single Index Model 2. Adding a Riskless Asset 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM 5. The One-Fund Theorem 6. The Characteristic Line 7. The Pricing Model Single Index Model 1 1. Covariance

More information

Portfolio Analysis Considering Estimation Risk and Imperfect Markets

Portfolio Analysis Considering Estimation Risk and Imperfect Markets Portfolio Analysis Considering Estimation Risk and Imperfect Markets Bruce L. Dixon and Peter J. Barry Mean-variance efficient portfolio analysis is applied to situations where not all assets are perfectly

More information

International Diversification Revisited

International Diversification Revisited International Diversification Revisited by Robert J. Hodrick and Xiaoyan Zhang 1 ABSTRACT Using country index returns from 8 developed countries and 8 emerging market countries, we re-explore the benefits

More information