Dry Powder Sometimes Explodes: Contracting on Fund Size and Investment Duration in Private Equity

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Dry Powder Sometimes Explodes: Contracting on Fund Size and Investment Duration in Private Equity"

Transcription

1 Dry Powder Sometimes Explodes: Contracting on Fund Size and Investment Duration in Private Equity Dawei Fang Department of Economics, University of Gothenburg 15 th February, 2015 Abstract: Private equity (PE) funds typically invest in a portfolio of projects and PE managers have considerable discretion over investment timing. Empirical studies find evidence of managerial opportunism and question whether the existing PE fund structure is optimal. We tackle this question by examining the interaction between investment pooling and investment timing. Pooling helps design more efficient contracts but gives fund managers incentives to make investments sequentially and gamble for resurrection when early investments fail. Restricting investment timing by shortening investment duration contracts off gambling for resurrection, but it improves efficiency only if managerial compensation sufficiently caps managers upside sharing, which may force managers to concede rents to competitive investors. When projects have high profitability potential, the equilibrium fund structure coincides with that in practice and results in managerial opportunism found in the empirical literature. Our results imply that the existing PE fund structure is optimal for fund managers but not society. Contact dawei.fang@cff.gu.se. I thank Alexander Guembel, Ulrich Hege, Tim Jenkinson, Alan Morrison, Thomas Noe, Ludovic Phalippou, John Quah, David Robinson, Linus Siming, and Anjan Thakor for helpful comments, and seminar participants at EFMA 2014, University of Gothenburg, University of Oxford, and Queen Mary University of London. Any remaining errors are my responsibility.

2 1 Introduction Private equity (PE) funds have a limited partnership structure with a finite lifespan, usually years (Robinson and Sensoy (2013)). The life of a PE fund is contractually partitioned into an investment period (usually the first 5 years of the fund) and a harvesting period. New investments are limited to the investment period (Metrick and Yasuda (2010)), during which the management team of the PE fund, who serves as the general partner (GP), seeks new investment opportunities and invests the capital committed by the limited partners (LPs) in a portfolio of projects. During the harvesting period, the GP manages and eventually exits from those investments to realize capital gains. GP compensation generally includes an option-like performance component, known as carried interest (or carry), which usually amounts to 20% of the overall performance of the fund above a pre-specified hurdle rate. 1 This incentive scheme aims to resolve the potential agency problems. However, as pointed out by Arcot, Fluck, Gaspar, and Hege (2014), for funds late in the investment period with substantial dry powder (unspent capital), the same (incentive) contract creates adverse incentives to window dress. Recent empirical studies find evidence of GP opportunism in the late phase of the investment period. For example, Dass, Hsu, Nanda, and Wang (2012), Arcot, Fluck, Gaspar, and Hege (2014), and Braun and Schmidt (2014) all find that a PE fund s late investments significantly underperform its early investments. Moreover, Degeorge, Martin, and Phalippou (2013) find that the secondary buyouts (SBOs) made in the late phase of the investment period of a PE fund not only underperform the SBOs made in the early phase but have negative NPVs on average. These findings suggest that the GP with substantial dry powder close to the end of the investment period has an incentive to do deals that are not in the interest of LPs. This naturally raises three questions. First, what drives such a phenomenon? Second, is there an alternative PE contract that can possibly alleviate GP opportunism? For example, Degeorge, Martin, and Phalippou (2013) suggest that LPs might benefit from contractually capping the percentage of a fund that the GP may invest in late SBOs. Third, if there exists a more efficient PE contract, how to explain the use of a suboptimal contract in practice? In this paper, we tackle these three questions based on a simple agency model, in which we endogenize GP compensation, fund size, and the length of the investment period of the partnership. In our model, to weed out the unskilled fly-by-night operators, the fund gives the GP a positive payoff only if the GP creates value for the fund. Given 1 See Sahlman (1990), Gompers and Lerner (1999), Phalippou (2007), Cumming and Johan (2009), and Metrick and Yasuda (2011) for a discussion of the PE partnership structure and GP compensation. 1

3 this option-like characteristic of GP compensation, the GP bears little of the downside risk and thus has an inclination toward risk shifting. We show that, if the partnership specifies a long investment period, the GP has an incentive to strategically time his investment decisions: he undertakes better quality projects in the early phase of the investment period and postpones his investment decisions regarding the worse quality projects until he accesses private information on the progress of his earlier investments. This strategic timing behavior enables the GP, in the middle of the investment period, to better predict the fund s final performance. Since GP compensation bases on the fund s final performance, the interim private information on fund performance is useful for the GP to game the compensation scheme in the late phase of the investment period. Particularly, if he anticipates the success of his earlier investments, he will pass up the worse quality projects, while if he foresees the failure of his earlier investments, he will gamble for resurrection by taking those bad deals. These results indicate that the calloption-like GP compensation and the long investment period without harsh restrictions on late investments are the key drivers for observed GP opportunism. To improve efficiency, the contract must restrict the GP s late investments by, for example, capping the amounts the GP can invest in the late phase, which is suggested by Degeorge, Martin, and Phalippou (2013), or shortening the investment period. However, such a restriction is only necessary but not sufficient to better discipline the GP. This is because, although such a restriction alleviates GP opportunism in the late phase of the investment period, it can exacerbate GP opportunism in the early phase. We show that, when project profitability potential is high and when the GP has a considerable share in the upside, restricting late investments induces the GP to gamble more aggressively for the upside in the early phase and causes more overinvestment in total. Thus, when project profitability potential is high, socially optimal contracting requires restricting both the GP s late investments and the GP s upside sharing, which may force the GP to concede rents to LPs. When project profitability potential is sufficiently high, upside concession results in large rent concession, which makes this socially optimal contract privately suboptimal for the GP to use. In this case, the GP s privately optimal contract imposes no late investment restriction and gives the GP a call-option-like security. Although this contract is not socially optimal, it is rent-saving and is more efficient than many other alternative financing arrangements. Since, in practice, PE funds typically invest in projects with high profitability potential, our model implies that the socially optimal contract is costly for the GP to use because of rent concession. Thus, our model offers an explanation for both the existing PE fund structure and the existence of GP opportunism found in the empirical studies. We further show that, when the socially optimal contract is not used, restricting fund 2

4 size can serve as an alternative but less efficient way to alleviate GP opportunism. A small fund minimizes overinvestment but also creates an underinvestment problem: the GP has to pass up some good investment opportunities if he encounters a sufficiently large number of good projects. Thus, fund size is restricted only if underinvestment does not create much inefficiency, which is likely the case when economic conditions are bad so that the GP has low chance of facing many good investment opportunities. Apart from the implications on PE fund structures, our model also contains a number of predictions for GP behavior, PE fund size and performance, and LP earnings. We list some of these predictions as follows: i. The GP takes more (less) risks if the fund has a lower (higher) cumulative performance. This prediction is consistent with the evidence in Ljungqvist, Richardson, and Wolfenzon (2008) and Barrot (2014) that, following periods of good (bad) performance, GPs become more (less) conservative. ii. The GP with more dry powder in the late phase of the investment period is more likely to take bad deals. This prediction receives empirical support from Degeorge, Martin, and Phalippou (2013) and Arcot, Fluck, Gaspar, and Hege (2014). iii. Projects undertaken earlier by a PE fund are more profitable than those undertaken later by the same fund. This coincides with the empirical findings of Dass, Hsu, Nanda, and Wang (2012), Degeorge, Martin, and Phalippou (2013), Arcot, Fluck, Gaspar, and Hege (2014), and Braun and Schmidt (2014) that a PE fund s late investments significantly underperform its early investments. iv. The funds which invest quicker outperform the funds with lower investment speed. This prediction receives support from the evidence in Giot, Hege, and Schwienbacher (2014) that experienced funds invest quicker than novice funds and outperform novice funds at a highly significant margin. v. LPs do not earn risk-adjusted excess returns from investing in PE funds, which is consistent with the findings in Phalippou (2014) and Sorensen, Wang, and Yang (2014). vi. PE fund size is procyclical. This is a testable prediction. Existing literature finds evidence of procyclicality of PE fundraising on the industry level. For example, Kaplan and Strömberg (2009) find that PE fundraising booms and busts are strongly correlated with public equity booms and busts. However, to our knowledge, procyclicality of fund size has not been tested. 3

5 To our knowledge, this is the first paper that studies the investment timing issue under the principal-agent framework when investment pooling is used. The theoretical literature on investment pooling typically focuses on how pooling can help design incentive compatible contracts, through the channels of risk diversification (Diamond (1984)) or inside wealth creation (Laux (2001) and Tirole (2006)). Although our paper confirms the benefits of investment pooling, it focuses on the interaction of investment pooling and investment timing. Our paper shows that, given investment pooling, the agent s investment decisions on part of the projects can be affected by the progress of the other part and the agent has an incentive to game the timing of investment decisions to exploit the contractual provisions. Such an incentive must be taken into account when designing optimal contract. The literature on investment timing typically takes a real options approach that emphasizes the value of waiting to invest under uncertainty. This literature usually adopts a decision-theoretic framework by examining the optimal investment/divestment timing rules with no agency problems involved (see Pindyck (1991) for an excellent survey). The effects of moral hazard on investment timing decisions is studied in Grenadier and Wang (2005), with a real options model in which the agent manages a single project. The key difference between our model and the real options models is that the NPV of a project is fixed in our model whereas in real options models, it generally follows a stochastic process. Thus, in contrast to real options models, in our model, the manager s incentive to wait is not driven by project quality fluctuation but by agency conflicts and investment pooling. This paper also relates to the theoretical literature analyzing PE fund structures. Kandel, Leshchinskii, and Yuklea (2011) argue that the finite lifespan of the partnership can induce the GP to make inefficient investments in risky projects. Their analysis is based on the exogenously specified GP compensation structure and a predetermined investment period of the fund. In contrast, this paper endogenizes both GP compensation and the length of the investment period and shows that inefficient fund structures can arise in equilibrium. Inderst, Mueller, and Münnich (2007) argue that investment pooling, combined with capital rationing, helps the GP commit to efficient liquidation decisions. However, in this paper, capital rationing never minimizes agency conflicts. Axelson, Strömberg, and Weisbach (2009) study the GP s financing of a portfolio of projects. They show that, in the pure ex ante financing setting, it is never optimal to make the GP capital-constrained, and they find that the optimal financing structure is a combination of ex ante pooled financing and ex post deal-by-deal financing. In contrast, this paper shows that, in the pure ex ante financing setting, although pooled financing can increase efficiency, the GP may prefer having the fund capital-constrained in order to save rents. Fulghieri and Sevilir (2009) study the optimal size and scope of the 4

6 fund s portfolio by focusing on the double-sided moral hazard problem between the GP and the entrepreneurs of the projects. They show that the GP finds it optimal to limit portfolio size when projects have high profitability potential and the GP expands the portfolio size only when project fundamentals are more moderate. In contrast, this paper abstracts from the effort-incentive problem and focuses on the GP-LP relationship rather than the GP-entrepreneur relationship. This paper finds that, even with exogenously fixed project quality, heterogeneous fund sizes can arise in equilibrium and the GP deliberately limits fund size only when project profitability potential is not too high. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the model. Section 3 analyzes the socially optimal financing arrangement and shows that this arrangement may force the GP to concede rents to LPs. Section 4 analyzes alternative financing arrangements, which are less efficient but rent-saving. Section 5 determines the equilibrium financing arrangement. Section 6 provides the implications of the model. Section 7 concludes. All the proofs are relegated to the Appendix. 2 The model 2.1 The players There are three types of players in the model: a GP, investors who are perfectly competitive, and fly-by-night operators. 2 All players are risk-neutral, with no discounting of the future, and have access to a storage technology yielding the risk-free interest rate, which is normalized to zero. 2.2 The projects The model has four dates (time 0, 1, 2, and 3). At time 0, all the players anticipate that the GP will be endowed with two projects at time 1 and they have the common prior that the quality of each project will be independently drawn from the same distribution, with probability λ (0,1) of being good (G) and probability 1 λ of being bad (B). 3 At time 1, two projects arrive. The quality of each project is privately observable to the GP, who possesses certain expertise that normal investors lack. Each project requires an investment of I to be undertaken. To undertake a project, the GP must invest I in the project at either time 1 or time 2; otherwise, the investment opportunity disappears. To 2 We use investors and LPs interchangeably throughout the paper. 3 There is no change in the qualitative nature of the result if we assume positive project quality correlation. This extension is available from the author upon request. 5

7 focus on the investment timing effect on investment efficiency through the GP s opportunistic behavior but not through the change in project quality, we assume no change in a project s quality no matter whether it is undertaken at time 1 or 2. 4 Particularly, we assume that a good project, if undertaken at either time 1 or 2, will succeed, producing cash flow R > I, with certainty at time 3. A bad project, if undertaken at either time 1 or 2, will succeed with some probability, i.e., it will produce, at time 3, R with probability p (0,1) and 0 with probability 1 p. We assume that bad projects are negative NPV investments, i.e., pr < I. To simply the analysis, we further assume that R > 2I. (1) Thus, the costs of investing in both projects can be covered when at least one investment succeeds. 5 Given that pr < I, condition (1) further implies that p < 1 2. To give the GP incentives to postpone part of his investment decisions, we assume that the progress of investments made at time 1 is privately observable to the GP at time 2. To deliver the key insight without getting into unnecessary complications, we assume that, at time 2, the GP knows whether the investments made at time 1 will eventually succeed or fail. Note that, if the GP aims to maximize efficiency, then such interim information is useless, because a project s cash flow distribution is independent of the outcome of the other project. However, if there is misalignment between the GP s interests and social interests, this interim information can be useful for the GP s investment decision at time 2, as we will see later on. 2.3 The GP s problem The GP has no money of his own and has to raise money from investors. 6 We focus on ex post information asymmetry regarding project quality by assuming that the GP has to raise funds by establishing a partnership with investors at time 0 (when the GP has no superior information on project quality). This assumption can be justified on the 4 Introducing project quality deterioration caused by investment delay will not change the qualitative nature of our result so long as the reduction in the probability of success for a bad project caused by delay is sufficiently small. 5 There is no change in the qualitative nature of the result if we extend the analysis to I < R 2I. This extension is available from the author upon request. 6 Although PE funds may have capital contribution provisions that require the GP to contribute 1% of the committed capital, the GP is frequently permitted to borrow money from the fund to meet his capital contribution requirements (see Harris (2010)). 6

8 grounds that PE fundraising is time consuming. The partnership lasts for three periods and is dissolved at time 3 when all cash flows are realized. At time 0, to raise funds, the GP offers investors a contract that specifies fund size, the length of the investment period, and GP compensation. Fund size is determined by investors committed capital, denoted by K. Because there are at most two good projects and because, in our model, having a financial slack does not help contracting, without loss of generality, we restrict the choice of K to K {I,2I}. When K = I (K = 2I), the fund size is small (big) and the GP can undertake at most one project (two projects). We denote the length of the investment period by l {1,2}, where l = 1 (l = 2) refers to a short (long) investment period, including time 1 only (both time 1 and 2). Note that new investments are limited to the investment period, so the GP is allowed to make new investments at time 2 only when the investment period is long, i.e., when l = 2. Let s(x) denote the GP security, which maps the final cash flow x to the GP s payoff and satisfies the following limited liability and monotonicity conditions: Limited Liability (LL): 0 s(x) x for all x 0; Monotonicity (M): s(x) and x s(x) are nondecreasing in x. The monotonicity condition is quite common in the financial literature on security design, e.g., Harris and Raviv (1989) and Nachman and Noe (1994). This condition contracts off the GP s moral hazard of increasing his own payoff by secretly borrowing money from a third party or by burning money. Given s, the investor security is automatically determined by x s(x). To introduce agency conflicts in a simple way (otherwise the two parties interests can be perfectly aligned by using an equity contract), we follow Axelson, Strömberg, and Weisbach (2009) by introducing an ex ante adverse selection problem, where flyby-night operators play a role. We assume that there is an infinite supply of fly-by-night operators who cannot bring success to any project but can store money at the riskfree interest rate. At time 0, without contracts as a signalling device, investors cannot distinguish capable GPs from unskilled fly-by-night operators. The ex ante contracting must resolve this adverse selection problem, because if fly-by-night operators have an incentive to mimic capable GPs by offering the same contract, given the infinite supply of fly-by-night operators, the probability that investors meet a fly-by-night operator would be one, in which case investors must lose money. Because fly-by-night operators can store money at the risk-free interest rate, to prevent them from mimicking, the contract has to ensure that they earn nothing by storing money. Thus, the GP security must satisfy the following condition: No-Profit-No-GP-Earning (NP): for raised capital K, s(x) = 0 whenever x K. Condition (NP) makes the GP bear little of the downside risk and thus induces the 7

9 GP s risk-shifting tendency. This condition is also consistent with GP compensation in practice: GPs earn no performance-based compensation before LPs are paid in full (see Sahlman (1990)). The GP s problem is to maximize his expected payoff by offering investors, at time 0, a contract (K, l, s) that specifies fund size, investment duration, and GP compensation. Investors accept the contract and provide the GP with K if they anticipate that they can at least break even. Figure 1 illustrates the timeline of the model. Time 0 Time 1 Time 2 Time 3 GP establishes partnership Partnership contracting: fund size investment period GP security Projects arrive GP observes quality GP makes investment decisions GP observes the progress of time 1 s investments If GP has dry powder and investment period is long, GP decides whether to invest dry powder in more projects All cash flows are realized Partnership is dissolved Figure 1: The timeline of the model We make one final assumption that specifies the GP s preference when two or more actions give him the same payoff. We assume that the GP has a lexicographic ordering of preferences over actions that give him the same payoff: (a) he prefers those that enable him to possibly have a successful project at time 3 to those that give him zero probability of having a successful project and (b) among the actions that give him positive probability of having a successful project, he prefers the one that produces higher investment surplus. This assumption is not crucial for the main results. It is mainly used to simplify the expression for the mathematical results in the borderline cases. Under this assumption, if the GP faces two bad projects and if we suppose that the GP chooses between undertaking 0, 1, and 2 of them with all the three choices delivering zero payoff to him, he will choose to undertake 1 of them. 3 The socially optimal financing arrangement 3.1 Conditions Since all the ex post efficiency loss will be borne by the GP ex ante, it is natural to start our analysis by investigating the optimal contract that minimizes inefficiency. At time 1, there are three states of the world, distinguished by the combination of two projects quality: (1) state GG, in which both projects are good, (2) state GB, in which one 8

10 project is good while the other is bad, 7 and (3) state BB, in which both projects are bad. Because of condition (NP), the first-best world, in which the GP invests in all good but no bad projects in all the three states, is unattainable: in state BB, the GP always has an incentive to invest in at least one bad project, since otherwise he earns nothing. Thus, it is impossible to contract off the efficiency loss from undertaking one bad project in state BB. It is thus natural to examine the second best, i.e., the financing arrangement that induces the GP to i. invest in two good projects in state GG, ii. invest in only the good project in state GB, iii. and invest in only one bad project in state BB. The investment surplus from the above prescribed investment behavior equals π s = λ 2 (2R 2I) + 2λ(1 λ)(r I) + (1 λ) 2 (pr I) (2) = ( 2λ + (1 λ) 2 p ) R (1 + λ 2 )I. In expression (2), 2R 2I is the surplus from investing in two good projects in state GG, which occurs with probability λ 2 ; R I is the surplus from investing in only the good project in state GB, which occurs with probability 2λ(1 λ); pr I is the surplus from investing in only one bad project in state BB, which occurs with probability (1 λ) 2. Financing is feasible only if the surplus expressed in (2) is nonnegative. This condition is equivalent to R/I 1 + λ 2 2λ + (1 λ) 2 p = r 0(p,λ). (3) We think of R/I as representing a project s profitability potential. Thus, financing is feasible only if the project s profitability potential is greater than the threshold, r 0, defined in (3). In what follows, we assume that condition (3) holds. We call the financing arrangements that induce the GP to follow the above prescribed investment behavior socially optimal arrangements. Note that, socially optimal arrangements must satisfy the following three conditions: Unconstrained Capital: sufficient funds raised for investing in two projects; Cross-Pledging: putting the two projects together under one roof; Short Investment Period: new investments are limited to time 1. The first condition unconstrained capital is necessary to contract off underinvestment; it requires that the GP raises 2I at time 0. The second condition cross-pledging is necessary to induce the GP to abandon a bad project, since if the GP instead estab- 7 Given that the two projects are identical, it is irrelevant which of the two projects is good. We therefore treat these two separate but symmetric cases effectively as a single case. 9

11 lishes two funds, each used to finance one project, given that each fund s contract has to satisfy condition (NP), the GP will never abandon any bad project. Given unconstrained capital and the use of cross-pledging, the third condition short investment period is necessary to minimize overinvestment. To see this, note that, if the contract specifies a long investment period, in state BB, the GP has an incentive to invest in one bad project at time 1 and, if he foresees the failure of this investment at time 2, he will gamble for resurrection by undertaking the other bad project at time 2. 8 The above analysis implies that a socially optimal arrangement must specify large fund size and a short investment period, i.e., K = 2I and l = 1. Conditioned on K = 2I and l = 1, to minimize agency conflicts, the GP security, s, must satisfy the following incentive-compatibility conditions: 9 s(r + I) ps(2r) + (1 p)s(r), (IC GB ) ps(r + I) p 2 s(2r) + 2p(1 p)s(r). (IC BB ) The left-hand side of (IC GB ) is the GP s expected payoff in state GB if he only undertakes the good project. The right-hand side of (IC GB ) is the GP s expected payoff in state GB if he undertakes both projects. When (IC GB ) holds, the GP only undertakes the good project in state GB. The left-hand side of (IC BB ) is the GP s expected payoff in state BB if he only undertakes one bad project. The right-hand side of (IC BB ) is the GP s expected payoff in state BB if he undertakes both projects. When (IC BB ) holds, conditioned on l = 1, the GP only undertakes one bad project in state BB. It is noticeable that (IC BB ) implies (IC GB ). Thus, a contract is socially optimal if and only if it is in the form of (K = 2I,l = 1,s) with s satisfying (IC BB ) and conditions (LL), (M), and (NP) specified in Section 2.3. Since our aim is to derive the equilibrium financing arrangement, that is, given a perfectly competitive capital market, the contract that maximizes the GP s payoff, it is natural for us to examine, among all the socially optimal contracts, the contract that maximizes the GP s payoff. Denote this contract by C s and denote by s s the associated GP security. The above analysis implies that C s = (K = 2I,l = 1,s s). In the next part of this section, we solve for s s. 8 Admittedly, our specification of the GP s preferences over actions that deliver him the same payoff plays a role here. If we instead assume that, among the actions that give the GP the same payoff, the GP always prefers the one that maximizes investment efficiency, then gambling for resurrection can be contracted off by having s(r) = 0. However, even in this case, imposing a short investment period will help minimize overinvestment. This is because, with a short investment period, we no longer require s(r) = 0 to design the incentive-compatible contract and, hence, the security design problem is relaxed. 9 Since we have assumed that good projects will succeed for sure, the incentive-compatibility conditions that induce the GP to undertake good projects are implied by the monotonicity condition (M). 10

12 3.2 Security design With cross-pledging, the final cash flow x can potentially take on one of the six different values, i.e., x {0,I,2I,R,I + R,2R}. The GP security, s, must specify the GP s payoff for each of these six cash flow realizations, among which, by condition (NP), s(0) = s(i) = s(2i) = 0. Thus, s s must solve the following program: maxe[s(x)] = λ 2 s(2r) + [ 2λ(1 λ) + (1 λ) 2 p ] s(r + I), s (P) subject to (LL), (M), (NP), (IC BB ), and the following investors break-even condition E[s(x)] π s, (BE) where πs is given by equation (2). There are two possible payoffs to the GP in the maximand. The first payoff, s(2r), occurs only in state GG. The second payoff, s(r + I), occurs both in state BB when the bad project undertaken succeeds and in state GB. 10 For investors to break even, the GP s payoff must not exceed the investment surplus, given by (2). To solve the problem (P), we first solve the following relaxed problem: maxe[s(x)] = λ 2 s(2r) + [ 2λ(1 λ) + (1 λ) 2 p ] s(r + I), s (P ) subject to (LL), (M), (NP), and (IC BB ). Denote the solution to the above relaxed problem by s o. The only difference between the relaxed problem and the primal problem is the exclusion/inclusion of condition (BE). (BE) is investors break-even condition which imposes the investment surplus as an upper bound on the objective function. Thus, if the maximal value of the relaxed problem falls below the investment surplus, the solution to the primal problem equals the solution to the relaxed problem, while if otherwise, the solution to the primal problem equals a scale transformation of the solution to the relaxed problem. This result is formally presented in the following lemma. Lemma 1. Suppose s s and s o represent the solutions to the primal problem (P) and to the relaxed problem (P ), respectively. Then [ s s(x) = s o π ] s (x)min 1, E[s o (x)] x 0, (4) 10 If in state BB, the undertaken bad project fails, the final cash flow is I. By condition (NP), s(i) equals zero and is hence missing in the maximand. 11

13 where E[s o (x)] represents the maximal value of the relaxed problem (P ) and π s is the investment surplus given by (2). Our first proposition presents the expressions for s o and E[s o (x)]. Proposition 1. The solution to the relaxed problem (P), s o, and the associated maximal value E[s o (x)] are as follows: s o (x) = 0 for all x 2I, and i. if R/I 3 2p, then s o (R) = R 2I, s o (R + I) = R I, and s o (2R) = 2R 2I, in which case, ii. if 3 2p < R/I 3, then a. if λ λ, where E[s o (x)] = ( 2λ + (1 λ) 2 p ) (R I); (5) λ = p 2 2p + p p 2 1 p 2, (6) then s o (R) = R 2I, s o (R+I) = R I, and s o (2R) = R I +(3I R)(1 p)/p, in which case E[s o (x)] = (2λ + (1 λ) 2 p λ 2 ) R p (2λ + 2λ 2 + (1 λ) 2 p 3λ 2 p ) I, b. while if λ > λ, then s o (R) = (I pr)/(1 p), s o (R+I) = (I pr)/(1 p)+i, and s o (2R) = (I pr)/(1 p) + R, in which case, ( E[s o (x)] = 1 + λ 2 + (1 λ) 2 p 1 ) ( R+ (1 λ)(3λ 1) + (1 λ) 2 p + 1 ) I; 1 p 1 p (8) iii. if R/I > 3, then a. if λ λ, then s o (R) = I and s o (R + I) = s o (2R) = 2I, in which case E[s o (x)] = ( 4λ 2λ 2 + 2(1 λ) 2 p ) I, (9) (7) b. while if λ > λ, the expressions for s o and E[s o (x)] are the same as those presented in (iib). Proposition 1 has implications on socially optimal security design. When projects profitability potential, represented by R/I, is low (below the threshold 3 2p), part (i) in Proposition 1 implies that s o has all the marginal cash flows in the region [2I,2R] pledged to the GP. Thus, s o is a call option with strike price equal to LPs committed capital. Given that, by Lemma 1, s s is a scale transformation of s o, s s is a call-optionlike security with strike price equal to LPs committed capital. This case is illustrated in Panel A of Figure 2. 12

14 When projects profitability potential is not too low (above the threshold 3 2p), an incentive-compatible security must not have all the marginal cash flows in the region [2I,2R] pledged to the GP. In this case, if the projects have high probability of being good (λ > λ), parts (iib) and (iiib) in Proposition 1 imply that s o is a call option with strike price between 2I and R. Thus, given that s s is a scale transformation of s o, s s is a call-option-like security with strike price between 2I and R. This case is illustrated in Panel B of Figure 2. If projects have low probability of being good (λ λ), part (iia) in Proposition 1 implies that s o must have some marginal cash flows in the region [R + I, 2R] pledged to the LPs when projects have medium profitability potential (between 3 2p and 3), while part (iiia) implies that s o must have all the marginal cash flows in the region [R + I,2R] and some marginal cash flows in the region [2I,R] pledged to the LPs when projects have high profitability potential (above 3). This implies, given that s s is a scale transformation of s o, that in both cases, s s must exhibit concavity in the high cash flow region. These two cases are illustrated in Panels C and D in Figure 2. Proposition 1 also presents the expression for E[s o (x)], which is the GP s maximal payoff by using a socially optimal contract with LPs break-even condition omitted. Including LPs break-even condition just imposes the investment surplus, πs, as an upper bound on the GP s payoff. Thus, with LPs break-even condition included, the GP s payoff by using the socially optimal contract equals the minimum of E[s o (x)] and πs. This result is presented in the next proposition. Proposition 2. The GP s expected payoff by using the socially optimal contract, Cs = (K = 2I,l = 1,s s), where s s solves problem (P), equals E[s s(x)] = min[e[s o (x)],π s ], (10) where E[s o (x)] is presented in Proposition 1 and π s is given by equation (2). 3.3 LPs rents By part (i) in Proposition 1, when projects profitability potential is low, s o pledges all the marginal cash flows in the region [2I,2R] to the GP and gives the GP a payoff expressed in (5). Since this payoff is greater than the investment surplus πs, by Proposition 2, when projects have low profitability potential, s s, which is a call-option-like security with strike price equal to LPs committed capital, gives the GP all the investment surplus and thus leaves LPs with no rents. However, when projects profitability potential is medium or high, to satisfy the incentive-compatibility condition (IC BB ), s o must leave some marginal cash flows in 13

15 Low Profitability Potential Medium or High Profitability Potential (in the case where λ>λ) s s (x) s s (x) G P G P P A Y O F F 0 2I R R+I 2R x P A Y O F F 0 2I R R+I 2R x Cash Flow Cash Flow Panel A. R/I 3 2p Panel B. R/I > 3 2p and λ > λ s s (x) Medium Profitability Potential (in the case where λ λ) s s (x) High Profitability Potential (in the case where λ λ) G P G P P A Y O F F 0 2I R R+I 2R x P A Y O F F 0 2I R R+I 2R x Cash Flow Cash Flow Panel C. 3 2p < R/I 3 and λ λ Panel D. R/I > 3 and λ λ Figure 2: The GP security, s s, that gives the GP the highest payoff among all the socially optimal securities. The graphs illustrate the shapes of s s in four cases, distinguished by parametric assumptions. Panel A illustrates the case where projects profitability potential, represented by R/I, is low (below 3 2p). Panel B illustrates the case where projects profitability potential is medium or high (above 3 2p) while a project s probability of being good is high, i.e., λ > λ. Panel C illustrates the case where projects profitability potential is medium (between 3 2p and 3) while a project s probability of being good is low, i.e., λ λ. Panel D illustrates the case where projects profitability potential is high (above 3) while a project s probability of being good is low, i.e., λ λ. the region [2I,2R] to LPs. Note that these marginal cash flows are pledged to LPs not because of LPs break-even condition but because of (IC BB ). Thus, it is possible that, at the solution to the primal security design problem (P), condition (IC BB ) is binding while LPs break-even condition is not. In this case, LPs earn positive rents. We use the case stated in part (iiia) in Proposition 1 as an example to show that LPs may earn rents when the projects s profitability potential is not too low. In part (iiia), projects have high profitability potential while low probability of having good quality. In this case, as shown in (iiia), regardless of the final cash flow, the GP s payoff cannot 14

16 exceed 2I. Since the GP s expected payoff equals the minimum of E[s o (x)] and the investment surplus, π s, and since, by equation (9), E[s o (x)] does not depend on R, an increase in R only increases π s but not E[s o (x)]. When R is sufficiently large, π s exceeds E[s o (x)], in which case, by using a socially optimal contract, the GP earns at most E[s o (x)], leaving π s E[s o (x)] as rents conceded to LPs. Note that, in practice, good projects are typically a minority of a PE fund s project candidates while PE-backed projects, conditioned on success, often produce stellar profits; examples include Apple, Federal Express, Genentech, Intel, Microsoft, etc. Thus, the parametric conditions in (iiia) seem to be consistent with the PE practice. Thus, the result in (iiia) suggests that the socially optimal contract can be costly for the GP to use because of rent concession. The rents paid to LPs can be considerably high if the projects profitability potential is sufficiently high. For instance, suppose p = 0.1, λ = 0.2, R = 8, and I = 1. These parameters satisfy the conditions in (iiia). Given these parameters, by (9), E[s o (x)] = 0.848, while by (2), π s = Thus, the GP s payoff, min[π s,e[s o (x)]], equals 0.848, while the LPs rents equal = In this case, although the capital market is perfectly competitive, by using the socially optimal contract, the LPs payoff is more than twice as much as the GP s payoff and the LPs net expected rate of return, which equals 1.824/2, is more than 90%! It is a general result that, ceteris paribus, an increase in R (and hence an increase in projects profitability potential) weakly increases LPs rents. We enclose this result in the next proposition. Proposition 3. Fixing p, λ, and I, increasing R weakly increases LPs rents. Given that the GP may not earn all the investment surplus by using the socially optimal contract, we still need to determine whether the socially optimal contract offers the GP the highest expected payoff compared to less efficient but possibly rent-saving contracts. We tackle this problem in the next section by examining those alternative financing arrangements. 4 Alternative financing arrangements Recall from the discussion in Section 3 that there are four conditions for socially optimal contracting: (i) unconstrained capital, i.e., K = 2I, (ii) cross-pledging, (iii) short investment period, i.e., l = 1, and (iv) the incentive-compatibility condition (IC BB ). By relaxing one or more conditions, we eventually obtain four mutually exclusive alterna- 15

17 tive financing arrangements, listed as follows: 11 a. the capital-constrained arrangement, under which the GP establishes a small fund, i.e., K = I; 12 b. the long duration arrangement, under which the GP establishes a large fund which specifies a long investment period, i.e., K = 2I and l = 2; c. the stand-alone arrangement, under which the GP establishes two small funds, each with K = I; d. the socially suboptimal short duration arrangement, under which the GP establishes a large fund which specifies a short investment period, i.e., K = 2I and l = 1, but the GP security violates (IC BB ). In what follows, we analyze each of these alternative financing arrangements. 4.1 The capital-constrained arrangement By using the capital-constrained arrangement, the GP can at most undertake one project. Because of condition (NP), the GP can only obtain a positive payoff if he creates value for the fund. Thus, the GP always has an incentive to undertake one project. In addition, in state GB, given that the good project has a higher probability of success than the bad one, the GP always picks the good project. Therefore, the GP s investment behavior by using the capital-constrained arrangement is as follows: (i) in state GG, undertake one good project, (ii) in state GB, undertake one good project, and (iii) in state BB, undertake one bad project. It is thus clear that the capital-constrained arrangement minimizes overinvestment but causes underinvestment. The next proposition shows that the capital-constrained arrangement is feasible so long as the investment surplus from the prescribed investment behavior is nonnegative, and by using a call-option-like GP security under the capital-constrained arrangement, the GP concedes no rents to the LPs. Proposition 4. The investment surplus by using the capital-constrained arrangement is π c = ( 2λ λ 2 + (1 λ) 2 p ) R I. (11) The capital-constrained arrangement is feasible if and only if the surplus in (11) is nonnegative. Under the capital-constrained arrangement, the optimal GP security is 11 Renegotiation at time 2 cannot alleviate the overinvestment problem. This is because, at time 2, LPs cannot observe the progress of time 1 s investments and thus the ex post renegotiation is still subject to the problem of fly-by-night operators. As a result, any ex post contract that gives the GP a positive payoff without bringing success to any project will not be accepted by LPs. 12 With a small fund, the choice of the length of the investment period has no effect on investment efficiency. 16

18 given by s 0 if x I c(x) =, (12) α c (x I) if x > I ( ) where α c = R I 1 I R. By using this security under the capital-constrained 2λ λ 2 +(1 λ) 2 p arrangement, the GP concedes no rents to the LPs and captures all the investment surplus π c. 4.2 The long duration arrangement By using the long duration arrangement, the GP can at most undertake two projects. As discussed in Section 3.1, with a long investment period, in state BB, the GP has an incentive to invest in one bad project at time 1 and, conditioned on anticipating the failure of this investment at time 2, the GP has an incentive to invest in the other bad project at time 2. Thus, to minimize agency conflicts conditioned on using the long duration arrangement, the GP security must induce the GP to (i) undertake two good projects in state GG, (ii) undertake only the good project in state GB, and (iii) in state BB, conditioned on foreseeing at time 2 the success of his earlier investment, keep the dry powder in the safe asset. Among the three requirements, (i) is implied by the monotonicity condition (M), while (ii) and (iii) are satisfied if and only if the GP security satisfies the weaker incentive-compatibility condition, (IC GB ), presented in Section 3.1. The next proposition shows that the long duration arrangement is feasible so long as the investment surplus from the prescribed investment behavior is nonnegative, and by using a call-option-like GP security under the long duration arrangement, the GP concedes no rents to the LPs. Proposition 5. The investment surplus by using the long duration arrangement is π l = ( 2λ + (1 λ) 2 (2 p)p ) R ( 1 + λ 2 + (1 λ) 2 (1 p) ) I. (13) The long duration arrangement is feasible if and only if the surplus in (13) is nonnegative. Under the long duration arrangement, the optimal GP security is given by s l (x) = 0 if x 2I, (14) α l (x 2I) if x > 2I where α l = (2λ+(1 λ)2 (2 p)p)r (1+λ 2 +(1 λ) 2 (1 p))i. By using this security under the (2λ+(1 λ) 2 (2 p)p)r (2λ+(1 λ) 2 (3 2p)p)I long duration arrangement, the GP concedes no rents to the LPs and captures all the 17

19 investment surplus π l. 4.3 The stand-alone and the socially suboptimal short duration arrangement Under the stand-alone arrangement, the GP finances two projects by establishing two small funds, with each fund financing one project. Since the GP security in each fund must satisfy condition (NP), the GP has an incentive to undertake both projects in any state, which implies that the GP undertakes two bad projects in state BB. Under the socially suboptimal short duration arrangement, the GP security violates condition (IC BB ), in which case, given the short investment period, the GP also undertakes two bad projects in state BB. Since the long duration arrangement only causes inefficiency in state BB, in which case the GP invests in 2 p bad projects on average, it is clear that the long duration arrangement is strictly more efficient than both the stand-alone and the socially suboptimal short duration arrangement. Moreover, by Proposition 5, by using the long duration arrangement, the GP concedes no rents to the LPs. The next proposition is thus straightforward. Proposition 6. The GP s payoff is higher under the long duration arrangement than under the stand-alone and the socially suboptimal short duration arrangement. 5 The equilibrium financing arrangement Proposition 6 implies that there are three financing arrangement candidates for the equilibrium: the socially optimal arrangement, the capital-constrained arrangement, and the long duration arrangement. Each has its own pros and cons. The socially optimal arrangement maximizes efficiency but may force the GP to concede rents to the LPs. As discussed in Section 3.3, rent concession occurs only if project profitability potential is not too low. Thus, the socially optimal arrangement will be used if project profitability potential is sufficiently low. When project profitability potential is not too low, the socially optimal arrangement causes rent concession, in which case the GP may turn to the capital-constrained or the long duration arrangement. Both these two alternative arrangements are rent-saving, but the capital-constrained arrangement causes underinvestment while the long duration arrangement causes more overinvestment. Everything else being equal, the higher the projects profitability potential, the larger the efficiency loss induced by underinvestment while the smaller the efficiency loss induced by overinvestment. Thus, the capital-constrained arrangement will be used only if project prof- 18

20 itability potential is neither too low nor too high, whereas the long duration arrangement will be used only if project profitability potential is sufficiently high. We present these results formally in the following theorem. Theorem 1. Suppose condition (3) is satisfied so that financing is feasible. The equilibrium financing arrangement has the following features: i. if R/I 3 2p, the GP chooses the socially optimal arrangement; ii. fixing p and λ, as R/I 1/p, the GP either chooses the socially optimal arrangement or the long duration arrangement; iii. fixing p and λ, if the GP chooses the socially optimal arrangement as R/I 1/p, then he chooses the socially optimal arrangement for all R/I < 1/p; iv. fixing p and λ, if the GP chooses the long duration arrangement as R/I 1/p, then there must either (a) exist a unique threshold r sl (3 2p,1/p) such that the GP chooses the socially optimal arrangement when R/I r sl and chooses the long duration arrangement when r sl < R/I < 1/p or (b) exist two thresholds r sc and r cl, where 3 2p < r sc < r cl < 1/p, such that the GP chooses the socially optimal arrangement when R/I r sc, chooses the capital-constrained arrangement when r sc < R/I r cl, and chooses the long duration arrangement when r cl < R/I < 1/p. Theorem 1 implies that the lower (higher) the projects profitability potential, the more likely the use of the socially optimal arrangement (the long duration arrangement) and the capital-constrained arrangement is used only if project profitability potential is moderate. The result thus suggests a positive relation between project profitability potential and the length of the investment period and a U-shaped relation between project profitability potential and fund size. We use an example to show how financing arrangement changes when projects profitability potential changes. In this example, p = 0.1 and λ = 0.2. We change projects profitability potential by changing R/I. By assumption, 2 < R/I < 1/p. Thus, given that p = 0.1, we must have 2 < R/I < 10. Given these parametric assumptions, there exist two thresholds π sc and π cl such that the socially optimal arrangement is used if R/I falls below π sc, the capital-constrained arrangement is used if R/I is between π sc and π cl, while the long duration arrangement is used if R/I is above π cl. 19

21 6 Implications of the model Our model contains several implications on PE fund structures and a number of predictions for GP behavior, PE fund size and performance, and LP earnings. Some of these predictions are consistent with the existing empirical findings, while others are potentially testable in future research. Below we talk in detail about model implications from several aspects. 6.1 Length of the investment period Our model suggests that the length of the investment period can potentially vary with the project characteristics. However, given the fact that PE funds typically invest in projects with high profitability potential, our result implies that PE funds may contractually define a relatively long investment period in practice. This is consistent with the evidence in Giot, Hege, and Schwienbacher (2014) that, although PE funds usually specify the first 5 years as the investment period, about 60% of all PE investments are made within the first 2 years and about 80% within the first 3 years, which suggests that PE funds are able to build their portfolio relatively quickly and the 5-year constraint does not seem to be binding in most cases. 6.2 Capping late investments Degeorge, Martin, and Phalippou (2013) find that the SBOs made in the late phase of the investment period of a PE fund not only underperform the SBOs made in the early phase but have negative NPVs on average. They thus suggest that LPs might benefit from capping the percentage of a fund that the GP may invest in late SBOs. The effect of capping the late investments is similar to the effect of shortening the investment period in our model: they both restrict the GP s ability to base investment decisions on the fund s cumulative performance. To evaluate its effect on investment efficiency, we have to take into account both its direct effect on the GP s late investment behavior and its indirect effect on the GP s early investment behavior. Our result suggests that, if a PE fund caps the late investments without sufficiently capping the GP s upside sharing, the agency problem can be exacerbated: knowing that the late investments are capped, the GP, with a considerable share in the upside, bets more heavily on the upside in the early phase of the investment period and he may undertake more bad deals in total. Thus, to design the socially optimal contract, GP compensation and late investment restriction must be considered jointly and, when project profitability potential is sufficiently large, concavifying GP compensation by, for example, introducing a GP s Carried Interest 20

Dry powder and short fuses: Private equity funds in emerging markets

Dry powder and short fuses: Private equity funds in emerging markets Dry powder and short fuses: Private equity funds in emerging markets Dawei Fang Department of Economics, University of Gothenburg 31 st July, 2015 Abstract: Private equity (PE) investors in emerging markets

More information

A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds

A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds Dawei Fang Centre for Finance, Gothenburg University Abstract: We take a portfolio approach, based on simple agency conflicts between

More information

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Online Appendix for Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Giacomo Rodano Bank of Italy Nicolas Serrano-Velarde Bocconi University December 23, 2014 Emanuele Tarantino University of Mannheim 1 1 Reorganization,

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

Macroprudential Bank Capital Regulation in a Competitive Financial System

Macroprudential Bank Capital Regulation in a Competitive Financial System Macroprudential Bank Capital Regulation in a Competitive Financial System Milton Harris, Christian Opp, Marcus Opp Chicago, UPenn, University of California Fall 2015 H 2 O (Chicago, UPenn, UC) Macroprudential

More information

Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics

Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics Fisher College of Business Working Paper Series Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics Why are Buyouts Levered? The Financial Structure of Private Equity Funds Ulf Axelson, Stockholm

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

Why are Buyouts Levered? The Financial Structure of Private Equity Funds

Why are Buyouts Levered? The Financial Structure of Private Equity Funds Paper 2 of 2 USC FBE FINANCE SEMINAR presented by MIchael Weisbach FRIDAY, October 12, 2007 10:30 am 12:00 pm, Room: JKP-202 Why are Buyouts Levered? The Financial Structure of Private Equity Funds Ulf

More information

Basic Assumptions (1)

Basic Assumptions (1) Basic Assumptions (1) An entrepreneur (borrower). An investment project requiring fixed investment I. The entrepreneur has cash on hand (or liquid securities) A < I. To implement the project the entrepreneur

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

ADVERSE SELECTION PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE. 1. Introduction

ADVERSE SELECTION PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE. 1. Introduction PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE LECTURE 2 LECTURER: DR. KUMAR ANIKET Abstract. We explore adverse selection models in the microfinance literature. The traditional market failure of under and over investment

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

Monetary Economics. Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable)

Monetary Economics. Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable) Monetary Economics Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one Chris Edmond 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable) 1 This lecture Main reading: Holmström and Tirole, Inside and outside liquidity, MIT

More information

Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives. Alan V. S. Douglas

Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives. Alan V. S. Douglas Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives by Alan V. S. Douglas JEL classification codes: G3, D82. Keywords: Capital structure, Optimal Compensation, Manager-Owner and Shareholder-

More information

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Corporate Control Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Managerial Discipline and Takeovers Managers often don t maximize the value of the firm; either because they are not capable

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure Corporate Financial Management Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure As we discussed in previous lectures, two extreme results, namely the irrelevance of capital structure and 100 percent

More information

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser. University of Konstanz Department of Economics Optimal Contracting with Reciprocal Agents in a Competitive Search Model Maria Breitwieser Working Paper Series 2015-16 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/econdoc/working-paper-series/

More information

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Juyan Zhang and Yi Zhang February 20, 2011 Abstract We investigate hold-up in the case of both simultaneous and sequential investment. We show that if

More information

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Juyan Zhang and Yi Zhang December 20, 2010 Abstract We investigate hold-up with simultaneous and sequential investment. We show that if the encouragement

More information

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Ahmer Tarar Department of Political Science Texas A&M University 4348 TAMU College Station, TX 77843-4348 email: ahmertarar@pols.tamu.edu

More information

Auctions in the wild: Bidding with securities. Abhay Aneja & Laura Boudreau PHDBA 279B 1/30/14

Auctions in the wild: Bidding with securities. Abhay Aneja & Laura Boudreau PHDBA 279B 1/30/14 Auctions in the wild: Bidding with securities Abhay Aneja & Laura Boudreau PHDBA 279B 1/30/14 Structure of presentation Brief introduction to auction theory First- and second-price auctions Revenue Equivalence

More information

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Evaluating Strategic Forecasters Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Motivation Forecasters are sought after in a variety of

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance (Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha Department of Economics UC Davis Part 6. Lending Relationships and Investor Activism V. F. Martins-da-Rocha (UC Davis) Corporate

More information

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector Bengt Holmstrom and Jean Tirole April 3, 2017 Holmstrom and Tirole Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector April 3, 2017

More information

Rural Financial Intermediaries

Rural Financial Intermediaries Rural Financial Intermediaries 1. Limited Liability, Collateral and Its Substitutes 1 A striking empirical fact about the operation of rural financial markets is how markedly the conditions of access can

More information

Incentives for Innovation and Delegated versus Centralized Capital Budgeting

Incentives for Innovation and Delegated versus Centralized Capital Budgeting Incentives for Innovation and Delegated versus Centralized Capital Budgeting Sunil Dutta Qintao Fan Abstract This paper investigates how the allocation of investment decision authority affects managers

More information

Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness

Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness James Dow Itay Goldstein Alexander Guembel London Business University of University of Oxford School Pennsylvania European Central Bank, 15-16 May, 2006

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Chapter 7 Moral Hazard: Hidden Actions

Chapter 7 Moral Hazard: Hidden Actions Chapter 7 Moral Hazard: Hidden Actions 7.1 Categories of Asymmetric Information Models We will make heavy use of the principal-agent model. ð The principal hires an agent to perform a task, and the agent

More information

Bargaining and exclusivity in a borrower lender relationship

Bargaining and exclusivity in a borrower lender relationship Rev. Econ. Design DOI 10.1007/s10058-007-0024-5 ORIGINAL PAPER Bargaining and exclusivity in a borrower lender relationship Levent Koçkesen Saltuk Ozerturk Received: 3 November 2004 / Accepted: 29 November

More information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Topic 5: Information Economics 21, Summer 2002 Andreas Bentz Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Introduction

More information

The role of asymmetric information

The role of asymmetric information LECTURE NOTES ON CREDIT MARKETS The role of asymmetric information Eliana La Ferrara - 2007 Credit markets are typically a ected by asymmetric information problems i.e. one party is more informed than

More information

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam Summer 2018 Microeconomics Qualifying Exam There are 100 points possible on this exam, 50 points each for Prof. Lozada s questions and Prof. Dugar s questions. Each professor asks you to do two long questions

More information

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Junfeng Qiu Central University of Finance and Economics

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Junfeng Qiu Central University of Finance and Economics QED Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No. 1317 Central Bank Screening, Moral Hazard, and the Lender of Last Resort Policy Mei Li University of Guelph Frank Milne Queen s University Junfeng Qiu

More information

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment Suehyun Kwon CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 6280 CATEGORY 12: EMPIRICAL AND THEORETICAL METHODS DECEMBER 2016 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded

More information

Persuasion in Global Games with Application to Stress Testing. Supplement

Persuasion in Global Games with Application to Stress Testing. Supplement Persuasion in Global Games with Application to Stress Testing Supplement Nicolas Inostroza Northwestern University Alessandro Pavan Northwestern University and CEPR January 24, 208 Abstract This document

More information

Expensive than Deposits? Preliminary draft

Expensive than Deposits? Preliminary draft Bank Capital Structure Relevance: is Bank Equity more Expensive than Deposits? Swarnava Biswas Kostas Koufopoulos Preliminary draft May 15, 2013 Abstract We propose a model of optimal bank capital structure.

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information. Appendix

Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information. Appendix Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information Ilan Lobel Appendix Wenqiang iao {ilobel, wxiao}@stern.nyu.edu Stern School of Business, New York University Appendix A: Proofs Proof

More information

SCREENING BY THE COMPANY YOU KEEP: JOINT LIABILITY LENDING AND THE PEER SELECTION EFFECT

SCREENING BY THE COMPANY YOU KEEP: JOINT LIABILITY LENDING AND THE PEER SELECTION EFFECT SCREENING BY THE COMPANY YOU KEEP: JOINT LIABILITY LENDING AND THE PEER SELECTION EFFECT Author: Maitreesh Ghatak Presented by: Kosha Modi February 16, 2017 Introduction In an economic environment where

More information

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I April 2005 PREPARING FOR THE EXAM What models do you need to study? All the models we studied

More information

Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending?

Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending? Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending? Christian Ahlin Michigan State University Brian Waters UCLA Anderson Minn Fed/BREAD, October 2012

More information

Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard with Multidimensional Types

Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard with Multidimensional Types 6631 2017 August 2017 Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard with Multidimensional Types Suehyun Kwon Impressum: CESifo Working Papers ISSN 2364 1428 (electronic version) Publisher and distributor: Munich

More information

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A.

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. THE INVISIBLE HAND OF PIRACY: AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE INFORMATION-GOODS SUPPLY CHAIN Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. {antino@iu.edu}

More information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information - preliminary and incomplete, please do not cite - Working Paper R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information Andreas Frick Heidrun C. Hoppe-Wewetzer Georgios Katsenos June 28, 2016 Abstract

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

Liquidity saving mechanisms

Liquidity saving mechanisms Liquidity saving mechanisms Antoine Martin and James McAndrews Federal Reserve Bank of New York September 2006 Abstract We study the incentives of participants in a real-time gross settlement with and

More information

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983)

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983) BANKING AND FINANCIAL FRAGILITY A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983) Professor Todd Keister Rutgers University May 2017 Objective Want to develop a model to help us understand: why banks and other

More information

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard December 5, 2012 Question 1 (Comparative Performance Evaluation) Consider the same normal linear model as in Question 1 of Homework 1. This time the principal employs

More information

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Chapter 5 Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Until now we implicitly adopted a view that a Nash equilibrium is a desirable outcome of a strategic game. In this chapter we consider two alternative

More information

An optimal board system : supervisory board vs. management board

An optimal board system : supervisory board vs. management board An optimal board system : supervisory board vs. management board Tomohiko Yano Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo January 10, 2006 Abstract We examine relative effectiveness of two kinds

More information

Development Economics 455 Prof. Karaivanov

Development Economics 455 Prof. Karaivanov Development Economics 455 Prof. Karaivanov Notes on Credit Markets in Developing Countries Introduction ------------------ credit markets intermediation between savers and borrowers: o many economic activities

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Private Information and Bargaining Power in Venture Capital Financing

Private Information and Bargaining Power in Venture Capital Financing University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Finance Papers Wharton Faculty Research 10-25-2014 Private Information and Bargaining Power in Venture Capital Financing Yrjo Koskinen University of Pennsylvania

More information

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma RESEARCH ARTICLE A MODEL OF COMPETITION BETWEEN PERPETUAL SOFTWARE AND SOFTWARE AS A SERVICE Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma School of Information Systems, Singapore Management University, 80 Stanford Road, Singapore

More information

MORAL HAZARD PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE

MORAL HAZARD PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE LECTURE 3 LECTURER: DR. KUMAR ANIKET Abstract. Ex ante moral hazard emanates from broadly two types of borrower s actions, project choice and effort choice. In loan contracts,

More information

Up-front payment under RD rule

Up-front payment under RD rule Rev. Econ. Design 9, 1 10 (2004) DOI: 10.1007/s10058-004-0116-4 c Springer-Verlag 2004 Up-front payment under RD rule Ho-Chyuan Chen Department of Financial Operations, National Kaohsiung First University

More information

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility and Coordination Failures What makes financial systems fragile? What causes crises

More information

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE81.98 School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology January Semester Presented by Dr. Thitisak Boonpramote Department

More information

Peer monitoring and moral hazard in underdeveloped credit markets. Shubhashis Gangopadhyay* and Robert Lensink**

Peer monitoring and moral hazard in underdeveloped credit markets. Shubhashis Gangopadhyay* and Robert Lensink** eer monitoring and moral hazard in underdeveloped credit markets. Shubhashis angopadhyay* and Robert ensink** *ndia Development Foundation, ndia. **Faculty of Economics, University of roningen, The Netherlands.

More information

Principles of Banking (II): Microeconomics of Banking (3) Bank Capital

Principles of Banking (II): Microeconomics of Banking (3) Bank Capital Principles of Banking (II): Microeconomics of Banking (3) Bank Capital Jin Cao (Norges Bank Research, Oslo & CESifo, München) Outline 1 2 3 Disclaimer (If they care about what I say,) the views expressed

More information

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk Chapter 23: Choice under Risk 23.1: Introduction We consider in this chapter optimal behaviour in conditions of risk. By this we mean that, when the individual takes a decision, he or she does not know

More information

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński Decision Making in Manufacturing and Services Vol. 9 2015 No. 1 pp. 79 88 Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment Andrzej Paliński Abstract. This paper presents a model of bank-loan repayment as

More information

Public-Private Partnerships and Contract Regulation

Public-Private Partnerships and Contract Regulation Public-Private Partnerships and Contract Regulation Jorge G. Montecinos and Flavio M. Menezes The University of Queensland, School of Economics April, 2012 Abstract: This paper explores some underlying

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 9 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3 Consider now a different cause for the failure of the Coase Theorem: the presence of transaction costs. Of course for this to be an interesting

More information

Moral Hazard. Economics Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior. Instructor: Songzi Du

Moral Hazard. Economics Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior. Instructor: Songzi Du Moral Hazard Economics 302 - Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior Instructor: Songzi Du compiled by Shih En Lu (Chapter 25 in Watson (2013)) Simon Fraser University July 9, 2018 ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture

More information

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation Afrasiab Mirza Department of Economics University of Birmingham a.mirza@bham.ac.uk Frank Strobel Department of Economics University of Birmingham f.strobel@bham.ac.uk

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations? Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 7, 0. Consider an individual faced with two job choices: she can either accept a position with a fixed annual salary of x > 0 which requires L x units of labor

More information

Cooperation and Rent Extraction in Repeated Interaction

Cooperation and Rent Extraction in Repeated Interaction Supplementary Online Appendix to Cooperation and Rent Extraction in Repeated Interaction Tobias Cagala, Ulrich Glogowsky, Veronika Grimm, Johannes Rincke July 29, 2016 Cagala: University of Erlangen-Nuremberg

More information

Where do securities come from

Where do securities come from Where do securities come from We view it as natural to trade common stocks WHY? Coase s policemen Pricing Assumptions on market trading? Predictions? Partial Equilibrium or GE economies (risk spanning)

More information

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM Course content Why do firms exist? And why do some firms cease to exist? How are firms financed? How are firms managed? These questions are analysed by using various models

More information

Competition and risk taking in a differentiated banking sector

Competition and risk taking in a differentiated banking sector Competition and risk taking in a differentiated banking sector Martín Basurto Arriaga Tippie College of Business, University of Iowa Iowa City, IA 54-1994 Kaniṣka Dam Centro de Investigación y Docencia

More information

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW. Contracts. I.1 Bargain Theory. I.2 Damages Part 1. I.3 Reliance

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW. Contracts. I.1 Bargain Theory. I.2 Damages Part 1. I.3 Reliance ECON 522 - DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW I Contracts When we were studying property law we were looking at situations in which the exchange of goods/services takes place at the time of trade, but sometimes

More information

Angels, Venture Capitalists, and Entrepreneurs: A Dynamic Model of Private Equity Financing

Angels, Venture Capitalists, and Entrepreneurs: A Dynamic Model of Private Equity Financing Angels, Venture Capitalists, and Entrepreneurs: A Dynamic Model of Private Equity Financing Thomas J Chemmanur* and Zhaohui Chen** Oct., 31, 2001 *Finance department, Carroll school of management, Boston

More information

The Role of the Value Added by the Venture Capitalists in Timing and Extent of IPOs

The Role of the Value Added by the Venture Capitalists in Timing and Extent of IPOs No. 2003/25 The Role of the Value Added by the Venture Capitalists in Timing and Extent of IPOs Tereza Tykvová Center for Financial Studies an der Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universität Taunusanlage 6 D-60329

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control (Preliminary and incomplete)

Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control (Preliminary and incomplete) Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control (Preliminary and incomplete) Cristian M. Litan Sorina C. Vâju October 29, 2007 Abstract We provide a model of strategic

More information

Fire sales, inefficient banking and liquidity ratios

Fire sales, inefficient banking and liquidity ratios Fire sales, inefficient banking and liquidity ratios Axelle Arquié September 1, 215 [Link to the latest version] Abstract In a Diamond and Dybvig setting, I introduce a choice by households between the

More information

Advanced Financial Economics 2 Financial Contracting

Advanced Financial Economics 2 Financial Contracting Advanced Financial Economics 2 Financial Contracting Prof. Dr. Roman Inderst Part 3 1 / 49 Liquidity, Free Cash Flow, and Risk Management 2 / 49 Main Questions Why do some firms hold liquid assets and

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

Volume 29, Issue 3. The Effect of Project Types and Technologies on Software Developers' Efforts

Volume 29, Issue 3. The Effect of Project Types and Technologies on Software Developers' Efforts Volume 9, Issue 3 The Effect of Project Types and Technologies on Software Developers' Efforts Byung Cho Kim Pamplin College of Business, Virginia Tech Dongryul Lee Department of Economics, Virginia Tech

More information

Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective

Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective Olivier Compte and Philippe Jehiel November 2003 Abstract A principal has to choose among several agents to fulfill a task and then provide

More information

Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring.

Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring. Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring. Olivier Compte First Version: June 2001 This Version: November 2003 Abstract In principal-agent relationships, a termination threat is often thought

More information

Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital

Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital Hung-Chia Hsu, Vikram Nanda, Qinghai Wang November, 2016 Abstract We study venture capital investment decision within and across successive VC funds

More information

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory Exercises Solutions: Game Theory Exercise. (U, R).. (U, L) and (D, R). 3. (D, R). 4. (U, L) and (D, R). 5. First, eliminate R as it is strictly dominated by M for player. Second, eliminate M as it is strictly

More information

Academic Editor: Emiliano A. Valdez, Albert Cohen and Nick Costanzino

Academic Editor: Emiliano A. Valdez, Albert Cohen and Nick Costanzino Risks 2015, 3, 543-552; doi:10.3390/risks3040543 Article Production Flexibility and Hedging OPEN ACCESS risks ISSN 2227-9091 www.mdpi.com/journal/risks Georges Dionne 1, * and Marc Santugini 2 1 Department

More information

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations Leslie M. Marx Duke University Greg Shaffer University of Rochester December 2006 Abstract When two sellers negotiate terms of trade with a common buyer, the

More information

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Davit Khantadze September 30, 017 Abstract We are interested in optimal signals for the sender when the decision maker (receiver) has to make two separate decisions.

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008 Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008 There are two questions on the exam, representing Asset Pricing (236D = 234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 26 January 2015 Failure of the Coase Theorem Recall that the Coase Theorem implies that two parties, when faced with a potential

More information

Short-term, Long-term, and Continuing Contracts

Short-term, Long-term, and Continuing Contracts Short-term, Long-term, and Continuing Contracts Maija Halonen-Akatwijuka and Oliver Hart Essex University, 12 June 2015 1 A large literature in economics and law has studied why parties write long-term

More information

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Two Period Exchange Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 2 1 Two Period Exchange Economy We shall start our exploration of dynamic economies with

More information

Public Goods Provision with Rent-Extracting Administrators

Public Goods Provision with Rent-Extracting Administrators Supplementary Online Appendix to Public Goods Provision with Rent-Extracting Administrators Tobias Cagala, Ulrich Glogowsky, Veronika Grimm, Johannes Rincke November 27, 2017 Cagala: Deutsche Bundesbank

More information

Up till now, we ve mostly been analyzing auctions under the following assumptions:

Up till now, we ve mostly been analyzing auctions under the following assumptions: Econ 805 Advanced Micro Theory I Dan Quint Fall 2007 Lecture 7 Sept 27 2007 Tuesday: Amit Gandhi on empirical auction stuff p till now, we ve mostly been analyzing auctions under the following assumptions:

More information

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening NMI Workshop, ISI Delhi August 3, 2015 Motivation A seller wants to sell an object to a prospective buyer(s). Buyer has imperfect private information θ about

More information

The Optimality of Being Efficient. Lawrence Ausubel and Peter Cramton Department of Economics University of Maryland

The Optimality of Being Efficient. Lawrence Ausubel and Peter Cramton Department of Economics University of Maryland The Optimality of Being Efficient Lawrence Ausubel and Peter Cramton Department of Economics University of Maryland 1 Common Reaction Why worry about efficiency, when there is resale? Our Conclusion Why

More information

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model ECON 4335 Economics of Banking, Fall 2016 Jacopo Bizzotto 1 Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model The model in Diamond and Dybvig (1983) incorporates important features of the real world:

More information