A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model"

Transcription

1 A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model Lars-Alexander Kuehn Tepper School of Business Carnegie Mellon University Jessie Jiaxu Wang Tepper School of Business Carnegie Mellon University Mikhail Simutin Rotman School of Management University of Toronto February 11, 2013 ABSTRACT We show that labor search frictions are an important determinant of the cross section of equity returns. In the data, sorting firms based on their loading on labor market tightness, the key statistic of search models, generates a spread in future returns of 6% annually. We propose a partial equilibrium labor market model in which heterogeneous firms make optimal employment decisions under labor search frictions. In the model, loadings on labor market tightness proxy for priced time variation in the labor force participation rate. Firms with low factor loadings are not hedged against adverse labor force shocks and thus require higher expected stock returns. JEL Classification: E24, G12, J21 Keywords: Cross sectional asset pricing, labor search frictions, labor force participation, labor market tightness. We thank Brent Glover, Burton Hollifield, Finn Kydland, Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau, Chris Telmer, Ping Yan, Lu Zhang; conference participants of the 2012 Western Economic Association Annual Conference, 2012 Midwest Macroeconomics Meetings and seminar participants at CMU, Goethe Universität Frankfurt, ESMT, and Humboldt Universität Berlin for helpful comments. Contact information, Kuehn: 5000 Forbes Avenue, Pittsburgh, PA 15213, kuehn@cmu.edu; Simutin: 105 St. George Street, Toronto ON, M5S 3E6, mikhail.simutin@rotman.utoronto.ca; Wang: 5000 Forbes Avenue, Pittsburgh, PA 15213, jiaxuwang@cmu.edu

2 I. Introduction Dynamics in the labor market are an integral component of business cycles. More than 10 percent of U.S. workers separate from their employers each quarter. Some move directly to a new job with a different employer, some become unemployed and some exit the labor force. These large flows, however, are very costly for firms because they need to spend time and resources to search for new employees. 1 Building on the seminal contributions of Diamond (1982), Mortensen (1972, 1982), and Pissarides (1985, 2000), we show that labor search frictions are an important determinant of the cross-section of equity returns. 2 In search models, firms post vacancies looking for workers, and unemployed workers search for jobs. The likelihood of matching a worker with a vacant job is determined endogenously and depends on the congestion of the labor market which is measured as ratio of vacant positions to unemployed workers. This ratio is usually referred to as labor market tightness and is the key variable of our analysis. We begin by studying the empirical relation between labor market conditions and the cross section of equity returns. To construct aggregate labor market tightness, we compute the ratio of the monthly vacancy index from the Conference Board to the unemployed population. Rather than using the unemployment rate as a proxy for the unemployed population, 3 we normalize employment by the total population, thereby correcting for time variation in the labor force participation rate as reported by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consistent with the empirical exercise, shocks to the labor force participation rate are a key driver of the model. To measure the sensitivity of firm value to labor market conditions, we estimate loadings of equity returns with respect to log changes in labor market tightness controlling for the 1 These search costs arise because of heterogeneity among workers and jobs and information imperfections. Davis, Faberman, and Haltiwanger (2006) document that the average duration for a job position being vacant ranges from 14 to 25 days. According to the U.S. Department of Labor, it costs one-third of a new hire s annual salary to replace them. Direct costs include advertising, sign on bonuses, headhunter fees and overtime. Indirect costs include recruitment, selection and training and decreased productivity while current employees pick up the slack. (Advance Online) 2 The importance of labor market dynamics for the business cycle has long been recognized (e.g., Merz (1995) and Andolfatto (1996)). 3 See for instance Shimer (2005) and Hornstein, Krusell, and Violantel (2005). 1

3 market return. We use rolling regressions based on three years of monthly data to allow for time variation in the loadings. Using the panel of US stock returns over the 1954 to 2009 period, we show that the loadings on the changes in the labor market tightness robustly and negatively relate to future stock returns in the cross section. Sorting stocks into deciles on the basis of the estimated loadings, we find an average return spread between firms in the lowand high-loading portfolios of 6% per year. This difference cannot be explained by commonly considered asset pricing models, for example, the Fama and French (1993) three-factor model. Portfolio sorts are potentially problematic as such univariate analysis fails to account for other firm characteristics that have been shown to relate to future returns. To ensure that the relation between labor search frictions and future stock returns is not attributable to such characteristics, we also run Fama and MacBeth (1973) regressions of annual stock returns on the estimated loadings and other firm attributes. We include conventionally used control variables such as a firm s market capitalization and recently documented determinants of the cross-section of stock returns that may potentially correlate with the estimated loadings, such as new hiring rates of Bazdresch, Belo, and Lin (2012). The Fama-MacBeth analysis confirms the robustness of results obtained in simple portfolio sorts. The coefficients of the labor market tightness loadings are negative and statistically significant in all regression specifications. The magnitude of the coefficients suggests that the relation is economically important: for each one standard deviation increase in the loading, subsequent annual returns decline by approximately 1.4%. To interpret the empirical findings, we propose a labor augmented capital asset pricing model. We build a partial equilibrium labor market model and study its implications for firm employment policies and stock returns. For tractability we do not model the supply of labor as optimal households decisions, instead we assume an exogenous pricing kernel. Our model features a cross section of firms with heterogeneity in their idiosyncratic shocks and employment levels, extending the representative firm framework in Pissarides (1985) and Mortensen and Pissarides (1994). Firms maximize their value either by posting vacancies to recruit workers or by firing workers to downsize. Both firm policies are costly at proportional 2

4 rates. In our model, the fraction of successfully filled vacancies depends on labor market tightness which results from the aggregation of firms vacancy policies. As such, equilibrium in the labor market requires that firm hiring policies are consistent with the implied labor market tightness. This imperfect labor market matching creates rents in equilibrium which are shared between each firm and its workforce according to a collective Nash Bargaining wage rate. Our model is driven by two aggregate shocks, both of which are priced. The first shock is an aggregate productivity shock which proxies for the market return. The second shock is a shock to the mass of workers which we interpret as labor market participation shock. A positive labor market participation shock reduces the congestion of the labor market as there are more unemployed workers looking for jobs. As a result, posting vacancies to hire workers becomes more attractive for firms. Quantitatively, our model replicates the negative relation between loadings on labor market tightness and future returns. As an equilibrium outcome of the labor market, labor market tightness is negatively related to labor market participation shocks. Consequently, firms with low labor market tightness loadings are very sensitive to labor market conditions arising from labor force participation shocks. After an adverse labor force participation shock, these firms face higher average recruiting costs as the labor market becomes more congested. As a result, these firms are riskier and require higher risk premia as their cash flows are not hedged against adverse labor force shocks. To solve the model numerically we follow the idea of approximate aggregation introduced in Krusell and Smith (1998). We approximate the firm level distribution with labor market tightness which is a sufficient statistic to solve the firm s problem. Its dynamics are approximated with a log-linear functional form. The application of Krusell and Smith (1998) here differs from Zhang (2005) in an important way. Zhang (2005) assumes that firms can perfectly forecast the next period s industry equilibrium given the current information set. In contrast, we assume that future labor market tightness is stochastic and firms form rational expectations about it. This modeling assumption is consistent with our empirical evidence 3

5 that stock return loadings with respect to labor market tightness affect valuations. Our paper builds on the production based asset pricing literature started by Cochrane (1991) and Jermann (1998). Pioneered by Berk, Green, and Naik (1999), there exists now a large literature studying cross sectional asset pricing implications of firm real investment decisions, for instance, Gomes, Kogan, and Zhang (2003), Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino (2004), Zhang (2005), and Cooper (2006). More closely related are Papanikolaou (2011), and Kogan and Papanikolaou (2012a,b) who highlight that investment specific shocks are related to firm risk premia. We differ by studying frictions on the labor market and specifically shocks to the labor force. The impact of labor market frictions on the aggregate stock market has been analyzed by Danthine and Donaldson (2002), Merz and Yashiv (2007), and Kuehn, Petrosky-Nadeau, and Zhang (2012). Along this line, there also exist recent papers linking cross-sectional asset prices to labor related firm characteristics. Gourio (2007), Chen, Kacperczyk, and Ortiz- Molina (2011) and Favilukis and Lin (2012) consider labor operating leverage coming from rigid wages, Donangelo (2012) focuses on labor mobilities, Eisfeldt and Papanikolaou (2012) study organizational capital embedded in specialized labor input, and Bazdresch, Belo, and Lin (2012) analyze convex labor adjustment costs. We differ by exploring the impact of search costs on cross sectional asset prices. II. Empirical Results In this section, we document a robust negative relation between the stock return correlations with changes in labor market conditions and future equity returns. We establish this result by studying portfolios sorted by loadings on the labor market tightness factor and confirm it using Fama and MacBeth (1973) regressions. We also show that loadings on the factor explain average industry returns. A. Data Our sample includes all common stocks (share code of 10 or 11) listed on NYSE, AMEX, and Nasdaq (exchange code of 1, 2, or 3) available from CRSP. To obtain meaningful risk 4

6 loadings at the end of month t, we require each stock to have non-missing returns in at least 24 of the last 36 months (t 35 to t). Availability of data on vacancy and unemployment rates restricts our tests based on portfolio sorts to the period. Fama-MacBeth regressions additionally require Compustat data on book equity and other firm attributes, and consequently analysis based on those data is conducted for the sample. In the Appendix we list the exact formulas for all of the firm characteristics used in our tests. B. Labor Market Tightness Factor We obtain the monthly vacancy index from the Conference Board and the monthly labor force participation and unemployment rate from the Current Population Survey of the Bureau of Labor Statistics. 4 We define labor market tightness as the ratio of total vacancy postings to total unemployed workers. The total number of unemployed workers is the product of unemployment rate and labor force participation rate (LFPR). Hence labor market tightness is given by θ t = Vacancy Index t Unemployment Rate t LFPR t. (1) Figure 1 plots the monthly time series of θ t and its components. Labor market tightness is strongly procyclical and autocorrelated as in Shimer (2005). We define the labor market tightness factor in month t as the change in logs of this ratio: ϑ t = log(θ t ) log(θ t 1 ). (2) The time series properties of ϑ t, its components and other macro variables are summarized in Table 1. Despite being a highly procyclical factor, ϑ t does not strongly comove with other monthly macro factors that are known to have non-zero prices of risk, such as dividend yield, term spread, default spread, change in the consumer price index, and change in industrial production. 4 The respective websites are and Help Wanted Advertising Index was discontinued in October 2008 and replaced with the Conference Board Help Wanted OnLine index. We concatenate the two time series to obtain the vacancy index. The index is not available after 2009 as the Conference Board replaced it with the actual number of online advertised vacancies. 5

7 To study the relation between stock return loadings on changes in labor market tightness and future equity returns, we first estimate loadings β θ i,τ on the ϑ factor for each stock i at the end of each month τ from rolling two-factor model regressions R i,t R f,t = α i,τ + β M i,τ (R M,t R f,t ) + β θ i,τ ϑ t + ε i,t, (3) where R f,t is the risk-free rate of return, and R i,t and R M,t are stock i and market excess returns in month t {τ 35, τ}. Figure 2 plots the time series of cross-sectional average, median, and other percentiles of the loadings on the labor market tightness factor, highlighting wide cross-sectional differences in the computed loadings. We now turn to exploring whether these loadings have significant predictive power for stock returns. C. Evidence from Portfolio Sorts At the end of each month τ, we rank stocks into deciles on the basis of loadings on the labor market tightness factor β θ i,τ computed from regressions (3). We skip a month to allow information on the vacancy and unemployment rates to become publicly available and hold the resulting ten value-weighted portfolios without rebalancing for one year (τ + 2 through τ + 13, inclusive). Consequently, in month τ each decile portfolio contains stocks that were added to that decile at the end of months τ 13 through τ 2. This design is similar to the approach used to construct momentum portfolios and ensures that noise due to seasonalities is reduced. We show robustness to alternative portfolio formation methods in the next section. Table 2 presents average firm characteristics of the resulting decile portfolios. No strong relation emerges between loadings on the labor market tightness factor and any of the considered characteristics. Firms in the high decile are on average somewhat smaller than those in the low group, but the relation is not monotonic. Median characteristics are qualitatively similar to the reported averages and are omitted for brevity. For each decile portfolio, we obtain monthly time series of returns from January 1954 until December Table 3 summarizes raw returns of each decile and of the portfolio that is long the decile with low loadings on the labor market tightness factor and short the group with high loadings. Table 3 also shows loadings on market, value, size, and momentum factors 6

8 of each group. Firms in the high decile have somewhat larger size betas and lower value and momentum loadings. To account for differences in risk across the deciles, we also present alphas from market, Fama and French (1993), and Carhart (1997) models. Both raw and risk-adjusted returns of the ten portfolios indicate a strong negative relation between loadings on the labor market tightness factor and future stock performance. Firms in the low β θ decile earn the highest average return, 1.14% monthly, whereas the high beta group performs most poorly, generating on average just 0.64% per month. The difference in performance of the two deciles, at 0.50%, is economically large and statistically significant (t-statistic of 3.60). The corresponding differences in alphas are similarly striking, ranging from 0.43% (t-statistic of 3.06) for Carhart four-factor alphas to 0.55% (t-statistic of 3.95) for market model alphas. Results of portfolio sorts thus strongly suggest that the loadings on the labor market tightness factor are an important predictor of future returns. To evaluate robustness of this relation over time, Panel A of Figure 3 plots cumulative returns of the portfolio that is long the low decile and short the high group. The cumulative return is steadily increasing throughout the sample period, indicating that the relation between the loadings on the labor market tightness factor and future stock returns persists over time. Table 4 presents summary statistics for returns on this portfolio and for market, value, size, and momentum factors. The long-short labor market tightness factor portfolio is less volatile than the market or the momentum factors (see also Panel B of Figure 3) and achieves a Sharpe ratio (0.14) comparable to that of the value factor. D. Evidence from Portfolio Sorts: Robustness We now demonstrate robustness of the relation between stock return loadings on changes in labor market tightness and future equity returns to considering alternative portfolio formation approaches, excluding micro cap stocks, and using a modified definition of labor market tightness factor. Table 5 summarizes the results of the robustness tests. Portfolio formation design employed in the previous section is motivated by investment strategies such as momentum studied the prior literature. It involves holding 12 overlapping 7

9 portfolios and ensures that noise due to seasonalities is reduced. We consider two alternatives: forming portfolios only once a year and holding the portfolios for one month. Both alternatives ensure that no portfolios overlap. Panels A and B of Table 5 show that each of these approaches results in even more dramatic difference in future performance of low and high β θ deciles. For example, the difference in average returns of the low and high groups reaches 0.62% monthly when portfolios are formed once a year, compared to 0.50% reported in Table 3. We next explore the sensitivity of the results to the length of time between calculation of β θ and beginning of the holding period. Our base case results in Table 3 are obtained assuming a one-month interval to ensure that all the variables needed to compute labor market tightness (vacancy index, unemployment rate, and labor force participation rate) are publicly available. The assumption is well-justified in the current markets, where the data for any month are typically available within days after the end of that month. To allow for a slower dissemination of data in the earlier sample, we consider a two-month period. Panel C of Table 5 shows that the results are not sensitive to this change in the methodology: The difference in future returns of stocks with low and high loadings on the labor market tightness factor reaches 0.49% per month. Panel D of Table 5 shows that the results are also robust to excluding microcaps, which we define to include stocks with market equity below the 20th NYSE percentile. Microcaps on average represent just 3% of the total market capitalization of all stocks listed on NYSE, Amex, and Nasdaq, but they account for about 60% of the total number of stocks. Excluding these stocks from the sample does not impact the results. 5 We also consider robustness to an alternative definition of labor market tightness factor. Table 1 shows that ϑ t as defined in equation (2) is correlated with changes in industrial production and other macro variables. To ensure that the relation between stock return loadings on the labor market tightness factor and future equity returns is not driven by these 5 Untabulated results also confirm robustness of the results to imposing a minimum price filter and to excluding Nasdaq-listed stocks. 8

10 variables, we define labor market tightness as the residual ϑ t from a time series regression ϑ t = γ 0 + γ 1 IP t + γ 2 CP I t + γ 3 DY t + γ 4 T B t + γ 5 T S t + γ 6 DS t + ϑ t, (4) where IP t, CP I t, DY t, T B t, T S t, and DS t are changes in industrial production, consumer price index, dividend yield, T-bill rate, term spread, and default spread, respectively. The disadvantage of this approach is that it introduces a look-ahead bias as the regression coefficients are estimated using the entire sample. Yet, it allows us to focus on the component of labor market tightness that is unrelated to other macro variables that can have non-zero prices of risk. Panel E of Table 5 shows that our results are little affected by the change in the definition of the labor market tightness factor: The difference in future raw and riskadjusted returns of portfolios with low and high loadings on the factor are always statistically significant and economically meaningful, ranging between 0.42% and 0.46% monthly. Finally, we also evaluate the relation between loadings β θ on the labor market tightness factor and future equity returns conditional on stocks market betas β M. We sort firms into quintiles based on their β θ and β M loadings and study subsequent returns of each of the resulting 25 portfolios. Table A1 of the Appendix shows that irrespective of whether we consider independent sorts or dependent sorts (e.g., first on β M and then by β θ within each market beta quintile), stocks with low loadings on the labor market tightness factor significantly outperform stocks with high loadings. E. Evidence from Fama-MacBeth Regressions The empirical evidence from portfolio sorts provides a strong indication of a negative relation between the stock return loadings on changes in labor market tightness, βi,τ θ, and subsequent equity returns. However, such univariate analysis does not account for other firm characteristics that have been shown to relate to future returns. In this section, we compare the loadings on the labor market tightness factor to other well-established determinants of the cross-section of stock returns. Our goal is to determine whether the ability of β θ i,τ to forecast returns is subsumed by other firm characteristics. To this end, we perform annual Fama-MacBeth (1973) 9

11 regressions K R i,t = γt 0 + γt 1 βi,τ θ + γ j T Xj i,t + η i,t, where R i,t is stock i return from July of year T to June of year T + 1, β θ i,τ j=1 is the loading from regressions (3) with τ corresponding to May of year T, and X i,t are K control variables all measured prior to the end of June of year T. The timing of the variables measurement in the regression follows the widely accepted convention as in Fama and French (1992). We include in the Fama-MacBeth regressions commonly considered control variables such as a firm s market capitalization (ME), book-to-market ratio (BM) and return runup (RU) (Fama and French (1992); Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)). We also consider other recently documented determinants of the cross-section of stock returns, including the asset growth rate (AG) of Cooper, Gulen, and Schill (2008) as well as the labor hiring (HN) and investment rates (IK) of Bazdresch, Belo, and Lin (2012). We winsorize all independent variables crosssectionally at 1% and 99%. Table 6 summarizes the results of Fama-MacBeth regressions. The coefficient on β θ is negative and statistically significant in each considered specification, even after accounting for other cross-sectional predictors of equity returns. These results confirm the negative relation between loadings on the labor market tightness factor and future stock returns documented in Table 3. The magnitude of the coefficient implies that for a one standard deviation increase in β θ (0.49), subsequent annual returns decline by approximately 1.5%. Average loadings of firms in the bottom and top deciles portfolios are 3.7 standard deviations apart, suggesting that the difference in future stock returns of the two groups exceeds 5%, in line with the results presented in Table 3. The labor market tightness factor is highly correlated with its components and with changes in industrial production (see Table 1). To ensure that our results are not driven by either of these macro variables, we first estimate loadings β LF P R, β Unemp, β V ac, and β IP from a two-factor regression of stock excess returns on market excess returns and log changes in either labor force participation rate, unemployment rate, vacancy rate, or industrial production, respectively. These loadings are estimated in the same manner as β θ in equation (3). 10

12 We next run Fama-MacBeth regressions of annual stock returns on lagged loadings β LF P R, β Unemp, β V ac, and β IP and on other control variables. Table A2 of the Appendix shows that none of the considered loadings are robustly related to future equity returns, suggesting that the relation between loadings on the labor market tightness factor and future stock returns is not driven by one particular component of the labor market tightness or by changes in industrial production. F. Evidence from Two-Pass Regressions on Industry Portfolio Returns Motivated by the empirical evidence of a strong negative relation between individual stocks loadings on the labor market tightness factor and future equity returns, we now turn to examining the pricing implications of labor market tightness cross-sectionally using 48 industry portfolios. 6 We perform the analysis in two stages. In the first stage, we regress monthly excess returns of each industry i on market excess returns, labor market tightness factor, and (depending on specification) on size, value, and momentum factors: R i,t R f,t = α i + β M i (R M,t R f,t ) + β θ i ϑ t + β HML i HML t + β SMB i SMB t + β UMD i UMD t + ε i,t, In the second stage, we run a cross-sectional regression of industry returns on the loadings estimated in the first stage. Table 7 summarizes the results of the second-stage regressions. Each considered specification shows a significantly negative price of risk for the labor market tightness factor, corroborating our previous findings of a strong negative relation between loadings on the labor market tightness factor and future stock performance. We now turn to understanding this empirical relation by formalizing a model of labor market frictions. III. Model The goal of this section is to provide an economic model which explains the empirical link between labor market frictions and the cross section of equity returns. To this end, we solve a partial equilibrium labor market model and study its implications for stock returns. For 6 We obtain industry returns from Ken French s website. 11

13 tractability we do not model endogenous labor supply decisions from households, instead we assume an exogenous pricing kernel. A. Revenue To focus on labor frictions, we assume that the only input to production is labor. We thus abstract from capital accumulation and investment frictions. Firms generate revenue, Y i,t, according to a decreasing returns to scale production function Y i,t = e xt+zi,t Ni,t, α (5) where α denotes the labor share of production and N i,t is the size of the firm s workforce. Both the aggregate productivity shock x t and the idiosyncratic productivity shocks z i,t follow AR(1) processes x t = ρ x x t 1 + σ x ε x t, (6) z i,t = ρ z z i,t 1 + σ z ε z i,t, (7) where ε x t, ε z i,t are standard normal i.i.d. innovations. Firm-specific shocks are independent across firms, and from aggregate shock. Firm s labor capital is determined in a Kydland and Prescott (1982) time-to-build fashion. Firms can expand the workforce by posting vacancies, V i,t, to attract unemployed workers. The key friction of search markets is that not all the posted vacancies are filled in a given period. Instead, the probability q that vacancies are filled is endogenously determined in equilibrium and depends on the congestion of the labor market denoted by θ t. Once workers and firms are randomly matched, workers either quit voluntarily at a constant rate of s or are fired endogenously by the firm, denoted by F i,t. Taken together, this implies the following law of motion for the firm level employment size N i,t+1 = (1 s)n i,t + q(θ t )V i,t F i,t. (8) B. Labor Market Matching Labor market tightness, θ t, determines how easily vacant jobs can be filled. It is measured as the ratio of aggregate vacancies, V t, to the aggregate unemployment level, Ūt, i.e., θ t = V t /Ūt. 12

14 The aggregate number of vacancies is simply the sum of all firm-level vacancies V t = V i,t dµ t, (9) where µ t denotes the time-varying distribution of firms over the firm level state space (z i,t, N i,t ). The mass of firms is normalized to one. An important feature of our model is the size of the aggregate labor force. It is commonly assumed in the literature a constant unit mass of workers (e.g. Diamond (1982), Merz (1995), Shimer (2005)). We instead model the mass of the labor force as stochastic with unit mean. The time varying size of the labor force captures the notion that the participation in the work force is not constant over time. For instance, discouraged people stop searching for jobs or the baby boomer generation enters the labor force. The labor force is defined as the sum of employed and unemployed. Thus, the total number of unemployed equals Ū t = e pt N i,t dµ t, (10) where e pt is the size of labor force, and p t denotes an exogenous labor market participation shock. This shock follows an AR(1) process with autocorrelation ρ p and i.i.d. normal innovation ε p t which is uncorrelated with aggregate productivity innovations εx t p t = ρ p p t 1 + σ p ε p t. (11) In the model, we treat the population as constant. The labor market participation shock therefore corresponds to the ratio of labor force to population, i.e., the labor force participation rate as reported by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Following den Haan, Ramey, and Watson (2000), vacancies are filled according to a constant returns to scale matching function M(Ūt, V Ū t Vt t ) = (Ū ξ t + V ξ, (12) t )1/ξ and the probability for a vacancy to be filled per unit of time can be computed from q(θ t ) = M(Ūt, V t ) V t = (1 + θ ξ t ) 1/ξ. (13) 13

15 This probability is decreasing in θ meaning that an increase in the relative scarcity of unemployed workers relative to job vacancies makes it more difficult for a firm to fill a vacancy. C. Nash Bargaining Wages Wages are determined as the outcome of collective Nash bargaining between each firm and its workforce. Workers have bargaining weight η (0, 1). If they decide not to work they receive unemployment benefit b which represents the value of their outside option. Let κ h be the unit cost of vacancy posting. Workers are also rewarded the saving of hiring costs (κ h θ t ) that firms enjoy when a job position is filled. When markets are tighter, workers can thus extract higher wages from the firm. The firm with employment size N i,t benefits from hiring the marginal worker through an increase in output by the marginal product of labor, αe xt+zi,t N α 1 i,t. Similar to Stole and Zwiebel (1996) on wage bargaining in multi-worker firms, collective Nash bargaining and worker homogeneity imply that each worker receives the average marginal product of labor, Y i,t /N i,t. The overall wage rate is then given by 7 w i,t = η(y i,t /N i,t + κ h θ t ) + (1 η)b. (14) D. Firm Value We do not model the supply side of labor coming form households. This would require to solve a full general equilibrium model. Instead, following Berk, Green, and Naik (1999) and Lettau and Wachter (2011), we specify an exogenous pricing kernel M t+1 = e rf,t exp( γ x x t+1 γ p p t+1 ) E t [exp( γ x x t+1 γ p p t+1 )] (15) We assume that both the aggregate productivity shock x t and labor force participation shock p t are priced with their respective market prices of risk γ x and γ p. The pricing kernel (15) implies that r f,t is the log risk-free rate which follows an affine process as a function of the aggregate shocks r f,t = r f + B(x t + p t ). (16) 7 See the Appendix for a detailed derivation. 14

16 implying an average risk-free rate of r f with variance B 2 (σ 2 p/(1 ρ 2 p) + σ 2 x/(1 ρ 2 x)). The objective of the firm is to maximize its value S i,t either by posting vacancies V i,t to hire workers or by firing F i,t employed workers to downsize. Both adjustments are costly at a rate κ h for hiring and κ f for firing. The firm s Bellman equation is S i,t = max {D i,t + E t [M t+1 S i,t+1 ]}, (17) V i,t 0,F i,t 0 subject to equations (4) - (14) where D i,t denotes dividends given by D i,t = Y i,t w i,t N i,t κ h V i,t κ f F i,t. (18) Notice that the firm s problem is well-defined given labor market tightness θ t and an expectation about how it evolves. Given optimal firm value S i,t, stock returns are defined as E. Equilibrium R i,t+1 = S i,t+1 S i,t D i,t. (19) Optimal firm employment policies depend on the dynamics of the labor market equilibrium. More specifically, the probability q, of a vacancy being filled with a worker, is a function of aggregate labor market tightness θ. Each individual firm is atomistic and takes labor market tightness as exogenous. Let Ω i,t = (N i,t, z i,t, x t, p t, µ t ) be the vector of state variables and Γ be the law of motion for the time-varying firm distribution µ t, µ t+1 = Γ(µ t, x t, p t ). (20) A given firm-level distribution µ t, together with the aggregate shocks, implies a value for labor market tightness θ t. Equilibrium in the labor market implies that the labor market tightness θ t at each date is determined as a fixed point satisfying V (Ωi,t )dµ t θ t = e pt. (21) N i,t dµ t The recursive competitive equilibrium is characterized by: (i) labor market tightness θ t, (ii) optimal firm policies V (Ω i,t ), F (Ω i,t ), and firm value function S(Ω i,t ), (iii) a law of motion of firm distribution Γ, such that: 15

17 Optimality: Given the pricing kernel (15), Nash bargaining wage rate (14), and labor market tightness θ t, V (Ω i,t ) and F (Ω i,t ) solve the firm s Bellman equation (17) where S(Ω i,t ) is its solution. Consistency: θ t is consistent with the labor market equilibrium (21), and the law of motion of firm distribution Γ is consistent with the optimal firm policies V (Ω i,t ) and F (Ω i,t ). F. Approximate Aggregation The firm s hiring and firing decisions trade off current costs and future benefits, which depend on the aggregation and evolution of the firm distribution. Rather than solving for the high dimensional firm distribution µ t exactly, we follow Krusell and Smith (1998) and approximate the firm level distribution with one moment. In search models, labor market tightness θ t is a sufficient statistic to solve the firm s problem (17) and thus enters the state vector replacing µ t, i.e., Ω i,t = (N i,t, z i,t, x t, p t, θ t ). To approximate the law of motion Γ in equation (20), we assume a log-linear functional form log θ t+1 = τ 0 + τ θ log θ t + τ x,0 x t + τ p,0 p t + τ x,1 x t+1 + τ p,1 p t+1. (22) Under rational expectations, the perceived labor market outcome equals the realized one at each date of the recursive competitive equilibrium. At equilibrium, we can express the labor market tightness factor ϑ as ϑ t+1 = τ 0 + (τ θ 1) log θ t + τ x,0 x t + τ p,0 p t + τ x,1 x t+1 + τ p,1 p t+1. (23) Our application of Krusell and Smith (1998) differs from Zhang (2005) along several dimensions. First, θ t+1 is a function of firm distribution at time t + 1 and hence is not in the information set of date t. The forecasting rule (22) at time t does not enable firms to learn θ t+1 exactly, but rather to form a rational expectation about θ t+1. In contrast, Zhang (2005) assumes that firms can perfectly forecast next period s industry price given time t states. Second, at each period of the simulation, we impose labor market equilibrium by solving θ t 16

18 as the fixed point in Equation (21). Hence, there is no discrepancy between the forecasted θ t+1 and the realized θ t+1. Third, the use of θ t as the sufficient statistic of firm distribution is consistent with the empirical findings that firms stock return sensitivity to changes in θ t is relevant for their valuation. G. Expected Returns and the Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model Given the pricing kernel (15), expected excess returns satisfy the Euler equation E t [M t+1 R e i,t+1 ] = 0. In order to derive a linear pricing relation, we apply a log linear approximation to the pricing kernel implying 8 Et[R e i,t+1] β x i,tλ x t + β p i,t λp t where βi,t x and βp i,t are loadings on aggregate productivity and labor force participations shocks and λ x t and λ p t are their respective factor risk premia. Since aggregate productivity is not directly observable in the data, we also approximate the return on the market as an affine function of the aggregate shocks RM,t+1 e = ν 0 + ν θ log θ t + ν x,0 x t + ν p,0 p t + ν x,1 x t+1 + ν p,1 p t+1. (24) As a result, expected excess returns obey a two factor structure in the market return and labor market tightness E t [Ri,t+1] e βi,t M λ t,m + βi,tλ θ t,θ, (25) where β M i,t and β θ i,t are the loadings on the market return and log-changes of labor market tightness and λ t,m and λ t,θ are the respective factor risk premia given by λ M t = ν x λ x t + ν p λ p t λ θ t = τ x λ x t + τ p λ p t We call relation (25) the Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model. IV. Quantitative Results In this section, we describe our calibration procedure and the benchmark parameterization. We first present the numerical results of the equilibrium forecasting rules. Given the equilibrium dynamics for the labor market, we calculate theoretical loadings on labor market 8 See the appendix for a detailed derivation. 17

19 tightness and show that the model is consistent with the inverse relationship between loadings and expected future stock returns in the cross section. At the end of this section, we discuss the main mechanism driving our model. We solve the competitive equilibrium numerically in the discretized state space Ω i,t using an iterative algorithm described in detail in Appendix C. Given the equilibrium forecasting rule, firms make optimal employment policies. We simulate panels with 5000 firms for 5300 periods. A. Calibration This section describes how we calibrate the parameter values and simulate the model. We adopt a monthly frequency because labor market and equity market data are available at that frequency. Table (8) summarizes the parameter calibration of the benchmark model. Since labor is the only input into production, the aggregate productivity shock process is calibrated to the nonfarm business labor productivity index (output per hour) reported by the BLS. We calculate the percentage deviations from the Hodrick-Prescott filtered trend for quarterly labor productivity and fit an AR(1) process to estimate the persistence parameter and conditional standard deviation. Then we transform the quarterly estimates to monthly frequency according to Heer and Mauner (2011) to get ρ x = and σ x = Regarding the shock to the labor force participation, we take the time series of monthly labor force participation rates from the BLS and normalize it to have unit mean. Then we fit an AR(1) process to the log of the normalized time series and estimate the persistence ρ p = , and conditional standard deviation σ p = Notice that the correlation of the two shock series estimated from data is only 0.019, which justifies our model assumption that the two aggregate shocks are independent. The average risk-free rate r f = is set according to the monthly risk-free rate. The affine structure coefficient B governs how the risk-free rate moves with the aggregate shocks. It is chosen such that the risk-free rate is countercyclical and has an annual standard deviation of 2.26%. The prices of risk of the aggregate shocks γ x and γ p are set to match the average market excess return and the Sharpe ratio. We assume that the aggregate productivity shock 18

20 x and labor force participation shock p both have positive price of risk. Berk, Green, and Naik (1999) and Zhang (2005) provide a motivation for γ x > 0 in an economy with only x shocks. The assumption of γ p > 0 can be motivated as follows. In general equilibrium economy with a representative household, labor market participation is an endogenous outcome determined as a consumption and leisure tradeoff where participation means a reduction in leisure. Eckstein and Wolpin (1989) and Schirle (2008) show that endogenous variation in participation can be linked to preference shocks. Under these assumption, the substitution effect between consumption and leisure dominates in equilibrium, implying that consumption and leisure are negatively correlated. This positive comovement between consumption and participation indicates that, in a model with exogenous shocks to participation, these shocks should display a positive price of risk. The labor literature provides several empirical studies to calibrate the labor market parameters. According to Davis, Faberman, and Haltiwanger (2012), the monthly total separation rate measured in the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS) is In JOLTS, each establishment reports employment hires, quits, and layoffs separately, which allows us to differentiate between voluntary quits and involuntary layoffs. In both den Haan, Ramey, and Watson (2000) and Davis, Faberman, and Haltiwanger (2012), the average level of quits are twice that of layoffs. As such, we set the monthly exogenous quit rate s = Shimer (2005) measures the aggregate monthly job finding rate f(θ) = 0.45 and the average vacancy filling rate q(θ) = Given these estimates, the curvature of the matching function has ξ = 1.28 coming from the steady state relation q = ( (f/q) ξ + 1 ) 1/ξ. The remaining parameters are chosen to match the simulated moments. Table (9) summarizes the selected target moments from data and the simulated moments under the benchmark calibration. The curvature of the production function α is set to match the average monthly unemployment rate which is 5.7% in the data as reported by the BLS. The level of unemployment benefit b relates to the average labor share of income measured as total compensation of employees divided by output. Using data from The National Income 19

21 and Product Accounts (NIPA), Gomme and Greenwood (1995) and Gomme and Rupert (2007) report for this moment. The bargaining power of workers η determines the rigidity of wages. On the simulated panel, for each firm we calculate the ratio of the standard deviation of log-changes of firmspecific wage rate to the standard deviation of log-changes of firm output. Then we average over all the firms to match the data moment as in Gourio (2007). We also calculate the standard deviation of log-changes of aggregate after-tax profit to that of total output, and match it to Gourio (2007). The cost parameters κ h and κ f determine both the overall costs of adjusting the workforce as well as the behavior of firm policies. Specifically, we determine the average total adjustment costs to total output, which Yashiv (2011) empirically estimates to be are around 2% of output. The proportional cost structure also implies the existence of firms that are neither posting vacancies nor laying off workers. The average percentage of Compustat firms with zero net annual employment growth rate during is 7.04%. We refer to this as average inaction fraction. On the simulated panel of firms, we average the monthly firm employment growth rate across 12 months to get the annual average for each firm every year. Then we compute the percentage of firms with absolute annual employment adjustment rate less than 1% to match the inaction fraction. 9 The persistence and volatility of firm idiosyncratic shock process correspond to the crosssectional dispersion and persistence of firm-level employment growth rate. We obtain the average dispersion of annual employment growth rates 0.25 by taking the cross-sectional standard deviation of firm level employment growth rate for each year, and take the average of the time series ranging in Compustat. The corresponding moment is calculated the same way in simulations to match the data. To measure the persistence and volatility of labor adjustment, Davis, Haltiwanger, Jarmin, Miranda, Foote, and Nagypal (2006) adopt a moving average formula and obtain the average volatility of annual employment growth rates 0.2 for Compustat firms. We follow their exact procedure on simulated data. 9 We use the 1% to allow for numerical errors in the simulation, and measurement errors in the data. 20

22 B. Equilibrium Forecasting Rules Table 10 shows the coefficient estimates for the equilibrium forecasting rule of labor market tightness using the benchmark calibration. With this forecasting rule, we solve the model, and simulate a panel of firms and estimate ex post the affine structure for market excess returns, (24). In the model, labor market tightness is autocorrelated, positively related to aggregate productivity and negatively to the labor force participation. An increase in aggregate productivity leads to more vacancy postings by firms because of an increase in the marginal product of labor and a decrease in discount rates. More vacant positions means tighter labor markets and a drop in matching probabilities. The direction of labor force participation shock on labor market tightness is not obvious because both the numerator and the denominator of labor market tightness (see Equation (21)) increase upon an increase in p t. Given our calibration, the second channel dominates in the competitive labor market equilibrium and θ t decreases endogenously with the participation shock. Figure 4 illustrates this endogenous link. In a model without a labor market equilibrium, p shocks only enter θ t through the denominator. When there is an increase in p from p 0 to p 1, we move along the black solid curve from point A to B. Accounting for the firms endogenous response, an increase in p t affects the pricing kernel and firms expectation about θ t and thus vacancy postings V (Ω i,t ) increase. This endogenous response shifts the curve outward, and we end up with the equilibrium at C. We also emphasize that when γ p is large enough, the endogenous increase in vacancies could be so strong that the curve shifts more outward to the dashed red line with equilibrium D. Consequently, endogenous firm behavior also imposes a constraint on our calibration. The realized market excess return is mainly driven by the innovations of the two aggregate shocks and not by lagged labor market tightness. When favorable aggregate shocks hit the economy, prices increase and the realized market excess return is positive. As such, the regression coefficients show that both ν x,1 > 0 and ν p,1 > 0. We use this information to compute theoretical loadings on labor market tightness controlling for the market excess 21

23 return. C. Cross Section of Equity Returns Following the empirical procedure in Section II, we calculate loadings β θ i,t on the θ factor of each stock i controlling for the market excess return. We emphasize that in the data, we calculate the loadings β θ i,t using a two-factor model of market excess return and labor market tightness, see Equation (3). In the model, since we know the theoretical conditional distribution of both the technology shock and the labor market participation shock, we can calculate the theoretical loadings implied by the equilibrium law (24). To assess to what extent our model can explain the empirically observed negative relationship between labor market tightness factor loadings and future stock returns, we use the simulated data and sort portfolios into portfolios according to their factor loadings. For the benchmark results, we use a monthly rebalancing procedure, sort the simulated 5000 firms into ten portfolios, and calculate value weighted average returns for each portfolio. Table 11 compares the simulated return spread with the data. In the model, the annualized average return difference between the low and heigh loading portfolio is 4.3% relative to 6.0% in the data. Our results are robust with respect to portfolios held and rebalanced at different horizons. Table 12 shows the simulated portfolio spread from the benchmark model with portfolio rebalanced after one month, two months, four months, six months, and 12 months. The portfolio spread decreases slightly as we increase the rebalancing horizon, because as noise increases month after month, the predictability becomes weaker. However, at a one year rebalancing horizon, the return spread is still significant. What is economic mechanism underlying our model? Due to the proportional hiring and firing costs, the optimal firm policy exhibits stylized (s, S) patterns in adjusting employment size and thus regions of inactivity. Figure 5 illustrates the optimal firm policy. The black line is the optimal policy when adjusting the workforce is costless. In the frictionless model, firms always adjust to the target employment size independent of the current size. The red line is the optimal policy in the benchmark model. It displays two kinks. In the region where the optimal policy coincides with the 45 degree line, firms are inactive. In the inactivity region 22

A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model

A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model Lars-Alexander Kuehn Mikhail Simutin Jessie Jiaxu Wang CMU UToronto ASU CSEF-EIEF-SITE Conference on Finance and Labor September 8th, 2016, Capri Labor Market Dynamics

More information

A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model

A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model Lars-Alexander Kuehn Tepper School of Business Carnegie Mellon University Jessie Jiaxu Wang Tepper School of Business Carnegie Mellon University Mikhail Simutin Rotman

More information

A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model

A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model Lars-Alexander Kuehn Tepper School of Business Carnegie Mellon University Jessie Jiaxu Wang Tepper School of Business Carnegie Mellon University Mikhail Simutin Rotman

More information

A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model

A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model Lars-Alexander Kuehn Tepper School of Business Carnegie Mellon University Jessie Jiaxu Wang W. P. Carey School of Business Arizona State University Mikhail Simutin Rotman

More information

Lecture Notes. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University

Lecture Notes. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University Lecture Notes Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1 1 The Ohio State University BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University Insight The textbook Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides

More information

Internet Appendix to: A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model

Internet Appendix to: A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model Internet Appendix to: A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model Lars-Alexander Kuehn Tepper School of Business Carnegie Mellon University Jessie Jiaxu Wang W. P. Carey School of Business Arizona State University

More information

New Business Start-ups and the Business Cycle

New Business Start-ups and the Business Cycle New Business Start-ups and the Business Cycle Ali Moghaddasi Kelishomi (Joint with Melvyn Coles, University of Essex) The 22nd Annual Conference on Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies Banking Supervision

More information

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Leonid Kogan 1 Dimitris Papanikolaou 2 1 MIT and NBER 2 Northwestern University Boston, June 5, 2009 Kogan,

More information

Asymmetric Labor Market Fluctuations in an Estimated Model of Equilibrium Unemployment

Asymmetric Labor Market Fluctuations in an Estimated Model of Equilibrium Unemployment Asymmetric Labor Market Fluctuations in an Estimated Model of Equilibrium Unemployment Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau FRB San Francisco Benjamin Tengelsen CMU - Tepper Tsinghua - St.-Louis Fed Conference May

More information

Internet Appendix to: A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model

Internet Appendix to: A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model Internet Appendix to: A Labor Capital Asset Pricing Model Lars-Alexander Kuehn Tepper School of Business Carnegie Mellon University Jessie Jiaxu Wang W. P. Carey School of Business Arizona State University

More information

The CAPM Strikes Back? An Investment Model with Disasters

The CAPM Strikes Back? An Investment Model with Disasters The CAPM Strikes Back? An Investment Model with Disasters Hang Bai 1 Kewei Hou 1 Howard Kung 2 Lu Zhang 3 1 The Ohio State University 2 London Business School 3 The Ohio State University and NBER Federal

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

Labor Hiring and Discount Rates *

Labor Hiring and Discount Rates * Labor Hiring and Discount Rates * FREDERICO BELO, ANDRES DONANGELO, XIAOJI LIN, and DING LUO ABSTRACT Using a standard production model with labor market frictions, we show that firms optimal hiring is

More information

Labor-Technology Substitution: Implications for Asset Pricing. Miao Ben Zhang University of Southern California

Labor-Technology Substitution: Implications for Asset Pricing. Miao Ben Zhang University of Southern California Labor-Technology Substitution: Implications for Asset Pricing Miao Ben Zhang University of Southern California Background Routine-task labor: workers performing procedural and rule-based tasks. Tax preparers

More information

The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany

The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany Russell Cooper Moritz Meyer 2 Immo Schott 3 Penn State 2 The World Bank 3 Université de Montréal Social Statistics and Population Dynamics

More information

Part 3: Value, Investment, and SEO Puzzles

Part 3: Value, Investment, and SEO Puzzles Part 3: Value, Investment, and SEO Puzzles Model of Zhang, L., 2005, The Value Premium, JF. Discrete time Operating leverage Asymmetric quadratic adjustment costs Counter-cyclical price of risk Algorithm

More information

Financial Risk and Unemployment

Financial Risk and Unemployment Financial Risk and Unemployment Zvi Eckstein Tel Aviv University and The Interdisciplinary Center Herzliya Ofer Setty Tel Aviv University David Weiss Tel Aviv University PRELIMINARY DRAFT: February 2014

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 2: Factor models and the cross-section of stock returns Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Next week (30

More information

Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations

Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations Andri Chassamboulli April 15, 2010 Abstract This paper studies the business-cycle behavior of a matching

More information

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Yuhang Xing Rice University This version: July 25, 2006 1 I thank Andrew Ang, Geert Bekaert, John Donaldson, and Maria Vassalou

More information

Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics

Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics Weh-Sol Moon* The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the official views of the Bank of Korea. When reporting or

More information

Financial Distress and the Cross Section of Equity Returns

Financial Distress and the Cross Section of Equity Returns Financial Distress and the Cross Section of Equity Returns Lorenzo Garlappi University of Texas Austin Hong Yan University of South Carolina National University of Singapore May 20, 2009 Motivation Empirical

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Credit and hiring. Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California.

Credit and hiring. Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California. Credit and hiring Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California November 14, 2013 CREDIT AND EMPLOYMENT LINKS When credit is tight, employers

More information

Asset Pricing Implications of Hiring Demographics

Asset Pricing Implications of Hiring Demographics Asset Pricing Implications of Hiring Demographics November 18, 2016 Abstract This paper documents that U.S. industries that shift their skilled workforce toward young employees exhibit higher expected

More information

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2521 Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model Vincent Bodart Olivier Pierrard Henri R. Sneessens December 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models. European Summer Symposium in International Macroeconomics, May 2015 Tarragona, Spain

The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models. European Summer Symposium in International Macroeconomics, May 2015 Tarragona, Spain The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models Lars Ljungqvist Stockholm School of Economics New York University Thomas J. Sargent New York University Hoover Institution European Summer Symposium in International

More information

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil Niklas Engbom June 16, 2016 Christian Moser World Bank-Bank of Spain Conference This project Shed light on drivers of earnings inequality

More information

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor In this online appendix, we provide a comparative static analysis of the theoretical model as well as further robustness checks on the trend factor.

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Unemployment (fears), Precautionary Savings, and Aggregate Demand

Unemployment (fears), Precautionary Savings, and Aggregate Demand Unemployment (fears), Precautionary Savings, and Aggregate Demand Wouter den Haan (LSE), Pontus Rendahl (Cambridge), Markus Riegler (LSE) ESSIM 2014 Introduction A FT-esque story: Uncertainty (or fear)

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

Aggregate Demand and the Dynamics of Unemployment

Aggregate Demand and the Dynamics of Unemployment Aggregate Demand and the Dynamics of Unemployment Edouard Schaal 1 Mathieu Taschereau-Dumouchel 2 1 New York University and CREI 2 The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania 1/34 Introduction

More information

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru i Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2012 ii Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru (B.Sc National University

More information

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation Chung Gu Chee The Ohio State University November 10, 2012 Abstract In this paper, I investigate the role of operative labor supply margin in explaining

More information

Can Investment Shocks Explain Value Premium and Momentum Profits?

Can Investment Shocks Explain Value Premium and Momentum Profits? Can Investment Shocks Explain Value Premium and Momentum Profits? Lorenzo Garlappi University of British Columbia Zhongzhi Song Cheung Kong GSB First draft: April 15, 2012 This draft: December 15, 2014

More information

Growth Opportunities, Technology Shocks, and Asset Prices

Growth Opportunities, Technology Shocks, and Asset Prices Growth Opportunities, Technology Shocks, and Asset Prices Leonid Kogan Dimitris Papanikolaou September 8, 2010 Abstract We explore the impact of investment-specific technology (IST) shocks on the crosssection

More information

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment Eduardo Engel Cowles Lunch. March 3rd, 2010 Eduardo Engel 1 1. Motivation Micro adjustment is lumpy for many aggregates of interest: stock of durable good nominal

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: From factor models to asset pricing Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Solution to exercise 1 of problem

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern.

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern. , JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 13, 2009 Outline 1 Motivation Production-Based Asset Pricing Framework 2 Assumptions Firm s Problem Equilibrium 3 Main Findings Mechanism Testable

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation Chung Gu Chee The Ohio State University November 10, 2012 Abstract In this paper, I investigate the role of operative labor supply margin in explaining

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: March 2013 First draft: October 2010 Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu. I am grateful

More information

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Ravi Bansal Fuqua School of Business, Duke University Robert F. Dittmar Kelley School of Business, Indiana University Christian T. Lundblad

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles : A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles, JF (2004) Presented by: Esben Hedegaard NYUStern October 12, 2009 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Long-Run Risk Solving the 3 Data and Calibration Results

More information

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? Rui Cui May 31, 2014 Introduction Credit cycles are growth cycles Cyclicality in the amount of new credit Explanations: collateral constraints, equity constraints, leverage

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market? International Review of Finance, 2017 Can Hedge Funds Time the Market? MICHAEL W. BRANDT,FEDERICO NUCERA AND GIORGIO VALENTE Duke University, The Fuqua School of Business, Durham, NC LUISS Guido Carli

More information

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach Hossein Asgharian and Björn Hansson Department of Economics, Lund University Box 7082 S-22007 Lund, Sweden

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT. Long Chen Lu Zhang. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT. Long Chen Lu Zhang. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT Long Chen Lu Zhang Working Paper 15219 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15219 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue

More information

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser. University of Konstanz Department of Economics Optimal Contracting with Reciprocal Agents in a Competitive Search Model Maria Breitwieser Working Paper Series 2015-16 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/econdoc/working-paper-series/

More information

FIRM DYNAMICS, JOB TURNOVER, AND WAGE DISTRIBUTIONS IN AN OPEN ECONOMY

FIRM DYNAMICS, JOB TURNOVER, AND WAGE DISTRIBUTIONS IN AN OPEN ECONOMY FIRM DYNAMICS, JOB TURNOVER, AND WAGE DISTRIBUTIONS IN AN OPEN ECONOMY A. Kerem Coşar, Nezih Guner, and James Tybout PennState, ICREA and U. Autònoma de Barcelona, PennState and NBER ESSIM, May 2010 MOTIVATION

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SOLVING THE DMP MODEL ACCURATELY. Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau Lu Zhang. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SOLVING THE DMP MODEL ACCURATELY. Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau Lu Zhang. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SOLVING THE DMP MODEL ACCURATELY Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau Lu Zhang Working Paper 1928 http://www.nber.org/papers/w1928 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 15 Massachusetts Avenue

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 Section 1. Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

Health Care Reform or Labor Market Reform? A Quantitative Analysis of the Affordable Care Act

Health Care Reform or Labor Market Reform? A Quantitative Analysis of the Affordable Care Act Health Care Reform or Labor Market Reform? A Quantitative Analysis of the Affordable Care Act Makoto Nakajima 1 Didem Tüzemen 2 1 Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia 2 Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

More information

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Yan Bai University of Rochester NBER Dan Lu University of Rochester Xu Tian University of Rochester February

More information

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices : Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices (2008, AER) December 5 th, 2008 Empirical motivation US PPI-based RER is highly volatile Under PPP, this should induce a high volatility

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

Lecture 6 Search and matching theory

Lecture 6 Search and matching theory Lecture 6 Search and matching theory Leszek Wincenciak, Ph.D. University of Warsaw 2/48 Lecture outline: Introduction Search and matching theory Search and matching theory The dynamics of unemployment

More information

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default Private Leverage and Sovereign Default Cristina Arellano Yan Bai Luigi Bocola FRB Minneapolis University of Rochester Northwestern University Economic Policy and Financial Frictions November 2015 1 / 37

More information

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment Avihai Lifschitz Tel Aviv University This Draft: October 2015 Abstract This paper develops a dynamic model of the labor market, in which the employed workers,

More information

Staggered Wages, Sticky Prices, and Labor Market Dynamics in Matching Models. by Janett Neugebauer and Dennis Wesselbaum

Staggered Wages, Sticky Prices, and Labor Market Dynamics in Matching Models. by Janett Neugebauer and Dennis Wesselbaum Staggered Wages, Sticky Prices, and Labor Market Dynamics in Matching Models by Janett Neugebauer and Dennis Wesselbaum No. 168 March 21 Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Düsternbrooker Weg 12, 2415

More information

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 2013 North American Summer Meeting Ralph Lütticke 13.06.2013 1 Joint-work with Christian Bayer, Lien Pham, and Volker Tjaden 1 / 30 Research

More information

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Addendum Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara This version: February 01 1 Hanken School of Economics. E-mail: paulofmaio@gmail.com. Nova School of Business

More information

Hedging Factor Risk Preliminary Version

Hedging Factor Risk Preliminary Version Hedging Factor Risk Preliminary Version Bernard Herskovic, Alan Moreira, and Tyler Muir March 15, 2018 Abstract Standard risk factors can be hedged with minimal reduction in average return. This is true

More information

Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1

Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick January 2006 address

More information

The Common Factor in Idiosyncratic Volatility:

The Common Factor in Idiosyncratic Volatility: The Common Factor in Idiosyncratic Volatility: Quantitative Asset Pricing Implications Bryan Kelly University of Chicago Booth School of Business (with Bernard Herskovic, Hanno Lustig, and Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh)

More information

Fama-French in China: Size and Value Factors in Chinese Stock Returns

Fama-French in China: Size and Value Factors in Chinese Stock Returns Fama-French in China: Size and Value Factors in Chinese Stock Returns November 26, 2016 Abstract We investigate the size and value factors in the cross-section of returns for the Chinese stock market.

More information

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Department of Economics HKUST August 7, 2018 Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics 1 / 48 Reference Krueger, Dirk, Kurt Mitman, and Fabrizio Perri. Macroeconomics

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Government spending and firms dynamics

Government spending and firms dynamics Government spending and firms dynamics Pedro Brinca Nova SBE Miguel Homem Ferreira Nova SBE December 2nd, 2016 Francesco Franco Nova SBE Abstract Using firm level data and government demand by firm we

More information

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases Vincent Sterk and Silvana Tenreyro UCL, LSE September 2015 Sterk and Tenreyro (UCL, LSE) OMO September 2015 1 / 28 The

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312/702 Basic New Keynesian Model of Transmission Can be derived from primitives:

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen June 15, 2012 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations June 15, 2012 1 / 59 Introduction We construct

More information

7 Unemployment. 7.1 Introduction. JEM004 Macroeconomics IES, Fall 2017 Lecture Notes Eva Hromádková

7 Unemployment. 7.1 Introduction. JEM004 Macroeconomics IES, Fall 2017 Lecture Notes Eva Hromádková JEM004 Macroeconomics IES, Fall 2017 Lecture Notes Eva Hromádková 7 Unemployment 7.1 Introduction unemployment = existence of people who are not working but who say they would want to work in jobs like

More information

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2015 Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis Seth E. Williams Utah State University

More information

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems?

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems? How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems? Andrea Gamba Alexander J. Triantis Corporate Finance Symposium Cambridge Judge Business School September 20, 2014 What do we know

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation Marcelo Veracierto WP 2002-12 On the cyclical behavior of employment, unemployment and

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults March, 2018 Contents 1 1 Robustness Tests The results presented in the main text are robust to the definition of debt repayments, and the

More information

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters A. Kerem Coşar Davide Suverato kerem.cosar@chicagobooth.edu davide.suverato@econ.lmu.de University of Chicago Booth School of Business

More information

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage: Economics Letters 108 (2010) 167 171 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Economics Letters journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolet Is there a financial accelerator in US banking? Evidence

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Ravi Bansal Fuqua School of Business, Duke University Robert F. Dittmar Kelley School of Business, Indiana University Christian T. Lundblad

More information

The Role of Uncertainty in the Joint Output and Employment Dynamics

The Role of Uncertainty in the Joint Output and Employment Dynamics The Role of Uncertainty in the Joint Output and Employment Dynamics Tsu-ting Tim Lin Gettysburg College January 18, 219 Abstract This paper examines the role uncertainty plays in the joint dynamics between

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

Endogenous Disasters and Asset Prices

Endogenous Disasters and Asset Prices Endogenous Disasters and Asset Prices Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau Lu Zhang Lars-Alexander Kuehn October 23 Abstract Frictions in the labor market are important for understanding the equity premium in the financial

More information

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application Russell Cooper, John Haltiwanger and Jonathan Willis January 2005 Abstract This paper studies capital adjustment costs. Our goal here

More information

External Equity Financing Costs, Financial Flows, and Asset Prices

External Equity Financing Costs, Financial Flows, and Asset Prices External Equity Financing Costs, Financial Flows, and Asset Prices Frederico Belo Xiaoji Lin Fan Yang November 18, 2013 Abstract The recent financial crisis in 2007-2008 suggests that financial shocks,

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

What Drives Anomaly Returns?

What Drives Anomaly Returns? What Drives Anomaly Returns? Lars A. Lochstoer and Paul C. Tetlock UCLA and Columbia Q Group, April 2017 New factors contradict classic asset pricing theories E.g.: value, size, pro tability, issuance,

More information

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis Answer each question in three or four sentences and perhaps one equation or graph. Remember that the explanation determines the grade. 1. Question

More information

The Search and matching Model

The Search and matching Model The Search and matching Model THE GREAT RECESSION AND OTHER BUSINESS CYCLES April 2018 The DMP search and matching model An equilibrium model of unemployment Firms and workers have to spend time and resources

More information

Monetary Policy and Resource Mobility

Monetary Policy and Resource Mobility Monetary Policy and Resource Mobility 2th Anniversary of the Bank of Finland Carl E. Walsh University of California, Santa Cruz May 5-6, 211 C. E. Walsh (UCSC) Bank of Finland 2th Anniversary May 5-6,

More information