Derivation and Comparative Statics of the Black-Scholes Call and Put Option Pricing Formulas

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Derivation and Comparative Statics of the Black-Scholes Call and Put Option Pricing Formulas"

Transcription

1 Derivation and Comparative Statics of the Black-Scholes Call and Put Option Pricing Formulas James R. Garven Latest Revision: February 27, 2012 Abstract This paper provides an alternative derivation of the Black-Scholes call and put option pricing formulas using an integration rather than differential equations approach. The economic and mathematical structure of these formulas is discussed, and comparative statics are derived. 1 Introduction The purposes of this paper are: (1) to provide a concise overview of the economic and mathematical assumptions needed to derive the Black-Scholes (1973) call and put option pricing formulas; (2) to provide an alternative derivation and comparative statics analysis of these formulas. This paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we discuss the economic and mathematical structure of the Black-Scholes model. In the third section, we provide an alternative derivation of the Black-Scholes option pricing formulas based upon an integration rather than differential equations approach. The advantage of the integration approach lies in its simplicity, as only basic integral calculus is required. The integration approach also makes the link between the economics and mathematics of the call and put option formulas more transparent for most readers. This paper concludes with comparative statics analyses of these formulas. James R. Garven is the Frank S. Groner Memorial Chair in Finance and Professor of Finance & Insurance at Baylor University (Address: HSB 351, One Bear Place #98004, Waco, TX 76798, telephone: , James Garven@baylor.edu). This article has benefited from the helpful comments of Soku Byoun, Richard Derrig, Gabriel Drimus, Bill Reichenstein, and J. T. Rose. Of course, the usual disclaimer applies. 1

2 2 Economic and Mathematical Structure of the Black-Scholes Model The most important economic insight contained in Black and Scholes seminal paper is the notion that an investor can create a riskless portfolio by dynamically hedging a long (short) position in the underlying asset with a short (long) position in a European call option. In order to prevent arbitrage, the expected return on such a portfolio must be the riskless rate of interest. Cox and Ross (1976) note that since the creation of such a hedge portfolio places no restrictions on investor preferences beyond nonsatiation, the valuation relationship between an option and its underlying asset is risk neutral in the sense that it does not depend upon investor risk preferences. Therefore, for a given price of the underlying asset, a call option written against that asset will trade for the same price in a risk neutral economy as it would in a risk averse or risk loving economy. Consequently, options can be priced as if they are traded in risk neutral economies. Black and Scholes assume that stock prices change continuously according to the Geometric Brownian Motion equation; i.e., ds = µsdt + σsdz. (1) Equation (1) is a stochastic differential equation because it contains the Wiener process dz = ε dt, where ɛ is a standard normal random variable. ds corresponds to the stock price change per dt time unit, S is the current stock price, µ is the expected return, and σ represents volatility. The Geometric Brownian Motion equation is commonly referred to as an exponential stochastic differential equation because its solution is an exponential function; specifically, S t = Se (µ σ2 /2)t+σz t, where S t represents the stock price t periods from now. Since z t is normally distributed, it follows that S t is lognormally distributed. S t s mean is µ St = Se µt, and its variance is σs 2 t = S 2 e 2µt (e σ2t 1). Ito s Lemma provides a rule for finding the differential of a function of one or more variables in which at least one of the variables follows a stochastic differential equation. At 2

3 any given point in time, the value of the call option (C ) depends upon the value of the underlying asset; i.e., C = C (S,t). 1 Since the value of the call option is a function of the stock price which evolves over time according to equation (1), Ito s Lemma justifies the use of a Taylor-series-like expansion for the differential dc : dc = C C dt + t S ds C 2 S 2 ds2. (2) Since ds 2 = S 2 σ 2 dt, substituting for ds 2 in equation (2) yields equation (3): dc = C C dt + t S ds σ2 S 2 2 C dt. (3) S2 Suppose we wish to construct a hedge portfolio consisting of one long call option position worth C (S, t) and a short position in some quantity t of the underlying asset worth S per share. We express the hedge ratio t as a function of t because the portfolio will be dynamically hedged; i.e., as the price of the underlying asset changes through time, so will t. Then the value of this hedge portfolio is V = C (S, t) - t S, which implies dv = dc t ds = ( C t + 1 ) ( ) 2 σ2 S 2 2 C C S 2 dt + S t ds. (4) Note that there are stochastic as well as deterministic terms on the right-hand side of equation (4). The deterministic terms are represented by the first product, whereas the stochastic terms are represented by the second product. However, by setting t equal to C, the second product equals zero and we have: S dv = dc t ds = ( C t + 1 ) 2 σ2 S 2 2 C S 2 dt. (5) Since this is a perfectly hedged portfolio, it has no risk. In order to prevent arbitrage, the 1 The call option value also depends upon the exercise price of the option (X ), the interest rate (r), and the volatility of the underlying asset (σ 2 S). However, since these parameters are constants, the differential equation for C only depends upon S and t. Since t is a deterministic time trend whereas instantaneous rates of return on S are assumed to be normally distributed, it follows that C is once differentiable in C and twice differentiable in S. 3

4 hedge portfolio must earn the riskless rate of interest r; i.e., dv = rv dt. (6) We will assume that t = C C, so V = C (S, t) - S. Substituting this into the right-hand S S side of equation (6) and equating the result with the right-hand side of equation (5), we obtain: ( r C S C ) ( C dt = S t + 1 ) 2 σ2 S 2 2 C S 2 dt. (7) Dividing both sides of equation (7) by dt and rearranging results in the Black-Scholes (nonstochastic) partial differential equation 2 rc = C t σ2 S 2 2 C C + rs S2 S. (8) Equation (8) shows that the valuation relationship between a call option and its underlying asset is deterministic because dynamic hedging enables the investor to be perfectly hedged over infinitesimally small units of time. Since risk preferences play no role in this equation, this implies that the price of a call option can be calculated as if investors are risk neutral. Suppose there are τ = T t periods until option expiration occurs, where T is the (fixed) expiration date and t is today. Then the value of a call option (C ) at time t must satisfy equation (8), subject to the boundary condition on the option s payoff at expiration; i.e., C T = Max[S T X, 0], where X represents the option s exercise price and S T represents the stock price at expiration. Black and Scholes transform their version of equation (8) into the heat transfer equation of physics, 3 which allows them to (quite literally) employ a textbook solution procedure 2 Note that equation (8) in this paper and equation (7) in the original Black-Scholes paper (cf. Black and Scholes (1973), available on the web at are the same equation (although the notation is marginally different). 3 Wilmott (2001, p. 156) notes that heat transfer equations date back to the beginning of the 19th century, and have been used to model a diverse set of physical and social phenomena, such as the flow of heat from one part of an object to another, electrical activity in the membranes of living organisms, the dispersion of populations, the formation of zebra stripes, and the dispersion of air and water pollution, 4

5 taken from Churchill s (1963) classic introduction to Fourier series and their applications to boundary value problems in partial differential equations of engineering and physics. This solution procedure results in the following equation for the value of a European call option: C = SN(d 1 ) Xe rt N(d 2 ), (9) where d 1 = ln(s/x) + (r +.5σ2 )t σ ; t d 2 = d 1 σ t; σ 2 = variance of underlying asset s rate of return; and N (z) = standard normal distribution function evaluated at z. Equation (9) implies that the price of the call option depends upon five parameters; specifically, the current stock price S, the exercise price X, the riskless interest rate r, the time to expiration t, and the volatility of the underlying asset σ. If it is not possible to form a riskless hedge portfolio, then other more restrictive assumptions are needed in order to obtain a risk neutral valuation relationship between an option and its underlying asset. Rubinstein (1976) has shown that the Black-Scholes option pricing formulas also obtain under the following set of assumptions: 1. The conditions for aggregation are met so that securities are priced as if all investors have the same characteristics as a representative investor; 2. The utility function of the representative investor exhibits constant relative risk aversion (CRRA); 3. The return on the underlying asset and the return on aggregate wealth are bivariate lognormally distributed; 4. The return on the underlying asset follows a stationary random walk through time; and 5. The riskless rate of interest is constant through time. Collectively, assumptions 1, 2, and 3 constitute sufficient conditions for valuing the option as if both it and the underlying asset are traded in a risk neutral economy. Assumptions among other things. 5

6 4 and 5 constitute necessary conditions for the Black-Scholes option pricing formulas, since they guarantee that the riskless rate of interest, the rate of return on the underlying asset, and the variance of the underlying asset will be proportional to time. 4 3 Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formula Derivations Rubinstein (1987) notes that the Black-Scholes call option pricing formula can be derived by integration if one assumes that the probability distribution for the underlying asset is lognormal. Fortunately, as noted earlier, this assumption is implied by the Geometric Brownian Motion equation given by equation (1). Therefore, our next task is to derive the Black-Scholes call option pricing formula by integration. Once we obtain the Black-Scholes call option pricing formula, the put option pricing formula follows directly from the put-call parity theorem. The value today (C ) of a European call option that pays C t = Max[S t X, 0] at date t is given by the following equation: C = V (C t ) = V (Max[S t X, 0]), (10) where V represents the valuation operator. Having established in equation (8) that a risk neutral valuation relationship exists between the call option and its underlying asset, it follows that we can price the option as if investors are risk neutral. Therefore, the valuation operator V determines the current price of a call option by discounting the risk neutral expected value of the option s payoff at expiration (Ê (C t)) at the riskless rate of interest, as indicated in equation (11): C = e rt Ê (C t ) = e rt (S t X)ĥ(S t)ds t, (11) X 4 Brennan (1979) shows that if the return on the underlying asset and the return on aggregate wealth are bivariate lognormally (normally) distributed, then the representative investor must have CRRA (CARA) preferences. Stapleton and Subrahmanyam (1984) extend Rubinstein s and Brennan s results to a world where payoffs on options depend on the outcomes of two or more stochastic variables. 6

7 where ĥ(s t) represents the risk neutral lognormal density function of S T. We begin our analysis by computing the expected value of C t : E(C t ) = E[Max(S t X, 0)] = X (S t X)h(S t )ds t, (12) where h(s t ) represents S t s lognormal density function. 5 To evaluate this integral, we rewrite it as the difference between two integrals: E(C t ) = X S t h(s t )ds t X X h(s t )ds t = E X (S t ) Xe rt [1 H(X)], (13) where E X (S t ) = the partial expected value of S T, truncated from below at X ; 6 H(X) = the probability that S t X. By rewriting the terminal stock price S T as the product of the current stock price S and the t-period lognormally distributed price ratio S t /S, S t = S (S t /S), equation (13) can be rewritten as E(C t ) = S (S t /S)g(S t /S)dS t /S X g(s t /S)dS t /S X/S X/S = SE X/S (S t /S) X[1 G(X/S)], (14) where g(s t /S) = lognormal density function of S T /S; 7 5 The difference between the ĥ(st) and h(st) density functions is easily explained. Since ST is a lognormally distributed random variable, E(S t) = 0 S th(s t)ds t =Se (µ+.5σ2 )t. Since all assets in a risk neutral economy are expected to return the riskless rate of interest, this implies that in a risk neutral economy, Ê(S t) = Se rt, which in turn implies that (µ +.5σ 2 )t = rt. The ĥ(st) density function is risk neutral in the sense that its location parameter µt is replaced by (r.5σ 2 )t. 6 The partial expected value of X for values of X ranging from y to z is Ey(X) z = z Xf(X)dX. If we y replace the y and z limits of integration with - and, then we have a complete expected value, or first moment. See Winkler, Roodman and Britney (1972) for more details concerning the computation of partial moments for a wide variety of probability distributions, including the normal distribution. 7 Note that g(s τ /S) = h(s T )/S. 7

8 and E X/S (S t /S) = the partial expected value of S T /S, truncated from below at X /S; G(X/S) = the probability that S t /S X /S. Next, we evaluate the right-hand side of equation (14) by considering its two integrals separately. First, consider the integral that corresponds to the partial expected value of the terminal stock price, SE X/S (S t /S). Let S t /S = e kt, where k is the rate of return on the underlying asset per unit of time. Since S t /S is lognormally distributed, ln (S t /S) = kt is normally distributed with density f (kt), mean µ k t and variance σk 2t.8 Furthermore, g(s τ /S) = (S/S t ) f (kt). 9 Also, since S t /S = e kt, ds t /S = e kt tdk. Consequently, (S t /S)g(S t /S)dS t /S = e kt f(kt)tdk. Thus, SE X/S (S t /S) = S ln(x/s) e kt 1 f(kt)tdk = S 2πσ 2 t ln(x/s) e kt e {.5[(kt µt)2 /σ 2 t]} tdk. (15) Next, we simplify equation (15) s integrand by adding the terms in the two exponents, multiplying and dividing the resulting expression by e.5σ2t, and rearranging: e kt e {.5[(kt µt)2 /σ 2 t]} = e {.5t[(k2 2µk+µ 2 2σ 2 k)/σ 2 ]} = e {.5t[(k2 2µk+µ 2 2σ 2 k+σ 4 σ 4 )/σ 2 ]} = e {.5t[((k µ σ2 ) 2 σ 4 2µσ 2 )/σ 2 ]} = e (µ+.5σ2 )t e {.5[(kt (µ+σ2 )t) 2 /σ 2 t]}. (16) In equation (16), the term e (µ+.5σ2 )t = E(S T /S), the mean of the t-period lognormally distributed price ratio S T /S. Therefore, we can rewrite equation (15) with this term appearing 8 For the sake of simplifying notation, the k subscripts are dropped in the subsequent analysis. 9 The relationship between f (kt) and g(s t/s) is apparent from differentiating the cumulative distribution function F (kt) with respect to S t/s : df (kt)/d(s t/s) = (df (kt)/d(kt))(dkt/d(s t/s)) = f(kt)(s/s t). 8

9 outside the integral: 1 SE X/S (S t /S) = SE(S t /S) 2πσ 2 t 1 = E(S t ) 2πσ 2 t ln(x/s) ln(x/s) e {.5[(kt (µ+σ2 )t) 2 /σ 2 t]} tdk e {.5[(kt (µ+σ2 )t) 2 /σ 2 t]} tdk. (17) Next, we let y = [kt (µ + σ 2 )t]/σ t, which implies that kt = (µ + σ 2 )t + σ ty and tdk = σ tdy. With this change in variables, [ln(x /S) - (µ + σ 2 )t]/σ t= δ 1 becomes the lower limit of integration. Thus equation (17) may be rewritten as: SE X/S (S t /S) = E(S t ) = E(S t ) [e.5y2 δ 1 δ1 n(y)dy / 2π]dy = E(S t )N(δ 1 ), (18) where n(y) is the standard normal density function evaluated at y and N(δ 1 ) is the standard normal distribution function evaluated at y = δ 1. In order to complete our computation of the expected value of C t, we must evaluate the integral X X/S g(s t /S)dS t /S. As noted earlier, since S t /S = e kt is lognormally distributed, ln (S t /S) = kt is normally distributed with density f (kt), mean µt and variance σ 2 t. Furthermore, this change in variable implies that f(kt)tdk must be substituted in place of g(s t /S)dS t /S. Therefore, X X/S g(s t /S)dS t /S = X f(kt)tdk ln(x/s) = X 1 2πσ 2 t ln(x/s) e {.5[(kt µt)2 /σ 2 t]} tdk. (19) Next, we let z = [kt µt]/σ t, which implies that kt = µt + σ tz and tdk = σ tdz. With this change in variables, the lower limit of integration becomes [ln(x/s) µt]/σ t = -(δ 1 - σ t) = δ 2. Substituting these results into the right-hand side of equation (19) 9

10 yields equation (20): X X/S g(s t /S)dS t /S = X = X [e.5z2 δ 2 δ2 n(z)dz / 2π]dz = XN(δ 2 ), (20) where n(z) is the standard normal density function evaluated at z and N(δ 2 ) is the standard normal distribution function evaluated at z = δ 2. Substituting the right-hand sides of equations (18) and (20) into the right-hand side of equation (14), we obtain E(C t ) = E(S t )N(δ 1 ) XN(δ 1 σ t). (21) Since equation (11) defines the price of a call option as the discounted, risk neutral expected value of the option s payoff at expiration; i.e., C = e rt Ê (C t ), our next task is to compute the risk neutral expected value of the stock price on the expiration date (Ê(S t)) and the risk neutral value for δ 1 (which we will refer to as d 1 ). In footnote (3), we noted that (µ +.5σ 2 )t = rt in a risk neutral economy. Since E(S t ) = Se (µ+.5σ2 )t, this implies that Ê(S t) = Se rt. In the expression for δ 1, the term (µ + σ 2 )t appears. In a risk neutral economy, (µ + σ 2 )t = (r +.5σ 2 )t; therefore,d 1 = [ln(s/x) +(r +.5σ 2 )t]/σ t. Substituting the right-hand side of equation (21) into the right-hand side of equation (11) and simplifying yields the Black-Scholes call option pricing formula: [ C = e rt Ê (C t ) = e rt Se rt N(d 1 ) XN(d 1 σ ] t) = SN(d 1 ) Xe rt N(d 2 ). (22) Now that we have the Black-Scholes pricing formula for a European call option, the put option pricing formula follows directly from the put-call parity theorem. Suppose two portfolios exist, one consisting of a European call option and a riskless discount bond, 10

11 and the other consisting of a European put option and a share of stock against which both options are written. The call and put both have exercise price X and t periods to expiration, and the riskless bond pays off X dollars at date t. Then these portfolios date t payoffs are identical, since the payoff on the first portfolio is Max(S t X, 0) + X = Max(S t, X) and the payoff on the second portfolio is Max(X S t, 0) + S T = Max(S t, X). Consequently, the current value of these portfolios must also be the same; otherwise there would be a riskless arbitrage opportunity. Therefore, the price of a European put option, P, can be determined as follows: P = C + Xe rt S = SN(d 1 ) Xe rt N(d 2 ) + Xe rt S = Xe rt [1 N(d 2 )] S [1 N(d 1 )] = Xe rt N( d 2 ) SN( d 1 ). (23) 4 Comparative Statics As indicated by equations (22) and (23), the prices of European call and put options depend upon five parameters: S, X, t, r, and σ. Next, we provide comparative statics analysis of call and put option prices. 4.1 Relationship between the call and put option prices and the price of the underlying asset Consider the relationship between the price of the call option and the price of the underlying asset, C/ S: C/ S = N(d 1 ) + S( N(d 1 )/ d 1 )( d 1 / S) Xe rt ( N(d 2 )/ d 2 )( d 2 / S) = N(d 1 ) + Sn(d 1 )( d 1 / S) Xe rt n(d 2 )( d 2 / S). (24) Substituting d 2 = d 1 -σ t, d 2 / S = d 1 / S, and n(d 2 ) = n(d 1 -σ t) into equation (24), 11

12 we obtain: C/ S = N(d 1 ) + ( d 1 / S)[Sn(d 1 ) Xe rt n(d 1 σ t)] 1 = N(d 1 ) + ( d 1 / S) [Se.5d2 1 Xe rt e.5(d 1 σ t) 2 ]. (25) 2π Recall that d 1 = [ln(s/x)+(r+.5σ 2 )t]/σ t. Solving for S, we find that S = Xe d 1σ t (r+.5σ 2 )t. Substituting this expression for S into the bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (25) s yields C/ S = 1 N(d 1 ) + ( d 1 / S) [Xe.5d2 1 e d 1 σ t (r+.5σ 2 )t Xe rt e.5(d 1 σ t) 2 ] 2π = 1 N(d 1 ) + ( d 1 / S) [X(e (r+.5σ2 )t+d 1 σ t.5d 2 1 e (r+.5σ 2 )t+d 1 σ t.5d 2 1 )]. (26) 2π Since the bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (26) equals zero, C/ S = N(d 1 ) > 0; i.e., the price of a call option is positively related to the price of its underlying asset. Furthermore, from our earlier analysis of the Black-Scholes partial differential equation, we know that a dynamically hedged portfolio consisting of one long call position per t = C/ S short shares of the underlying asset is riskless (cf. equation (5)). Since C/ S = N (d 1 ), N (d 1 ) is commonly referred to as the option s delta, and the dynamic hedging strategy described here is commonly referred to as delta hedging. Intuitively, since the put option provides its holder with the right to sell rather than buy, one would expect an inverse relationship between the price of a put option and the price of its underlying asset. Next, we analyze this relationship by finding P/ S: P/ S = N( d 1 ) + Xe rt ( N( d 2 )/ d 2 )( d 2 / S) S( N( d 1 )/ d 1 )( d 1 / S) = N( d 1 ) + Xe rt n( d 2 )( d 1 / S) Sn( d 1 )( d 1 / S) = N( d 1 ) + ( d 1 / S)[Xe rt n(σ t d 1 ) Sn( d 1 )] (27) Given the symmetry of the standard normal distribution about its mean of zero, Sn( d 1 ) = 12

13 Sn(d 1 ) and Xe rt n( d 2 ) = Xe rt n(d 2 ). Since we know from equation (26) that Sn(d 1 ) Xe rt n(d 1 σ t) = 0, it follows that the bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (27), Xe rt n(σ t d 1 ) Sn( d 1 ) = 0. Therefore, P/ S = N( d 1 ) < 0. Thus, our intuition is confirmed; i.e., the price of a put option is inversely related to the price of its underlying asset. 4.2 Relationship between call and put option prices and the exercise price Consider next the relationship between the price of the call option and the exercise price, C/ X : C/ X = e rt N(d 2 ) + S( N(d 1 )/ d 1 )( d 1 / X) Xe rt ( N(d 2 )/ d 2 )( d 2 / X) = e rt N(d 2 ) + Sn(d 1 )( d 1 / X) Xe rt n(d 2 )( d 2 / X) (28) Substituting d 2 = d 1 -σ t, d 2 / X = d 1 / X and n(d 2 ) = n(d 1 -σ t) into equation (28) gives us C/ X = e rt N(d 2 ) + ( d 1 / X)[Sn(d 1 ) Xe rt n(d 1 σ t)] = e rt N(d 2 ) < 0. (29) Intuition suggests that since the price of a call option is inversely related to its exercise price, one would expect to find that a positive relationship exists between the price of a put option and its exercise price, which we confirm in equation (30): P/ X = e rt N( d 2 ) + Xe rt ( N( d 2 )/ d 2 )( d 2 / X) S( N( d 1 )/ d 1 )( d 1 / X) = e rt N( d 2 ) + Xe rt n( d 2 )( d 1 / X) Sn( d 1 )( d 1 / X) = e rt N( d 2 ) + ( d 1 / X)[Xe rt n(σ t d 1 ) Sn( d 1 )] = e rt N( d 2 ) > 0. (30) 13

14 4.3 Relationship between call and put option prices and the interest rate Consider the relationship between the price of the call option and the rate of interest, C/ r: C/ r = txe rt N(d 2 ) + S( N(d 1 )/ d 1 )( d 1 / r) Xe rt ( N(d 2 )/ d 2 )( d 2 / r) = txe rt N(d 2 ) + Sn(d 1 )( d 1 / r) Xe rt n(d 2 )( d 2 / r) = txe rt N(d 2 ) + ( d 1 / r)[sn(d 1 ) Xe rt n(d 1 σ t)] = txe rt N(d 2 ) > 0. (31) Since the right-hand side of equation (31) is positive, this implies that the price of a call option is positively related to the rate of interest. This comparative static relationship is commonly referred to as the option s rho. Intuition suggests that since the price of a call option is positively related to the rate of interest, one would expect to find that an inverse relationship exists between the price of a put option and the rate of interest, which we confirm in equation (32): P/ r = txe rt N( d 2 ) + Xe rt ( N( d 2 )/ d 2 )( d 2 / r) + S( N( d 1 )/ d 1 )( d 1 / r) = txe rt N( d 2 ) + Xe rt n( d 2 )( d 2 / r) Sn( d 1 )( d 1 / r) = txe rt N( d 2 ) + ( d 1 / r)[xe rt n(σ t d 1 ) Sn( d 1 )] = txe rt N( d 2 ) < 0. (32) 14

15 4.4 Relationship between call and put option prices and the time to expiration Consider next the relationship between the price of the call option and the time to expiration, C/ t: C/ t = rxe rt N(d 2 ) + S( N(d 1 )/ d 1 )( d 1 / t) Xe rt ( N(d 2 )/ d 2 )( d 2 / t). (33) Substituting X = Se d 1σ t+(r+.5σ 2 )t into equation (33) and simplifying further, we obtain C/ t = rxe rt N(d 2 ) + S[n(d 1 )/ d 1 )( d 1 / t) e d 1σ t+(r+.5σ 2 )t rt n(d 1 σ t)( d 2 / t) = rxe rt N(d 2 ) + S 1 2π [( d 1 / t)e.5d2 1 ( d2 / t)e d 1σ t+(r+.5σ 2 )t rt.5(d 1 σ t) 2 ] = rxe rt N(d 2 ) + S 1 2π [( d 1 / t)e.5d2 1 ( d2 / t)e d 1σ t+d 1 σ t+rt rt+.5σ 2 t.5σ 2 t.5d 2 1 ] = rxe rt N(d 2 ) + Sn(d 1 )[( d 1 / t) ( d 2 / t)] = rxe rt N(d 2 ) + Sn(d 1 ).5σ t. (34) Since both terms on the right-hand side of equation (34) are positive, this implies that the price of a call option is positively related to the time to expiration; i.e., longer lived European call options are worth more than otherwise identical shorter lived European call options. Next, we consider the relationship between the price of a put option and the time to expiration: P/ t = rxe rt N( d 2 ) + Xe rt ( N( d 2 )/ d 2 )( d 2 / t) S( N( d 1 )/ d 1 )( d 1 / t). (35) 15

16 Substituting X = Se d 1σ t+(r+.5σ 2 )t into equation (35) and simplifying further, we obtain P/ t = rxe rt N( d 2 ) + Se d 1σ t+(r+.5σ 2 )t rt n(σ t d 1 )( d 2 / t) Sn(d 1 )( d 1 / t) = rxe rt N( d 2 ) + S 2π e d 1σ t+(r+.5σ 2 )t rt.5(σ t d 1 ) 2 ( d 2 / t) Sn( d 1 )( d 1 / t) = rxe rt N( d 2 ) + S 2π [( d 2 / t)e d 1σ t+d 1 σ t+rt rt+.5σ 2 t.5σ 2 t.5d 2 1 ( d1 / t)e.5d2 1 ] = rxe rt N( d 2 ) + Sn(d 1 )[( d 2 / t) ( d 1 / t)] = rxe rt N( d 2 ) + Sn(d 1 ).5σ t. (36) It is not possible to sign P/ t, because the first term is negative and the second term is positive. Therefore, the relationship between put value and time to expiration is ambiguous Relationship between call and put option prices and volatility of the underlying asset Finally, consider the relationship between the price of the call option and the volatility of the underlying asset, C/ σ: C/ σ = S N(d 1) d 1 d 1 σ Xe rt N(d 2) d 2 d 2 σ. (37) 10 The theta for an option represents the rate at which its value changes with the passage of time, given a fixed time to expiration. Therefore, the first term on the left-hand side of equation (8) corresponds to the theta for a call option which expires in T periods, where T represents a fixed unit of time. Thus theta for a call option, Θ C, is equal to 1 C/ t, where C/ t corresponds to the right-hand side of equation (34); i.e., Θ C = rxe rt N(d 2) Sn(d 1).5σ t < 0. Since the theta of a call option is negative, this implies that with the passage of time, call options become less valuable. However, since, Θ P = rxe rt N( d 2) Sn(d 1).5σ k t, this implies that the theta for a put option may be positive or negative depending upon the relative magnitudes of the two terms with opposing signs. 16

17 Substituting N(d 2) d 2 = n(d 2 ) = n(d 1 σ k t), d 2 σ = d 1 σ t, and X = Se d 1σ t+(r+.5σ 2 )t into the right-hand side of equation (37) and simplifying further, we obtain [ C/ σ = S n(d 1 ) d 1 = S ] σ e d 1σ t+(r+.5σ 2 )t rt d 2 n(d 1 σ k t) σ t+rt+.5σ 2 t rt.5(d 1 σ t) 2 [ e.5d2 1 2π d 1 σ e d1σ 2π ( d1 σ t ) ]. (38) Since e d 1σ t+rt+.5σ 2 t rt.5(d 1 σ t) 2 = e.5d2 1 and n(d1 ) = e.5d2 1 2π, equation (38) can be rewritten as [ ( d1 C/ σ = Sn(d 1 ) σ d1 σ )] t = Sn(d 1 ) t > 0. (39) As equation (39) indicates, the price of a call option is positively related to the volatility of the underlying asset. This comparative static relationship is commonly referred to as the option s vega. Next, we consider the relationship between the price of a put option and the volatility of the underlying asset, P/ σ: P/ σ = Xe rt N( d 2) d 2 d 2 σ S N( d 1) d 1 d 1 σ = Xe rt n( d 2 ) d 2 σ + Sn( d 1) d 1 σ. (40) Substituting d 2 = σ t d 1, d 2 σ = d 1 σ t, and X = Se d 1σ t+(r+.5σ 2 )t into the right hand side of equation (40) and simplifying further yields: P/ σ = S[n( d 1 ) d t+rt+.5σ 1 σ e d1σ 2 t rt.5(σ t d 1) 2 ( d 1 2π σ t)] = Sn( d 1 )[ d 1 σ ( d 1 σ t)] = Sn( d 1 ) t > 0. (41) 17

18 As equation (41) indicates, the price of a put option is positively related to the volatility of the underlying asset. Table 1 summarizes the comparative statics of the Black-Scholes call and put option pricing formulas. 18

19 Table 1. Comparative Statics of the Black-Scholes Model Derivative Call Option Put Option C P and C S S S = N (d 1) > 0 (delta) C P C and X X X = -e rt N (d 2 ) < 0 C P and C r r r = txe rt N (d 2 ) > 0 (rho) C P C and t t t =rxe rt N(d 2 ) + Sn(d 1 ).5σ t > 0 theta C P and σ σ (vega) - C t = rxe rt N(d 2 ) Sn(d 1 ).5σ t < 0 C σ = Sn(d 1) t > 0 P S = -N (-d 1) < 0 P X = e rt N (-d 2 ) > 0 P r = -txe rt N (-d 2 ) < 0 P t = rxe rt N( d 2 )+Sn(d 1 ).5σ? k t <> 0 - P t =rxe rt N( d 2 ) Sn(d 1 ).5σ? k t <> 0 P σ = Sn( d 1) t > 0 19

20 5 References Black, F., and M. Scholes (1973), The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, Journal of Political Economy 81: Brennan M. J., 1979, The Pricing of Contingent Claims in Discrete Time Models, Journal of Finance, Vol. 34, No. 1 (March), pp Churchill, R. V. (1963), Fourier Series and Boundary Value Problems, 2 nd edition, New York: McGraw-Hill. Cox, J. C., and S. A. Ross (1976), The Valuation of Options for Alternative Stochastic Processes, Journal of Financial Economics 3: Rubinstein, M. (1976), The Valuation of Uncertain Income Streams and the Pricing of Options, Bell Journal of Economics 7: Rubinstein, M. (1987), Derivative Assets Analysis, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1(Autumn): Stapleton, R. C. and M. G. Subrahmanyam, 1984, The Valuation of Multivariate Contingent Claims in Discrete Time Models, Journal of Finance, Vol. 39, No. 1 (March), pp Wilmott, P. (2001), Paul Wilmott Introduces Quantitative Finance, Chichester, England: John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Winkler, R. L., G. M. Roodman and R. R. Britney (1972), The Determination of Partial Moments, Management Science 19(3):

Derivation and Comparative Statics of the Black-Scholes Call and Put Option Pricing Formulas

Derivation and Comparative Statics of the Black-Scholes Call and Put Option Pricing Formulas Derivation and Comparative Statics of the Black-Scholes Call and Put Option Pricing Formulas James R. Garven Current Version: November 15, 2017 Abstract This paper provides an alternative derivation of

More information

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather Review of some financial models for MAT 483 Parity and Other Option Relationships The basic parity relationship for European options with the same strike price and the same time to expiration is: C( KT

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu 4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs Math6911 S08, HM Zhu References 1. Chapter 13, J. Hull. Section.6, P. Brandimarte Outline Derivation of Black-Scholes equation Black-Scholes models for options Implied

More information

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 2017 14 Lecture 14 November 15, 2017 Derivation of the

More information

Financial Risk Management

Financial Risk Management Risk-neutrality in derivatives pricing University of Oulu - Department of Finance Spring 2018 Portfolio of two assets Value at time t = 0 Expected return Value at time t = 1 Asset A Asset B 10.00 30.00

More information

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Black-Scholes Option Pricing Black-Scholes Option Pricing The pricing kernel furnishes an alternate derivation of the Black-Scholes formula for the price of a call option. Arbitrage is again the foundation for the theory. 1 Risk-Free

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

25857 Interest Rate Modelling 25857 Interest Rate Modelling UTS Business School University of Technology Sydney Chapter 19. Allowing for Stochastic Interest Rates in the Black-Scholes Model May 15, 2014 1/33 Chapter 19. Allowing for

More information

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Black-Scholes-Merton Model Black-Scholes-Merton Model Weerachart Kilenthong University of the Thai Chamber of Commerce c Kilenthong 2017 Weerachart Kilenthong University of the Thai Chamber Black-Scholes-Merton of Commerce Model

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory Dr. Roman V Belavkin MSO4112 Contents 1 Geometric Brownian motion 1 2 The Black-Scholes pricing 2 3 The Black-Scholes equation 3 References 5 1 Geometric Brownian motion

More information

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing theory of financial derivatives Pricing theory of financial derivatives One-period securities model S denotes the price process {S(t) : t = 0, 1}, where S(t) = (S 1 (t) S 2 (t) S M (t)). Here, M is the number of securities. At t = 1,

More information

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation International Journal of Mathematics and Soft Computing Vol.5, No.2 (2015), 69-74. ISSN Print : 2249-3328 ISSN Online: 2319-5215 Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation Purity J. Kiptum 1,

More information

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING Version date: June 3, 017 C:\CLASSES\TEACHING NOTES\TN98-04.WPD The exchange option, first developed by Margrabe (1978), has proven to be an extremely powerful

More information

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying

More information

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes Bluff our Way Through Black-Scholes Saurav Sen December 000 Contents What is Black-Scholes?.............................. 1 The Classical Black-Scholes Model....................... 1 Some Useful Background

More information

WITH SKETCH ANSWERS. Postgraduate Certificate in Finance Postgraduate Certificate in Economics and Finance

WITH SKETCH ANSWERS. Postgraduate Certificate in Finance Postgraduate Certificate in Economics and Finance WITH SKETCH ANSWERS BIRKBECK COLLEGE (University of London) BIRKBECK COLLEGE (University of London) Postgraduate Certificate in Finance Postgraduate Certificate in Economics and Finance SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS,

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh The Black-Scholes Model In these notes we will use Itô s Lemma and a replicating argument to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula

More information

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008 Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 008 Background Dynamic replication is a risk management technique used to mitigate market risk We hope to spend a certain

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes 1/ 27 Introduction Using a mixture of jump and di usion processes can model asset prices that are subject to large, discontinuous changes,

More information

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels 1/ 36 Introduction A contingent claim s price process can be transformed into a martingale process by 1 Adjusting

More information

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6 Lecture 3 Sergei Fedotov 091 - Introduction to Financial Mathematics Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) 091 010 1 / 6 Lecture 3 1 Distribution for lns(t) Solution to Stochastic Differential Equation

More information

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Financial Derivatives Section 5 Financial Derivatives Section 5 The Black and Scholes Model Michail Anthropelos anthropel@unipi.gr http://web.xrh.unipi.gr/faculty/anthropelos/ University of Piraeus Spring 2018 M. Anthropelos (Un. of

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13. FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 Asset Price Dynamics Introduction These notes give assumptions of asset price returns that are derived from the efficient markets hypothesis. Although a hypothesis,

More information

Probability in Options Pricing

Probability in Options Pricing Probability in Options Pricing Mark Cohen and Luke Skon Kenyon College cohenmj@kenyon.edu December 14, 2012 Mark Cohen and Luke Skon (Kenyon college) Probability Presentation December 14, 2012 1 / 16 What

More information

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions Arfima Financial Solutions Contents Definition 1 Definition 2 3 4 Contenido Definition 1 Definition 2 3 4 Definition Definition: A barrier option is an option on the underlying asset that is activated

More information

Simulation Analysis of Option Buying

Simulation Analysis of Option Buying Mat-.108 Sovelletun Matematiikan erikoistyöt Simulation Analysis of Option Buying Max Mether 45748T 04.0.04 Table Of Contents 1 INTRODUCTION... 3 STOCK AND OPTION PRICING THEORY... 4.1 RANDOM WALKS AND

More information

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 and Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 Prof. Dr. Erich Walter Farkas Lecture 06: March 26, 2015 1 / 47 Remember and Previous chapters: introduction to the theory of options put-call parity fundamentals

More information

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Aspects of Financial Mathematics: Aspects of Financial Mathematics: Options, Derivatives, Arbitrage, and the Black-Scholes Pricing Formula J. Robert Buchanan Millersville University of Pennsylvania email: Bob.Buchanan@millersville.edu

More information

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market Journal of Uncertain Systems Vol.2, No., pp.7-2, 28 Online at: www.jus.org.uk Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market Zhongfeng Qin, Xiang Li Department of Mathematical Sciences Tsinghua University,

More information

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna) A imple Approach to CA and Option ricing Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna) rcesari@economia.unibo.it dadda@spbo.unibo.it eptember, 001 eywords: asset pricing, CA, option pricing.

More information

Arbitrages and pricing of stock options

Arbitrages and pricing of stock options Arbitrages and pricing of stock options Gonzalo Mateos Dept. of ECE and Goergen Institute for Data Science University of Rochester gmateosb@ece.rochester.edu http://www.ece.rochester.edu/~gmateosb/ November

More information

Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk *

Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk * Seoul Journal of Business Volume 4, Number (December 018) Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk * JONG-RYONG LEE **1) Kangwon National University Gangwondo, Korea Abstract This paper develops the credit

More information

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 The Greeks Introduction We have studied how to price an option using the Black-Scholes formula. Now we wish to consider how the option price changes, either

More information

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation Peter Cassar May 0, 05 Assumptions of the Black-Scholes Model We have a risk free asset given by the price process, dbt = rbt The asset price follows a geometric

More information

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation Solving the Black-Scholes Equation An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2014 Initial Value Problem for the European Call The main objective of this lesson is solving

More information

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions he chapter references below refer to the chapters of the ActuraialBrew.com Study Manual. Solution 1 C Chapter 16, Sharpe Ratio If we (incorrectly) assume that the

More information

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS. MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS May/June 2006 Time allowed: 2 HOURS. Examiner: Dr N.P. Byott This is a CLOSED

More information

1 Geometric Brownian motion

1 Geometric Brownian motion Copyright c 05 by Karl Sigman Geometric Brownian motion Note that since BM can take on negative values, using it directly for modeling stock prices is questionable. There are other reasons too why BM is

More information

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12 Lecture 11: Ito Calculus Continuous time models We start with the model from Chapter 3 log S j log S j 1 = µ t + p tz j Sum it over j: log S N log S 0 = NX µ t + NX p tzj j=1 j=1 Can we take the limit

More information

TEACHING NOTE 00-03: MODELING ASSET PRICES AS STOCHASTIC PROCESSES II. is non-stochastic and equal to dt. From these results we state the following:

TEACHING NOTE 00-03: MODELING ASSET PRICES AS STOCHASTIC PROCESSES II. is non-stochastic and equal to dt. From these results we state the following: TEACHING NOTE 00-03: MODELING ASSET PRICES AS STOCHASTIC PROCESSES II Version date: August 1, 2001 D:\TN00-03.WPD This note continues TN96-04, Modeling Asset Prices as Stochastic Processes I. It derives

More information

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Eni Musta Università degli studi di Pisa San Miniato - 16 September 2016 Overview 1 Self-financing portfolio 2 Complete

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.7J Fall 213 Lecture 19 11/2/213 Applications of Ito calculus to finance Content. 1. Trading strategies 2. Black-Scholes option pricing formula 1 Security

More information

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation Solving the Black-Scholes Equation An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2010 Initial Value Problem for the European Call rf = F t + rsf S + 1 2 σ2 S 2 F SS for (S,

More information

The Black-Scholes Equation

The Black-Scholes Equation The Black-Scholes Equation MATH 472 Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2018 Objectives In this lesson we will: derive the Black-Scholes partial differential equation using Itô s Lemma and no-arbitrage

More information

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Department of Statistics and Modelling Science University of Strathclyde Glasgow, G1 1XH China 2009 Outline Stochastic Modelling in Asset Prices 1 Stochastic

More information

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems Steve Dunbar No Due Date: Practice Only. Find the mode (the value of the independent variable with the

More information

Option Pricing in Continuous-Time: The Black Scholes Merton Theory and Its Extensions

Option Pricing in Continuous-Time: The Black Scholes Merton Theory and Its Extensions Chapter 2 Option Pricing in Continuous-Time: The Black Scholes Merton Theory and Its Extensions This chapter is organized as follows: 1. Section 2 provides an overview of the option pricing theory in the

More information

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 217 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 217 13 Lecture 13 November 15, 217 Derivation of the Black-Scholes-Merton

More information

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly).

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly). 1 EG, Ch. 22; Options I. Overview. A. Definitions. 1. Option - contract in entitling holder to buy/sell a certain asset at or before a certain time at a specified price. Gives holder the right, but not

More information

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility Abstract Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility Artur Sepp Mail: artursepp@hotmail.com, Web: www.hot.ee/seppar 16 November 2002 We study pricing under the local volatility. Our research is mainly

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58-6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15-19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9-31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36-37)

More information

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time Nico van der Wijst 1 Finance: A Quantitative Introduction c Cambridge University Press 1 Modelling stock returns in continuous

More information

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options Options An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2014 Definitions and Terminology Definition An option is the right, but not the obligation, to buy or sell a security such

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing We shall go over this note quickly due to time constraints. Key concept: Ito s lemma Stock Options: A contract giving

More information

European call option with inflation-linked strike

European call option with inflation-linked strike Mathematical Statistics Stockholm University European call option with inflation-linked strike Ola Hammarlid Research Report 2010:2 ISSN 1650-0377 Postal address: Mathematical Statistics Dept. of Mathematics

More information

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk Continuous Time Finance Tomas Björk 1 II Stochastic Calculus Tomas Björk 2 Typical Setup Take as given the market price process, S(t), of some underlying asset. S(t) = price, at t, per unit of underlying

More information

Greek Maxima 1 by Michael B. Miller

Greek Maxima 1 by Michael B. Miller Greek Maxima by Michael B. Miller When managing the risk of options it is often useful to know how sensitivities will change over time and with the price of the underlying. For example, many people know

More information

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee orean J. Math. 3 015, No. 1, pp. 81 91 http://dx.doi.org/10.11568/kjm.015.3.1.81 LOCAL VOLATILITY FOR QUANTO OPTION PRICES WITH STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee Abstract. This paper

More information

Math 181 Lecture 15 Hedging and the Greeks (Chap. 14, Hull)

Math 181 Lecture 15 Hedging and the Greeks (Chap. 14, Hull) Math 181 Lecture 15 Hedging and the Greeks (Chap. 14, Hull) One use of derivation is for investors or investment banks to manage the risk of their investments. If an investor buys a stock for price S 0,

More information

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility Simple Arbitrage Relations Payoffs to Call and Put Options Black-Scholes Model Put-Call Parity Implied Volatility Option Pricing Options: Definitions A call option gives the buyer the right, but not the

More information

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

Edgeworth Binomial Trees Mark Rubinstein Paul Stephens Professor of Applied Investment Analysis University of California, Berkeley a version published in the Journal of Derivatives (Spring 1998) Abstract This paper develops a

More information

Ṽ t (H) = e rt V t (H)

Ṽ t (H) = e rt V t (H) liv10.tex Week 10: 31.3.2014 The Black-Scholes Model (continued) The discounted value process is and the interest rate is r. So Ṽ t (H) = e rt V t (H) dṽt(h) = re rt dt.v t (H) + e rt dv t (H) (since e

More information

Degree project. Pricing American and European options under the binomial tree model and its Black-Scholes limit model

Degree project. Pricing American and European options under the binomial tree model and its Black-Scholes limit model Degree project Pricing American and European options under the binomial tree model and its Black-Scholes limit model Author: Yuankai Yang Supervisor: Roger Pettersson Examiner: Astrid Hilbert Date: 2017-09-28

More information

PAijpam.eu ANALYTIC SOLUTION OF A NONLINEAR BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION

PAijpam.eu ANALYTIC SOLUTION OF A NONLINEAR BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION International Journal of Pure and Applied Mathematics Volume 8 No. 4 013, 547-555 ISSN: 1311-8080 (printed version); ISSN: 1314-3395 (on-line version) url: http://www.ijpam.eu doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.173/ijpam.v8i4.4

More information

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 1/ 36 Introduction Asset prices are modeled as following di usion processes, permitting the possibility of continuous trading. This environment

More information

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE DOI: 1.1214/ECP.v7-149 Elect. Comm. in Probab. 7 (22) 79 83 ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS in PROBABILITY OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE FIMA KLEBANER Department of Mathematics & Statistics,

More information

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions Course MFE/3F Practice Exam Solutions he chapter references below refer to the chapters of the ActuraialBrew.com Study Manual. Solution C Chapter 6, Sharpe Ratio If we (incorrectly) assume that the cost

More information

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS Commun. Korean Math. Soc. 23 (2008), No. 2, pp. 285 294 EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS Kyoung-Sook Moon Reprinted from the Communications of the Korean Mathematical Society

More information

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying Sensitivity analysis Simulating the Greeks Meet the Greeks he value of a derivative on a single underlying asset depends upon the current asset price S and its volatility Σ, the risk-free interest rate

More information

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch chris bemis November 27, 2006 0-0 Goal: Derive the Black-Scholes PDE To do this, we will need to: Come up with some dynamics for the stock returns Discuss Brownian motion

More information

Lévy models in finance

Lévy models in finance Lévy models in finance Ernesto Mordecki Universidad de la República, Montevideo, Uruguay PASI - Guanajuato - June 2010 Summary General aim: describe jummp modelling in finace through some relevant issues.

More information

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model he Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model Vladimir Vovk he Game-heoretic Probability and Finance Project Working Paper #39 September 6, 011 Project web site: http://www.probabilityandfinance.com

More information

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing CHAPTR 2. CONTINUUM MODL 8 2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing Options are some of the commonest examples of derivative securities (also termed financial derivatives or simply derivatives). A uropean

More information

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market Xiaowei Chen Uncertainty Theory Laboratory, Department of Mathematical Sciences Tsinghua University, Beijing 184, China chenxw7@mailstsinghuaeducn

More information

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

25857 Interest Rate Modelling 25857 UTS Business School University of Technology Sydney Chapter 20. Change of Numeraire May 15, 2014 1/36 Chapter 20. Change of Numeraire 1 The Radon-Nikodym Derivative 2 Option Pricing under Stochastic

More information

THE BLACK-SCHOLES FORMULA AND THE GREEK PARAMETERS FOR A NONLINEAR BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION

THE BLACK-SCHOLES FORMULA AND THE GREEK PARAMETERS FOR A NONLINEAR BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION International Journal of Pure and Applied Mathematics Volume 76 No. 2 2012, 167-171 ISSN: 1311-8080 printed version) url: http://www.ijpam.eu PA ijpam.eu THE BLACK-SCHOLES FORMULA AND THE GREEK PARAMETERS

More information

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1.

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1. THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** Abstract The change of numeraire gives very important computational

More information

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 3 - Derivatives with averaging style payoffs 3.1 Pricing models of Asian options Partial differential approach for continuous models Closed form pricing

More information

[AN INTRODUCTION TO THE BLACK-SCHOLES PDE MODEL]

[AN INTRODUCTION TO THE BLACK-SCHOLES PDE MODEL] 2013 University of New Mexico Scott Guernsey [AN INTRODUCTION TO THE BLACK-SCHOLES PDE MODEL] This paper will serve as background and proposal for an upcoming thesis paper on nonlinear Black- Scholes PDE

More information

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model Credit Risk : Firm Value Model Prof. Dr. Svetlozar Rachev Institute for Statistics and Mathematical Economics University of Karlsruhe and Karlsruhe Institute of Technology (KIT) Prof. Dr. Svetlozar Rachev

More information

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II Options Pricing II Intrinsic Value and Time Value Boundary Conditions for Option Pricing Arbitrage Based Relationship for Option Pricing Put Call Parity 2 Binomial Option

More information

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN 2010-2011 LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK In this section we look at some easy extensions of the Black

More information

Monte Carlo Simulations

Monte Carlo Simulations Monte Carlo Simulations Lecture 1 December 7, 2014 Outline Monte Carlo Methods Monte Carlo methods simulate the random behavior underlying the financial models Remember: When pricing you must simulate

More information

Black-Scholes model: Derivation and solution

Black-Scholes model: Derivation and solution III. Black-Scholes model: Derivation and solution Beáta Stehlíková Financial derivatives Faculty of Mathematics, Physics and Informatics Comenius University, Bratislava III. Black-Scholes model: Derivation

More information

Models of Option Pricing: The Black-Scholes, Binomial and Monte Carlo Methods

Models of Option Pricing: The Black-Scholes, Binomial and Monte Carlo Methods Registration number 65 Models of Option Pricing: The Black-Scholes, Binomial and Monte Carlo Methods Supervised by Dr Christopher Greenman University of East Anglia Faculty of Science School of Computing

More information

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 MSc Financial Engineering 2012-13 CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 Department EMS, Birkbeck Introduction The assignment consists of Reading

More information

ON AN IMPLEMENTATION OF BLACK SCHOLES MODEL FOR ESTIMATION OF CALL- AND PUT-OPTION VIA PROGRAMMING ENVIRONMENT MATHEMATICA

ON AN IMPLEMENTATION OF BLACK SCHOLES MODEL FOR ESTIMATION OF CALL- AND PUT-OPTION VIA PROGRAMMING ENVIRONMENT MATHEMATICA Доклади на Българската академия на науките Comptes rendus de l Académie bulgare des Sciences Tome 66, No 5, 2013 MATHEMATIQUES Mathématiques appliquées ON AN IMPLEMENTATION OF BLACK SCHOLES MODEL FOR ESTIMATION

More information

1 The continuous time limit

1 The continuous time limit Derivative Securities, Courant Institute, Fall 2008 http://www.math.nyu.edu/faculty/goodman/teaching/derivsec08/index.html Jonathan Goodman and Keith Lewis Supplementary notes and comments, Section 3 1

More information

Option Pricing Model with Stepped Payoff

Option Pricing Model with Stepped Payoff Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol., 08, no., - 8 HIARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com https://doi.org/0.988/ams.08.7346 Option Pricing Model with Stepped Payoff Hernán Garzón G. Department of Mathematics Universidad

More information

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards Chapter 7 Forwards and Futures Copyright c 2008 2011 Hyeong In Choi, All rights reserved. 7.1 Basics of forwards and futures The financial assets typically stocks we have been dealing with so far are the

More information

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products June 2016 2 Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products Jungmin Choi Department of Mathematics East Carolina University Abstract In this study, a hybrid

More information

7.1 Volatility Simile and Defects in the Black-Scholes Model

7.1 Volatility Simile and Defects in the Black-Scholes Model Chapter 7 Beyond Black-Scholes Model 7.1 Volatility Simile and Defects in the Black-Scholes Model Before pointing out some of the flaws in the assumptions of the Black-Scholes world, we must emphasize

More information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous

More information

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I) Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I) Paul J. Atzberger General comments or corrections should be sent to: paulatz@cims.nyu.edu 1 Introduction When using the Black-Scholes-Merton model to price derivative

More information

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1 Computational Finance Computational Finance p. 1 Outline Binomial model: option pricing and optimal investment Monte Carlo techniques for pricing of options pricing of non-standard options improving accuracy

More information