Nonlinear pricing in imperfect financial markets

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Nonlinear pricing in imperfect financial markets"

Transcription

1 Nonlinear pricing in imperfect financial markets Agnès Sulem INRIA, Paris International summer school in mathematical finance on Informational and Imperfect Financial Markets, University of Alberta in Edmonton, Canada, June 25-30, 2016

2 Abstract The aim of the lectures is to study pricing and hedging issues for various options (European, American, game options) in the case of imperfections on the market. These imperfections are taken into account via the nonlinearity of the wealth dynamics. In this setting, the pricing system is expressed as a nonlinear g-expectation/g-evaluation induced by a nonlinear BSDE. We shall address in particular superhedging issues for American and game options in this context and their links with generalized optimal stopping problems and Dynkin games.

3 Overview 1. The perfect market model (linear case) Linear pricing system and linear BSDEs 2. Market with imperfections Nonlinear pricing system and nonlinear BSDEs (g-evaluation). Links with dynamic risk measures 3. Nonlinear pricing of American Contingent claims - Introduction to reflected BSDEs. Links with optimal stopping. 4. Game options in an imperfect market. Links with generalized Dynkin games and doubly reflected nonlinear BSDEs. 5. Market model with default

4 I. Linear pricing theory Market model Let (Ω, (F t ) t 0, P)) be a filtered probability space, where (F t ) t 0 is generated by the Wiener process W and completed. Let T > 0 be fixed. Consider a complete financial market with one risk free and one risky investment possibility, with prices S 0, S 1 per unit given by, respectively { dst 0 = St 0 r t dt ; S0 0 (1) = 1 dst 1 = St 1 [µ t dt + σ t dw t ] ; S0 1 > 0; where r t, µ t, σ t are bounded predictable processes. Assume σ t 0 and σt 1 bounded.

5 Linear pricing theory Strategy Wealth/Portfolio Definition (Strategy) A strategy is given by a couple of predictable processes V t the value of the wealth of the investor (or the value of his portfolio) ϕ t the portfolio process equal to the amount of total wealth invested in the risky asset at time t. A strategy is self-financing if dv t = (V t ϕ t ) ds0 t dst 1 St 0 + ϕ t St 1 = (V t ϕ t )rdt + ϕ t (µ t dt + σ t dw t ] = (rv t + θ t σ t ϕ t )dt + σ t ϕ t dw t where θ t := µ t r t σ t is the risk premium process.

6 Linear pricing theory Pricing and hedging European contingent claims We consider a European contingent claim with maturity T > 0 and payoff ξ which is F T -measurable. The problem is to find a self-financing strategy (V t, ϕ t ) which reaches ξ at time T. Classical approach (without BSDE theory) : (Karatzas-Shreve...) Discounting and change of probability measure. integrability conditions under Q (unique martingale measure) BSDE approach No discounting and no change of probability measure. integrability conditions (for ξ and ϕ) under P (reference probability)

7 Linear pricing theory Classical approach Let Q be the unique martingale probability measure defined by dq dp F T T = exp( θ s dw s 1 T θs 2 ds) From Girsanov theorem, under Q, Wt := W t + t 0 θ sds is a F- Brownian motion and by Itô, S := e t 0 rsds S t is a martingale under Q. d S = Sσ t d W t. We consider the discounted wealth Ṽ := e t 0 rsds V t. We get dṽ = ϕσ t d W t, where ϕ := e t 0 rsds ϕ t is the discounted portfolio.

8 The pricing/hedging problem is to construct a couple (V t, ϕ t ) (value of portfolio, portfolio) such that { dv t = (r t V t + θ t ϕ t σ t )dt + ϕ t σ t dw t ; 0 t T. V T = ξ a.s. that is to find (Ṽ t, ϕ t ) (2) { d Ṽ t = ϕσ t d W t ; 0 t T. Ṽ T = ξ a.s. where ξ = e T 0 ξ. In order to have uniqueness we need integrability conditions. Here the integrability conditions are under Q. It is required that E Q (ξ 2 ) < + (or equivalently, E Q ( ξ 2 ) < + since r t is bounded), and we look for ϕ in H 2 Q (set of predictable processes, square integrable under Q, that is E Q ( T equivalently, E Q ( T 0 ϕ 2 s ds < ), since σ t, σt 1 0 ϕ2 s ds < ) (or bounded).

9 Theorem If ξ L 2 Q (F T ),!(Ṽ, ϕ) H 2 Q H2 Q satisfying (2). Proof. Take Ṽ t = E Q ( ξ F t ). By the theorem of representation of martingales under Q with respect to Brownian motion W, t!(ψ t ) H 2 Q, s.t. Ṽ t = Ṽ0 + Ψ s d W s. 0 Set ϕ t = Ψ t σt 1. We obtain dṽ t = ϕσ t d W t ; Ṽ T = ξ. We get ϕ t = e t 0 rsds ϕ t and V t = e t 0 rsds Ṽ t, i.e.,under P: V t = E P [e T t r sds e T t θ sdw s T t θ 2 s ds ξ F t ] = E P [Γ t,t ξ F t ] ; 0 t T a.s. where the process Γ, called deflator or change of numeraire, is given by dγ t,s = Γ t,s [ r s ds θ s dw s ] ; Γ t,t = 1, Γ t,s = exp( s t θ u dw u + s t i.e. { r u 1 2 θ2 u})du.

10 Linear pricing theory BSDE approach The problem can be formulated in terms of a BSDE problem. Set (3) Z t = ϕ t σ t. Suppose E P [ξ 2 ] < (in L 2 P (F T )). We want to find a couple of square integrable (with respect to P) predictable processes (V, Z) such that { dv t = (r t V t + θ t Z t )dt + Z t dw t ; 0 t T. (4) V T = ξ a.s. Equation (4) is an example of a (linear) BSDE in the pair (V t, Z t ) of unknown processes. If we can solve this equation, then the replicating portfolio ϕ t is given by Z t σt 1 and V t is the hedging price of the claim at time t. Note that, in contrast to ordinary SDEs, Equation (4) has two unknown processes and the terminal value V T of V is given, not the initial value.

11 Both classical and BSDE approaches are possible for the linear case, but in the case of imperfections (nonlinear wealth), the classical approach can no more be used.

12 II. Imperfect financial markets An example leading to nonlinear wealth Different borrowing and lending interest rates, denoted respectively by R t and r t, adapted and bounded with R t r t. Amount borrowed at t: (V t ϕ t ) (at interest rate R t ) Amount lended at t: (V t ϕ t ) + (invested at bond rate r t ) We have: V t ϕ t = (V t ϕ t ) + (V t ϕ t ) Self- financing property gives: dv t = (V t ϕ t ) + r t dt (V t ϕ t ) R t dt + ϕ t ds 1 t S 1 t Using (V t ϕ t ) + = (V t ϕ t ) + (V t ϕ t ), we get, by easy computations dv t = r t V t dt (R t r t )(V t ϕ t ) dt + ϕ t σ t θ t dt + ϕ t σ t dw t.

13 Consider a European option with payoff ξ L 2 (F T ). Pricing and hedging this claim by constructing a replicating portfolio lead to the following problem : Find (V, ϕ) H 2 H 2 such that { dv t = (r t V t (R t r t )(V t ϕ t ) )dt + ϕ t σ t θ t dt + ϕ t σ t dw t ; V T = ξ. This is an example of nonlinear BSDE (coefficient of dt is nonlinear in V and φ). Does a solution exists?

14 Nonlinear BSDEs (Ω, F, P) W = (W t ) t 0 : d-dim Brownian motion; W t = (W 1 t,..., W d t ) F t = σ(w s, 0 s t) augmented with the P-null sets. T > 0 : terminal time H 2 (R) = {(φ t ) 0 t T, real-valued predictable processes s.t. E( T 0 φ2 t dt) < }. We denote φ H 2 = E( T 0 φ2 t dt). H 2 (R d ) = {(φ t ) 0 t T, predictable processes s.t. E( T 0 φ t 2 dt) < }.

15 Definition (Standard coefficients) ξ L 2 (F T ) (the terminal condition) g (the driver) : Ω [0, T ] R R d g(ω, t, y, z) such that (i) g is P B(R) B(R d ) - measurable (ii) E T 0 g(t, 0, 0)2 dt < (iii) g is uniformly Lipschitz w.r.t. y, z, i.e. C > 0 s.t. dt dp- a.s., y, y R, z, z R d, g(ω, t, y, z) g(ω, t, y, z ) C( y y + z z ).

16 Theorem (Existence and uniqueness for BSDEs) There exists a unique solution (Y, Z) H 2 (R) H 2 (R d ) of the BSDE associated to standard coefficients (ξ, g), that is satisfying: { dy t = g(t, Y t, Z t )dt Zt dw t 0 t T (5) Y T = ξ. This result can be extended when the terminal time T is replaced by a stopping time S T 0,T.

17 Proof Suppose g does not depend on y and z, i.e. g(ω, t, y, z) = g(t, ω) H 2 (R) (6) dy t = g(t)dt Z t dw t ; Y T = ξ. Uniqueness. Integrating (6) between t and T, we get Y t = ξ + Taking E( F t ) we get T (7) Y t = E[ξ + t g(s)ds T t T t Z s dw s g(s)ds F t ]. Existence. Consider the candidate Y given by (7). Then Y t + t 0 g(s)ds = E[ξ + T 0 g(s)ds F t]. It is a martingale. By the martingale representation thm, there exists a unique Z in H 2 s. t. Y t + t 0 g(s)ds = Y 0 + t 0 Z s dw s. and we get dy t + g(t)dt = Zt dw t and Y T = ξ. (Y, Z) is thus a solution in H 2 (R) H 2 (R d ) of the BSDE.

18 Moreover we have i.e. Y S 2. E[ sup Yt 2 ] < + 0 t T Hint: Use Burkholder-Davis-Gundy inequalities.

19 General standard driver g(t, ω, y, z) Proof of existence and uniqueness of the solution of the BSDE: We define a mapping Φ as follows. Given (U, V ) H 2 (R) H 2 (R d ), let Φ(U, V ) = (Y, Z) where (Y, Z) is the solution of the BSDE associated with driver g(s) = g(ω, s, U s (ω), V s (ω)) and terminal condition ξ (which is well defined.) We can show that Φ is a contraction (for the norm φ 2 β := E[ T 0 eβs φ 2 s ds] with β well chosen large enough) and thus admits an unique fixed point, which corresponds to the solution of BSDE (5). Detailed proof on the blackboard (see also Pham s book).

20 Linear BSDEs Theorem Let α, β be bounded predictable processes, ξ L 2 P (F T ) and φ predictable with E P [ T 0 φ2 t dt] <. Then there exists a unique solution (Y, Z) of square integrable predictable processes of the linear BSDE dy t = [φ t + α t Y t + β t Z t ]dt Z t dw t ; 0 t T ; Y T = ξ given by T Y t = E[Γ t,t ξ + Γ t,s φ s ds F t ] ; 0 t T a.s. t where the process Γ, usually called adjoint process, is given by dγ t,s = Γ t,s [α s ds + β s dw s ] ; Γ t,t = 1, i.e. s Γ t,s = exp( β u dw u + t s t {α u 1 2 β2 u})du.

21 Sketch of Proof: - Apply Itô formula to Y s Γ t,s - we obtain Y s Γ t,s + s t Γ t,r φ r dr is a martingale. Hence, T Y t = E[Γ t,t ξ + Γ t,s φ s ds F t ] ; 0 t T a.s. t Remark: Note that if ξ 0 and φ 0, then Y t 0.

22 Application to the replication portfolio problem in the linear case: { dy t = ( r t Y t θ t Z t )dt Z t dw t ; 0 t T. Y T = ξ a.s. In this case, we have φ t = 0, α t = r t, β t = θ t. This leads to the classical quasi explicit expression for the wealth Y t (value of replicating portfolio): Y t = E[Γ t,t ξ F t ], where Γ t,s is the deflator process, started at t, such that Γ t,s = exp{ s t r u du} exp{ s t θ u dw u 1 2 s t θ 2 udu}. This defines a linear price system Y : L 2 P H2 P ; ξ Y (ξ), which is increasing and corresponds to the classical free-arbitrage price system. Y (ξ) is called the hedging price of ξ. Note that in particular if ξ 0 a.s. then the price Y t 0.

23 Linear BSDEs were first introduced by Bismut 1973 as the adjoint equation associated with the stochastic Pontryagin maximum principle for stochastic control.

24 Theorem (Comparison theorem for BSDEs) Let (g 1, ξ 1 ), (g 2, ξ 2 ) be standard coefficients and (Y 1, Z 1 ), (Y 2, Z 2 ) be the solutions of the associated BSDEs. Assume ξ 1 ξ 2 g 1 (t, Yt 2, Zt 2 ) g 2 (t, Yt 2, Zt 2 ) Then Yt 1 Yt 2, 0 t T a.s.

25 Proof: Set Ȳ = Y 1 Y 2, Z = Z 1 Z 2 and take d = 1 to simplify. By difference of the 2 BSDEs, { dȳ t = {g 1 (t, Yt 1, Zt 1 ) g 2 (t, Yt 2, Zt 2 )}dt Z t dw t Ȳ T = ξ 1 ξ 2. Now g 1 (t, Yt 1, Zt 1 ) g 2 (t, Yt 2, Zt 2 ) = {g 1 (t, Yt 1, Zt 1 ) g 1 (t, Yt 2, Zt 1 )} + {g 1 (t, Yt 2, Zt 1 ) g 1 (t, Yt 2, Zt 2 )} + {g 1 (t, Yt 2, Zt 2 ) g 2 (t, Yt 2, Zt 2 )} = y g 1 (t)(yt 1 Yt 2 ) + z g 1 (t)(zt 1 Zt 2 ) + φ t where y g 1 (t) := g 1 (t, Yt 1, Zt 1 ) g 1 (t, Yt 2, Zt 1 ) Yt 1 Yt 2 z g 1 (t) := g 1 (t, Yt 2, Zt 1 ) g 1 (t, Yt 2, Zt 2 ) Zt 1 Zt if Yt 1 Yt 2 0; 0 otherwise if Z 1 t Z 2 t 0; 0 otherwise

26 So { dȳ t = { y g 1 (t)ȳ t + z g 1 (t) Z t + φ t }dt Z t dw t Ȳ T = ξ 1 ξ 2 This is a linear BSDE. Note that y g 1 (t) and z g 1 (t) are bounded since g is Lipschitz. Since φ t 0 and ξ 1 ξ 2 0 we get that Ȳt 0, 0 t T a.s.

27 Theorem (Strict Comparison theorem for BSDEs) Let (g 1, ξ 1 ), (g 2, ξ 2 ) be standard coefficients and (Y 1, Z 1 ), (Y 2, Z 2 ) be the solutions of the associated BSDEs. Assume ξ 1 ξ 2 a.s. g 1 (s, Y 2 s, Z 2 s ) g 2 (s, Y 2 s, Z 2 s ) a.s 0 s T Yt 1 = Yt 2 on A F t (for fixed t in [0, T ]) Then ξ 1 = ξ 2 on A and g 1 (s, Ys 2, Zs 2 ) = g 2 (s, Ys 2, Zs 2 ) a.s on A [t, T ]

28 Corollary (Sufficient condition of positivity) If ξ 0 a.s. and g(t, 0, 0) 0 a.s., then Y t 0, 0 t T a.s. Proof. We apply the comparison theorem to (g 1 = g, ξ 1 = ξ), (g 2 = 0, ξ 2 = 0). Solution associated to (g 1, ξ 1 ) : (Y 1, Z 1 ) = (Y, Z). Solution associated to (0, 0) : (Y 2, Z 2 ) = (0, 0).

29 Application to the example of higher interest rate for borrowing Consider an option with payoff ξ L 2 (F T ) in this market. Recall that the pricing/hedginp problem of European option with payoff ξ leads to the BSDE: find (V, ϕ) such that dv t = (r t V t (R t r t )(V t ϕ t ) )dt +ϕ t σ t θdt +ϕ t σ t dw t ; V T = ξ. or equivalently, setting Z t = ϕ t σ t, dv t = g(t, V t, Z t )dt Z t dw t, V T = ξ. with g(t, y, z) = r t y + (R t r t )(y z σ ) + θ t z By the thm of existence and uniqueness, there exists a unique solution (V, Z) of this BSDE in H 2 H 2 with nonlinear driver g. Note that g(t, 0, 0) = 0 in this example. By the corollary, we obtain that if ξ 0 a.s, then V t 0, 0 t T a.s.

30 Other examples of imperfections leading to nonlinear dynamics: dv t = g(t, V t, ϕ t σ t )dt ϕ t σ t dw t Large investor with trading strategy ϕ t affecting the market prices: r t (ω) = r(t, ω, ϕ t ) and similarly for σ, θ. g(t, V t, ϕ t σ t ) = r(t, ϕ t )V t ϕ t ( θ σ)(t, ϕ t ). Taxes on the profits on risky investments. g(t, V t, ϕ t σ t ) = (r t V t + ϕ t θ t σ t ) + ρϕ + t. Here, ρ ]0, 1[ represents an instantaneous tax coefficient on the gains made from the investments in the risky assets.

31 Imperfect financial markets More generally, when there are market imperfections captured by the nonlinearity of the wealth process dv t = g(t, V t, σ t ϕ t )dt σ t ϕ t dw t ; with driver g(t, y, z) uniformly Lipschitz with respect to y and z, the theory of BSDEs implies that given a claim ξ L 2 (F T ), there exists a unique solution (Y, ϕ) with Y and ϕ in H 2 (R) (i.e. predictable and square integrable) such that dy t = g(t, Y t, σ t ϕ t )dt σ t ϕ t dw t ; Y T = ξ. Y t is the price of the option at time t and ϕ t is the hedging portfolio.

32 Nonlinear pricing system E g The operator E g : (ξ, T ) Y (ξ, T ), where (Y (ξ, T ), Z(ξ, T )) is solution of the associated BSDE with coefficients (ξ, g) and terminal time T was first introduced in El-Karoui-Quenez 96 and called nonlinear pricing system, and later called g-conditional expectation in Peng This notion can be extended to the case where T is replaced by a stopping time τ T 0 and ξ by a random variable η L 2 (F τ ). Definition The g-conditional expectation E g is defined for all stopping time τ T 0 and all η L 2 (F τ ) by E g t,τ (η) := Y t (η, τ); 0 t T, where (Y (η, τ), Z(η, τ)) is the solution of the BSDE associated with driver g, terminal time τ and terminal condition η.

33 In the case of a perfect market, g(t, y, z) = r t y θ t z (linear) and the pricing system is linear, i.e. α, β R, E g t,t (αξ1 + βξ 2 ) = αe g t,t (ξ1 ) + βe g t,t (ξ2 )

34 Properties of the nonlinear pricing system (or g-evaluation) The price system is increasing: if ξ 1 ξ 2 a.s. then E t,t (ξ 1 ) E t,t (ξ 2 ) a.s. (By comparison thm) if g(t, 0, 0) = 0 a.s. on [0, T ] Ω, then E t,t (0) = 0 t. (i.e. the price of the null option is 0) (By uniqueness of the solution: (0, 0) is solution and it is the only one) Moreover the price system is positive, i.e. if ξ 0 a.s. then E t,t (ξ) 0. (By comparison thm) If g(t, 0, 0) = 0 a.s. then the pricing system satifies the non arbitrage property, i.e. if for t, A F t given, if if ξ 1 ξ 2 a.s. on A and Et,T (ξ 1 ) = E t,t (ξ 2 ) a.s. on A F t Then ξ 1 = ξ 2 a.s. on A Proof: Apply strict comparison thm with g 1 = g 2 = g.

35 if g is convex w.r.t. y, z, then the price system is convex, i.e. α [0, 1], ξ 1, ξ 2 L 2 (F T ), E t,t (αξ 1 + (1 α)ξ 2 ) αe t,t (ξ 1 ) + (1 α)e t,t (ξ 2 ) (By comparison thm)

36 The price system is time-consistent, i.e. if S T, then E t,t (ξ) = E t,s (E S,T (ξ)) 0 t S This corresponds to the flow property of BSDEs (also holds if S is a stopping time T ). In other words, s [0, T ], ξ L 2 (F s ), the g-evaluation E g t,s(ξ) is an E g -martingale. A continuous adapted process X t in S 2 is said to be an E-martingale if E σ,τ (X τ ) = X σ a.s. on σ τ, for all σ, τ T 0.

37 A brief introduction to risk measures Static framework We assume that uncertainty is described by a measurable space (Ω, F) of possible scenarios, and that risky positions belong to a linear space X. Let A X : Subset of acceptable positions. We require that A contains all constants and that X A whenever X Y for some Y A. We define the monetary risk measure by ρ(x ) : inf{m R X + m A} The functional ρ satisfies: 1. ρ(x + m) = ρ(x ) m for all X X and all constants m. (Translation invariance) 2. If X 1 X 2 then ρ(x 1 ) ρ(x 2 ). (Monotonicity) Interpretation: ρ(x ) is the amount to be added to X to make it acceptable, since by translation invariance, ρ(x + ρ(x )) = 0.

38 Example: Value at Risk (VaR) Suppose that a probability measure is given on the set Ω of all scenarios. A position is acceptable for the VaR if the probability of loss P[X < 0] is below some level β: VaR(X ) := inf{m R P[X + m < 0] β} It is thus a β-quantile of the distribution of X under P. VaR is widely used in practice but it is not convex; however convexity is a good property for a risk measure since it means that diversification should not increase the risk.

39 This has motivated an axiomatic approach for a general theory of monetary risk measures called coherent (A is a cone), Arzner et al. 99 then extended to the convex case (A convex) For all λ [0, 1] and all X 1, X 2 X. ρ(λx 1 + (1 λ)x 2 ) λρ(x 1 ) + (1 λ)ρ(x 2 ) (Föllmer & Schied 02, Frittelli & Rosazza-Gianin 02)

40 Example: the entropic risk measure ρ(x ) = 1 γ ln E P[exp( γx )] = sup {E Q [ X ] 1 H(Q P)} Q Q γ where H(Q P) is the relative entropy of Q with respect to P defined by: { E Q [ln dq H(Q P) = dp ] if Q admits a density w.r.t. P + otherwise

41 Dual Representation: Convex dualiy theory implies that convex risk measures are typically of the form: ρ(x ) = sup {E Q [ X ] α(q)} Q Q where Q is a set of probability measures and α is a penalty fonction which can take the value +. The penalty term vanishes in the special case of coherent risk measures. Interpretation in terms of model uncertainty : Worst case

42 Dynamic risk measures and relations to BSDEs Extension to the dynamic case. Additional axioms are required to get time-consistency ; Natural link with BSDEs. In the Brownian case, cf e.g. P. Barrieu - N. El Karoui 2004). in the case with jumps, see M.C. Quenez, A.S. SPA 13

43 Dynamic risk measures associated to BSDEs Let g be a standard Lipschitz driver. For each T > 0 and ξ L 2 (F T ), set ρ t (ξ, T ) := E g t,t (ξ), 0 t T, If T represents a given maturity and ξ a financial position at time T, then ρ t (ξ, T ) is interpreted as the risk measure of ξ at time t. The functional ρ : (ξ, T ) ρ (ξ, T ) defines then a dynamic risk measure induced by the BSDE with driver g.

44 ρ t (, T ) is monotonous (nonincreasing with respect to financial position ξ:) if ξ 1 ξ 2 then ρ t (ξ 1, T ) ρ t (ξ 2, T ) a.s. ρ satisfies the nonarbitrage property: If ξ 1 ξ 2 and if ρ t (ξ 1, T ) = ρ t (ξ 2, T ) a.s. on an event A F t, then ξ 1 = ξ 2 a.s. on A. If g is concave w.r.t. y, z, then ρ t (, T ) is convex. If g only depends on z (not on y), then ρ is invariant by translation (monetary risk measure), i.e. ρ t (ξ + ξ, T ) = ρ t (ξ, T ) ξ, ξ L 2 (F T ), ξ L 2 (F t ). Example: the dynamic entropic risk measure ρ t (ξ, T ) := 1 γ ln E[exp( γξ) F t] is associated to the BSDE with driver g(t, y, z) := 1 2 γz2.

45 Recursive utility (Duffie & Epstein (1992), Epstein & Zin (1989), Kreps & Porteus (1978)). Let g(t, y, c) be an F t -adapted process. Assume that c g(t, y, c) is concave for all t, y. The recursive utility process of a given consumption process c( ) 0 is defined as the solution Y of the equation [ T ] (8) Y t = E g(s, Y s, c s ))ds F t t ; 0 t T. This equation is equivalent to the following BSDE in (Y, Z): { dy t = g(t, Y t, c t )dt Z t db t (9) Y T = 0.

46 The Markovian case - Links of BSDEs with PDEs Let (t, x) [0, T ] R p. Let (Ss t,x, t s T ) the solution of the forward SDE: { ds s = b(s, S s )ds + σ(s, S s )dw s, t s T S t = x where b : [0, T ] R p R p and σ : [0, T ] R p R p d are Borelian Lipschitz w.r.t. x. Let (Ys t,x, Zs t,x ) be the solution of the BSDE { dy s = g(t, Ss t,x, Y s, Z s )dt Zs dw s t s T (10) Y T = Ψ(S t,x T ), where Ψ : R p R, g is Lipschitz w.r.t. (y, z) with constant C (uniformly wrt (t, s)), and b, σ, g, Ψ have linear growth. Y t,x t is a deterministic function of (t, x), denoted by u(t, x).

47 t,x t,x Theorem (Generalized Feyman-Kac representation) Let v a function of class C 1,2 such that v(t, x) + σ(t, x) x v(t, x) C(1 + x ), solution of the PDE { t v(t, x) + Lv(t, x) + g(t, x, v(t, x), σ(t, x) x v(t, x)) = 0 v(t, x) = Ψ(x) where x v denotes the gradient of v and L t,x is the infinitesimal generator of S s : L t,x := i b i (t, x) xi + i,j a i,j (t, x) 2 x i x j with a ij = 1 2 (σσ ) ij. Then v(t, x) = Y t,x t

48 Moreover Z t,x s Y t,x s = σ(s, S t,x s = v(s, Ss t,x ) s t ) x v(s, S t,x s ) s t. Proof. Apply Itô to v(s, S t,x s ). We get : dv(s, Ss t,x ) = { t v(s, S s ) + Lv(s, S s )}ds + x v(s, S s ) σ(s, S s )dw s Since v satisfies the PDE, the term in ds above is equal to g(t, S s, v(s, S s ), σ(s, S s ) x v(s, S s )). Moreover v(t, S T ) = Ψ(S T ) (terminal condition). So (v(s, Ss t,x ), σ (s, Ss t,x ) x v(s, Ss t,x )) is solution of the BSDE (10). By uniqueness it is equal a.s. to (Y s, Z s ). reference: Pardoux-Peng: BSDEs and quasi-linear PDEs 1992

49 This is a verification theorem. We have also a theorem which states that the function u(t, x) := Yt t,x is a viscosity solution of the PDE. (El Karoui-Peng-Quenez 97).

50 III. Nonlinear pricing of American Contingent claims Recall that an American option gives the right to the owner to exercise the option at any time before maturity. Consider the imperfect market M g, when under nonlinear constraints, the strategy (wealth V, portfolio ϕ) satisfies: dv t = g(t, V t, σ t ϕ t )dt σ t ϕ t dw t. where g is nonlinear (Lipschitz).

51 Consider an American option associated with horizon T > 0 and a payoff given by a continuous process (ξ t, 0 t T ). At time 0, it consists in the selection of a stopping time ν T leading to the payment of the payoff ξ ν from the seller to the buyer. We have seen that for an European option with payoff ξ and maturity T, its initial hedging price is given by E g 0,T (ξ). A natural price for the American option is the quantity (11) sup E g 0,ν (ξ ν), ν T which we call the g-value of the American option (first introduced in NEK-Quenez 96 and called fair value ).

52 Main results: 1. The g-value sup ν T E g 0,ν (ξ ν) of the American option with payoff ξ coincides with the solution of an associated reflected BSDE with barrier ξ. 2. It is equal to the superhedging price u 0 of the American option, (i.e. the minimal initial capital which enables the seller to invest in a portfolio which will cover his liability to pay to the buyer no matter the exercise time of the buyer). Mathematical tools: theory of (nonlinear) reflected BSDEs.

53 Reflected BSDEs Reflected BSDEs have been introduced by El Karoui et al. (1997). The solution of such a BSDE is forced to stay above a given process, called obstacle (or barrier). An increasing process is introduced to push the solution upwards in a minimal way so that it remains above the obstacle.

54 Reflected BSDEs Given: a standard driver g(t, y, z) an obstacle (ξ t ),0 t T, continuous on [0, T [, adapted, belonging to S 2, i.e. E(sup t ξ t 2 ) < and satisfying lim t T,t<T ξ t ξ T. A solution of the reflected BSDE associated with driver g and obstacle ξ. consists in a triplet (Y, Z, K) in H 2 (R) H 2 (R n ) S 2 (R) such that (12) dy t = g(t, Y t, Z t )dt + dk t Z t dw t ; Y T = ξ T Y t ξ t, 0 t T a.s., K is a nondecreasing continuous predictable process with K 0 = 0 and T 0 (Y t ξ t )dk t = 0 ( i.e. t K t increases only on{t, Y t = ξ t }) The process K is the minimal push which allows the solution to stay above the obstacle.

55 Reflected BSDEs The special case of a driver process Suppose g does not depend on y, z, k, that is g(ω, t, y, z) = g(ω, t), where g is a process in H 2. Theorem (Link with classical optimal stopping problems) If (Y, Z, K) satisfies the reflected BSDE associated with driver g = g(ω, t) and obstacle ξ, then Y t = ess sup τ T t E[ξ τ + τ t g(s)ds F t ] a.s. and the supremum is attained at D t = inf{s t; Y s = ξ s }. Proof. on blackboard

56 Theorem (Existence and Uniqueness) The reflected BSDE associated with driver g = g(ω, t) and obstacle ξ admits a unique solution (Y, Z, K). Proof. Uniqueness. It comes from the previous characterization theorem. Existence. The proof is based on Doob-Meyer decomposition for super martingales, the theorem of martingale representation and the optimal stopping theory. (Proof on the blackboard).

57 Reflected BSDEs The general case of a Lipschitz driver process Theorem (Existence and Uniqueness) Let g(t, y, z) and ξ. be a couple of standard parameters. Then, the associated reflected BSDE admits a unique solution (Y, Z, K).

58 Proof. Define a mapping Φ as follows. Given (U, V ) H 2 (R) H 2 (R d ), let (Y, Z) = Φ(U, V ) where (Y, Z, K), with t t K t = Y t + Y 0 g(s, U s, V s ) ds + Zs dw s, 0 t T, 0 0 is the solution of the Reflected BSDE associated with driver g(s) = g(s, U s, V s ) and obstacle ξ (which is well defined from previous proposition) Prove that Φ is a contraction in the Banach space H 2 (R) H 2 (R d ) equipped with the norm β (with β well chosen) and thus admits an unique fixed point, which corresponds to the solution of RBSDE (12). Detailed proof on the blackboard.

59 Theorem (Characterization) Let (Y, Z, K) be the solution of the reflected BSDE. Then and the supremum is attained at Y t = ess sup τ T t,t E g t,τ (ξ τ ) D t := inf{s t; Y s = ξ s }, that is Y t = E t,dt (ξ Dt ).

60 Proof. Let D t := inf{s t; Y s = ξ s }. On [t, D t ], the solution Y t > ξ t, so (K t ) remains constant and (Y, Z) the solution of the BSDE with driver g, terminal time D t and terminal condition ξ Dt (= Y Dt by continuity of Y and ξ). In other terms, Y t = E t,dt (ξ Dt ). It remains to prove that for each τ T t,t, we have: Y t E t,τ (ξ τ ). Set X t := E t,τ (ξ τ ); It satisfies the BSDE dx s = g(s, X s, π s)ds π s dw s, t s τ ; X τ = ξ τ Note that on [t, τ], the pair (Y, Z) satisfies dy s = g(s, Y s, Z s )ds + dk s Z s dw s ; Y τ = Y τ. In other terms, (Y, Z) is a solution of the BSDE associated with terminal time τ, terminal condition Y τ and driver g(s,, ) + dks ds. But we have : g(s, y, z)ds + dk s g(s, y, z) and Y τ ξ τ. The comparison thm for BSDEs implies Y t E t,τ (ξ τ ).

61 Theorem (Comparison theorem for reflected BSDEs) Let (f 1, ξ 1 ), (f 2, ξ 2 ) be standard coefficients and (Y 1, Z 1, K 1 ), (Y 2, Z 2, K 2 ) be the solutions of the associated reflected BSDEs. Assume ξ 1 t ξ 2 t, 0 T, a.s. f 1 (t, y, z f 2 (t, y, z) Then Y 1 Y 2, P-a.s. t, y, z Proof. By the comparison thm for BSDEs, for all stopping time τ t, we have: Et,τ 1 (ξτ 1 ) Et,τ 2 (ξτ 2 ). Taking the supremum over τ, we get: Y 1 t Y 2 t.

62 Theorem (Optimality criterium) We have the following equivalence: (i) τ is t-optimal, i.e. Y t = ess sup τ T t,t E g t,τ (ξ τ ) = E t,τ (ξ τ ) (ii) dk s = 0, t s τ and Y τ = ξ τ. In other terms (Y s, t s τ ) is solution of the BSDE associated with the terminal condition ξ τ. Proof. (ii) (i): clear (i) (ii) application of the strict comparison thm (detailed proof on the blackboard)

63 Application to American option pricing Under nonlinear constraints, the wealth is supposed to satisfy: dv t = g(t, V t, σ t π t )dt σ t π t dw t. If the exercise time τ T t,t is fixed, then the American option is a European option with maturity τ and payoff ξ τ. The price of this European option is given by E t,τ (ξ τ ). Definition The g-value of the American option at time t is defined by the F t -measurable random variable: Y t = ess sup Et,τ g (ξ τ ) a.s. τ T t,t Using the previous theory we have that Y is the solution of the reflected BSDE assciated to driver g and obstacle ξ. More precisely,

64 Proposition: Z in H(R d ), K continuous, increasing process, such that dy t = g(t, Y t, Z t )dt + dk t Zt dw t Y T = ξ T Y t ξ t 0 t T a.s. T 0 (Y s ξ s )dk s = 0 Moreover, D t := inf{s t; Y s = ξ s } is optimal i.e. Y t = E t,dt (ξ Dt ).

65 Theorem The g-value Y 0 := sup ν T E g 0,ν (ξ ν) of the American option with payoff ξ satisfies Y 0 = u 0 where u 0 is the superhedging price of the American option defined as the lowest price which allows the seller to be superhedged, i.e. where u 0 = inf H H = {x R, ϕ H 2 s.t. V x,ϕ t ξ t a.s. 0 t T } Proof: 1.Y 0 u 0. Let x H. Let us show that Y 0 x. For all τ T 0, we have: ξ τ Vτ x,ϕ. So by comparison thm, E 0,τ (ξ τ ) E 0,τ (Vτ x,ϕ ) = V x,ϕ 0 = x. Taking supremum over τ, we get Y 0 = sup τ T0 E 0,τ (ξ τ ) x.

66 2. u 0 Y 0 Consider V Y 0,ϕ t the wealth associated to portfolio ϕ t = (σt ) 1 Z t and initial value Y 0. It satisfies: and we have V t = Y 0 Y t = Y 0 t 0 t 0 g(s, Y s, Z s )ds + t 0 Z s dw s t g(s, Y s, Z s )ds + Zs dw s K t. 0 We can prove by using a comparison argument for forward differential equations, that Now V Y 0,ϕ t Y t. Y t ξ t, So V Y 0,ϕ t ξ t, for all 0 t T. So Y 0 belongs to H.

67 Relation with PDEs (Variational inequalities) We now focus on the Markovian case. Let b and σ be continuous mappings, globally Lipschitz. For each (t, x) [0, T ] R, let {Xs t,x, t s T } the solution of s s Xs t,x = x + b(xr t,x )dr + σ(xr t,x )dw r t t We consider the Reflected BSDE associated driver f (s, Xs t,x,.) and obstacle ξ t,x of the following form: { ξ t,x s ξ t,x T := h(s, Xs t,x ), s < T t,x := g(xt ) where g C(R) has at most polynomial growth at infinity, h : [0, T ] R R is jointly continuous in t and x and there exist p N and C > 0, such that h(t, x) C(1 + x p ), t, x and h(t, x) g(x), x.

68 For each (t, x) [0, T ] R, there exists a unique triple (Y t,x, Z t,x, K t,x ) S 2 H 2 S 2 of adapted processes, which solves the Reflected BSDE: (13) T = g(x t,x ) + Y t,x s T T s f (r, X t,x r, Y t,x r, Zr t,x )dr + K t,x T K s t,x Zr t,x dw r s Ys t,x ξs t,x, 0 s T a.s., K t,x is a nondecreasing, continuous predictable process with T t (Y t,x s K t,x t = 0 and such that ξs t,x )dks t,x = 0 a.s.

69 Theorem The function u, defined by u(t, x) := Y t,x t, t [0, T ], x R is a viscosity solution (i.e. both a viscosity sub- and supersolution) of the following PDE with obstacle (14) min(u(t, x) h(t, x), u u (t, x) Lu(t, x) f (t, x, u(t, x), (σ )(t, x)) = 0, (t, x) [0, T ) t x u(t, x) = g(x), x R where Lφ(x) := 1 2 σ2 (x) 2 φ (x) + b(x) φ x 2 x (x).

70 Definition A continuous function u is said to be a viscosity subsolution of (14) if u(t, x) g(x), x R, and if for any point (t 0, x 0 ) (0, T ) R and for any φ C 1,2 ([0, T ] R) such that φ(t 0, x 0 ) = u(t 0, x 0 ) and φ u attains its minimum at (t 0, x 0 ), we have min(u(t 0, x 0 ) h(t 0, x 0 ), φ t (t 0, x 0 ) Lφ(t 0, x 0 ) f (t 0, x 0, u(t 0, x 0 ), (σ φ x )(t, x))(t 0, x 0 )) 0. In other words, if u(t 0, x 0 ) > h(t 0, x 0 ), φ t (t 0, x 0 ) Lφ(t 0, x 0 ) f (t 0, x 0, u(t 0, x 0 ), (σ φ x )(t, x))(t 0, x 0 )) 0. A continuous function u is said to be a viscosity supersolution of (14) if u(t, x) g(x), x R, and if for any point (t 0, x 0 ) (0, T ) R and for any φ C 1,2 ([0, T ] R) such that φ(t 0, x 0 ) = u(t 0, x 0 ) and φ u attains its maximum at (t 0, x 0 ), we have min(u(t 0, x 0 ) h(t 0, x 0 ), t φ(t 0, x 0 ) Lφ(t 0, x 0 ) f (t 0, x 0, u(t 0, x 0 ), (σ φ x )(t 0, x 0 )) 0.

71 Under some additional hypothesis on f, there exists a unique solution of the obstacle problem (27) in the class of continuous functions with polynomial growth.

72 IV. Nonlinear pricing of Game options Definition Game options are derivative contracts that can be terminated by both counterparties at any time before maturity T (introduced by Kifer 2000). extend the setup of American options by allowing the seller to cancel the contract. More precisely If the buyer exercises at time τ, he gets ξ τ from the seller, If the seller cancels at σ before τ, then he pays ζ σ to the buyer. We assume ζ t ξ t 0 for all t and this difference is interpreted as a penalty for the seller for cancellation of the contract.

73 Game options Superhedging The game option consists for the seller to select a cancellation time σ T and for the buyer to choose an exercise time τ T, so that the seller pays to the buyer at time τ σ the amount I (τ, σ) = ξ τ 1 τ σ + ζ σ 1 σ<τ. Definition (Superhedging price) It is the minimal initial wealth which enables the seller to choose a cancellation time σ and a portfolio which cover his liability to pay to the buyer up to σ no matter the exercise time chosen by the buyer (Kifer). Definition: For each initial wealth x, a super-hedge against the game option is a pair (σ, ϕ) of a stopping time σ and a portfolio ϕ s.t. Vt σ x,ϕ I (t, σ), 0 t T a.s. (or equivalently Vt x,ϕ ξ t, 0 t σ a.s. and Vσ x,ϕ ζ σ a.s.).

74 Let A(x) be the set of all super-hedges associated with initial wealth x. The superhedging price u 0 is then defined as the infimum of initial wealths such that there exists a hedge against the game option, that is u 0 = inf{x R, (σ, ϕ) A(x)}.

75 In the case of perfect markets, Kifer shows in the CRR discrete-time model and in the Black-Scholes model that u 0 = value function of a Dynkin game: u 0 = sup inf E Q[ ξ τ 1 τ σ + ζ σ 1 τ>σ ] = inf sup E Q [ ξ τ 1 τ σ + ζ σ 1 τ>σ ], τ σ σ τ where ξ t and ζ t are the discounted values of ξ t and ζ t. Here, E Q denotes the expectation under the unique martingale probability measure Q of the market model.

76 Nonlinear pricing of Game options Consider the imperfect market M g, when under nonlinear constraints, the wealth satisfies: dv t = g(t, V t, σ t ϕ t )dt σ t ϕ t dw t. where g is nonlinear (Lipschitz). Suppose that the seller has chosen his cancellation time σ. Then, the game option reduces to an American option with payoff I (., σ), whose superhedging initial price is given by sup τ T E g 0,τ σ [I (τ, σ)]. It is thus natural to define the g-value of the game option as inf sup E g 0,τ σ (I (τ, σ)). σ T τ T

77 Questions :? inf sup E g 0,τ σ (I (τ, σ)) = sup inf σ T τ T τ T σ T Eg 0,τ σ (I (τ, σ)) In other words, does this generalized Dynkin game has a value?? Links with superhedging price of game options The classical approach based on a change of probability measure and an actualization procedure (see Hamadène) cannot be adapted to the nonlinear case. Mathematical tools: theory of (nonlinear) doubly reflected BSDEs and links with generalized Dynkin games. Dumitrescu-Quenez-Sulem 2014

78 Doubly reflected BSDEs We define Doubly reflected BSDEs (DRBSDEs), for which the solution is constrained to stay between two given processes called barriers ξ ζ. Two nondecreasing processes A and A are introduced in order to push the solution Y above ξ and below ζ in a minimal way. This minimality property of A and A is ensured by the Skorohod conditions.

79 Definition (Doubly reflected BSDEs) Let T > 0 be a fixed terminal time and g be a Lipschitz driver. Let ξ and ζ be two adapted continuous on [t,t) processes with ζ T = ξ T a.s., ξ S 2, ζ S 2, ξ t ζ t, t [0, T ] a.s. A process (Y, Z, A, A ) in S 2 H 2 A 2 A 2 is a solution of the doubly reflected BSDE associated with driver g and barriers ξ, ζ if dy t = g(t, Y t, Z t )dt + da t da t Z t dw t ; 0 t T Y T = ξ T, ξ t Y t ζ t, da t da t T 0 t T a.s., 0 (Y t ξ t )da t = 0 and T 0 (ζ t Y t )da t = 0 a.s. (Skorohod conditio A 2 = {nondecreasing continuous adapted processes A with A 0 = 0 and E(A 2 T ) < }

80 Classical Dynkin games Links with linear doubly reflected BSDEs We start by the case of the driver g = 0 and ξ T = 0 a.s. Then the associated doubly reflected BSDE is related to a classical Dynkin game problem with payoff: I (τ, σ) = ξ τ 1 {τ σ} + ζ σ 1 {σ<τ}.

81 Definition (Classical Dynkin game) For any S T 0, the upper and lower value functions at time S are defined respectively by V (S) := ess inf σ T S ess sup τ T S E[I (τ, σ) F S ] V (S) := ess sup τ T S ess inf σ T S E[I (τ, σ) F S ]. We clearly have the inequality V (S) V (S) a.s. We say that the Dynkin game is fair (or there exists a value function) at time S if V (S) = V (S) a.s.

82 Definition (S-saddle point) Let S T 0. A pair (τ, σ ) TS 2 all (τ, σ) TS 2, we have is called an S-saddle point if for E[I (τ, σ ) F S ] E[I (τ, σ ) F S ] E[I (τ, σ) F S ] a.s.

83 When it exists, the value function of the Dynkin game can be written as the difference of 2 supermartingales J and J solutions of a coupled optimal stopping problems: V (S) = V (S) = J S J S, where for all θ T 0, J θ = ess sup τ T θ E [ J τ + ξ τ F θ ] and J θ = ess sup σ T θ E [J σ ζ σ F θ ] a.s. J and J are finite (and in S 2 ) iff Mokobodzki s condition holds, that is if there exist two nonnegative continuous supermartingales H and H in S 2 such that: (15) ξ t H t H t ζ t 0 t T a.s. (which is for example satisfied when ξ and ζ are semimartingales)

84 is an S-saddle point. Theorem Under this condition, the doubly reflected BSDE dy t = da t da t Z t dw t ; Y T = 0 ξ t Y t ζ t, 0 t T a.s., da t da t T 0 (Y t ξ t )da t = 0 and T 0 (ζ t Y t )da t = 0 admits a unique solution (Y, Z, A, A ) in S 2 H 2 (A 2 ) 2. S T 0, Y S is the common value function of the Dynkin game associated with the gain I (τ, σ) = ξ τ 1 {τ σ} + ζ σ 1 {σ<τ}., i.e. (16) Y S = V (S) = V (S) a.s. Moreover, S T 0, the pair of stopping times (τ s, σ s ) defined by (17) σ S := inf{t S, Y t = ζ t }; τ S := inf{t S, Y t = ξ t }

85 Sketch of proof : Suppose that J, J S 2. Define (18) Y t := J t J t; 0 t T. Let us show that there exist (Z, A, A ) H 2 A 2 A 2 such that (Y, Z, A, A ) is a solution of DRBSDE (15) associated with driver process g = 0. By assumption, J and J are square integrable supermartingales. The process Y is thus well defined. We have J T = J T a.s. Hence, Y T = ξ T a.s. By the Doob-Meyer decomposition, there exist two square integrable martingales M and M and two processes A and A A 2 such that: (19) dj t = dm t da t ; dj t = dm t da t. Set M t := M t M t. By (19), (18), we derive dy t = dm t dα t, with α := A A. By the martingale representation theorem, there exist Z H 2 such that dm t = Z t dw t. Hence, dy t = dα t Z t dw t.

86 By the optimal stopping theory, the process A increases only when the value function J is equal to the corresponding reward J + ξ. Now, {J t = J t + ξ} = {Y t = ξ t }. Hence, T 0 (Y t ξ t )da t = 0 a.s. Similarly the process A satisfies T 0 (Y t ζ t )da t = 0 a.s. We have Y σ S = ζ σ S and Y τ S = ξ τ S a.s. On [S, τs [, we have Y t > ξ t a.s., so A is constant on [S, τs ]. Similarly, A is constant on [S, σs ] a.s. The process (Y t + t 0 g(s)ds, S t τ S σ S ) is thus a martingale. Hence, Y S = E[I S (τs, σ S ) F S] a.s. Similarly we can show that τ, σ T S, E[I S (τ, σs ) F S] Y S and Y S E[I S (τs, σ) F S] a.s., So (τs, σ S ) is an S-saddle point.

87 This result can easily be extended to the case when g = (g t ) in H 2 is a driver process and ξ T 0, by doing the change of variables: T T ξ t g := ξ t E[ξ T + g(s)ds F t ], ζ t g := ζ t E[ζ T + g(s)ds F t ], t t The associated payoff of the Dynkin game is then I S (τ, σ) = σ τ S g(u)du + ξ τ 1 {τ σ} + ζ σ 1 {σ<τ}.

88 Generalized Dynkin games and links with nonlinear DRBSDEs From now on, we are given a standard Lipschitz driver g and we suppose that Mokobodzki s condition is satisfied. Theorem (Existence and uniqueness for DRBSDEs) Then, DRBSDE (15) admits a unique solution (Y, Z, A, A ) S 2 H 2 (A 2 ) 2. Proof. based on a contraction argument (similar to the case of BSDEs and Reflected BSDEs)

89 Generalized Dynkin games We introduce a generalized Dynkin game expressed in terms of E g -expectations. Let g(t, y, z) be a given a Lipschitz driver. For each pair (τ, σ) of stopping times valued in [0, T ], the criterium is given by ( ) ξτ 1 {τ σ} + ζ σ 1 {σ<τ} E g 0,τ σ with ξ, ζ two continuous adapted processes satisfying ξ ζ. When the driver g does not depend on the solution, that is, when it is given by a process (g(t)), the criterium coincides with ( τ σ ) E g s ds + ξ τ 1 {τ σ} + ζ σ 1 {σ<τ}. 0

90 For each stopping time S T 0, the upper and lower value functions at time S are defined respectively by (20) V (S) := ess inf σ T S ess sup τ T S E S,τ σ (I (τ, σ)); (21) V (S) := ess sup τ T S ess inf σ T S E S,τ σ (I (τ, σ)). with I (τ, σ) := ξ τ 1 τ σ + ζ σ 1 σ<τ. We clearly have the inequality V (S) V (S) a.s. By definition, we say that the game is fair (or there exists a value function) at time S if V (S) = V (S) a.s.

91 Definition (S-saddle) Let S T 0. A pair (τ, σ ) TS 2 is called an S-saddle point for the generalized Dynkin game if for each (τ, σ) TS 2 we have E g S,τ σ (I (τ, σ )) E g S,τ σ (I (τ, σ )) E g S,τ σ (I (τ, σ)) a.s. Definition Let Y be an RCLL process in S 2. The process Y is said to be a E g -supermartingale (resp E g -submartingale), if E g σ,τ (Y τ ) Y σ (resp. E g σ,τ (Y τ ) Y σ ) a.s. on σ τ, for all σ, τ T 0.

92 We first provide a sufficient condition for the existence of an S-saddle point and for the characterization of the common value function as the solution of the DRBSDE. Lemma Let (Y, Z, A, A ) be the solution of the DRBSDE. Let S T 0. Let (ˆτ, ˆσ) T S. Suppose that (Y t, S t ˆτ) is a E-submartingale and that (Y t, S t ˆσ) is a E-supermartingale with Yˆτ = ξˆτ and Yˆσ = ζˆσ a.s. The pair (ˆτ, ˆσ) is then an S-saddle point for the generalized Dynkin game (20)-(21) and Y S = V (S) = V (S) a.s.

93 Proof. Since the process (Y t, S t ˆτ ˆσ) is a E-martingale and since Yˆτ = ξˆτ and Yˆσ = ζˆσ a.s., we have Y S = E g S,ˆτ ˆσ (Yˆτ ˆσ) = E g S,ˆτ ˆσ (ξˆτ 1ˆτ ˆσ +ζˆσ 1ˆσ<ˆτ ) = E g S,ˆτ ˆσ (I (ˆτ, ˆσ)) a.s. Let τ T S. We want to show that for each τ T S (22) Y S E S,τ ˆσ (I (τ, ˆσ)) a.s. Since the process (Y t, S t τ ˆσ) is a E-supermartingale, we get (23) Y S E S,τ ˆσ (Y τ ˆσ ) a.s. Since Y ξ and Yˆσ = ζˆσ a.s., we also have Y τ ˆσ = Y τ 1 τ ˆσ + Yˆσ 1ˆσ<τ ξ τ 1 τ ˆσ + ζˆσ 1ˆσ<τ = I (τ, ˆσ) a.s. By inequality (23) and the monotonicity property of E, we derive inequality (22). Similarly, one can show that for each σ T S, we have: Y S E S,ˆτ σ (I (ˆτ, σ)) a.s. The pair (ˆτ, ˆσ) is thus an S-saddle point and Y S = V (S) = V (S) a.s.

94 Theorem (Existence of S-saddle points) Let (Y, Z, A, A ) be the solution of the DRBSDE (15). For each S T 0, let τ S := inf{t S, Y t = ξ t }; σ S := inf{t S, Y t = ζ t }. Then, for each S T 0, the pair of stopping times (τs, σ S ) is a S-saddle point for the generalized Dynkin game and Y S = V (S) = V (S) a.s. Moreover, Y σ S = ζ σ S, Y τ S = ξ τ S, A τ S = A S and A σs = A S a.s.

95 Proof. Let S T 0. Since Y and ξ are continuous processes, we have Y σ S = ζ σ S and Y τ S = ξ τ S a.s. By definition of τs, Y t > ξ t (ω) for each t [S, τs [. Hence, since Y is solution of the DRBSDE, the process A is constant on [S, τs ] a.s. because A is continuous. Hence, A τs = A S a.s. Similarly, A σs = A S a.s. By previous Lemma, (τs, σ S ) is an S-saddle point and Y S = V (S) = V (S) a.s.

96 Application to nonlinear pricing of game options We consider now a game option associated with continuous payoffs ξ and ζ in S 2 with ζ T = ξ T ; ξ t ζ t, 0 t T a.s. satisfying Mokobodski s condition (which is for example satisfied when ξ and ζ are semimartingales) The game option consists for the seller to select a cancellation time σ T and for the buyer an exercise time τ T, so that the seller pays to the buyer at time τ σ the payoff I (τ, σ) := ξ τ 1 τ σ + ζ σ 1 σ<τ. A natural price for the seller of the game option, is the g-value given by (24) Y (0) := inf sup E g 0,τ σ [I (τ, σ)] σ T τ T

97 Under the assumptions above, this generalized Dynkin game is fair, i.e inf sup E g 0,τ σ [I (τ, σ)] = sup inf σ T τ T τ T σ T Eg 0,τ σ [I (τ, σ)] and its value Y (0) equals Y 0, where (Y, Z, A, A ) is the unique solution in S 2 L 2 (W ) A 2 A 2 of the Doubly Reflected BSDE associated to driver g and obstacles ξ, ζ.

98 Definition: Superhedging price u 0 of the game option := minimal initial wealth which enables the seller to choose a cancellation time σ and a portfolio which will cover his liability to pay to the buyer up to σ no matter what exercise time the buyer chooses (Kifer). Definition: For each initial wealth x, a super-hedge against the game option is a pair (σ, ϕ) of a stopping time σ and a portfolio ϕ s.t. Vt σ x,ϕ I (t, σ), 0 t T a.s. (or equivalently Vt x,ϕ ξ t, 0 t σ a.s. and Vσ x,ϕ ζ σ a.s.). Let A(x) be the set of all super-hedges associated with initial wealth x. The superhedging price is then defined as the infimum of initial wealths such that there exists a hedge against the game option, that is u 0 = inf{x R, (σ, ϕ) A(x)}.

99 Theorem superhedging price u 0 = g-value of the game option, that is u 0 = inf sup E g 0,τ σ [I (τ, σ)] = sup inf σ T τ T τ T σ T Eg 0,τ σ [I (τ, σ)]. Let (Y, Z, A, A ) be the solution of the DRBSDE associated with driver g and barriers ξ, ζ. We have Let u 0 = Y 0. σ := inf{t 0, Y t = ζ t } and ϕ t = (σ t ) 1 Z t. The pair (σ, ϕ ) belongs to A(u 0 ), i.e. the cancellation time σ and the strategy ϕ allow the seller of the game option to be super-hedged. The proof is based on links between generalized Dynkin games and DRBSDEs

100 Buyer point of view Definition: (Kifer) A stopping time τ is a rational exercise time for the game option if V Y 0,ϕ t ζ t, 0 t τ a.s. and V Y 0,ϕ τ = ξ τ a.s. Lemma: The stopping time (25) τ := inf{t 0 : Y t = ξ t } is a rational exercise time for the buyer of the game option.

101 The pair (τ, σ ) is a saddle point for the generalized Dynkin game, that is for each (τ, σ) T 2 we have E g 0,τ σ [I (τ, σ )] Y 0 = E g 0,τ σ [I (τ, σ )] E g 0,τ σ [I (τ, σ)]. In this case, τ is optimal for the optimal stopping problem sup τ T E g [I (τ, σ )] (as in the case of an American option) and σ is optimal for inf σ T E g [I (τ, σ)].

102 Relations with variational inequalities (VI) We consider now the Markovian case and study the links between generalized Dynkin games (or equivalently DRBSDEs) and obstacle problems. Let b : R R, σ : R R be continuous, globally Lipschitz. (t, x) [0, T ] R, let (Xs t,x, t s T ) solution of s s Xs t,x = x + b(xr t,x )dr + t t and set X t,x s = x for s t. σ(xr t,x )dw r

103 We consider the DRBSDE associated with obstacles ξ t,x, ζ t,x of the following form: ξ t,x s := h 1 (s, Xs t,x ), ζs t,x := h 2 (s, Xs t,x ), s < T, ξ t,x T = ζt,x T t,x := g(xt ) with g C(R), h 1, h 2 : [0, T ] continuous with respect to t and Lipschitz continuous with respect to x, uniformly in t and g, h 1, h 2 have at most polynomial growth with respect to x. Moreover, we assume that the obstacles ξs t,x and ζs t,x satisfy Mokobodski s condition, which holds e.g; if h 1 and h 2 are C 1,2. Let f : [0, T ] R 3 R be continuous in t uniformly with respect to x, y, z, uniformly Lipschitz with respect to x, y, z uniformly in t, such that f (t, x, 0, 0, ) at most polynomial growth with respect to x. The driver is defined by f (s, Xs t,x (ω), y, z).

104 For each (t, x) [0, T ] R, there exists an unique solution (Y t,x, Z t,x, A t,x, A t,x ) of the associated DRBSDE. We define: (26) u(t, x) := Y t,x t, t [0, T ], x R. which is a deterministic quantity. u is continuous in (t, x) and has at most polynomial growth at infinity.

105 A solution of the obstacle problem is a function u : [0, T ] R R which satisfies the equality u(t, x) = g(x) and (27) where h 1 (t, x) u(t, x) h 2 (t, x) if u(t, x) < h 2 (t, x) then Hu 0 if h 1 (t, x) < u(t, x) then Hu 0 Lφ(x) := 1 2 σ2 (x) 2 φ (x) + b(x) φ x 2 x (x), Hφ(t, x) := φ φ (t, x) Lφ(t, x) f (t, x, φ(t, x), (σ )(t, x)). t x

106 Definition A continuous function u is said to be a viscosity subsolution (resp. supersolution) of (27) if u(t, x) g(x), (resp ) x R, for all (t, x), h 1 (t, x) u(t, x) h 2 (t, x) for all φ C 1,2 ([0, T ] R) such that φ(t 0, x 0 ) = u(t 0, x 0 ) and φ u attains its minimum (resp. maximum) at (t 0, x 0 ), if u(t 0, x 0 ) > h 1 (t 0, x 0 ) (resp. <), then (Hφ)(t 0, x 0 ) 0 (resp.)

107 Theorem The function u defined by (26) is a viscosity solution (i.e. both a viscosity sub- and supersolution) of the obstacle problem (27). This result provides a probabilistic interpretation of semi linear PDEs with two barriers in terms of game problems.

108 References Classical Dynkin Games in continuous time: Alario-Nazaret, Lepeltier and Marchal, B. (1982). Links with Doubly RBSDEs when the driver g does not depend on y, z: Cvitanic and Karatzas (1996), Hamadène (2002) and Lepeltier (2000) (Hyp: Brownian+ regularity). Generalized Dynkin games and DRBSDEs, Dumitrescu-Quenez-A.S EJP Game options in an imperfect market with default, Dumitrescu-Quenez-A.S

109 Market model with default Setup Let (Ω, G, P) be a probability space, equipped with two stochastic processes: a one-dimensional standard Brownian motion W and a jump process N defined by N t := 1 ϑ t for any t 0, where ϑ is a random variable which represents a default time. We assume that this default can appear at any time that is P(ϑ t) > 0 for any t 0. We denote by G = (G t, t 0)) the complete natural filtration generated by W and N. We suppose that W is a G-Brownian motion.

110 Let Λ be the predictable compensator of the nondecreasing process N (i.e. the unique RCLL increasing predictable process null at 0 such that N t Λ is a martingale). Note that Λ t ϑ is then the predictable compensator of N t ϑ = N t. By uniqueness of the predictable compensator, Λ t ϑ = Λ t. We assume that Λ is absolutely continuous w.r.t. Lebesgue s measure, so that there exists a nonnegative process λ, called the intensity process, such that Λ t = t 0 λ sds. Since Λ t ϑ = Λ t, λ vanishes after ϑ. We denote by M the compensated martingale which satisfies t M t = N t λ s ds. 0

111 Let T > 0. We introduce the following sets : S 2 is the set of G-adapted RCLL processes ϕ such that E[sup 0 t T ϕ t 2 ] < +. A 2 is the set of real-valued non decreasing RCLL predictable processes A with A 0 = 0 and E(A 2 T ) <. H 2 is the set [ of G-predictable processes such that ] Z 2 T := E 0 Z t 2 dt <. is the set [ of G-predictable processes such that ] U 2 λ := E T 0 U t 2 λ t dt <. H 2 λ

112 We recall the martingale representation theorem (see e.g. Jeanblanc-Yor-Chesnay 09): Lemma Any G-local martingale m has the representation t t (28) m t = m 0 + z s dw s + l s dm s, t [0, T ] a.s., 0 0 where z and l are predictable such that the two above stochastic integrals are well defined. If m is a square integrable martingale, then z H 2 and l H 2 λ.

Doubly reflected BSDEs with jumps and generalized Dynkin games

Doubly reflected BSDEs with jumps and generalized Dynkin games Doubly reflected BSDEs with jumps and generalized Dynkin games Roxana DUMITRESCU (University Paris Dauphine, Crest and INRIA) Joint works with M.C. Quenez (Univ. Paris Diderot) and Agnès Sulem (INRIA Paris-Rocquecourt)

More information

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers Université de Lyon 1, ISFA April 23 2014 Tlemcen - CIMPA Research School Motivations Study of optimal risk transfer structures, Natural question in Reinsurance.

More information

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES from BMO martingales MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES CNRS - CMAP Ecole Polytechnique March 1, 2007 1/ 45 OUTLINE from BMO martingales 1 INTRODUCTION 2 DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES Time Consistency

More information

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations Anne EYRAUD-LOISEL Workshop : Enlargement of Filtrations and Applications to Finance and Insurance May 31st - June 4th, 2010, Jena

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Xiaoguang Wang STAT 598W January 21th, 2014 (STAT 598W) Lecture 3 1 / 51 Outline 1 Some model independent definitions and principals

More information

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Department of Banking and Finance University of Zurich April 22 2013 Math Finance Colloquium USC Change of the probability measure Change of

More information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B 166 Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information by Hans Föllmer ) Martin Schweizer ) October 199 ) Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft,

More information

Hedging under arbitrage

Hedging under arbitrage Hedging under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics AnStAp10 August 12, 2010 Motivation Usually, there are several trading strategies at one s disposal to obtain a given

More information

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims Beatrice Acciaio Gregor Svindland December 2011 Abstract We prove that in a discrete-time market model the lower arbitrage bound of an American

More information

Non-semimartingales in finance

Non-semimartingales in finance Non-semimartingales in finance Pricing and Hedging Options with Quadratic Variation Tommi Sottinen University of Vaasa 1st Northern Triangular Seminar 9-11 March 2009, Helsinki University of Technology

More information

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models Beatrice Acciaio the London School of Economics and Political Science (based on a joint work with C. Fontana and

More information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information Exponential utility maximization under partial information Marina Santacroce Politecnico di Torino Joint work with M. Mania AMaMeF 5-1 May, 28 Pitesti, May 1th, 28 Outline Expected utility maximization

More information

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University November 2007 Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance measurement of investment strategies 2 Market

More information

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility Nasir Rehman Allam Iqbal Open University Islamabad, Pakistan. Outline Mathematical

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs. Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs Andrea Cosso LPMA, Université Paris Diderot joint work with Francesco Russo ENSTA,

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 6, 2012, no. 112, 5597-5602 Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities Nasir Rehman Department of Mathematics and Statistics

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes Math 6810 (Probability) Fall 2012 Lecture notes Pieter Allaart University of North Texas April 16, 2013 2 Text: Introduction to Stochastic Calculus with Applications, by Fima C. Klebaner (3rd edition),

More information

Forward Dynamic Utility

Forward Dynamic Utility Forward Dynamic Utility El Karoui Nicole & M RAD Mohamed UnivParis VI / École Polytechnique,CMAP elkaroui@cmapx.polytechnique.fr with the financial support of the "Fondation du Risque" and the Fédération

More information

Exact replication under portfolio constraints: a viability approach

Exact replication under portfolio constraints: a viability approach Exact replication under portfolio constraints: a viability approach CEREMADE, Université Paris-Dauphine Joint work with Jean-Francois Chassagneux & Idris Kharroubi Motivation Complete market with no interest

More information

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging Introduction and echniques Lecture 9 in Financial Mathematics UiO-SK451 Autumn 15 eacher:s. Ortiz-Latorre Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging 1 Risk Neutral Pricing Assume that we are in the basic

More information

Robust Portfolio Choice and Indifference Valuation

Robust Portfolio Choice and Indifference Valuation and Indifference Valuation Mitja Stadje Dep. of Econometrics & Operations Research Tilburg University joint work with Roger Laeven July, 2012 http://alexandria.tue.nl/repository/books/733411.pdf Setting

More information

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS Stat 391/FinMath 346 Lecture 8 STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS X t = CONTINUOUS PROCESS θ t = PORTFOLIO: #X t HELD AT t { St : STOCK PRICE M t : MG W t : BROWNIAN MOTION DISCRETE TIME: = t < t 1

More information

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of New South Wales Joint work with T. Bielecki, M. Jeanblanc and K. Yousiph Seminar 26 September, 2007

More information

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods Finite difference and finite element methods Lecture 4 Outline Black-Scholes equation From expectation to PDE Goal: compute the value of European option with payoff g which is the conditional expectation

More information

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach Ying JIAO Université Paris 7 This presentation is based on joint works with N. El Karoui, M. Jeanblanc and H. Pham Introduction Motivation :

More information

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default T. Bielecki, M. Jeanblanc and M. Rutkowski Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, 6 February 2006 1 Based on N. Vaillant (2001) A

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard Indifference pricing and the minimal entropy martingale measure Fred Espen Benth Centre of Mathematics for Applications

More information

The stochastic calculus

The stochastic calculus Gdansk A schedule of the lecture Stochastic differential equations Ito calculus, Ito process Ornstein - Uhlenbeck (OU) process Heston model Stopping time for OU process Stochastic differential equations

More information

Utility indifference valuation for non-smooth payoffs on a market with some non tradable assets

Utility indifference valuation for non-smooth payoffs on a market with some non tradable assets Utility indifference valuation for non-smooth payoffs on a market with some non tradable assets - Joint work with G. Benedetti (Paris-Dauphine, CREST) - Luciano Campi Université Paris 13, FiME and CREST

More information

INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH

INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH HAMPUS ENGSNER, MATHIAS LINDHOLM, AND FILIP LINDSKOG Abstract. We present an approach to market-consistent multi-period valuation

More information

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models Alexander Cox 1 Jiajie Wang 2 1 University of Bath 2 Università di Roma La Sapienza Advances in Financial Mathematics, 9th January,

More information

Path Dependent British Options

Path Dependent British Options Path Dependent British Options Kristoffer J Glover (Joint work with G. Peskir and F. Samee) School of Finance and Economics University of Technology, Sydney 18th August 2009 (PDE & Mathematical Finance

More information

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics The Third Western Conference in Mathematical Finance November 14, 2009 How should an investor trade

More information

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Constructing Markov models for barrier options Constructing Markov models for barrier options Gerard Brunick joint work with Steven Shreve Department of Mathematics University of Texas at Austin Nov. 14 th, 2009 3 rd Western Conference on Mathematical

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria   web:   July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M Girsanov s Theorem Bernardo D Auria email: bernardo.dauria@uc3m.es web: www.est.uc3m.es/bdauria July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M Girsanov s Theorem Decomposition of P-Martingales as Q-semi-martingales Theorem

More information

CHAPTER 12. Hedging. hedging strategy = replicating strategy. Question : How to find a hedging strategy? In other words, for an attainable contingent

CHAPTER 12. Hedging. hedging strategy = replicating strategy. Question : How to find a hedging strategy? In other words, for an attainable contingent CHAPTER 12 Hedging hedging dddddddddddddd ddd hedging strategy = replicating strategy hedgingdd) ddd Question : How to find a hedging strategy? In other words, for an attainable contingent claim, find

More information

The British Russian Option

The British Russian Option The British Russian Option Kristoffer J Glover (Joint work with G. Peskir and F. Samee) School of Finance and Economics University of Technology, Sydney 25th June 2010 (6th World Congress of the BFS, Toronto)

More information

ABOUT THE PRICING EQUATION IN FINANCE

ABOUT THE PRICING EQUATION IN FINANCE ABOUT THE PRICING EQUATION IN FINANCE Stéphane CRÉPEY University of Evry, France stephane.crepey@univ-evry.fr AMAMEF at Vienna University of Technology 17 22 September 2007 1 We derive the pricing equation

More information

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options By Yasin LUT Supevisor:Prof. Tuomo Kauranne December 2010 Introduction Pricing an European call option Conclusion INTRODUCTION A stochastic

More information

Asymmetric information in trading against disorderly liquidation of a large position.

Asymmetric information in trading against disorderly liquidation of a large position. Asymmetric information in trading against disorderly liquidation of a large position. Caroline Hillairet 1 Cody Hyndman 2 Ying Jiao 3 Renjie Wang 2 1 ENSAE ParisTech Crest, France 2 Concordia University,

More information

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property Dmitry Kramkov joint work with Sergio Pulido (Évry, Paris) Carnegie Mellon University Workshop on Equilibrium Theory, Carnegie Mellon,

More information

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note Working Paper Series Department of Economics University of Verona Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note Louis Raymond Eeckhoudt, Elisa Pagani, Emanuela Rosazza Gianin WP

More information

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model (joint work with J. Dong and L. Korobenko) A. Deniz Sezer University of Calgary April 28, 2016 Merton s model of corporate debt A corporate bond is a contingent

More information

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Local Volatility Dynamic Models René Carmona Bendheim Center for Finance Department of Operations Research & Financial Engineering Princeton University Columbia November 9, 27 Contents Joint work with Sergey Nadtochyi Motivation 1 Understanding

More information

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that. 1. EXERCISES RMSC 45 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk Exercises 1 Exercises 1. (a) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-martingale. Show that E(X n ) = E(X ) n N (b) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-submartingale.

More information

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension Mathematical Statistics Stockholm University Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension Kristoffer Lindensjö Research Report 216:21 ISSN 165-377

More information

Optimal Order Placement

Optimal Order Placement Optimal Order Placement Peter Bank joint work with Antje Fruth OMI Colloquium Oxford-Man-Institute, October 16, 2012 Optimal order execution Broker is asked to do a transaction of a significant fraction

More information

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance Bernardo D Auria email: bernardo.dauria@uc3m.es web: www.est.uc3m.es/bdauria July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M The Financial Market The Financial Market We assume there are

More information

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES THE SOURCE OF A PRICE IS ALWAYS A TRADING STRATEGY SPECIAL CASES WHERE TRADING STRATEGY IS INDEPENDENT OF PROBABILITY MEASURE COMPLETENESS,

More information

Dynamic Protection for Bayesian Optimal Portfolio

Dynamic Protection for Bayesian Optimal Portfolio Dynamic Protection for Bayesian Optimal Portfolio Hideaki Miyata Department of Mathematics, Kyoto University Jun Sekine Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto University Jan. 6, 2009, Kunitachi, Tokyo 1

More information

Optional semimartingale decomposition and no arbitrage condition in enlarged ltration

Optional semimartingale decomposition and no arbitrage condition in enlarged ltration Optional semimartingale decomposition and no arbitrage condition in enlarged ltration Anna Aksamit Laboratoire d'analyse & Probabilités, Université d'evry Onzième Colloque Jeunes Probabilistes et Statisticiens

More information

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Jan Obłój j.obloj@imperial.ac.uk based on joint works with L. Carraro, N. El Karoui, A. Meziou and M. Yor Welsh Probability Seminar, 17 Jan 28 Are the Azéma-Yor

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations Claudio Fontana Laboratoire de Probabilités et Modèles Aléatoires Université Paris Diderot XVI Workshop on Quantitative Finance

More information

Pricing early exercise contracts in incomplete markets

Pricing early exercise contracts in incomplete markets Pricing early exercise contracts in incomplete markets A. Oberman and T. Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin May 2003, typographical corrections November 7, 2003 Abstract We present a utility-based

More information

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

Martingale invariance and utility maximization Martingale invariance and utility maximization Thorsten Rheinlander Jena, June 21 Thorsten Rheinlander () Martingale invariance Jena, June 21 1 / 27 Martingale invariance property Consider two ltrations

More information

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval A. N. Shiryaev M. V. Zhitlukhin arxiv:1212.379v1 [math.st] 15 Dec 212 December 18, 212 Abstract We consider optimal

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments Tom Hurd Financial Mathematics at McMaster www.phimac.org Thanks to Tahir Choulli and Shui Feng Financial Mathematics Seminar

More information

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS MATHEMATICAL TRIPOS Part III Friday, 27 May, 2016 1:30 pm to 4:30 pm PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS Attempt no more than FOUR questions. There are SIX questions in total. The questions carry equal

More information

Lévy models in finance

Lévy models in finance Lévy models in finance Ernesto Mordecki Universidad de la República, Montevideo, Uruguay PASI - Guanajuato - June 2010 Summary General aim: describe jummp modelling in finace through some relevant issues.

More information

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps Jhonny Gonzalez School of Mathematics The University of Manchester Magical books project August 23, 2012 Clip for this slide Pricing

More information

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Zorana Grbac Department of Math. Stochastics, University of Freiburg Joint work with Ernst Eberlein Croatian Quants Day University of Zagreb, 9th

More information

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS MATHEMATICAL TRIPOS Part III Thursday, 5 June, 214 1:3 pm to 4:3 pm PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS Attempt no more than FOUR questions. There are SIX questions in total. The questions carry

More information

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t Economathematics Problem Sheet 1 Zbigniew Palmowski 1. Calculate Ee X where X is a gaussian random variable with mean µ and volatility σ >.. Verify that where W is a Wiener process. Ws dw s = 1 3 W t 3

More information

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Eni Musta Università degli studi di Pisa San Miniato - 16 September 2016 Overview 1 Self-financing portfolio 2 Complete

More information

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications Huyen Pham Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications 4y Springer Some elements of stochastic analysis 1 1.1 Stochastic processes 1 1.1.1 Filtration and processes 1

More information

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours This question paper consists of 3 printed pages FinKont KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 211/212) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours This exam paper

More information

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6 Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6 Magnus Wiktorsson September 14, 2017 Magnus Wiktorsson L6 September 14, 2017 1 / 13 Feynman-Kac representation This is the link between a class of Partial Differential

More information

The Life Cycle Model with Recursive Utility: Defined benefit vs defined contribution.

The Life Cycle Model with Recursive Utility: Defined benefit vs defined contribution. The Life Cycle Model with Recursive Utility: Defined benefit vs defined contribution. Knut K. Aase Norwegian School of Economics 5045 Bergen, Norway IACA/PBSS Colloquium Cancun 2017 June 6-7, 2017 1. Papers

More information

Optimal Stopping Under Ambiguity In Continuous Time

Optimal Stopping Under Ambiguity In Continuous Time Working Papers Institute of Mathematical Economics 429 April 2010 Optimal Stopping Under Ambiguity In Continuous Time Frank Riedel IMW Bielefeld University Postfach 100131 33501 Bielefeld Germany email:

More information

Optimal Stopping Rules of Discrete-Time Callable Financial Commodities with Two Stopping Boundaries

Optimal Stopping Rules of Discrete-Time Callable Financial Commodities with Two Stopping Boundaries The Ninth International Symposium on Operations Research Its Applications (ISORA 10) Chengdu-Jiuzhaigou, China, August 19 23, 2010 Copyright 2010 ORSC & APORC, pp. 215 224 Optimal Stopping Rules of Discrete-Time

More information

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s An Informal Introduction Olav Kallenberg Graduate Student Seminar, April 18, 2012 1 / 33 2 / 33 Simple recursion: Deterministic system, discrete time x n+1 = f (x

More information

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance Alexander Cox Jiajie Wang University of Bath Bachelier 21, Toronto Financial Setting Option priced on an underlying asset S t Dynamics of S t unspecified,

More information

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View An Introduction to Point Processes from a Martingale Point of View Tomas Björk KTH, 211 Preliminary, incomplete, and probably with lots of typos 2 Contents I The Mathematics of Counting Processes 5 1 Counting

More information

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Matematiikan päivät, Tampere, 4-5. January 2006 Tommi Sottinen University of Helsinki 4.1.2006 Outline 1. The classical pricing model:

More information

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh Option Pricing Mrinal K. Ghosh 1 Introduction We first introduce the basic terminology in option pricing. Option: An option is the right, but not the obligation to buy (or sell) an asset under specified

More information

Real Options and Free-Boundary Problem: A Variational View

Real Options and Free-Boundary Problem: A Variational View Real Options and Free-Boundary Problem: A Variational View Vadim Arkin, Alexander Slastnikov Central Economics and Mathematics Institute, Russian Academy of Sciences, Moscow V.Arkin, A.Slastnikov Real

More information

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Model-independent bounds for Asian options Model-independent bounds for Asian options A dynamic programming approach Alexander M. G. Cox 1 Sigrid Källblad 2 1 University of Bath 2 CMAP, École Polytechnique University of Michigan, 2nd December,

More information

Stochastic Partial Differential Equations and Portfolio Choice. Crete, May Thaleia Zariphopoulou

Stochastic Partial Differential Equations and Portfolio Choice. Crete, May Thaleia Zariphopoulou Stochastic Partial Differential Equations and Portfolio Choice Crete, May 2011 Thaleia Zariphopoulou Oxford-Man Institute and Mathematical Institute University of Oxford and Mathematics and IROM, The University

More information

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing theory of financial derivatives Pricing theory of financial derivatives One-period securities model S denotes the price process {S(t) : t = 0, 1}, where S(t) = (S 1 (t) S 2 (t) S M (t)). Here, M is the number of securities. At t = 1,

More information

Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels

Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels Kiseop Lee Department of Statistics, Purdue University Mathematical Finance Seminar University of Southern California

More information

Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs

Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs Gennady Shaikhet supervised by Dr. Gady Zohar The model Market with two securities: b(t) - bond without interest rate p(t) - stock, an Ito process db(t)

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

The Uncertain Volatility Model

The Uncertain Volatility Model The Uncertain Volatility Model Claude Martini, Antoine Jacquier July 14, 008 1 Black-Scholes and realised volatility What happens when a trader uses the Black-Scholes (BS in the sequel) formula to sell

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

Sample Path Large Deviations and Optimal Importance Sampling for Stochastic Volatility Models

Sample Path Large Deviations and Optimal Importance Sampling for Stochastic Volatility Models Sample Path Large Deviations and Optimal Importance Sampling for Stochastic Volatility Models Scott Robertson Carnegie Mellon University scottrob@andrew.cmu.edu http://www.math.cmu.edu/users/scottrob June

More information

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Jan Obłój j.obloj@imperial.ac.uk based on joint works with L. Carraro, N. El Karoui, A. Meziou and M. Yor Swiss Probability Seminar, 5 Dec 2007 Are the Azéma-Yor

More information