Long Term E cient Contracting with Private Information

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Long Term E cient Contracting with Private Information"

Transcription

1 Long Term E cient Contracting with Private Information Tracy R.Lewis Alan Schwartz y March 2010 Abstract This paper explores the possibility for e cient long term contracts for traders with changing and privately known incentives for exchange. We suggest a negociation process enabling the parties to adapt the default rules of exchange to changes in their preferences for trade. The selection of control rights and default options is delegated to the traders themselves who are collectively best informed as to what investment and exchanges are e cient. The paper demonstrates how contracts with exible and endogenous default options are tailored to maximize the gains from exchange. Applications of our ndings for contract theory and the design of commercial contracts are discussed. 1 Introduction. Contracts are intended to support e cient relationship investment and expost exchange. Of the numerous obstacles there are to e cient trade, none are thought to be more troublesome than trading with privately informed parties with changing preferences for exchange. 1 The incentives for making relation enhancing investments are reduced when the motives of traders are unknown and their actions can not be observed. Contract theory predicts that the costs of monitoring investments and bargaining for exchange may Fuqua School of Business, Duke University y Yale Law School 1 See Williamson (1979), Akerlof (1979) and Stiglitz (2002) 1

2 grow so large as to preclude e cient contracting among privately informed parties. This can arise even in environments most favorable to contracting where agreements are complete and enforceable. 2 The contract models that make this important prediction all share this feature. In the absence of an agreement the contract is governed by a rigid default rule or property right that typically cedes control of the tangible assets to one party or another. For example Coase s (1960) theory of bargaining, which was the rst and is arguably the most in uential contacting model, asserts that either the buyer or the seller have the exclusive right to property as a default position from which the parties can renegotiate. 3 This paper proposes an alternative process for assigning control and default options. We explore what possibilities there are for long term e cient contracting with private information when default rules are endogenously determined. We develop a model of complete contracting that enables the parties to negotiate the default rule and rights as part of the contract. The default rule is renegotiated at the end of each period as the parties receive new information about their preferences for continuing or terminating the agreement. For instance, this process allows for default rights to adjust in favor of the buyer or the seller in response to new requests or demands the parties may report. Control rights, like commodities and services, may be exchanged to the mutual bene t of parties. This model is then employed to predict when long term contracts can support e cient relation speci c investment and expost exchange in the most di cult environments where private parties are continually receiving private information about their preferences and options for contracting in the future. Our analysis reveals new insights on the role of legal entitlements and control rights as well as the bene ts of delegating decisions to privately informed agents in the design of long term contracts. 1.1 Recent Developments Before summarizing our ndings and the outline for this paper, we provide a brief overview of recent developments in the theory of contracting with private information to put our analysis in perspective. Modern contract 2 See Akerlof ( 1979) and Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983) 3 See Merges (1996) for another view on the importance of strong property rights in contracting 2

3 theory begins with Coases (1960) celebrated analysis of "The Problem of Social Cost", that has come to be known as the, The Coase Theorem: To achieve e cient exchange, one need only assign unambiguous rights of control to one individual and allow the parties to bargain. The Coase Theorem is virtually a tautology as it follows that rational self-interested parties will exchange to their mutual bene t when left unobstructed. Furthermore it may fail to hold when parties are asymmetrically informed 4. Nonetheless the Theorem it provides a useful guide to e cient contracting when there is complete information, or when only one of the party s is asymmetrically informed. A short while after the Coase Theorem came the important discovery by Vickrey(1961), Clark (1971 ) and Groves (1973) extending the theory of e cient contracting to the private information setting. VCG Mechanisms: E cient trade among privately informed traders is only possible if each trader pays or receives the value lost or gained by the other traders in the exchange. For instance this requires that in bilateral exchange, the buyer pay the seller s cost of supply and that the seller receive payment equal to the buyers value. In e ect each party to the exchange becomes the residual claimant of the net surplus created by the trade. Following on the heels of VCG were the disappointing disclosures of d Aspremont and Varet (1979) and Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983) that the VCG mechanism could not be implemented by many standard form contracts. Impossibility of E cient Exchange with Budget Balancing and Voluntary Participation. Private contracting requires the parties consent and voluntary participation. It also requires a balance of transfers between the parties so the contract is self nancing. Neither voluntary participation or budget balance is ensured under VCG when property rights are vested with one trader. The payments that owners demand to reveal their value of trade exceeds the potential gains from trade. E cient exchange requires subsidization from a third party, like the government, which is typically not possible in private agreements. 4 See Farrell (1987). 3

4 In an attempt to restore e cient contracting, Cramton, Gibbons and Klemperer CGK(1987) demonstrate how privately informed members may e ciently dissolve a partnership. 5 CGK: Possibility of E cient Exchange with shared ownership of assets. Partnerships with share ownership may be e ciently dissolved. Members who are uncertain whether to be a buyer or seller of assets demand less to reveal their value of trade. Consequently it is possible to restore e cient exchange along with voluntary participation and balanced transfers when ownership is properly distributed to traders. Default rights play an important role in contracting according to the theories we ve reviewed about. Yet this theory typically views default options as exogenous or determined by events prior to contracting. 6 When viewed this way, the success of the contract depends on whether the default happens to be set correctly in the beginning and whether the parties incentives to bargain over time remain aligned. In reality, however, as the traders preference for exchange change with time, their incentives to perform under the original contract may become misaligned. In this case default options must be adjusted if the parties are to continue supporting the contract. This calls for a bargaining processes in which the default rights at each stage are negotiated as part of the contract. 1.2 Summary of theoretical results We model a contract as an agreement that governs the parties behavior over the term of their relationship. In period the parties privately observes an estimate of their costs and bene ts of investment and exchange. The parties report this information to each other. Based on the reports, the agreement speci es what investments and exchanges the parties will undertake and the payment each will receive. Most important, the contract is voluntary. The agreement may be permanently voiding by any party in any period. In case of default, the contract provides for rights and rules that govern their behavior 5 See also Ayres and Talley (1995), Edlin and Reichelstein (1996), Lewis and Sappington (1989), Schweizer (2006) and Segal and Whinston (2009) for related results. 6 Some notable exceptions are Ayres (2004), Matuschek (2004) and Kuribko and Lewis (2009) 4

5 in the absence of agreement. For example a default rule may give each party ownership and control of all the property he has previously developed under the contract. In addition, the default rules themselves are renegotiated as part of the contract each period following the exchange of services and transfer of payments. Three main results emerge from our analysis of this model of contracting. First and most important, (a) Existence of E cient long term contracts. Voluntary and self nancing contracts that implement e cient investment and exchange exist These agreements are supported by exible default rules which are optimally adjusted each period in response to previous negotiations and the arrival of new private information. The unique feature of these contracts is that parties are delegated responsibility for the setting the default rights based on their private information. Incentives are provided for each party to negotiate default rules that ensure their continued support of the agreement. (b) Contract simplicity: The agreement is surprisingly simple. Each party receives two transfers. The rst transfer is a payment equal to the surplus created by the other parties to the agreement. This payment ensure each party is the residual claimant of the entire net surplus that the contract creates. Being an owner of the entire surplus endows each party with the right incentives to invest and exchange e ciently. The second transfer is an assessment equal to the additional surplus each party expects to receive from supporting the agreement. These assessments are collected to ensure the contract is self nancing. The default rules that the parties negotiates determine the transfer that each party is assessed to support the agreement. The assessments can not be too large, otherwise parties would void the agreement to seek their outside default option (c) Determination of Default Rights: The default rules are selected to maximize the assessments subject to the constraint that each party prefers to support the agreement rather than quit. The optimal default rule minimizes the aggregate value of the parties outside default options. Hence the parties with assets that are most highly valued outside the agreement are allocated the smallest control rights. This rule maximizes the incentives for parties to remain under contract. 5

6 Section 2 begins with a one period example that illustrates many of our main conclusion. Section 3 discusses implications of the example and extends the analyses to a multiperiod setting. Section 4 concludes with a formal model that summarizes and extends the results suggested in the examples. 2 An Example Suppose that a decision to replace a used machine must be made. There are two parties who care about the decision, the buyer, B who uses the machine and the seller, S; who originally sold the machine. The machine may be in either of two states of repair denoted by x: In state x = n the machine is not functioning. This means there is a probability of n = :00 that the machine can operate. In the other state, x = f; the machine is functioning which means that it operates with probability f = :50: A new machine operates with probability equal to 1:00: Preferences for replacing the machine naturally di er between B and S. S incurs a cost of c to replace the machine. This cost c varies with uniform probability between 0 and 100 depending on how busy S is servicing other customers. B derives a net bene t of (1 x )v from replacing a machine in state x: The bene t of replacement is the increased likelihood of operation, (1 x ) multiplied by v; the value of the machine s output. This value v varies with uniform probability between 0 and 100 depending on B 0 s demand for output. It is e cient to replace the machine if the bene t exceeds the cost, or (1 x ) v c: Otherwise the machine should not be replaced. The gain in surplus from e cient replacement available for B and S to divide is therefore, W x (v; c) = max f(1 x ) v; cg 2.1 An e cient replacement contract with complete information When the original machine is purchased, the parties arrange in advance for the e cient replacement of the machine in the future. They anticipate knowing the state of repair of the machine, x the replacement cost c and the value of production v at the time the machine may be replaced. However at the 6

7 time they negotiate the contract the parties only know the distribution of possible values for x; c and v: The parties want a contract that will implement the e cient replacement. They know this will require that it be individually rational for each party to abide by the contract at the time of replacement. They also realize that payments in exchange for replacement of the machine must nanced by the buyer and seller. The contract must balance the budget, whatever compensation one party receives must be paid for by the other. Of course by now we know that Coase (1960) discovered the very contract that the parties desire. Coase envisioned that one of the parties, say B would initially purchase the right to replace the machine from S for a mutually agreed upon price. Then at the time of replacement after the parties learned the machine s state of repair, x; the value of production v and the costs of replacement c, B would o er to sell his right of replacement to S for an amount c; provided it exceeded B 0 s replacement bene t,(1 x ) v. Otherwise B would demand S replace the machine at no cost. The Coase contract described above does implement the e cient replacement. B will demand the machine be replaced when his bene ts exceed the cost of replacement. Otherwise B will forego replacement if he receives a payment of c that exceeds his bene t. Moreover the contract is individually rational, as neither party is harmed by the agreement. And nally, of course the contract balances the budget, as the payments each party receives sum to zero. Coase s contract is so simple and compelling that it is easy for us loose sight of how it works. The party, in this case, B; who buys the right to replacement, also acquires the claim to the additional surplus W x (v; c) = max ((1 x ) v; c) generated by the e cient replacement. Since B is the chooser who decides whether to replace or not, he will opt for the choice that maximizes total surplus. Coase recognized that it is necessary as well as su cient for the chooser to be the residual claimant to the total surplus if he is to decide e ciently. 7

8 2.2 Contracting between a Privately Informed Buyer and Seller Contracting for e cient exchange is much more di cult when the buyer and seller are privately informed about their values. Suppose B and S privately observe their bene ts and costs before negotiating for the replacement of a machine in state x = n that is known to be non functioning. Unfortunately Coasean bargaining does not work for this setting because there is no individual with complete information to propose and enforce e cient exchange. Instead a contract is needed for delegating the replacement decision to the privately informed buyer and seller. Fortunately such a contract exists that can be implemented by the following two stage process: The explanation of the contract is simpler if we start with second stage of the agreement. Agreement to Choose and Compensate: The agreement begins once B and S observe their valuations. Based on their observation B reports a bene t ~v 2 [0; 100] and S reports a cost ~c 2 [0; 100] : The party reporting the higher value becomes the "chooser" who decides on replacement. The party reporting the lower value is compensated with a payment equal to the chooser s derived surplus. The payments for B and S are therefore p n B (~v; ~c) = 0 if ~v ~c ~c if ~v < ~c ; p n S (~v; ~c) = 0 if ~c ~v ~v if ~c < ~v The e ect of the Agreement is to make each party the residual claimant of the total exchange surplus. Consequence, each party reveals his actual replacement valuation to maximize total surplus To illustrate suppose B 0 s valuation is 50: If B reports ~v = 50 he either receives 50 (if he is the chooser) or ~c (if S is the chooser) whichever amount is larger. In this case B 0 s expected surplus becomes E ~c max(50; ~c) which is exactly the net expected surplus from exchange. Consequently B is best served by truthfully reporting his valuation to maximize total surplus. By the same argument, S also reports truthfully to maximize his surplus. Hence in equilibrium the Agreement implements e cient exchange by delegating the decision to replace to the privately informed buyer and seller. The Choose and Compensation Agreement implements e cient exchange, 8

9 but it does so at a signi cant cost. The parties only reveal their private information if each is the residual claimant to the entire surplus. The parties together must receive payments equal to the expected exchange surplus of E v;c W n (v; c) = 66:67: Somehow these payments must be nanced for the budget to balance. This brings us to the initial Optional Contracting stage of the contract. Optional Contracting: Setting Default Rights Before learning their valuations, the parties agree to default control rights. The default rights are a pair of probabilities ( n B; n S) that sum to one, specifying the likelihood B or S controls the replacement decision, in the default state where there is no agreement. The control rights are strong property rights when either n B = 1 or n S = 1: Otherwise when n B and n B lie strictly between 0 and 1 the rights may be interpreted as probabilistic liability rules. 7 Optional Contracting: Determining Deposits Payments: B and S are then required to make respective deposits of d B ( n B) and d S ( n S) to ensure their participation in the subsequent stage of the contract. The deposits are collected to nance the transfer payments the parties receive from the Choose and Compensate part of the contract. Participation in the agreement is however voluntary. The deposits are returned if either party terminates the agreement to pursue his outside default option. The optional control rights, ( n B; n S) ; and the deposits d B ( n B) and d S ( n S) are crucial in ensuring the participation of B and S in the Agreement. To make the contract self nancing, the parties combined deposits must cover or exceed the expected sum of transfer payments, equal to E v;c W n (v; c) : The amount each party is willing to deposit depends on their control rights. The deposits can not exceed the minimum payments that B and S expect to gain from the contract in excess of their default option, which is calculated to be, d n B ( n B) = min v w (E ~c W n (v w ; ~c) n B (1 n ) v w ) d n S ( n S) = min c w (E ~v W n (~v; c w ) n Sc w ) 7 See Calabreshi and Melamed (1972) 9

10 Strong Default Property Rights To illustrate, imagine for instance, that B is awarded the exclusive default right to choose replacement, as we assumed before in the Coase contract. This would mean that n B = 1 and n S = 0: In this case v w = 100 is the valuation that minimizes B 0 s contract surplus compared to his outside option. The largest deposit that B is willing to make turns out to be d n B (1) = E ~c W n (100; ~c) 1x (100) = E ~c max (100; ~c) 100 = 0 The fact that B has such strong control rights in default explains why d B (1) = 0, as he is unwilling to deposit any positive amount to contract with S: In contrast S; whose minimizing cost occurs at c w = 0 is willing to deposit d n S (0) = E ~v W n (~v; 0) 0 = E ~v max (~v; 0) = 50 The relatively large deposit of d n S (0) = 50 re ects S0 s desire to negotiate away from her outside default option where she has no control. The buyer and seller s combined deposits are d n B (1) + dn S (0) = 50: This sum does cover the expected transfer payments of 66:67 that must be nanced. The budget is not balanced and hence it is not possible to implement the e cient replacement if B is given sole control of the replacement in the default. If S is awarded sole control in default instead of B; we reach the same conclusion, e cient replacement can not be implemented. This illustrates the Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983) nding, noted in the Introduction, that e cient exchange between privately informed agents with strong property rights can not sustained. Deposit Maximizing Default Rights An alternative to either assigning property rights or otherwise, arbitrary rights, is to select default rights that maximize total deposits 8. For this example deposits are maximized by assigning equal control rights where 8 Schweizer (2006) also suggests this method for selecting property right assignments. 10

11 ( n B = :5; n S = :5) : In this instance B and S deposit d n B (:5) = dn S (:5) = 37:50 for a total of 75:00: 9 The deposits easily cover the expected sum of transfer payments E v;c W n (v; c) = 66:67 so that the contract is self nancing. To ensure the payments are balanced for all realizations of (v; c) ; requires one to adjust the transfer payments. This adjustment, which we describe in section 4 is easy to implement. 2.3 Contracting with Private Information Under different Conditions To complete the example let s derive the e cient contract under di erent conditions when the machine to be replaced is known to be functioning. The contracting process will remain the same, of course, however the terms of the contract will be modi ed to account for the di erence in operating status of the machine. When the machine is functioning the bene t to B from replacement is just 5v; since the old machine functions 50 percent of the time. The buyer s production value v is still the same ranging with equal probability between 0 and 100. S 0 s cost of replacement, is still c; and it also ranges between 0 and 100 with equal probability. The transfer payments under the Choose and Compensate Agreement are now modi ed to account for the diminished bene t B derives from replacement, p f B (~v; ~c) = 0 if.:5~v ~c ~c if 5~v < ~c ; p f S (~v; ~c) = 0 if ~c 5~v ~v if ~c < 5~v These are the payments ensuring each of the parties is a residual claimant of the entire replacement surplus. The expected sum of these transfers is now, E v;c max [v; c] = 54:16 The transfers are smaller because the bene ts from replacement are decreased compared to the case where the old machine is non functioning. 9 For example S s deposit is calculated as The calculation for B is the same. d n S (:5) = E v max (v; 50) :25 = 37:50 11

12 In order to nance these transfers we select control rights f B ; f S maximize the sum of the deposits, d f B + df S, that are collected. The depositmaximizing control rights are calculated to be fb = :66; fs = :33 and the corresponding deposits turn out to be d f S (:33) = 25:00 and df B (:66) = 33:33: The sum of these deposits exceed the expected transfers, with d f S (:33) + df B (:67) E v;cw f (v; c) = 58:33 54:16 > 0: Hence, as with the non functioning machine, this contract is self nancing and therefore capable of implementing e cient replacement. Comparing the control rights for the two cases x = f and n reveals that f B > n B: The buyer is allocated greater control when the old machine is functioning as compared to when it is not. B 0 s replacement demand is greater for a non functioning machine. Hence B 0 s control rights vary inversely with his demand for replacement. We show in section 4, this is a general property of optimal control right allocations. The rationale is that controls are chosen to minimize the parties outside options to create the greatest incentives for them to continue contracting. 3 Implications Coase was, and still is, right. To contract e ciently requires that traders have clearly de ned legal rights and that they be allowed to bargain, unobstructed, to their mutual bene t. What does require some reconsideration, however, is the way in which contracts are implemented when traders are privately about their preference for exchange 3.1 Coasean Contracting with Private Information We argue through example that two modi cations to the Coase contract are required to contract e ciently. The rst arises because the information required to exchange e ciently resides separately with the privately informed traders. There is no individual who can make e cient choices alone, as in Coase s world. Instead, decisions must be collectively delegated to the di erent privately informed parties. However, as in Coase s world, e cient decision making requires that those to 12

13 who choose must become the residual claimants of all the surplus they create. This is easily accomplished through transfers between the parties. Each trader is paid the surplus that the other traders generate through their exchange. So for example, the seller who supplies the machine is paid the bene t that the buyer receives when the old machine is replaced. But how is this bene t determined if the buyer is privately informed about his valuation? Fortunately there is a relatively straightforward process for gathering this information. As we explained in our example of the Choose and Compensate agreement, the buyer and seller report their willingness to pay in order to decide. The party bidding the highest amount, in this case the buyer, selects his preferred option, to replace the machine. The loosing party, the seller, is paid the buyer s bene t as compensation. All the information needed to implement these payments is provided by the buyer and seller. The decision to exchange, is in e ect, delegated to the privately informed buyer and seller to make. Given the elegance and simplicity of this process, it s probably no surprise that agreements like these are frequently used in bilateral contracting, market allocations and as default options in the absence of consensual agreement. Perhaps the best known of these mechanisms is the second price auction, that Vickrey(1961) rst noticed. In this case the winner pays the second highest bid as compensation for the reduction in surplus he imposes on the other bidders. Most liability rules are also based on some type of choose and compensate agreement that we introduced in the example. Infact when contracting and bargaining are viewed through the lens of option theory as in Ayres (2004), there are countless examples of formal and informal allocation processes that are implemented in one form or another as a choose and compensate agreement. What makes residual claimancy so attractive is that each party acts ef- ciently because he owns the total surplus. But therein lies the problem there is only one surplus to distribute among a multitude of claimants. It is this imbalance between the promised transfer payments and the surplus available to fund these payments that calls for the second and more di cult modi cation of the Coase contract. In order to nance the transfers, traders must deposit su cient funds in advance of bargaining with each other. Since contracting is voluntary, each trader will only deposit the amount he expects to earn in excess of what he would receive from his outside option. Of course the value of the outside option is determined by the control rights of each party in the absence of 13

14 an agreement. If these rights are mis-speci ed, the contract for e cient exchange can not be implemented. For instance, in the foregoing example we illustrate that strong property rights, that gives one of the traders exclusive control of the assets in default, will typically not work. Strong rights endow the parties with asymmetric bargaining power. The trader who controls the property is not eager to bargain and therefore unwilling to post a deposit to ensure his participation in the exchange. Consequently the contract fails because the transfers between traders required to make them residual claimants can not be internally nanced. 10 This is the cause for what Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983) observe as an ine ciency in bilateral exchange. The solution, as we show by example, is to select control rights that maximize the deposits collected. The optimal control rights are simple to characterize: they are the controls that minimize the traders outside option value. The intuition is that traders with a low outside options are most eager to bargain and are therefore willing to post the largest deposits. These deposits are typically su cient to cover the transfers between the parties, so the contract can be internally nanced and is therefore feasible 11. In principle the setting of control rights to maximize deposits is straightforward. All that is required is for the traders to know the distributions of each other s values, and to anticipate the types of exchanges that they will eventually negotiate. This is su cient information to predict the expected gains from exchange for each party and therefore to select the default controls that will maximize the traders deposits. It seems plausible to ful ll these information requirements in short term contracts during which the private information of the traders does not change. In long term contracts the initial common information about the traders preferences for exchange and the types of exchanges that may arise is certain change with the passage of time. The likelihood that traders acquire additional private information with time, may further constrain the set of e cient contracts that one can implement. 10 Strong property rights are however e ective when the traders have interdependent valuations for the exhange. In that case the amount the parties are willing to deposit is maximized by giving one of the traders exclusvie rights of control See Jehiel and Pauzner( 2006) and Fieseler,Kittsteiner and Moldovanu (2003) 11 Our s is not the rst demonstration that properly set control rights can support ef- cient contractual agreements. Aside from CGK(1987)) who demonstrate this result for equal share partnerships, see Segal and Whinston (2009), and Schweizer (2006). 14

15 3.2 Boundaries of E cient Contracting with Private Information To our knowledge the models and examples demonstrating e cient contracting with private information, all consider short term contracts in which the common information of the parties about their distribution of values and the types of exchanges that arise does not change. 12 For instance in CGK (1987) the distribution of values of the partners is assumed to be known and xed at the time the partnership is dissolved. All of these model rely on common information about the traders exchanges and preferences to determine default control rights and transfer payment that will support e cient exchange. When the contract last for several periods, the assumption that the parties future trade opportunities and distribution of their preferences for exchange is common knowledge becomes untenable. In this case we propose an augmented contract that solicits updated information from the traders each period to set default rights and transfer payments for future exchanges. 3.3 Augmented Contracts with Endogenous Default Controls: Imagine that in our example of machine replacement that the type x = n; f of the machine to be replaced is initially unknown. Moreover assume that B may make an unobserved investment to a ect the reliability of the machine in future use and that only B will privately observe the repair state of when it is replaced. While these are realistic possibilities to model, they all serve to complicate the contract designer s life in two ways. First, we must now rely on B to provide information on the type of machine to be replaced. This information is required to set the terms including default rights and transfer payments for e cient exchange. Second, we rely on B to invest e ciently to until replacement. B 0 s investment incentives are, of course, be a ected by the replacement agreements. We address these complications with an augmented contracting process that is fully explained by the formal model presented section 4, The process relies on information provided by B of his observation of the machine type 12 One exception is Kuribko and Lewis (2009), who describe an e cient multiperiod contract where the traders receive new and presistent private information in each of the period of the contract. 15

16 to design e cient exchange. While we have no guarantee that B reports accurate information we can provide incentives for B to disclose truthfully. Working backwards, we begin with the augmented contract just prior to period 1; after B has invested and learns the working state of the used machine. Realizing this,b is o ered a menu of choices denoted by 8 9 >< >= M = >: hqn ; M n ( n ; p n ; d n )i q f ; M f f ; p f d f {z } {z } >; non functional option functional option B may select the non functional or the functional machine replacement option. When B chooses option x = n or f; he receives payment qb x and the subsequent replacement of the machine is governed by the agreement M x that speci es the contract terms ( x ; p x ; d x ) that we have previously derived in the example. To induce B to select the e cient agreement, requires that he be the residual claimant of the replacement surplus. Suppose U B (M x ) is the expected surplus B expects from the replacement of a type x machine under agreement M x. Then B is o ered a payment of qb x that satis es, q x B + U B (M x ) = E v;c W x (v; c) The payment to B must be nanced by S; so that qs x = surplus from B 0 s selection is equals qx B and S0 s net q x S + U S (M x ) = U B (M x ) E v;c W x (v; c) + U S (M x ) = 0 At this stage B is the sole claimant to all future expected surplus from exchange. Rolling the contract back to the beginning, the parties anticipate B will be the sole claimant to surplus at the time of replacement. Consequently B has the incentive to invest e ciently to maintain the machine because he owns the stream of bene ts the machine produces and the surplus created after the machine is replaced. Therefore it is e cient for B to purchase the exclusive rights from S to maintain and contract for the eventual replacement 16

17 of the machine. Assume W : is the maximized value of the machine that is e ciently maintained and replaced. Then provided B and S negotiate to split the excess surplus from e cient investment and exchange, B will pay S an amount qb 0 that is equal to q 0 B = W E c c 2 Summarizing, the augmented contract works by delegating the choice of control rights and contract terms to the privately informed parties. The missing common information on the types of exchanges that may arise in the future and the distribution of value for exchange is supplied by the contracting parties. Their incentives are to report this information truthfully since they are residual claimants to the surplus that results. In cases where a one party has all the information required to decide, he acquires the sole claim on future surplus by buying out the other party. For instance, the buyer purchases the sole rights to maintain and direct replacement of the machine because he alone is informed about the e cient replacement decision. Most important, though, augmented contracting can substitute for common information that is needed to structure contracts that implement e cient investment and exchange Model of Supply Contracting This section formally models the supply contracting process. The supply contract consists of two stages. In the rst stage the buyer B and the supplier, S contract for the purchase and investment in machine maintenance. In the second stage B and S contract for the servicing and possible replacement of the machine in the future. As with many analyses of long term contracts, it s most instructive to start with the second stage contract and work backwards: 13 By comparison,other dynamic models including Bergemann and Valimaki (2006) and Athey and Segal (2007) analyze e cient VCG types of contracts, where however the property and default rights are xed. These models nd, that although there is e cient investment and exchange of services, the contract are not necessarily individually rational or budget balanced. The inability of parties to adjust control through time with the arrival of new information precludes these contract from be implemented as voluntary budget balance mechanisms. 17

18 4.1 Part 1: The Service and Maintenance Agreement Suppose that a decision to replace a used machine must be made. There are two parties who care about the decision, the buyer, B who purchased and uses the machine and the seller, S; who originally sold the machine and would replace it if required to do so. The current reliability of the machine is denoted by 2 [0; 1] : is the probability the machine is up and running at any time. The only way to restore the reliability of the current machine is to replace it with a new one. The buyer and seller preference s for replacing the machine naturally differ. The seller incurs a cost of c to replace the machine. The cost c varies with uniform probability between 0 and 100 depending on how busy S is servicing other buyers. The buyer derives a bene t from having a machine of type replaced that equals (1 )v; which is the increased probability the machine operates after being replaced, multiplied by v the value of the materials produced by the machine. The value v varies with uniform probability between 0 and 100 depending on the buyers need for materials. The e cient replacement rule is readily derived. Let (v; c) be the e cient decision,where 1 if (1 ) v c (v; c) = 0 if (1 ) v < c It is only e cient to replace the machine if the bene t exceeds the cost, or (1 x ) v c; : otherwise the machine should not be replaced. The total surplus from replacement for the parties to divide is may therefore be written as The Contract W (v; c) = (v; v) (1 ) v + (1 (v; v)) c = max f(1 ) v; cg In order to derive the e cient contract we make some assumptions about the sequence at which information is acquired and contracted upon by the parties which is summarized in Figure 1. Suppose that initially the parties 18

19 observe that the machine reliability is < 1: 14. At this time all that is known about c and v is that each is independently and uniformly distributed over the [0; 100] interval. Following this in period 0 the parties agree to a contract, denoted by M = ( ; (~v; ~c) ; p (~v; ~c) ; d ( )) The contract has the following provisions: Default Option: Beginning of period 1; B privately observes the realization of v and S privately observes the realization of cost, c: At that time either party may choose to default. In case of default the contract is governed by control rights = ( B ; S ) where B can have the machine replaced with probability B ; and S can not replace the machine with probability S = 1 B :15 Note, M is designed to be individually rational, so that in equilibrium both traders prefer to contract rather than default. Nonetheless, the rights are important in determining the parties bargaining position in subsequent stages of the contract. Payment of Deposit: If the parties decide to continue they make deposits d B ( ) and d S ( ) : These deposits ensure the parties participation in the subsequent agreement. Replacement Decision: Based on their observation B reports valuation ~v 2 [0; 100] and S reports a cost ~c 2 [0; 100] : The reports may or may not truthful since they can not be veri ed. Based on the reports, the machine replacement occurs according to rule (~v; ~c) : Following this B and S exchange payments p B (~v; ~c) and p S (~v; ~c) and the contract ends. 14 If = 1 there is no reason to replace the machine. 15 Note when B = 1 or S = 1; this corresponds to Coasian property rights where one party has exclusive control rights. 19

20 Parties observe reliability Negotiation of contract B learns v S leans c Parties consider default option B and S continue and make deposits B reports v S reports c Contract is implemented t=0 t= Response of B and S Timing of Replacement Contract Each party selects a report that to maximize his expected surplus, given his information and the expected report of the other party. B chooses ~v to maximize expected utility U B (v) which is U B (v) max E ~c (p B (~v; ~c) + ~v (~v; ~c) (1 ) v) d B (1) B 0 s surplus consists of his expected transfer payment plus the expected surplus from replacement minus his deposit. S similarly selects a report ~c to maximize expected surplus U S (c) which is U S (c) max E ~v (p S (~v; ~c) + (1 ~c (~v; ~c)) ~c) d S (2) Desired Properties of the Contract We would like the contract to be individually rational, budget balanced and that it be expost e cient. Speci cally this requires the following: We require M to be incentive compatible, so that B and S truthfully report their valuations ~c = c; ~v = v for all c; v 2 [0; 100] (IC) 20

21 The actual replacement rule (~v; ~c) will be e cient provided there is truthful reporting of valuations. M should be individually rational. This means both parties prefer the contract to the default, which requires U B (v) B (1 ) v 0 (IIR) U S (v) S c 0 M should balance the budget so that p B (v; c) + p S (v; c) d B ( ) d S ( ) = 0 (BB) Derivation of the Contract Incentive Compatible Payments: To construct an incentive compatible contract that implements e cient exchange it is necessary that each party become the residual claimant of the entire exchange surplus. Notice, the parties individual contribution to surplus W B (v; c) and W S (v; c) are given by W B (v; c) = (v; c) (1 ) v (3) W S (v; c) = (1 (v; c))c (4) To induce truthtelling it is su cient for the parties expected utilities to take the form U B U S (v) = max E ~c (W B (~v; ~c) + W S (~v; ~c)) ~v d B ( ) (5) (c) = max E ~v (W B (~v; ~c) + W S (~v; ~c)) ~c d S ( ) (6) Substituting for U B (v) and U S (c) into (1) and (2) and solving for the transfers, we obtain the payment that induce truthful reporting are 21

22 U B (v) = E ~cw (v; ~c) d B B (1 ) v (IIR) p S (~v; ~c) = W B (v; c) + W S (~v; ~c) (1 (v; c))c = W B (~v; ~c) (7) p x B (~v; ~c) = W B (v; c) + W S (~v; ~c) (~v; ~c) (1 ) v = W S (~v; ~c) (8) Each party is paid the contribution to surplus provided by their trading partner. For example B receives a payment equal to the surplus generated by S. Hence each party becomes a claimant for the total surplus from trade. Deposits Required for Individually Rationality and Budget Balance To ensure both parties agree to contract requires that the deposit payments are not so large as to induce a party to default. The parties will not default provided their expected surplus from contracting exceeds their surplus from default, or U S (v) = E ~cw (v; ~c) d S S c This implies that the deposits cannot exceed d B ( ) and d S ( ) which are the largest allowable deposits for which the contract is individually rational, where d B ( ) = min v w E ~c W (v w ; ~c) B (1 ) v w (9) d S ( ) = min c w E ~v W (~v; c w ) S c w (10) Note that the minimizing valuations v w and c w are de ned by B = E c (v w ; c) S = E v (1 (v; c w )) 22

23 Hence substituting for the control rights into (9) and (10) we obtain: d B ( ) = E ~c (W (v w ; ~c) (v w ; c) (1 ) v w ) = E ~c p B (v w; ~c) (11) d S ( ) = E ~v (W (~v; c w ) S c w) = E ~v p S (~v; c w) (12) The deposits d B ( ) and d S ( ) represent the amount each party expects to be paid under the agreement, evaluated at their initial default bargaining position To balance the budget we want the largest deposits possible that ensure the contract is individually rational. De ne as the deposit maximizing control rights. is are determined as the solution to, = arg max ((d B ( ) + d S ( ))) (13) s:t: B + x S = 1 Necessary and su cient conditions for the maximization are d d B (E c W (v w ; c) B () (1 ) v w + E v W (v; c w ) (1 B ) c w) = 0 Given the envelop theorem this is equivalent to minimizing the sum of the parties outside options, which requires that (1 ) v w + c w = 0 Summarizing, the optimal default rights that maximize the sum of deposits are characterized by B = E c (v w; c) = prob (c (1 ) v w ) S = E v (1 (v; c w )) = prob (v c w = (1 )) It s worthwhile pausing here to interpret these conditions. First the control rights are selected to minimize the value of the parties s outside option. This is intuitive. To limit the payments, the parties are o ered an outside option that is least attractive, so that they are willing to post higher fees to 23

24 participate in the contract. Second the controls adjust to the parties willingness to trade. For instance, compare B 0 s control when = :5 and when = 0: When the machine is nonfunctional, B is more eager to trade for a replacement than when the product is relatively functional. B default control rights for the two cases are :5 B = :66 and 0 B = :33: Hence, when B 0 s demand for a replacement is greater his control rights are smaller. This is done to place B on the "right side of the market" where he will be most eager to trade. In other words, the control rights are set to maximize the parties willingness to exchange Verifying Payments are Balanced Budget It remains for us to verify that the maximum deposits characterized in (9) (10) are large enough to cover the transfers payments so that E v;c (p B (v; c) + p S (v; c)) d B d S 0 From (7) (8) and (11) (12) note that we calculate that the sum of expected payments as follows. E v;c (p B (v; c) + p S (v; c)) d B d S = (14) E v;c W (v; c) (E ~c W (v w ; ~c) B (1 ) v w ) (E ~v W (~v; c w ) S c w) For the purposes of this calculation assume v; c 2 0; k and v is distributed by F (v) and c is distributed by G (c) with strictly positive densities in the 0; k interval. Then we can write Ev;c W x (v; c) as E c;v W (v; c) = Z k 0 E v W (v; c) dg (c) (15) = E v W k; v = = Z k 0 Z k 0 Z k 0 de v W (v; c) G (c) dc dc de v W (v; c) (1 G (c)) dc + E v W (0; v) dc c F 1 Z k (1 G (c)) dc + (1 F (v)) (1 ) dv 0 24

25 and Z k d B = Ec W S (v w; c) = (1 G (c)) dc + B (1 ) v w (16) c w Z k d S = Ev W B (v; c w) = (1 F (v)) (1 ) dv + c w S (17) v w Substituting (15) (17) into (14) we obtain, E v;c W (v; c) E ~c W S v w; ~c) E ~v W B (~v; c w) (18) Z cw 0 = (1 ) Z k c w c 1 F (1 G (c)) dc 1 c c + F F G (c) dc < 0 Hence we see that the deposits more than cover the transfer payments. In order to insure the budget is balanced at each realization of (v; c) requires that we adjust the transfer payments in the following way. De ne new transfer payments p B (v; c) and p S (v; c) as p B (v; c) = E Cp B (v; c) E v;c (p B (v; c) + p S (v; c)) d B 2 +E vc p S (v; c) E v p S (v; c) d S p S (v; c) = E V p S (v; c) E v;c (p B (v; c) + p S (v; c)) d B 2 +E vc p B (v; c) E cp B (v; c) d S Then it is easy to verify that, p B (v; c) + p S (v; c) d B d S = 0 The sum of the newly de ned payments is zero at each realization (v; c) : 25

26 4.1.6 Summary of Service Contract: The provisions of the type Service Contract are summarized by the following M = ( ; (~v; ~c) ; p (~v; ~c) ; d ( )) where B = E c (v w ; c) ; S = (1 E c (v w ; c)) p B (v; c) = E cw S (v; c) + d B + d S ( ) E v;c W (v; c) 2 +E vc p S (v; c) E vp S (v; c) p S (v; c) = E sw S (v; c) + d B + d S ( ) E v;c W (v; c) 2 +E vc p B (v; c) E cp B (v; c) (v; c) = 1 if (1 ) v c 0 if (1 ) v < c d B = Ec (W x S (v w ; c)) d S = Ev (W x B (v; c w )) U B = E v;cw (v; c) + d S 2 U S = E v;cw (v; c) + d B 2 d B d S 4.2 Part II: Purchase and Investment The foregoing analysis describes the e cient contract, beginning at the stage where the operating state of the machine is known. Now we wish to model the contracting process that proceeds this stage where the initial purchase and investment in machine reliability are undertaken. At the time of purchase the parties bargain over a sequence of two events that are illustrated in Figure 26

27 2. First shortly after the machine is purchased, the buyer is expected to make an investment to maintain the machine in good working order. Second following his investment B uses the machine for a period of time, where upon he assesses how reliable the machine is for future use. Based on this assessment, B selects a service Agreement, M that provides for the eventual replacement of the machine if warranted. The parties negotiations of these events are governed by the contract M 0 ; q 0 ; I ; M ~ ; q (~) with the following provisions Default Options: Initially default options 0 B ; S 0 are assigned and payments (qb 0 ; q0 S ) are exchanged. Prior to each event, either party may decide to void the contract in favor of their default option. Maintenance Investment: The contract calls for B to make an e - cient investment I in reliability to maintain and improve the operating state of the machine. The buyer s actual investment is voluntary and unobservable. The operating status of the machine, described by 2 [0; 1] is the probability the machine will fail in succeeding periods. The surplus derived from a type of machine is E v;c (v + W (v; c)) where E vc v is the expected value the machine produces and E v;c W (v; c) is the additional surplus from e cient replacement of the machine. The likelihood the machine operates atleast percent of the time, is 1 F ( j I) which is increasing in I: The recommended investment I is the investment that maximizes W (I) the surplus from reliability 16 where, W (I) = max I Z 1 0 E v;c (v + W (v; c)) df ( j I) I 16 We assume I exists and is well de ned. 27

28 Selection of M Agreement: After investing, B observes the resulting reliability, ; of the machine just prior to period 1. B selects a replacement agreement and payment from the menu fm ; q B ()g, where M = M ( ; p ; ; d ( )) is the contract governing replacement and q B () is B 0 s payment. Negotiation of contract B Obtains control rights B observe reliability B reports reliability Replacement Contract Implemented B invests t= 1 t=0 t= Response of the Parties Contracting for Investment In this stage of the contract, B is the only party to take an action, (invest) or to observe information (machine reliability). Consequently the contract delegates the decision to invest and to choose the supply agreement to B: U B is B0 s replacement surplus from a type machine, which is U B = max U B ~ M ~ + q B (~) where U B M ~ ; is the surplus from the M ~ agreement, q B (~) is B 0 s payment and d B 0 is a payment depending only on the default right allocation. U S is S0 s corresponding replacement surplus which is U S = U S M ~ + q S (~) 28

Pay for Play: A Theory of Hybrid Relationships 1

Pay for Play: A Theory of Hybrid Relationships 1 Pay for Play: A Theory of Hybrid Relationships 1 Tracy R. Lewis 2 Alan Schwartz 3 March 2015 Abstract Numerous "arrangements," such as hybrids, alliances, joint ventures, are formed with the goal of creating

More information

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam Dirk Bergemann Department of Economics Yale University Microeconomic Theory (50b) Comprehensive Exam. (5) Consider a moral hazard model where a worker chooses an e ort level e [0; ]; and as a result, either

More information

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Economic Theory 14, 247±253 (1999) Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Christopher M. Snyder Department of Economics, George Washington University, 2201 G Street

More information

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1 Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose,

More information

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham So far we have considered efficient auctions What about maximizing the seller s revenue? she may be willing to risk failing to sell the good she may be

More information

A Multitask Model without Any Externalities

A Multitask Model without Any Externalities A Multitask Model without Any Externalities Kazuya Kamiya and Meg Sato Crawford School Research aper No 6 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1899382 A Multitask Model without Any Externalities

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus Summer 2009 examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2008/2009 syllabus Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours. This paper contains nine questions in three sections. Answer question one

More information

Reference Dependence Lecture 3

Reference Dependence Lecture 3 Reference Dependence Lecture 3 Mark Dean Princeton University - Behavioral Economics The Story So Far De ned reference dependent behavior and given examples Change in risk attitudes Endowment e ect Status

More information

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation Pai-Ling Yin First Draft: October 2002 This Draft: June 2005 Abstract This paper proposes tests to empirically examine whether auction prices aggregate information

More information

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Sta Report November 2009 Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

WORKING PAPER NO COMMENT ON CAVALCANTI AND NOSAL S COUNTERFEITING AS PRIVATE MONEY IN MECHANISM DESIGN

WORKING PAPER NO COMMENT ON CAVALCANTI AND NOSAL S COUNTERFEITING AS PRIVATE MONEY IN MECHANISM DESIGN WORKING PAPER NO. 10-29 COMMENT ON CAVALCANTI AND NOSAL S COUNTERFEITING AS PRIVATE MONEY IN MECHANISM DESIGN Cyril Monnet Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia September 2010 Comment on Cavalcanti and

More information

Dynamic Marginal Contribution Mechanism

Dynamic Marginal Contribution Mechanism Dynamic Marginal Contribution Mechanism Dirk Bergemann y Juuso Välimäki z First Version: September 2006 Current Version: June 2007 We thank the editor, Eddie Dekel, and two anonymous referees for many

More information

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University WORKING PAPER NO. 11-4 OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University Daniel R. Sanches Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia December 2010 Optimal

More information

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade Jesse A. Schwartz Kennesaw State University Quan Wen Vanderbilt University May 2012 Abstract In a bilateral bargaining problem with private

More information

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Henrik Horn (Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm) Giovanni Maggi (Princeton University) Robert W. Staiger (Stanford University and

More information

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1 Auction Theory II Lecture 19 Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1 Lecture Overview 1 Recap 2 First-Price Auctions 3 Revenue Equivalence 4 Optimal Auctions Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 2 Motivation

More information

April 29, X ( ) for all. Using to denote a true type and areport,let

April 29, X ( ) for all. Using to denote a true type and areport,let April 29, 2015 "A Characterization of Efficient, Bayesian Incentive Compatible Mechanisms," by S. R. Williams. Economic Theory 14, 155-180 (1999). AcommonresultinBayesianmechanismdesignshowsthatexpostefficiency

More information

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS 5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS We studied how individual consumers and rms behave in Part I of the book. In Part II of the book, we studied how individual economic agents make decisions when there are strategic

More information

II. Competitive Trade Using Money

II. Competitive Trade Using Money II. Competitive Trade Using Money Neil Wallace June 9, 2008 1 Introduction Here we introduce our rst serious model of money. We now assume that there is no record keeping. As discussed earler, the role

More information

Acquisition and Disclosure of Information as a Hold-up Problem

Acquisition and Disclosure of Information as a Hold-up Problem Acquisition and Disclosure of Information as a Hold-up Problem Urs Schweizer, y University of Bonn October 10, 2013 Abstract The acquisition of information prior to sale gives rise to a hold-up situation

More information

A Nearly Optimal Auction for an Uninformed Seller

A Nearly Optimal Auction for an Uninformed Seller A Nearly Optimal Auction for an Uninformed Seller Natalia Lazzati y Matt Van Essen z December 9, 2013 Abstract This paper describes a nearly optimal auction mechanism that does not require previous knowledge

More information

A Mechanism-Design Approach to Speculative Trade

A Mechanism-Design Approach to Speculative Trade A Mechanism-Design Approach to Speculative Trade K r Eliaz y and Ran Spiegler z November 9, 006 Introduction One of the primary tasks of the mechanism-design literature has been to draw theoretical barriers

More information

Lecture Notes 1

Lecture Notes 1 4.45 Lecture Notes Guido Lorenzoni Fall 2009 A portfolio problem To set the stage, consider a simple nite horizon problem. A risk averse agent can invest in two assets: riskless asset (bond) pays gross

More information

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation Edgar A. Ghossoub The University of Texas at San Antonio Abstract Most studies that use an overlapping generations setting assume complete depreciation

More information

Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information. Appendix

Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information. Appendix Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information Ilan Lobel Appendix Wenqiang iao {ilobel, wxiao}@stern.nyu.edu Stern School of Business, New York University Appendix A: Proofs Proof

More information

Optimal Auctions with Participation Costs

Optimal Auctions with Participation Costs Optimal Auctions with Participation Costs Gorkem Celik and Okan Yilankaya This Version: January 2007 Abstract We study the optimal auction problem with participation costs in the symmetric independent

More information

Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities

Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities Alberto Galasso September 2, 2007 Abstract Building on Genicot and Ray (2006) we develop a model of non-cooperative bargaining that combines

More information

Simple e ciency-wage model

Simple e ciency-wage model 18 Unemployment Why do we have involuntary unemployment? Why are wages higher than in the competitive market clearing level? Why is it so hard do adjust (nominal) wages down? Three answers: E ciency wages:

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 26 January 2015 Failure of the Coase Theorem Recall that the Coase Theorem implies that two parties, when faced with a potential

More information

Auction Theory Lecture Note, David McAdams, Fall Bilateral Trade

Auction Theory Lecture Note, David McAdams, Fall Bilateral Trade Auction Theory Lecture Note, Daid McAdams, Fall 2008 1 Bilateral Trade ** Reised 10-17-08: An error in the discussion after Theorem 4 has been corrected. We shall use the example of bilateral trade to

More information

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty Chifeng Dai Department of Economics Southern Illinois University Carbondale, IL 62901, USA August 2014 Abstract We study optimal

More information

Optimal Progressivity

Optimal Progressivity Optimal Progressivity To this point, we have assumed that all individuals are the same. To consider the distributional impact of the tax system, we will have to alter that assumption. We have seen that

More information

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Some Notes on Timing in Games Some Notes on Timing in Games John Morgan University of California, Berkeley The Main Result If given the chance, it is better to move rst than to move at the same time as others; that is IGOUGO > WEGO

More information

Unbundling Ownership and Control

Unbundling Ownership and Control Unbundling Ownership and Control Daniel Ferreira Emanuel Ornelas John L. Turner June 8, 2010 Abstract We study optimal corporate control allocations under asymmetric information. We modify the canonical

More information

Problem Set # Public Economics

Problem Set # Public Economics Problem Set #3 14.41 Public Economics DUE: October 29, 2010 1 Social Security DIscuss the validity of the following claims about Social Security. Determine whether each claim is True or False and present

More information

Dynamic Principal Agent Models: A Continuous Time Approach Lecture II

Dynamic Principal Agent Models: A Continuous Time Approach Lecture II Dynamic Principal Agent Models: A Continuous Time Approach Lecture II Dynamic Financial Contracting I - The "Workhorse Model" for Finance Applications (DeMarzo and Sannikov 2006) Florian Ho mann Sebastian

More information

SEQUENTIAL INFORMATION DISCLOSURE IN AUCTIONS. Dirk Bergemann and Achim Wambach. July 2013 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

SEQUENTIAL INFORMATION DISCLOSURE IN AUCTIONS. Dirk Bergemann and Achim Wambach. July 2013 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. SEQUENTIAL INFORMATION DISCLOSURE IN AUCTIONS By Dirk Bergemann and Achim Wambach July 2013 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1900 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY Box 208281

More information

Auctions with Resale and Bargaining Power

Auctions with Resale and Bargaining Power Auctions with Resale and Bargaining Power Harrison Cheng and Guofu Tan Department of Economics University of Southern California 36 South Vermont Avenue Los Angeles, CA 989 November 8, 8 Preliminary Abstract

More information

Auction Theory: Some Basics

Auction Theory: Some Basics Auction Theory: Some Basics Arunava Sen Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi ICRIER Conference on Telecom, March 7, 2014 Outline Outline Single Good Problem Outline Single Good Problem First Price Auction

More information

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Mechanism Design and Auctions Mechanism Design and Auctions Game Theory Algorithmic Game Theory 1 TOC Mechanism Design Basics Myerson s Lemma Revenue-Maximizing Auctions Near-Optimal Auctions Multi-Parameter Mechanism Design and the

More information

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking (preliminary draft) Ying Syuan Li National Taiwan University Yiting Li National Taiwan University April 2009 Abstract We consider an economy where people have the needs

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY Summer 2011 Examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours + 10 minutes reading time. This paper contains seven questions in three

More information

Lobby Interaction and Trade Policy

Lobby Interaction and Trade Policy The University of Adelaide School of Economics Research Paper No. 2010-04 May 2010 Lobby Interaction and Trade Policy Tatyana Chesnokova Lobby Interaction and Trade Policy Tatyana Chesnokova y University

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice 1. MWG - Decisive Subgroups Recall proposition 21.C.1: (Arrow s Impossibility Theorem) Suppose that the number of alternatives is at least

More information

Size and Focus of a Venture Capitalist s Portfolio

Size and Focus of a Venture Capitalist s Portfolio Size and Focus of a enture Capitalist s Portfolio Paolo Fulghieri University of North Carolina paolo_fulghieriunc.edu Merih Sevilir University of North Carolina merih_sevilirunc.edu October 30, 006 We

More information

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies Geo rey Heal and Bengt Kristrom May 24, 2004 Abstract In a nite-horizon general equilibrium model national

More information

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth Florian Misch a, Norman Gemmell a;b and Richard Kneller a a University of Nottingham; b The Treasury, New Zealand March

More information

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation Ed Nosal December 2008 Abstract An increase in in ation will cause people to hold less real balances and may cause them to speed up their spending.

More information

Matching Markets and Google s Sponsored Search

Matching Markets and Google s Sponsored Search Matching Markets and Google s Sponsored Search Part III: Dynamics Episode 9 Baochun Li Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering University of Toronto Matching Markets (Required reading: Chapter

More information

1 Two Period Production Economy

1 Two Period Production Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 3 1 Two Period Production Economy We shall now extend our two-period exchange economy model

More information

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not Chapter 11 Information Exercise 11.1 A rm sells a single good to a group of customers. Each customer either buys zero or exactly one unit of the good; the good cannot be divided or resold. However, it

More information

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters Khaled Bennour 2006 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7233/ MPRA Paper No. 7233, posted. September

More information

October An Equilibrium of the First Price Sealed Bid Auction for an Arbitrary Distribution.

October An Equilibrium of the First Price Sealed Bid Auction for an Arbitrary Distribution. October 13..18.4 An Equilibrium of the First Price Sealed Bid Auction for an Arbitrary Distribution. We now assume that the reservation values of the bidders are independently and identically distributed

More information

The European road pricing game: how to enforce optimal pricing in high-transit countries under asymmetric information by

The European road pricing game: how to enforce optimal pricing in high-transit countries under asymmetric information by The European road pricing game: how to enforce optimal pricing in high-transit countries under asymmetric information by Saskia VAN DER LOO Stef PROOST Energy, Transport and Environment Center for Economic

More information

On the virtues of the ascending price auction: New insights in the private value setting

On the virtues of the ascending price auction: New insights in the private value setting On the virtues of the ascending price auction: New insights in the private value setting Olivier Compte y and Philippe Jehiel z First version: September 2000 This version: December 2000 Abstract This paper

More information

D S E Dipartimento Scienze Economiche

D S E Dipartimento Scienze Economiche D S E Dipartimento Scienze Economiche Working Paper Department of Economics Ca Foscari University of Venice Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi Illiquidity and Under-Valutation of Firms ISSN: 1827/336X No. 36/WP/2008

More information

Strategic information acquisition and the. mitigation of global warming

Strategic information acquisition and the. mitigation of global warming Strategic information acquisition and the mitigation of global warming Florian Morath WZB and Free University of Berlin October 15, 2009 Correspondence address: Social Science Research Center Berlin (WZB),

More information

Optimal Acquisition Strategies in Unknown Territories

Optimal Acquisition Strategies in Unknown Territories Optimal Acquisition Strategies in Unknown Territories Onur Koska Department of Economics University of Otago Frank Stähler y Department of Economics University of Würzburg August 9 Abstract This paper

More information

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default 0.287/MSOM.070.099ec Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default Robert Swinney Serguei Netessine The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, 904

More information

Debt vs Foreign Direct Investment: The Impact of International Capital Flows on Investment in Environmentally Sound Technologies

Debt vs Foreign Direct Investment: The Impact of International Capital Flows on Investment in Environmentally Sound Technologies Debt vs Foreign Direct Investment: The Impact of International Capital Flows on Investment in Environmentally Sound Technologies J. O. Anyangah Abstract This paper employs the methods of mechanism design

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy

Optimal Monetary Policy Optimal Monetary Policy Graduate Macro II, Spring 200 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims Here I consider how a welfare-maximizing central bank can and should implement monetary policy in the standard

More information

1 Unemployment Insurance

1 Unemployment Insurance 1 Unemployment Insurance 1.1 Introduction Unemployment Insurance (UI) is a federal program that is adminstered by the states in which taxes are used to pay for bene ts to workers laid o by rms. UI started

More information

Game Theory Lecture #16

Game Theory Lecture #16 Game Theory Lecture #16 Outline: Auctions Mechanism Design Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanism Optimizing Social Welfare Goal: Entice players to select outcome which optimizes social welfare Examples: Traffic

More information

Practice Questions Chapters 9 to 11

Practice Questions Chapters 9 to 11 Practice Questions Chapters 9 to 11 Producer Theory ECON 203 Kevin Hasker These questions are to help you prepare for the exams only. Do not turn them in. Note that not all questions can be completely

More information

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Mechanism Design and Auctions Multiagent Systems (BE4M36MAS) Mechanism Design and Auctions Branislav Bošanský and Michal Pěchouček Artificial Intelligence Center, Department of Computer Science, Faculty of Electrical Engineering, Czech

More information

Price Discrimination As Portfolio Diversification. Abstract

Price Discrimination As Portfolio Diversification. Abstract Price Discrimination As Portfolio Diversification Parikshit Ghosh Indian Statistical Institute Abstract A seller seeking to sell an indivisible object can post (possibly different) prices to each of n

More information

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469 Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469 1 Introduction and Motivation International illiquidity Country s consolidated nancial system has potential short-term

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

Exercise List 2: Market Failure

Exercise List 2: Market Failure Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Microeconomics II ME&MEIM Exercise List 2: Market Failure Exercise 1. A good of two qualities, high (H) and low (L), is traded in competitive markets in which each seller

More information

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing /49 Introduction We present models of asset pricing where investors preferences are subject to psychological biases or where investors

More information

Internal Financing, Managerial Compensation and Multiple Tasks

Internal Financing, Managerial Compensation and Multiple Tasks Internal Financing, Managerial Compensation and Multiple Tasks Working Paper 08-03 SANDRO BRUSCO, FAUSTO PANUNZI April 4, 08 Internal Financing, Managerial Compensation and Multiple Tasks Sandro Brusco

More information

Exercises - Moral hazard

Exercises - Moral hazard Exercises - Moral hazard 1. (from Rasmusen) If a salesman exerts high e ort, he will sell a supercomputer this year with probability 0:9. If he exerts low e ort, he will succeed with probability 0:5. The

More information

Monetary credibility problems. 1. In ation and discretionary monetary policy. 2. Reputational solution to credibility problems

Monetary credibility problems. 1. In ation and discretionary monetary policy. 2. Reputational solution to credibility problems Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 2/4 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Monetary credibility problems 1. In ation and discretionary monetary policy 2. Reputational solution

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version

Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version Andreea Cosnita and Jean-Philippe Tropeano y Abstract We develop a theoretical model to compare the current ex post

More information

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result Arantza Gorostiaga Rubio-Ramírez Juan F. Universidad del País Vasco Duke University and Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Abstract

More information

The MM Theorems in the Presence of Bubbles

The MM Theorems in the Presence of Bubbles The MM Theorems in the Presence of Bubbles Stephen F. LeRoy University of California, Santa Barbara March 15, 2008 Abstract The Miller-Modigliani dividend irrelevance proposition states that changes in

More information

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Ozan Eksi TOBB University of Economics and Technology November 2 Abstract The standard new Keynesian

More information

Experiments on Auctions

Experiments on Auctions Experiments on Auctions Syngjoo Choi Spring, 2010 Experimental Economics (ECON3020) Auction Spring, 2010 1 / 25 Auctions An auction is a process of buying and selling commodities by taking bids and assigning

More information

Rent Shifting, Exclusion and Market-Share Contracts

Rent Shifting, Exclusion and Market-Share Contracts Rent Shifting, Exclusion and Market-Share Contracts Leslie M. Marx y Duke University Greg Sha er z University of Rochester October 2008 Abstract We study rent-shifting in a sequential contracting environment

More information

Dynamic games with incomplete information

Dynamic games with incomplete information Dynamic games with incomplete information Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium (PBE) We have now covered static and dynamic games of complete information and static games of incomplete information. The next step

More information

Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements

Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements Mostafa Beshkar (University of New Hampshire) Eric Bond (Vanderbilt University) July 17, 2010 Prepared for the SITE Conference, July

More information

A New Regulatory Tool

A New Regulatory Tool A New Regulatory Tool William C. Bunting Ph.D. Candidate, Yale University Law and Economics Fellow, NYU School of Law January 8, 2007 Fill in later. Abstract 1 Introduction Shavell (1984) provides a seminal

More information

Fuel-Switching Capability

Fuel-Switching Capability Fuel-Switching Capability Alain Bousquet and Norbert Ladoux y University of Toulouse, IDEI and CEA June 3, 2003 Abstract Taking into account the link between energy demand and equipment choice, leads to

More information

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES. Optimal IPO Design with Informed Trading

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES. Optimal IPO Design with Informed Trading UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES 2007 Optimal IPO Design with Informed Trading Sarah Parlane, University College Dublin Fabrice Rousseau, NUI Maynooth WP07/06 May 2007 UCD SCHOOL OF

More information

Core Deviation Minimizing Auctions

Core Deviation Minimizing Auctions Core Deviation Minimizing Auctions Isa E. Hafalir and Hadi Yektaş April 4, 014 Abstract In a stylized environment with complementary products, we study a class of dominant strategy implementable direct

More information

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D by Eytan Sheshinski* (Contribution to the Baumol Conference Book) March 2005 * Department of Economics, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, ISRAEL.

More information

E cient Minimum Wages

E cient Minimum Wages preliminary, please do not quote. E cient Minimum Wages Sang-Moon Hahm October 4, 204 Abstract Should the government raise minimum wages? Further, should the government consider imposing maximum wages?

More information

Hold-up and the Evolution of Investment and Bargaining Norms

Hold-up and the Evolution of Investment and Bargaining Norms Hold-up and the Evolution of Investment and Bargaining Norms Herbert Dawid Department of Economics University of Bielefeld P.O. Box 100131 Bielefeld 33501, Germany hdawid@wiwi.uni-bielefeld.de W. Bentley

More information

SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS

SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS Question : Answers should recognize that this result does not hold when there are search frictions in the labour market. The proof should follow a simple matching

More information

International Trade

International Trade 14.581 International Trade Class notes on 2/11/2013 1 1 Taxonomy of eoclassical Trade Models In a neoclassical trade model, comparative advantage, i.e. di erences in relative autarky prices, is the rationale

More information

PROPERTY RIGHTS AND THE EFFICIENCY OF BARGAINING

PROPERTY RIGHTS AND THE EFFICIENCY OF BARGAINING PROPERTY RIGHTS AND THE EFFICIENCY OF BARGAINING Ilya Segal Department of Economics, Stanford University Michael D. Whinston Department of Economics and Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute

More information

Econ 277A: Economic Development I. Final Exam (06 May 2012)

Econ 277A: Economic Development I. Final Exam (06 May 2012) Econ 277A: Economic Development I Semester II, 2011-12 Tridip Ray ISI, Delhi Final Exam (06 May 2012) There are 2 questions; you have to answer both of them. You have 3 hours to write this exam. 1. [30

More information

On Indescribable Contingencies and Incomplete. Contracts

On Indescribable Contingencies and Incomplete. Contracts On Indescribable Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts Eric Maskin y Institute for Advanced Study and Princeton University September 2001 This paper is based on a talk given at the European Economic Association

More information

Opting out of publicly provided services: A majority voting result

Opting out of publicly provided services: A majority voting result Soc Choice Welfare (1998) 15: 187±199 Opting out of publicly provided services: A majority voting result Gerhard Glomm 1, B. Ravikumar 2 1 Michigan State University, Department of Economics, Marshall Hall,

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

Energy & Environmental Economics

Energy & Environmental Economics Energy & Environmental Economics Public Goods, Externalities and welfare Università degli Studi di Bergamo a.y. 2015-16 (Institute) Energy & Environmental Economics a.y. 2015-16 1 / 29 Public Goods What

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

Estimating Welfare in Insurance Markets using Variation in Prices

Estimating Welfare in Insurance Markets using Variation in Prices Estimating Welfare in Insurance Markets using Variation in Prices Liran Einav 1 Amy Finkelstein 2 Mark R. Cullen 3 1 Stanford and NBER 2 MIT and NBER 3 Yale School of Medicine November, 2008 inav, Finkelstein,

More information

Subsidization to Induce Tipping

Subsidization to Induce Tipping Subsidization to Induce Tipping Aric P. Shafran and Jason J. Lepore December 2, 2010 Abstract In binary choice games with strategic complementarities and multiple equilibria, we characterize the minimal

More information