1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not"

Transcription

1 Chapter 11 Information Exercise 11.1 A rm sells a single good to a group of customers. Each customer either buys zero or exactly one unit of the good; the good cannot be divided or resold. However, it can be delivered as either a high-quality or a low-quality good. The quality is characterised by a non-negative number q; the cost of producing one unit of good at quality q is C(q) where C is an increasing and strictly convex function. The taste of customer h is h the marginal willingness to pay for quality. Utility for h is U h (q; x) = h q + x where h is a positive taste parameter and x is the quantity consumed of all other goods. 1. If F is the fee required as payment for the good write down the budget constraint for the individual customer. 2. If there are two types of customer show that the single-crossing condition is satis ed and establish the conditions for a full-information solution. 3. Show that the second-best solution must satisfy the no-distortion-at-the-top principle. 4. Derive the second-best optimum. Outline Answer 1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is x + F (q) y where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not buy and buy. 2. Assume that each person s type is common knowledge. (a) If there are two taste types a ; b with The preferences are as shown in Figure a > b (11.1)

2 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION x τ b τ a quality q Figure 11.1: Preferences: quality F Π 2 = F 2 C(q) increasing profit Π 1 = F 1 C(q) Π 0 = F 0 C(q) quality q Figure 11.2: Isopro t curves: quality cfrank Cowell

3 Microeconomics F τ a q F *a τ b q F *b q *b q *a quality q Figure 11.3: Full-information solution: quality (b) Given that each person s type can be observed the rm can tailor the fee schedule exactly to personal characteristics, charging F a to an a-type and F b to an b-type The rm s pro ts from each of the two groups of consumers are F a C (q a ) (11.2) F b C q b (11.3) and the isopro t curves are as shown in Figure (c) If a person chooses not to buy the good then his utility is just y. So the rm chooses q a and F a to maximise (11.2) subject to the a-type s participation constraint a q a F a + y y or, equivalently a q a F a 0; (11.4) it likewise chooses q b and F b to maximise (11.3) subject to the b- type s participation constraint b q b F b 0: (11.5) The full information solution is found at the tangency of an isopro t curve with a reservation indi erence for each of the two types, as shown in gure 11.3 Clearly, at the optimum (q a ; F a ) and q b ; F b, each of the participation constraints (11.4) and (11.5) is binding and each person just gets his reservation utility y. 3. Now it is no longer possible to condition the fee schedule directly on a person s type. cfrank Cowell

4 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION F F *a preference τ a q τ b q F *b q *b q *a quality q Figure 11.4: Type a prefers type b contract (a) If the full-information contracts from part 2 were available an a-type person would want to take a b-type contract since his utility would then be a q b F b +y which, in view of the fact that b q b F b = 0, becomes a b q b + y which is strictly greater than y. See Figure (b) We need to nd the second-best contracts that take account of this incentive-compatibility problem. Incentive compatibility requires that, for a: a q a F a a q b F b (11.6) and, for b: b q b F b b q a F a (11.7) Suppose it is known that there is a proportion, 1 of a-types and b-types, respectively. Now the rm s problem is to choose q a, q b, F a and F b to maximise [F a C (q a )] + [1 ] F b C q b (11.8) subject to the participation constraints (11.4) and (11.5) and the incentive-compatibility constraints (11.6) and (11.7). As in the text we can simplify the problem by determining which constraints are slack and which are binding. Note that: (11.6) and (11.1) imply a q a F a a q b F b b q b F b (11.9) This implies that if constraint (11.5) were slack, then constraint (11.4) would also be slack; this cannot be true at the optimum cfrank Cowell

5 Microeconomics since it would then be possible for the rm to increase both F a and F b and increase pro ts. Hence (11.5) must be binding. Given that F b > 0 at the optimum (11.5) then implies that q b > 0: However (11.1). (11.9) and q b > 0 imply a q a F a a q b F b > b q b F b = 0 (11.10) which implies that a q a F a > 0 (11.11) So constraint (11.4) is slack and can be ignored. If (11.6) were slack then, by (11.11) it would be possible to increase F a without violating the constraint. So (11.6) must be binding. a q a F a = a q b F b (11.12) If (11.7) were binding, then this and (11.12) would imply q b a b = q a a b but, given (11.1).this can only be true if q b = q a : But this implies a pooling outcome and we know that the rm can do better than a pooling outcome by forcing the high-value consumers to reveal themselves. This implies that constraint (11.7) is slack and can be ignored. F preference τ a q F a τ b q F b q b q *a quality q Figure 11.5: Second-best solution: quality (c) The Lagrangean is therefore [F a C (q a )] + [1 ] F b C q b + b q b F b + a q a F a a q b + F b (11.13) cfrank Cowell

6 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION where and are the Lagrange multipliers for the constraints (11.5, 11.6) respectively. The rst-order conditions are C q (q a ) + a = 0 (11.14) [1 ] C q q b + b a = 0 (11.15) = 0 (11.16) 1 + = 0 (11.17) From (11.16) and (11.17) and we have = and = 1. Using these values in (11.14) and (11.15) we have C q (q a ) = a (11.18) C q q b = b a b < b (11.19) 1 Clearly the a-type s consumption is at the point where marginal cost - marginal willingness to pay for quality see Fig cfrank Cowell

7 Microeconomics Exercise 11.2 An employee s type can take the value 1 or 2, where 2 > 1. The bene t of the employee s services to his employer is proportional to z, the amount of education that the employee has received. The cost of obtaining z years of education for an employee of type is given by The employee s utility function is C (z; ) = ze : U(y; z) = e y C (z; ) where y is the payment received from his employer. The risk-neutral employer designs contracts contingent on the observed gross bene t, to maximise his expected pro ts. 1. If the employer knows the employee s type, what contracts will be o ered? If he does not know the employee s type, which type will self-select the wrong contract? 2. Show how to determine the second-best contracts. Which constraints bind? How will the solution to the second-best problem compare with that in part 1? Outline Answer This is a problem of hidden information: The type of the employee is exogenously given, but private information. The problem for the employer is to design a contract that leads the employee to reveal his true type. The employer is interested in truthful revelation since it is less costly for employees of type 2 to attain a given level of education. Hence, the employer would have to reward 2 types by less to get the same level of education. However, type 2 would like to pretend to be of type 1 to receive the higher payment. The reservation utility of the employee corresponds to the case where the employee receives 0 years of education, for which he receives 0 from the employer: = 1: This yields participation constraints for each type: 1 e y ze 0 For further reference, we can deduce the shape of the indi erence curves for a given type. The rst and second derivatives, respectively, are: dy = e y dz i > 0 (11.20) d 2 y dz 2 = e y dy i dz = e2[y i] > 0 See Figure 11.6 for an illustration of the reservation indi erence curves for the two types, which go through the origin. The shaded areas are the acceptance sets for the two types of individuals. Note that as dy dz is independent of z, the indi erence curves for a given type must be horizontally parallel in (z; y) space. Also note that the single crossing property is satis ed. cfrank Cowell

8 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION y υ_υ 1 υ_υ 2 y * 2 y * 1 0 z * 1 z * 2 z Figure 11.6: Full-information contracts 1. If the employer knows the employee s type, then, as before, the employer can implement full-information contracts, maximising the return from each type separately. Let be the type. Then the problem of the employer is to max z;y := z y subject to the participation constraint 1 e y ze 0 (11.21) We can now set up the Lagrangean associated with this maximization problem L (z; y; ) := z y + 1 e y ze where is the Lagrange multiplier for the constraint (11.21). The = 1 e = 0 (11.22) = 1 + e y = 0 (11.23) = 1 e y ze 0 (11.24) Combining equations (11.22) and (11.23), we see that e = e y and hence that y = Those equations also imply that > 0, and hence that the participation constraint (11.24) must bind. Hence cfrank Cowell z = 1 e y e = e 1 > 0

9 Microeconomics Thus the employer o ers two di erent contracts to the two types, where the level of education is zi = e i 1, and the compensation is yi = i. Since the slope of the indi erence curve in Figure 11.6 was given by equation 11.20, we see that the contracts are located where the slope of the reservation indi erence curves are equal to Now assume that the employer cannot observe the type of the employee. (a) Given the contracts found in part 1 an employee of type 2 will selfselect the wrong contract. To see this, compare the utility of type 2 when choosing the type-2 contract 2 = e 2 [e 2 1] e 2 to that when choosing the type-1 contract: 2 = e 1 [e 1 1] e 2 Since 1 < 2 it is clear that 2 > 2. Hence, type 2 would self-select the type 1 contract, and hence incentive compatibility is violated. (b) If there is an incentive for type 2 to self-select the wrong contract, then any second-best contract has to insure that the incentive compatibility constraint for type 2 is not violated. Type 1 will never have an incentive to select the type 2 contract, hence the incentive compatibility constraint for type 1 will not be binding. Furthermore, since any non-trivial contract for type 1 would enable type 2 to achieve a utility level greater than his reservation utility level, the participation constraint for type 2 cannot be binding. However, we can keep type 1 on his reservation utility. Hence, we expect that the two constraints which will be binding in the second-best contract will be the participation constraint for type 1 1 e y1 z 1 e 1 0 (11.25) and the incentive-compatibility constraint for type 2: e y2 z 2 e 2 e y1 z 1 e 2 (11.26) This is as in the standard adverse selection model: (c) Assume that the probability of encountering a type 1 employee is 2 (0; 1). We may now set up the maximization problem for the monopolist, which consists of choosing z 1 ; y 1 ; z 2 ; y 2 to maximise : := [z 1 y 1 ] + [1 ] [z 2 y 2 ] subject to (11.25) and (11.26). The Lagrangean is L (z 1 ; y 1 ; z 2 ; y 2 ; ; ) := [z 1 y 1 ] + [1 ] [z 2 y 2 ] + [1 e y1 z 1 e 1 ] + [e y1 e y2 + z 1 e 2 z 2 e 2 ] cfrank Cowell

10 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION where and are the Lagrange multipliers associated with the constraints (11.25) and (11.26), respectively. Maximising this yields 1 = e 1 + e 2 = 1 = + [ ] e y1 = 2 = [1 ] e 2 = 2 = [1 ] + e y2 = 0 (11.30) As 0 by Kuhn-Tucker conditions, and > 0, equation implies that > 0. Hence, constraint (11.25) will bind. Considering equation 11.29, we see similarly that > 0, so that constraint (11.26) will bind. Since both constraints will bind, and the rst order conditions are satis ed, we have a system with six equations and six variables. Call the solutions to this system (^z 1 ; ^y 1 ) and (^z 2 ; ^y 2 ). (d) Since the incentive-compatibility constraint (11.26) is binding, these two contracts will lie on the same type 2 indi erence curve. But the type-1 incentive compatibility constraint is slack, so type 1 strictly prefers (^z 1 ; ^y 1 ) to (^z 2 ; ^y 2 ). Given the Single Crossing Property and the fact that the type 2 indi erence curves are atter that of type 1, we must have ^z 1 < ^z 2 and ^y 1 < ^y 2. Consider equations and We nd that ^y 2 = 2, the no distortion at the top result. Clearly, the marginal rate of substitution for type 2 at this point is e 2 =e y2 = 1; which is the same as the slope of the isopro t contour. Now compare the second-best contracts with the full-information solution. Type 2 was on his reservation indi erence curve 2 under the full-information contract. But under the second-best, the participation constraint for type 2 is slack, and hence he is now on an indi erence curve I 2 above 2. But since ^y 2 = y 2 = 2 ; this must mean that ^z 2 < z 2. (e) Finally, how far has the solution moved from 2? There are two possibilities: The new (^z 1 ; ^y 1 ) could be below and to the left of the full-information (z1; y1), or above and to the right. We will show that ^z 1 < z1 and ^y 1 < y1 (recall that (11.25) is still binding, so the new solution will be on the reservation indi erence curve for type 1). The slope of the indi erence curve 1 at (^z 1 ; ^y 1 ) is e 1 e ^y1 : From equations (11.27) and (11.28) we have cfrank Cowell e ^y1 = + e ^y1 e 1 = + e 2

11 Microeconomics hence the slope of the indi erence curve is + e 2 < 1 (11.31) ^y1 + e This follows because ^y 1 < ^y 2 = 2 which implies e 2 < e ^y1. We found that the slope of the type 1 indi erence curve at (z1; y1) was 1, so condition (11.31) implies that ^z 1 < z1 and ^y 1 < y1. See gure y υ_υ 1 υ_υ 2 ^y2 ^y1 0 ^z1 ^z2 z Figure 11.7: Second-best contracts cfrank Cowell

12 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION Exercise 11.3 A large risk-neutral rm employs a number of lawyers. For a lawyer of type the required time to produce an amount x of legal services is given by z = x The lawyer may be a high-productivity a-type lawyer or a low-productivity b-type: a > b > 0. Let y be the payment to the lawyer. The lawyer s utility function is z y 1 2 and his reservation level of utility is 0. The lawyer knows his type and the rm cannot observe his action z: The price of legal services is If the rm knows the lawyer s type what contract will it o er? Is it e - cient? 2. Suppose the rm believes that the probability that the lawyer has low productivity is : Assume b [1 ] a : In what way would the rm then modify the set of contracts on o er if it does not know the lawyer s type and cannot observe his action? Outline Answer. The problem is one of adverse selection with hidden information. y υ b _υ b _υ a y *a = 1 slope = 1 y *b = ¼ slope = 1 0 x *b = ½ x x *a = 2 Figure 11.8: Full-information contracts 1. Full-information. (a) The principal knows the type and so maximises x where p y x = 0 y subject to cfrank Cowell

13 Microeconomics for each individual type. We know that the participation constraint binds and that there is no distortion. So = p y Di erentiate to nd the slope of the indi erence curve: dy dx = 2p y = x (11.32) (11.33) Since there is no distortion (11.33) must be equal to 1 which implies y = : (11.34) Using the fact that = and substituting (11.34) into (11.32) we get x = : (11.35) In this case the optimal contracts are (x a ; y a ) and shown in Figure x b ; y b as (b) Since there is no distortion the solution is e cient. There is no change which could make one person better o without making the other worse o. 2. Types unknown. (a) If it is impossible to monitor the lawyer s type it is no longer viable to o er the e cient contracts (x a ; y a ) and x b ; y b from part 1. If a type-a lawyer accepts the e cient contract meant for him he gets utility p y a x a a = 1 2 a 1 2 [ a ] 2 a = 0 But if a type-a lawyer were to get a type-b contract he would get utility p y b x b a = 1 2 b 1 2 b 2 a = 1 2 b 1 So a type a would prefer to take a type-b contract. b a > 0: (b) Given this problem the best that the rm can do is to maximise expected pro ts subject to an incentive-compatibility constraint for the a types: p y a x a a p y b x b a Let be the the probability that the lawyer is of type a. expected pro ts are cfrank Cowell [x a y a ] + [1 ] x b y b Then

14 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION In the problem of maximising expected pro ts under these conditions we know from previous exercises (such as Exercise 11.2) that the participation constraint (11.32) for type b will be binding p y b x b b = b (11.36) as is the incentive-compatibility constraint for type: p y a So the relevant Lagrangean is x a a = p y b x b a : (11.37) L x a ; y a ; x b ; y b ; ; := [x a y a ] + [1 ] x b y b 9 hp i >= + y b x b h py b p i + a x a a yb + >; xb a (11.38) where and are the Lagrange multipliers for the constraints (11.36) and (11.37) respectively. (c) Let the solution values for maximising (11.38) be denoted ^x a, ^y a, ^x b, ^y b. Di erentiating (11.38) the FOC are: From (11.41) and (11.42) we have + 2 p^y a = 0; (11.39) [1 ] + 2 p^y b 2 p^y = 0; (11.40) b a = 0; (11.41) 1 b + a = 0: (11.42) = a = b ; and substituting these values in (11.39) and (11.40) we get [1 ] + b + a 2 p y a = 0 2 p^y b a 2 p^y b = 0 which implies ^y a = 1 4 [ a ] 2 cfrank Cowell ^y b b a = 2 [1 ] 2

15 Microeconomics And so, using the participation constraint (11.32) we have ^x b = bp^y b = b b 2 [1 ] a Finally, from the incentive- which is non-negative by assumption. compatibility constraint we get ^x a = [ a ] 2 2 a b b ^x b : y υ b _υ b _υ a ^ya ^yb 0 ^xb ^xa x Figure 11.9: The second-best solution in the adverse selection problem (d) Note that ^x a < x a ^x b < x b ^y a = y a ^y b < y b see Figure This is the no-distortion-at-the-top result. Note that indi erence curves for a given type are horizontally parallel because utility is linear in x. So ^y a = y a is immediate. cfrank Cowell

16 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION Exercise 11.4 The analysis of insurance in the text (section ) was based on the assumption that the insurance market is competitive. Show how the principles established in section for a monopolist can be applied to the insurance market: 1. In the case where full information about individuals risk types is available. 2. Where individuals risk types are unknown to the monopolist. Outline Answer 1. See Figure x BLUE profits, π b _ y a profits, π b y L κ a 0 _ y a y x RED Figure 11.10: Insurance: iso-pro t (a) The endowment point for both types of individual is at (y; y L). Given that the probability of an accident for high-risk type a is a an insurance rm would break even if it sold insurance against the loss L for a premium a where De ne a = a L: (11.43) y a := y a L = a : (11.44) The line with slope 1 a passing through the endowment point and a the point (y a ; y a ) is an isopro t contour for the rm when dealing with the high-risk types. Pro ts must increase to the South-West (consider the impact on pro ts if the rm were able to charge a higher premium, all other things being equal). cfrank Cowell

17 Microeconomics (b) For the low-risk types the isopro t contours are a family of lines with slope 1 b b. (c) Clearly the reservation indi erence curve for each type of person is given as the contour passing through the endowment point. It has slope 1 h ; h = a; b where it intersects the 45 line see Figure h x BLUE (y a, y a ) (y b, y b ) (y, y L) 0 x RED Figure 11.11: Insurance: monopoly with full information (d) So the full-information outcome is where the high-risk types are located at (y a ; y a ) and the low-risk types at y b ; y b : the monopoly insurance rm rationally o ers better insurance terms to the lowrisk. 2. Take the case where the individual s risk type is unknown to the insurer. (a) Given that there is imperfect information it is clear that a high-risk type would like to masquerade as a low-risk type and so take advantage of the more favourable terms. In Figure see the a-type indi erence curve passing through the point y b ; y b. The monopolist must take account of this possibility in setting up the second-best optimisation problem. (b) The solution to this problem will be of the following form: restrict the low-risk b-types in the amount of insurance that they can purchase so that they choose the prospect ~ P which lies on the b-type reservation indi erence curve in Figure 11.12; o er full insurance at point (~y a ; ~y a ) cfrank Cowell

18 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION x BLUE (y b, y b ) P ~ b ~ ~ (y a, y a ) (y, y L) 0 x RED Figure 11.12: Insurance: monopoly second-best solution only the a-types will wish to take up this o er. The formal analysis closely follows that of section cfrank Cowell

19 Microeconomics Exercise 11.5 Good second-hand cars are worth a 1 to the buyer and a 0 to the seller where a 1 > a 0. Bad cars are worth b 1 to the buyer and b 0 to the seller where b 1 > b 0. It is common knowledge that the proportion of bad cars is. There is a xed stock of cars and e ectively an in nite number of potential buyers 1. If there were perfect information about quality, why would cars be traded in equilibrium? What would be p a and p b, the equilibrium prices of good cars and of bad cars respectively? 2. If neither buyers nor sellers have any information about the quality of an individual car what is p, the equilibrium price of cars? 3. If the seller is perfectly informed about quality and the buyer is uninformed show that good cars are only sold in the market if the equilibrium price is above a Show that in the asymmetric-information situation in part 3 there are only two possible equilibria The case where p b < a 0: equilibrium price is p b. The case where p a 0: equilibrium price is p. Outline Answer. 1. If there is perfect information about quality then: (a) Cars of whatever quality will always be traded if the value of the buyer is greater than that to the seller, as in the question. (b) Equilibrium prices are p a = a 1 p b = b 1 2. Given that neither party can verify the quality of a car ex ante, but both know that the probability of a bad car is : (a) The expected value of a car to the buyer is and the expected value of a car to the seller is [1 ] a 1 + b 1 (11.45) [1 ] a 0 + b 0 (11.46) (b) Given that (11.45) is greater than (11.46) the equilibrium price is p = [1 ] a 1 + b 1 (11.47) 3. Sellers will only be willing to supply good cars to the market if the price is at least as great as their private valuation a 0. cfrank Cowell

20 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION 4. Consider two cases. If the price is less than a 0 then, from part 3, the sellers will only supply bad cars and the buyers will be well aware of this. The fact that, after purchase, the quality is revealed as bad con rms the buyers beliefs. Hence we have an equilibrium with price set at the buyers valuation of bad cars: p = b 1 If the price is not less than a 0 then both types of car may be supplied to the market. Once again the buyers will be aware of this and, in the absence of further information will estimate the value as given by (11.45). We have an equilibrium with price p = p where p is given by (11.47) if this price is at least as high as the sellers valuation of good cars [1 ] a 1 + b 1 a 0: (11.48) cfrank Cowell

21 Microeconomics Exercise 11.6 In an economy there are two types of worker: type-a workers have productivity 2 and type-b workers have productivity 1. Workers productivities are unobservable by rms but workers can spend their own resources to acquire educational certi cates in order to signal their productivity. It is common knowledge that the cost of acquiring an education level z equals z for type-b workers and 1 2z for type-a workers. 1. Find the least-cost separating equilibrium. 2. Suppose the proportion of type-b workers is. For what values of will the no-signalling outcome dominate any separating equilibrium? 3. Suppose = 1 4. What values of z are consistent with a pooling equilibrium? Outline Answer 1. There is some z such that rms believe a worker to be of type a if z z and type b otherwise. Beliefs are self-con rming if type-a workers choose z = z and type-b workers choose z = 0. This is satis ed if in other words z z 1 z 2: Any z in [1; 2] does the job so that there is a continuum of separating equilibria. z = 1 is the least-cost separating equilibrium. The net payo to an a-type in the least-cost separating equilibrium is z = Given the de nition of the expected productivity of a randomly chosen worker is + 2 [1 ] = 2 : This would give a better payo to a-types in the separating equilibrium if so that < > If z is education in the pooling equilibrium then the net payo to a-type workers is z = z and for b-type workers is 2 z = z The b-type workers are better o in the pooling equilibrium if z > 1 cfrank Cowell z < 3 4

22 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION The a-type workers are better o in the pooling equilibrium if z > 11 2 z < 1 2 cfrank Cowell

23 Microeconomics Exercise 11.7 A worker s productivity is given by an ability parameter > 0. Firms pay workers on the basis of how much education, z, they have: the wage o ered to a person with education z is w (z) and the cost to the worker of acquiring an amount of education z is ze. 1. Find the rst-order condition for a type person and show that it must satisfy dw (z ) = log (11.49) dz 2. If people come to the labour market having the productivity that the employers expect on the basis of their education show that the optimal wage schedule must satisfy w (z) = log (z + k) (11.50) where k is a constant. 3. Compare incomes net of educational cost with incomes that would prevail if it were possible to observe directly. Outline Answer 1. Individual income, net of educational costs is w (z) ze : Maximising this with respect to z gives the FOC w z (z ) e = 0 from which (11.49) immediately follows. 2. If the employer s expectations are ful lled then the revealed marginal product equals the wage paid w (z). Using this result in (11.49) we obtain dw (z) log = w (z) (11.51) dz which is a rst-order di erential equation in z. Rearranging we have Integrating over z we get w(z) dw (z) e = 1 (11.52) dz e w(z) = z + k (11.53) where k is a constant of integration. From this (11.50) follows. 3. In this model the costs of education ze are a net loss to the workers who would have been paid according to their type anyway, if only could have been observed. cfrank Cowell

24 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION Exercise 11.8 The manager of a rm can exert a high e ort level z = 2 or a low e ort level z = 1. The gross pro t of the rm is either 1 = 16 or 2 = 2. The manager s choice a ects the probability of a particular pro t outcome occurring. If he chooses z, then 1 occurs with probability = 3 4, but if he chooses z then that probability is only = 1 4. The risk neutral owner designs contracts which specify a payment y i to the manager contingent on gross pro t i. The utility function of the manager is u(y; z) = y 1=2 z, and his reservation utility = Solve for the full-information contract. 2. Con rm that the owner would like to induce the manager to take action z. 3. Solve for the second-best contracts in the event that the owner cannot observe the manager s action. 4. Comment on the implications for risk sharing. Outline Answer. 1. Under the full-information contract, both manager and owner can observe the action of the manager. So we can solve the optimization problem for the owner for both high and low e ort levels separately, and then let the owner choose the one that yields higher expected pro ts. (a) Formally, denoting the expected pro t to the owner under high and low e ort levels by the manager as and respectively, we have the following pair of optimisation problems for the owner: subject to in the high-e ort case and subject to max = [ 1 y 1 ] + [1 ] [ 2 y 2 ] (11.54) y 1;y 2 u (y 1 ; z) + [1 ] u (y 2 ; z) 0 (11.55) max y 1;y 2 = i [ 1 y 1 ] + [1 ] [ 2 y 2 ] (11.56) u (y 1 ; z) + [1 ] u (y 2 ; z) 0 (11.57) in the low-e ort case, where (11.55) and (11.57) are the participation constraints that will be binding at the optimum. (b) Since the owner can observe the manager s action, and since the manager is risk-averse, the owner will set y 1 = y 2 = y in the solution to (11.54, 11.55) and we can solve for y simply by setting which implies u (y; z) = 0 y 1=2 z = 0 Likewise in the solution to (11.56,11.57) we can solve for y from the equation y 1=2 z = 0 cfrank Cowell

25 Microeconomics (c) Using the numerical values given in the question, we obtain y = 4 y = 1 2. From part 1 the optimal payments in the case of high and low e ort yield expected pro ts to the owner of = 8:5 = 4:5 Thus, the owner would indeed like to induce the manager to take action z. By construction, the manager is indi erent between taking z or z, since he receives his reservation utility in either case. 3. However, if the manager could convince the owner that he was using z, and get the owner to pay him y, while in fact only using z, his payo would be u(y; z) = y 1=2 z = 1 > 0 and hence the incentive-compatibility constraint would be violated. Thus, we now consider the second-best contract, where the owner cannot observe the action of the manager, but can induce him to take the right e ort level. (a) Under the second-best contract, the owner has the choice of inducing the manager to choose either high or low e ort levels. Since there is no incentive compatibility problem with the low e ort level, the full-information solution continues to hold. The interesting case is inducing the manager to take the high e ort level with a second-best contract. (b) Under the second-best contract, the participation constraint continues to hold. In addition, however, we have an incentive compatibility constraint that guarantees that the manager would choose z over z, given the contract. Thus, the owner has to solve the problem max = [ 1 y 1 ] + [1 ] [ 2 y 2 ] y 1;y 2 subject to the participation constraint y [1 ] y z 0 which becomes 3y y (11.58) and the incentive-compatibility constraint y [1 ] y z y [1 ] y z which becomes y y (11.59) cfrank Cowell

26 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION (c) We may set up the appropriate Lagrangean as: L(y 1 ; y 2 ; ; ) = 3 4 [16 y 1]+ 1 h i h i 4 [2 y 2]+ 3y y y y where and are the Lagrange multipliers on constraints (11.58) and (11.59) respectively. Using the Kuhn-Tucker conditions the FOC for a maximum we = y y = 0 if y 1 > 0 = y 1 = h 3y y y = 0 if y 2 > 0 (11.61) i = = h y y From (11.60) and (11.61) we have i (11.63) [6 + 2] y = 3 (11.64) 2 [ ] y = 1 (11.65) We need to determine whether the constraints will be binding. Consider = 0. By equations (11.64) and (11.65), this implies that y = y = 1 2 and hence that y 1 = y 2. But this would violates the incentivecompatibility constraint, as before. Thus, > 0, and, by (11.62) the incentive-compatibility constraint (11.59) must bind. But equation (11.65) implies that >, and hence (11.58) must bind as well. We can now solve for y 1 and y 2 using the participation and incentive-compatibility constraints, and obtain that y 1 = 25 4 y 2 = 1 4 It can be shown that the expected pro ts associated with this contract are higher than those under a rst best contract with low e ort level, but lower than those under rst best contract with high e ort level. 4. We observe that y 1 > y > y 2. The manager receives more than under rst best in the good outcome, but less in the bad outcome. While it was rational for the owner to bear all the risk under rst best, given that he was risk-neutral while the manager was risk-averse, under the second-best contract the risk is shared between the owner and manager. This induces the manager to take the action which yields a higher probability of a good outcome. cfrank Cowell

27 Microeconomics Exercise 11.9 The manager of a rm can exert an e ort level z = 4 3 or z = 1 and gross pro ts are either 1 = 3z 2 or 2 = 3z. The outcome 1 occurs with probability = 2 3 if action z is taken, and with probability = 1 3 otherwise. The manager s utility function is u(y; z) = log y z, and his reservation utility is = 0. The risk neutral owner designs contracts which specify a payment y i to the manager, contingent on obtaining gross pro ts i. 1. Solve for the full-information contracts. Which action does the owner wish the manager to take? 2. Solve for the second-best contracts. What is the agency cost of the asymmetric information? 3. In part 1, the manager s action can be observed. Are the full-information contracts equivalent to contracts which specify payments contingent on effort? Outline Answer 1. The structure of the problem is identical to that of Exercise 11.8 so we may follow the same logic. (a) Since the owner can observe the manager s action, and since the manager is risk-averse, the owner will set y 1 = y 2 = y in the solution to the counterpart to (11.54, 11.55) and we can solve for y by setting In the present case, this implies u (y; z) = 0: log y z = 0 Likewise we can solve for y from the equation log y z = 0 Substituting in the speci c values given in the questions, we immediately obtain that the full-information contract puts y = e 4=3 (11.66) and y = e: (11.67) (b) To ascertain which action the owner would like the manager to take, compare expected pro ts under the two actions: 2 = e 4=3 (11.68) and = e : (11.69) cfrank Cowell

28 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION Clearly = 1 3 [ 1 2 ] h e 4=3 i e which is positive. Hence, the owner would like the manager to take z. 2. To solve for the second-best contract, we again use the structure developed in the Exercise (a) The goal is to nd a contract that induces the manager to take the high e ort level. From the Exercise 11.8, we know that both the participation and incentive-compatibility constraints will be binding. Hence, denoting v(y) = log(y), we have the participation constraint: log (y 1 ) + [1 ] log (y 2 ) z = 0 (11.70) and the incentive-compatibility constraint: log (y 1 ) + [1 ] log (y 2 ) z = log (y 1 ) + [1 ] log (y 2 ) z (11.71) Rearranging equations (11.70) and (11.71), we nd log (y 1 ) log (y 2 ) = z z (11.72) Substituting in the values given in the question, the right-hand side of (11.72) is 1 and so we have Hence, using (11.70) we have log (y 1 ) = 1 + log (y 2 ) (11.73) [1 + log (y 2 )] + [1 ] log (y 2 ) z = 0 Substituting in the values given in the question we have Using this value in (11.73) we get y 2 = e 2 3 (11.74) y 1 = e 5 3 (11.75) [ 1 y1] + [1 ] [ 2 y2)] 2 h i 3z 2 e h i 3z e (b) The agency cost of asymmetric information is given by the di erence of pro ts under a full information contract, given by (11.68) and those under a second-best contract. So the agency cost is [ 1 y] + [1 ] [ 2 y] {z } [under full information] > 0 [ 1 y 1] + [1 ] [ 2 y 2] {z } [under second-best] cfrank Cowell

29 Microeconomics which becomes [y 1 y] + [1 ] [y 2 y] substituting in from (11.66),(11.67), (11.74) and (11.75) we get 2 h i e 5 3 e h i e 2 3 e 4 3 = e e 2 3 e 4 3 which is positive. Hence, the agency cost of asymmetric information is greater than zero, as expected. The owner incurs an agency cost, which arises from delegating the decision making to the manager and not observing the manager s e ort level. 3. Full-information contracts are equivalent to contracts which specify payments contingent on e ort, since in both kinds of contracts, the owner can induce the manager to implement the high e ort level, and expected gross pro ts are the same. However, the high-e ort manager extracts a positive rent, so we do not have equivalence in payo structure. cfrank Cowell

30 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION Exercise A risk-neutral rm can undertake one of two investment projects each requiring an investment of z. The outcome of project i is x i with probability i and 0 otherwise, where 1 x 1 > 2 x 2 > z x 2 > x 1 > 0 1 > 2 > 0: The project requires credit from a monopolistic, risk-neutral bank. limited liability, so that the bank gets nothing if the project fails. There is 1. If the bank stipulates repayment y from any successful project what is the expected payo to the rm and to the bank if the rm selects project i? 2. What would be the outcome if there were perfect information? 3. Now assume that the bank cannot monitor which project the rm chooses. Show that the rm will choose project 1 if y y where y := 1x 1 2 x Plot the graph of the bank s expected pro ts against y. Show that the bank will set y = y if 1 y > 2 x 2 and y = x 2 otherwise. 5. Suppose there are N such rms and that the bank has a xed amount M available to fund credit to the rms where z < M < Nz Show that if 1 y > 2 x 2 there will be credit rationing but no credit rationing otherwise. Outline Answer. 1. The expected payo to the rm if project i is selected is given by i [x i y] (11.76) The expected pro t for the bank is i y z 2. If there were perfect information then the bank can observe which project is carried out and whether or not it succeeds. Only project 1 (with the higher probability of success) will be funded and carried out and the bank will require a repayment y = x 1. The rm is e ectively forced on to its reservation indi erence curve so that no rm gets less in the absence of credit than with credit; there is no credit rationing. cfrank Cowell

31 Microeconomics Π Π (y) 0 y x 2 y π 1 π 2 Figure 11.13: Credit rationing 3. The rm will choose the project that gives the greatest pro ts so that, given z, project 1 is chosen if and only if: 1 [x 1 y] 2 [x 2 y] which is equivalent to the condition y y where y := 1x 1 2 x The bank s pro ts are given by 8 < 1 y z if y y (y) := : 2 y z if y < y x 2 see Figure There are clearly two local maxima for and the bank would set y = y if 1 y > 2 x 2 (11.77) and set y = x 2 if 1 < 2 x 2 : (11.78) 5. Distinguish between the situations at the two local maxima Take the case (11.78). From (11.76) the rm s expected payo from the loan is 2 [x 2 x 2 ] = 0: So rms are indi erent between There is no credit rationing. taking and not taking the loan. cfrank Cowell

32 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION Take the case (11.77). From (11.76) the rm s expected payo from the loan is 1 [x 1 y] > 0: All rms would wish to apply for the loan, so that the total demand is Nz. However, the amount available is M so that there is credit rationing. cfrank Cowell

33 Microeconomics Exercise The tax authority employs an inspector to audit tax returns. The dollar amount of tax evasion revealed by the audit is x 2 fx 1 ; x 2 g. It depends on the inspector s e ort level z and the random complexity of the tax return. The probability that x = x i conditional on e ort z is i (z) > 0 i = 1; 2. The tax authority o ers the inspector a wage rate w i = w(x), contingent on the result achieved and obtains the bene t B (x w). The inspector s utility function is U(w; z) = u(w) v(z) and his reservation level of utility is. Assume B 0 () > 0; B 00 () 0; u 0 () > 0; u 00 () 0; v 0 () > 0; v 00 () 0: where primes denote derivatives. speci ed. Information is symmetric unless otherwise 1. For each possible e ort level nd the rst-order conditions characterising the optimal contract w i i = 1; :::; n. 2. What is the form of the optimal contract when the tax-authority is riskneutral and the inspector is risk-averse? Comment on your solution and illustrate it in a box diagram. 3. How does this optimal contract change if the inspector is risk-neutral and the tax-authority is risk-averse? Characterise the e ort level that the tax authority will induce. State clearly any additional assumptions you wish to make. 4. As in part 2 assume that the tax authority is risk-neutral and the tax inspector is risk-averse. E ort can only take two possible values z or z with z > z. The e ort level is no longer veri able. Because the agency cost of enforcing z is too high the tax authority is content to induce z. What is the optimal contract? Outline Answer. 1. The problem is max 2X i (z)b(x i w i ) i=1 over z and w i such that X i (z)u(w i ) v(z) : First x z, write down the Lagrangian, and di erentiate with respect to w i to obtain i (z)b 0 (x i w i ) + i (z)u 0 (w i ) = 0 so 8i : = B0 (x i w i ) u 0 (w i ) so that the participation constraint binds. cfrank Cowell > 0

34 Microeconomics CHAPTER 11. INFORMATION x 2 x 1 w 1 Authority w 2 x 2 w 2 υ Inspector 45 o w 1 x 1 Figure 11.14: Inspector-authority equilibrium 2. Risk neutrality implies that B 0 () is constant and so u 0 (w i ) is constant. As u 00 () 6= 0 this implies w(x 1 ) = w(x 2 ) = w, say. The tax authority bears all the risk see Figure Therefore X i (z)u(w) v(z) = w = u 1 ( + v(z)) Of course the wage rate does depend on the e ort demanded. 3. In this case we have so B 0 (x i which implies u 0 () = constant w i ) is constant 8i. Therefore x i w i = constant > 0 w(x i ) = x i This is a franchise contract where the inspector keeps the result x i but pays a xed amount k for the privilege independent of the results. The participation constraint implies Thus k(z) = X i (z)x i v(z) X i (z)b(x i w i ) = B(k(z)) X i (z) cfrank Cowell k = B(k(z))

35 Microeconomics x 2 x 1 w 1 Authority w 2 x 2 w 2 45 o υ Inspector w 1 x 1 Figure 11.15: Inspector is risk-neutral As B 0 () > 0 the tax authority seeks to induce an e ort level which maximises k. This implies that it chooses z to maximise X i (z)x i v(z) so i X 0 i(z)x i v 0 (z) = 0 i which has the interpretation expected marginal payo = marginal cost. The second-order condition is X 00 i (z)x i v 00 (z) 0 and so a su cient condition is X 00 i (z)x i 0 i Note that this is trivially satis ed if z is discrete. See O er w L = u 1 ( +v(z L )) irrespective of x i :This guarantees the inspector his reservation level of utility. As u(w L ) v(z L ) u(w L ) v(z H ) the incentive compatibility constraint is satis ed. hazard problem here. There is no moral cfrank Cowell

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus Summer 2009 examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2008/2009 syllabus Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours. This paper contains nine questions in three sections. Answer question one

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1 Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose,

More information

Econ 277A: Economic Development I. Final Exam (06 May 2012)

Econ 277A: Economic Development I. Final Exam (06 May 2012) Econ 277A: Economic Development I Semester II, 2011-12 Tridip Ray ISI, Delhi Final Exam (06 May 2012) There are 2 questions; you have to answer both of them. You have 3 hours to write this exam. 1. [30

More information

Simple e ciency-wage model

Simple e ciency-wage model 18 Unemployment Why do we have involuntary unemployment? Why are wages higher than in the competitive market clearing level? Why is it so hard do adjust (nominal) wages down? Three answers: E ciency wages:

More information

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam Dirk Bergemann Department of Economics Yale University Microeconomic Theory (50b) Comprehensive Exam. (5) Consider a moral hazard model where a worker chooses an e ort level e [0; ]; and as a result, either

More information

Dynamic games with incomplete information

Dynamic games with incomplete information Dynamic games with incomplete information Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium (PBE) We have now covered static and dynamic games of complete information and static games of incomplete information. The next step

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY Summer 2011 Examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours + 10 minutes reading time. This paper contains seven questions in three

More information

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS 5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS We studied how individual consumers and rms behave in Part I of the book. In Part II of the book, we studied how individual economic agents make decisions when there are strategic

More information

1 Consumer Choice. 2 Consumer Preferences. 2.1 Properties of Consumer Preferences. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text.

1 Consumer Choice. 2 Consumer Preferences. 2.1 Properties of Consumer Preferences. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text. 1 Consumer Choice In this chapter we will build a model of consumer choice and discuss the conditions that need to be met for a consumer to

More information

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin 4.454 - Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin Juan Pablo Xandri Antuna 4/22/20 Setup Continuum of consumers, mass of individuals each endowed with one unit of currency. t = 0; ; 2

More information

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the form Economic Growth and Development : Exam Consider the model by Barro (990). The production function takes the Y t = AK t ( t L t ) where 0 < < where K t is the aggregate stock of capital, L t the labour

More information

Exercises - Moral hazard

Exercises - Moral hazard Exercises - Moral hazard 1. (from Rasmusen) If a salesman exerts high e ort, he will sell a supercomputer this year with probability 0:9. If he exerts low e ort, he will succeed with probability 0:5. The

More information

Prerequisites. Almost essential Risk MORAL HAZARD. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. April 2018 Frank Cowell: Moral Hazard 1

Prerequisites. Almost essential Risk MORAL HAZARD. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. April 2018 Frank Cowell: Moral Hazard 1 Prerequisites Almost essential Risk MORAL HAZARD MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell April 2018 Frank Cowell: Moral Hazard 1 The moral hazard problem A key aspect of hidden information

More information

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469 Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469 1 Introduction and Motivation International illiquidity Country s consolidated nancial system has potential short-term

More information

The role of asymmetric information

The role of asymmetric information LECTURE NOTES ON CREDIT MARKETS The role of asymmetric information Eliana La Ferrara - 2007 Credit markets are typically a ected by asymmetric information problems i.e. one party is more informed than

More information

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences Problem Set Answer Key I. Short Problems. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences u (q ; q ) = q = + q = u (q ; q ) = q + q u (q ; q ) = ln q + ln q All three

More information

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 805 Extra Problems on Production and Uncertainty: Questions and Answers Winter 003 Prof. Peck () In the following economy, there are two consumers,

More information

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010 Answer Key Problem Set 1 Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010 Please give your answers to your class teacher by Friday of week 6 LT. If you not to hand in at your class, make

More information

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly EconS 50 - Micro Theory I Recitation #9 - Monopoly Exercise A monopolist faces a market demand curve given by: Q = 70 p. (a) If the monopolist can produce at constant average and marginal costs of AC =

More information

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 1 Imperfect Credibility of Policy: Trade Reform 1.1 Model Assumptions Output is exogenous constant endowment (y), not useful for consumption, but can be exported

More information

Problems in Rural Credit Markets

Problems in Rural Credit Markets Problems in Rural Credit Markets Econ 435/835 Fall 2012 Econ 435/835 () Credit Problems Fall 2012 1 / 22 Basic Problems Low quantity of domestic savings major constraint on investment, especially in manufacturing

More information

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D by Eytan Sheshinski* (Contribution to the Baumol Conference Book) March 2005 * Department of Economics, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, ISRAEL.

More information

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from: Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ On the Implementation of Markov-Perfect Monetary Policy Michael Dotsey y and Andreas Hornstein

More information

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Microeconomics, IB and IBP Microeconomics, IB and IBP ORDINARY EXAM, December 007 Open book, 4 hours Question 1 Suppose the supply of low-skilled labour is given by w = LS 10 where L S is the quantity of low-skilled labour (in million

More information

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Some Notes on Timing in Games Some Notes on Timing in Games John Morgan University of California, Berkeley The Main Result If given the chance, it is better to move rst than to move at the same time as others; that is IGOUGO > WEGO

More information

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk Chapter 23: Choice under Risk 23.1: Introduction We consider in this chapter optimal behaviour in conditions of risk. By this we mean that, when the individual takes a decision, he or she does not know

More information

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017 Problem Set Theory of Banking - Academic Year 06-7 Maria Bachelet maria.jua.bachelet@gmai.com March, 07 Exercise Consider an agency relationship in which the principal contracts the agent, whose effort

More information

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage 1 Introduction Central questions: What determines the pattern of trade? Who trades what with whom and at what prices? The pattern of trade is based on comparative

More information

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing BEE14 { Basic Mathematics for Economists BEE15 { Introduction to Mathematical Economics Week 1, Lecture 1, Notes: Optimization II 3/12/21 Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter

More information

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. 1 Oligopoly The key feature of the oligopoly (and to some extent, the monopolistically competitive market) market structure is that one rm

More information

Credit Market Problems in Developing Countries

Credit Market Problems in Developing Countries Credit Market Problems in Developing Countries November 2007 () Credit Market Problems November 2007 1 / 25 Basic Problems (circa 1950): Low quantity of domestic savings major constraint on investment,

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Pareto optimality in microeconomics Harald Wiese University of Leipzig Harald Wiese (University of Leipzig) Advanced Microeconomics 1 / 33 Part D. Bargaining theory and Pareto optimality

More information

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default 0.287/MSOM.070.099ec Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default Robert Swinney Serguei Netessine The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, 904

More information

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Sta Report November 2009 Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University WORKING PAPER NO. 11-4 OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University Daniel R. Sanches Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia December 2010 Optimal

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 and 2 in the first Blue Book and Problems 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A

More information

II. Competitive Trade Using Money

II. Competitive Trade Using Money II. Competitive Trade Using Money Neil Wallace June 9, 2008 1 Introduction Here we introduce our rst serious model of money. We now assume that there is no record keeping. As discussed earler, the role

More information

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market. 1 Supply and Demand Consider the following supply and demand functions for Ramen noodles. The variables are de ned in the table below. Constant values are given for the last 2 variables. Variable Meaning

More information

Revision Lecture. MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Revision Lecture. MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I Revision Lecture Topics in Banking and Market Microstructure MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I April 2006 PREPARING FOR THE EXAM ² What do you need to know? All the

More information

Credit Market Problems in Developing Countries

Credit Market Problems in Developing Countries Credit Market Problems in Developing Countries September 2007 () Credit Market Problems September 2007 1 / 17 Should Governments Intervene in Credit Markets Moneylenders historically viewed as exploitive:

More information

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome.

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome. Moral Hazard Example Well, then says I, what s the use you learning to do right when it s troublesome to do right and ain t no trouble to do wrong, and the wages is just the same? I was stuck. I couldn

More information

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking (preliminary draft) Ying Syuan Li National Taiwan University Yiting Li National Taiwan University April 2009 Abstract We consider an economy where people have the needs

More information

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information November 25, 2013 1 Single-Agent Problems 1. Nonlinear Pricing with Two Types Suppose a seller of wine faces two types of customers, θ 1 and θ 2, where θ 2 >

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters Khaled Bennour 2006 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7233/ MPRA Paper No. 7233, posted. September

More information

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing Consumption-Savings, State Pricing 1/ 40 Introduction We now consider a consumption-savings decision along with the previous portfolio choice decision. These

More information

A New Regulatory Tool

A New Regulatory Tool A New Regulatory Tool William C. Bunting Ph.D. Candidate, Yale University Law and Economics Fellow, NYU School of Law January 8, 2007 Fill in later. Abstract 1 Introduction Shavell (1984) provides a seminal

More information

Problem Set (1 p) (1) 1 (100)

Problem Set (1 p) (1) 1 (100) University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 0) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Problem Set Risk Aversion Suppose your preferences are given by u(c) = c ; > 0 Suppose you face the

More information

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium? Money in OLG Models 1 Econ602, Spring 2005 Prof. Lutz Hendricks, January 26, 2005 What this Chapter Is About We study the value of money in OLG models. We develop an important model of money (with applications

More information

UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory (SPRING 2016) Instructions: You have 4 hours for the exam Answer any 5 out of the 6 questions. All questions are weighted equally.

More information

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid May Microeconomics Grade

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid May Microeconomics Grade Universidad Carlos III de Madrid May 015 Microeconomics Name: Group: 1 3 4 5 Grade You have hours and 45 minutes to answer all the questions. The maximum grade for each question is in parentheses. You

More information

Introduction to Economics I: Consumer Theory

Introduction to Economics I: Consumer Theory Introduction to Economics I: Consumer Theory Leslie Reinhorn Durham University Business School October 2014 What is Economics? Typical De nitions: "Economics is the social science that deals with the production,

More information

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. You have 3 hours to answer the questions in the final exam. We will collect the exams at 2.30 sharp. Show your work, and good luck! Problem 1. Utility Maximization.

More information

Practice Problems. w U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Practice Problems. w U(w, e) = p w e 2, Practice Problems nformation Economics (Ec 55) George Georgiadis Problem. Static Moral Hazard Consider an agency relationship in which the principal contracts with the agent. The monetary result of the

More information

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization 12 December 2006. 0.1 (p. 26), 0.2 (p. 41), 1.2 (p. 67) and 1.3 (p.68) 0.1** (p. 26) In the text, it is assumed

More information

Microeconomics I - Midterm

Microeconomics I - Midterm Microeconomics I - Midterm Undergraduate Degree in Business Administration and Economics April 11, 2013-2 hours Catarina Reis Marta Francisco, Francisca Rebelo, João Sousa Please answer each group in a

More information

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets EconS 50 - Micro Theory I Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets Exercise. Exercise.5, NS: Suppose that the demand for stilts is given by Q = ; 500 50P and that the long-run total operating costs of each

More information

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Economic Theory 14, 247±253 (1999) Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Christopher M. Snyder Department of Economics, George Washington University, 2201 G Street

More information

Economics 326: Pro t Maximization and Production. Ethan Kaplan

Economics 326: Pro t Maximization and Production. Ethan Kaplan Economics 326: Pro t Maximization and Production Ethan Kaplan October 15, 2012 Outline 1. Pro t Maximization 2. Production 1 Pro t Maximiztion What is pro t maximization? Firms decide how many inputs to

More information

Reference Dependence Lecture 3

Reference Dependence Lecture 3 Reference Dependence Lecture 3 Mark Dean Princeton University - Behavioral Economics The Story So Far De ned reference dependent behavior and given examples Change in risk attitudes Endowment e ect Status

More information

1 Two Period Production Economy

1 Two Period Production Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 3 1 Two Period Production Economy We shall now extend our two-period exchange economy model

More information

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion Expected Utility and Risk Aversion Expected utility and risk aversion 1/ 58 Introduction Expected utility is the standard framework for modeling investor choices. The following topics will be covered:

More information

Mean-Variance Analysis

Mean-Variance Analysis Mean-Variance Analysis Mean-variance analysis 1/ 51 Introduction How does one optimally choose among multiple risky assets? Due to diversi cation, which depends on assets return covariances, the attractiveness

More information

Moral Hazard, Collusion and Group Lending. Jean-Jacques La ont 1. and. Patrick Rey 2

Moral Hazard, Collusion and Group Lending. Jean-Jacques La ont 1. and. Patrick Rey 2 Moral Hazard, Collusion and Group Lending Jean-Jacques La ont 1 and Patrick Rey 2 December 23, 2003 Abstract While group lending has attracted a lot of attention, the impact of collusion on the performance

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice 1. MWG - Decisive Subgroups Recall proposition 21.C.1: (Arrow s Impossibility Theorem) Suppose that the number of alternatives is at least

More information

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns 1/ 38 Introduction We analyze the Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model (ICAPM) of Robert Merton (1973). The standard single-period CAPM holds when

More information

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 26/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case

More information

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010 Models of Wage-setting.. Huw Dixon 200 Cardi January 5, 200 Models of Wage-setting. Importance of Unions in wage-bargaining: more important in EU than US. Several Models. In a unionised labour market,

More information

Monetary Economics. Chapter 5: Properties of Money. Prof. Aleksander Berentsen. University of Basel

Monetary Economics. Chapter 5: Properties of Money. Prof. Aleksander Berentsen. University of Basel Monetary Economics Chapter 5: Properties of Money Prof. Aleksander Berentsen University of Basel Ed Nosal and Guillaume Rocheteau Money, Payments, and Liquidity - Chapter 5 1 / 40 Structure of this chapter

More information

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard December 5, 2012 Question 1 (Comparative Performance Evaluation) Consider the same normal linear model as in Question 1 of Homework 1. This time the principal employs

More information

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade. Product Di erentiation Introduction We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade. Now we see how product di erentiation can provide a basis for trade due to consumers valuing

More information

Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments

Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments 1 Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments David C. Mills, Jr. 1 Federal Reserve Board Washington, DC E-mail: david.c.mills@frb.gov Version: May 004 I explore

More information

Professor Rachel Kranton University of Maryland Econ 413 Fall Adverse Selection in Insurance Answers to Problems

Professor Rachel Kranton University of Maryland Econ 413 Fall Adverse Selection in Insurance Answers to Problems Professor Rachel Kranton University of Maryland Econ 413 Fall 2000 Adverse Selection in Insurance Answers to Problems 1. When the insurance industry is monopolized by a single rm, it will o er each type

More information

Firm s Problem. Simon Board. This Version: September 20, 2009 First Version: December, 2009.

Firm s Problem. Simon Board. This Version: September 20, 2009 First Version: December, 2009. Firm s Problem This Version: September 20, 2009 First Version: December, 2009. In these notes we address the firm s problem. questions. We can break the firm s problem into three 1. Which combinations

More information

Subsidy Design and Asymmetric Information: Wealth versus Bene ts

Subsidy Design and Asymmetric Information: Wealth versus Bene ts Subsidy Design and Asymmetric Information: Wealth versus Bene ts Simona Grassi and Ching-to Albert Ma Department of Economics Boston University 270 Bay State Road Boston, MA 02215, USA emails: sgrassi@bu.edu

More information

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result Arantza Gorostiaga Rubio-Ramírez Juan F. Universidad del País Vasco Duke University and Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Abstract

More information

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth Alberto Bisin October 29, 2009 Question Consider a two period economy. Agents are all identical, that is, there is

More information

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017 For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market June 017 This appendix contains the proofs and additional analyses that we mention in paper but that

More information

JEFF MACKIE-MASON. x is a random variable with prior distrib known to both principal and agent, and the distribution depends on agent effort e

JEFF MACKIE-MASON. x is a random variable with prior distrib known to both principal and agent, and the distribution depends on agent effort e BASE (SYMMETRIC INFORMATION) MODEL FOR CONTRACT THEORY JEFF MACKIE-MASON 1. Preliminaries Principal and agent enter a relationship. Assume: They have access to the same information (including agent effort)

More information

For Online Publication Only. ONLINE APPENDIX for. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

For Online Publication Only. ONLINE APPENDIX for. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market For Online Publication Only ONLINE APPENDIX for Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market By: Thierry Foucault (HEC, Paris) and Laurent Frésard (University of Maryland) January 2016 This appendix

More information

Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements

Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements Transaction Costs, Asymmetric Countries and Flexible Trade Agreements Mostafa Beshkar (University of New Hampshire) Eric Bond (Vanderbilt University) July 17, 2010 Prepared for the SITE Conference, July

More information

Problem Set # Public Economics

Problem Set # Public Economics Problem Set #5 14.41 Public Economics DUE: Dec 3, 2010 1 Tax Distortions This question establishes some basic mathematical ways for thinking about taxation and its relationship to the marginal rate of

More information

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

We will make several assumptions about these preferences: Lecture 5 Consumer Behavior PREFERENCES The Digital Economist In taking a closer at market behavior, we need to examine the underlying motivations and constraints affecting the consumer (or households).

More information

1 Supply and Demand. 1.1 Demand. Price. Quantity. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 2 of the text.

1 Supply and Demand. 1.1 Demand. Price. Quantity. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 2 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 2 of the text. 1 Supply and emand The rst model we will discuss is supply and demand. It is the most fundamental model used in economics, and is generally

More information

Energy & Environmental Economics

Energy & Environmental Economics Energy & Environmental Economics Public Goods, Externalities and welfare Università degli Studi di Bergamo a.y. 2015-16 (Institute) Energy & Environmental Economics a.y. 2015-16 1 / 29 Public Goods What

More information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Topic 5: Information Economics 21, Summer 2002 Andreas Bentz Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Introduction

More information

BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists

BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists Juliette Stephenson and Amr (Miro) Algarhi Author: Dieter Department of Economics, University of Exeter Week 1 1 Objectives 2 Isoquants 3 Objectives for the week Functions

More information

Problem Set # Public Economics

Problem Set # Public Economics Problem Set #3 14.41 Public Economics DUE: October 29, 2010 1 Social Security DIscuss the validity of the following claims about Social Security. Determine whether each claim is True or False and present

More information

Discussion of Chiu, Meh and Wright

Discussion of Chiu, Meh and Wright Discussion of Chiu, Meh and Wright Nancy L. Stokey University of Chicago November 19, 2009 Macro Perspectives on Labor Markets Stokey - Discussion (University of Chicago) November 19, 2009 11/2009 1 /

More information

Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management

Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management Douglas W. Blackburn Fordham University Andrey D. Ukhov Indiana University 17 October 2007 Abstract Research on executive compensation has been unable

More information

Labour Supply. Lecture notes. Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003

Labour Supply. Lecture notes. Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003 Labour Supply Lecture notes Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003 1 Introduction Definition 1 Labour economics is the study of the workings and outcomes of the market for labour. ² Most require

More information

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Two Period Exchange Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 2 1 Two Period Exchange Economy We shall start our exploration of dynamic economies with

More information

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics Group I Suppose a representative firm in a perfectly competitive, constant-cost industry has a cost function: T C(q) = 2q 2 + 100q + 100 (a) If market demand

More information

Problem Set #5 Solutions Public Economics

Problem Set #5 Solutions Public Economics Prolem Set #5 Solutions 4.4 Pulic Economics DUE: Dec 3, 200 Tax Distortions This question estalishes some asic mathematical ways for thinking aout taxation and its relationship to the marginal rate of

More information

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation Ed Nosal December 2008 Abstract An increase in in ation will cause people to hold less real balances and may cause them to speed up their spending.

More information

Almost essential MICROECONOMICS

Almost essential MICROECONOMICS Prerequisites Almost essential Games: Mixed Strategies GAMES: UNCERTAINTY MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell April 2018 1 Overview Games: Uncertainty Basic structure Introduction to the

More information

Quality, Upgrades, and Equilibrium in a Dynamic Monopoly Model

Quality, Upgrades, and Equilibrium in a Dynamic Monopoly Model Quality, Upgrades, and Equilibrium in a Dynamic Monopoly Model James Anton and Gary Biglaiser Duke and UNC November 5, 2010 1 / 37 Introduction What do we know about dynamic durable goods monopoly? Most

More information

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics ISSN 974-40 (on line edition) ISSN 594-7645 (print edition) WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY

More information