Unprecedented changes in the terms of trade

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Unprecedented changes in the terms of trade"

Transcription

1 Unprecedented changes in the terms of trade Mariano Kulish and Daniel M. Rees September 9, 214 Preliminary Draft Abstract The development of Asia exposed many commodity-exporting economies to unprecedented changes of their terms of trade. We set up a small open economy model to estimate the magnitude and timing of breaks in the long-run level and variance of the terms of trade. The model s balanced growth path gives rise to wedges between tradable, headline, and non-tradable rates of inflation and between the growth rates of investment and aggregate output as a result of multiple productivity trends that trigger off drifts in relative prices as in the data. Using Australian unfiltered aggregate data, we find evidence of an increase in the long-run level and volatility of the terms of trade. Single-equation structural break tests point to a larger increase in the long-run level of the terms of trade. But inferences in general equilibrium rely on many observables that also respond to shifts in the long-run level of the terms of trade. For comments and discussions we thank James Morley, Tim Robinson and Adrian Pagan. The usual disclaimer applies. School of Economics, UNSW, m.kulish@unsw.edu.au Economic Research, Reserve Bank of Australia reesd@rba.gov.au Please do not circulate without the authors consent. 1

2 1 Introduction Over the past two decades, the increasing development of Asia has exposed many economies to a surge in global commodity prices. There have been commodity price booms before, but this one, fueled by an unprecedented era of high growth in China, has been by far the largest and most persistent. In response, policy makers, market economists and the press in these economies have entertained the idea that commodity prices have reached a new normal, with a permanently higher level and greater volatility. 1 Understanding whether the terms of trade of commodity-exporting economies have reached a new normal and its implications for these economies has become of first order importance. 2 Measuring the macroeconomic impact of unprecedented changes in the terms of trade is a considerable task because the models used to study business cycles in small open economies are typically solved and estimated around a constant unconditional mean, but the idea of a new normal points to a shift of the unconditional mean. Moreover, changes in the terms of trade affect many relative prices that in the data trend at different rates, in particular the price of non-tradable goods and the price of investment goods. When estimating small open economy models, it is common to abstract from many of these trends and to resort to pre filtering the data somehow. While pre filtering aligns the data with the model, it comes at the cost of distorting the facts. As Beneš et al. [29] point out, a limitation of this approach is that it treats trends and cycles separately. In this paper we have gone to some effort to develop a unified model of the trends that we see in the data and to estimate it in the presence of shifts in the long-run level of the terms of trade. We add sector-specific productivity trends to an otherwise standard small open economy model that has nominal price frictions, imperfect exchange rate passthrough, capital accumulation and investment adjustment costs as well as a tradable, a non-tradable and a commodity-exporting sector. On the balanced growth path relative prices trend at different rates but nominal expenditure shares remain constant. In the model as in the data non-tradable goods prices run faster than consumer goods prices which run faster than tradable goods prices which, in turn, run faster than investment goods prices, while real investment and foreign output grow faster than domestic output. One significant contribution of this paper is to set up a small open economy that can account for these observed trends. The long-run level of the terms of trade, among other parameters, determines the balanced growth path, so a permanent change of the long-run level of the terms of trade gives rise to a transition towards a new balanced growth path that temporarily affects relative prices. It is an empirical issue to identify trends that belong to the balanced growth path, cycles around those trends, and fluctuations that originate from a transition towards a new balanced growth path. This is what we do in this paper. One contribution is to show how these forces may be identified in the data. Australia is an example of a commodity-exporting economy exposed to the rise of Asia. 1 See Bernanke [28], Bloxham et al. [212], Stevens [211], Tasker [213] and Yellen [211]. 2 The implications of commodity price booms are likely to differ among economies that produce commodities and those that consume them. Our focus here is on the impact of commodity price booms in commodity-exporting economies. Because for commodity-exporting economies the bulk of recent terms of trade fluctuations come from commodity prices movements, we use these terms interchangeably. 2

3 Over the past two decades, the foreign currency price of Australia s commodity exports increased by more than 2 per cent. 3 As Figure 1 shows, Australia s commodity prices are representative of world commodity prices which suggests that many other commodity exporting economies have experienced similar fluctuations as well. For these reasons, we estimate the model on Australian aggregate data. Figure 1: Commodity Price Indices Index 3 Australia Index World * Deflated by US CPI; average = 1 Sources: IMF; RBA We find that the long-run level of commodity prices increased by 4 per cent in mid 23. An increase of this magnitude is probably less than what would be inferred from visual inspection of Figure 1; it is also less than the 9 per cent increase suggested by single equation structural break tests. Our inferences, however, rely on more observables: an increase of 9 per cent is unlikely, but not because commodity prices would disagree, but because other observables series would disagree. The estimated long-run properties of the economy in our case depend on the cross-equations restrictions that rational expectations imposes on every observable series. This is not to say, however, that the 4 per cent increase we estimate in the longrun level of commodity prices has no significant impact. In fact, some of the economic implications are these: the commodity sector s share of exports increases from 35 to 52 per cent; the non-commodity tradable sector s share of value added decreases from 36 to 32 per cent; inflation falls by 2 percentage points with tradable inflation and nontradable inflation rates strongly offsetting each other; the relative price of non-tradable goods increase by 7 per cent and the real exchange appreciates permanently by 3 per cent. 3 Other structural features of the Australian economy, including its monetary policy regime, have remained stable over the past two decades. 3

4 Our work builds on that of Rabanal [29] and Siena [214], who set up models with different productivity trends in the tradable and non-tradable sectors. We add capital accumulation with a differential trend in the productivity of the investment goods producing sector as well as a commodity-exporting goods producing sector that takes the relative price of its output as given. Our work relates to a large literature on the role of terms of trade shocks in open economies to which we cannot possibly do justice. 4 Mendoza [1995] studies the contribution of terms of trade shocks to the business cycle in a calibrated open economy RBC model and finds that terms of trade shock account for 5 per cent of output fluctuations. Other papers, like Dib [28] and Medina and Soto [27], study the impact of terms of trade shocks in DSGE models with nominal frictions. Our work is different because we distinguish temporary shocks to the terms of trade which has been the focus in the small open literature from permanent shifts of the long-run level of the terms of trade. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses the model. Many details can be found in the online appendix. 5 Section 3 discusses our empirical approach which involves calibration and estimation of date breaks and parameters. Section 4 describes the main results. Section 5 analyses the responses of the estimated model to temporary and permanent changes in the terms of trade. Section 6 concludes suggesting avenues for further research. 2 Model We extend the standard small open economy model with nominal rigidities in the following ways. 6 We include capital accumulation, non-tradable and commodity-exporting sectors; and we include trends, following Rabanal [29], in sector-specific productivity technology processes to give rise to inflation differentials in steady state. We add Rotemberg [1982] style price adjustment costs in the home-produced tradeable, non-tradeable and import sectors. Sector-specific capital and investment adjustment costs restrict the economy s ability to adjust the composition of output in response to shocks. To help the model match the empirical volatility of many observables we include intertemporal and labour market preference shocks, investment-specific productivity shocks and risk premium shocks to the uncovered interest parity equation. Since the model is large, we present the basic ingredients in the main text and leave a comprehensive presentation to the appendix. 4 Instead, we point the reader to Ostry and Reinhart [1992], Bidarkota and Crucini [2], Bleaney and Greenaway [21], Broda [24], Blattman et al. [27], Jääskelä and Smith [213], Charnavoki and Dolado [214] and the references therein. 5 ADD LINK. 6 For a version of the small open model with nominal rigidities see, for example, Gali and Monacelli [25]. 4

5 2.1 Households The preferences of a typical household in the small open economy are given by: IE t= β t ζ t U (C t, L t ) where IE denotes the time conditional expectation, β is the discount factor and the preference shock ζ t follows the autoregressive process: ln ζ t = ρ ζ ln ζ t 1 + u ζ,t (1) where ρ ζ < 1 and u ζ,t is an identically and independently distributed (iid) random variable with mean zero and standard deviation σ ζ. The single period utility function U is strictly increasing in aggregate consumption, C t, decreasing in hours worked, L t, and given by: L 1+ν t U(C t, L t ) = ln(c t hc t 1 ) ε L,t 1 + ν where h [, 1] governs the degree of external habit formation and ν controls the responsiveness of aggregate labour supply to changes in real wages. ε L,t is a labour supply shock that follows: ln ε L,t = ρ ε ln ε L,t 1 + u L,t (2) where ρ ε < 1 and u L,t is an iid random variable with mean zero and standard deviation σ L. The functional form of the labour aggregate takes the form L t = [ ] ξ H L 1+ω H,t + ξ N L 1+ω N,t + ξ X L 1+ω 1 1+ω X,t (3) making employment in the different sectors of the economy imperfect substitutes: ω controls the degree of substitutability between employment in different sectors. 7 In Equation (3), L H,t stands for hours worked in the home-tradable goods producing sector, L N,t stands for hours worked in the non-tradable goods producing sector and L X,t stands for hours worked in the commodity-exporting goods producing sector. The parameters ξ H, ξ N and ξ X govern the relative desirability of supplying labour to each sector. Households enter the period with K j,t units of capital from sector j {H, N, X}, B t units of risk free bonds denominated in domestic currency and Bt units of risk free bonds denominated in foreign currency. During the period, the household supplies labour and capital to the domestic production sector, receives profits, Γ j,t, from these sectors, and pays a lump sum tax, T t, to the government. The household uses its income to purchase new domestic and foreign bonds, to invest in new capital in sector j {H, N, X}, I j,t, and to purchase consumption goods. The resulting flow budget constraint is given by: P t C t + P I,t I j,t + B t+1 + S t Bt+1 R t 1 B t j {H,N,X} +R F t 1S t B t + j {H,N,X} (W j,t L j,t + R j tk j,t + Γ j,t ) T t 7 When ω = labour is perfectly substitutable between sectors. 5

6 where P t is the consumer price index, P I,t is the price of the aggregate investment good and W j,t and R j t are the wage rate and rate of return on capital in sector j. R t and Rt F are the rates of return on risk-free bonds in domestic and foreign currency. S t is the nominal exchange rate, the domestic price of foreign currency. The stock of capital in sector j evolves according to: K j,t+1 = (1 δ) K j,t + Ṽt [ 1 Υ ( Ij,t I j,t 1 )] I j,t (4) where δ is the capital depreciation rate and Υ is an investment adjustment cost with the standard restrictions that in steady state Υ( ) = Υ ( ) = and Υ ( ) >. V t is a process that governs the efficiency with which investment adds to the capital stock which we assume to follow, ( ) t 1 Ṽ t = v V t (5) z I where z I is the differential growth rate of real investment over the growth rate of labouraugmenting technology, z, and Ṽt is a stationary autoregressive process that affects the marginal efficiency of investment of the form: ln V t = ρ V ln V t 1 + u V,t (6) where ρ V < 1 and u V,t is an iid random variable with mean zero and standard deviation σ V. On the balanced growth path I j,t can be shown to grow at z z I. The term in the left hand side of Equation (4), Ṽ t I j,t, grows at z. Thus, the trend in Ṽt is necessary for balanced growth if real investment grows faster than real consumption, as is the case here. As the real rental rate on capital is stationary, the household s budget constraint implies that the growth rate of real consumption, z, must equal the growth rate of the capital stocks. The trend in Ṽt offsets the differential growth that real investment brings to the capital accumulation equations. As explained by Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe [23], to ensure stationarity we link the foreign interest rate to the net-foreign asset position. In particular, the interest rate on foreign bonds is given by [ ( ) ] Rt F = Rt St Bt exp ψ b b + NGDP ψ b,t (7) t where R t is the foreign interest rate, b is the steady-state net foreign asset-to-gdp ratio and NGDP t is nominal GDP. ψ b,t is a risk-premium shock that follows the process: ψ b,t = ρ ψ ψb,t + u ψ,t (8) where ρ ψ deviation σ ψ. < 1 and u ψ,t is an iid random variable with mean zero and standard 6

7 2.2 Final goods producing firms Final consumption goods Final consumption goods are produced by a representative competitive firm with the technology: [ ] η C t = γ 1 η η + γ 1 η 1 η η η 1 T,t C T,t η 1 N,t C N,t where C N,t is the output of the non-traded sector that is directed towards consumption and has price P N,t while C T,t is the output of the traded sector that is directed towards consumption and has price P T,t. The deterministic processes γ T,t and γ N,t ensure, as in Rabanal [29], that expenditure shares remain stationary along the balanced growth path. 8 C T,t is itself a composite of domestically- and foreign-produced tradable goods produced according to the following technology C T,t = (C H,t) γ H (C F,t ) γ F (γ H ) γ H (γf ) γ F The Cobb-Douglas specification guarantees that the expenditure shares in the tradable consumption basket remain constant. This assumption is convenient to find the normalisations to make the system stationary. Otherwise, γ H and γ F would have to trend to keep nominal expenditure shares constant in steady state. The trends in γ H and γ F together with the differential growth rate of the home-tradable producing goods, z H, and the differential growth rate of the foreign goods producing sector, z, would determine the differential growth rate of the tradable basket, that is, z T. But to find the trends in γ H and γ F one must know z T. The non-traded, home-produced traded and imported consumption goods are all bundles of a continuum of imperfectly substitutable goods: 9 ( 1 C j,t θ j ) 1 θ θ 1 θ C j,t (i) j di The zero-profit condition implies that the price index of the final consumption good is given by P t = [ ] γ T,t P 1 η T,t + γ N,t P 1 η 1 1 η N,t (9) and the price index of the tradable consumption good, in turn, is given by: Final Investment Goods P T,t = (P H,t ) γ H (P F,t ) γ F (1) Final investment goods are produced by a representative competitive firm with the technology: I t = zv t (I T,t ) γi T (IN,t ) γi N (γt I T (γ I )γi N )γi N 8 See the online appendix for details about the normalisations. 9 This is also the case for investment, I j,t for j {H, N, F }. 7

8 where I N,t is the output of the non-traded sector directed towards the production of investment, I T,t is the output of the traded sector that is directed towards investment and z v is a productivity trend that jointly with the growth rates of I T,t and I N,t determines the steady state growth rate of final investment, that is z I. 1 I T,t is, as before, a composite of domestically-and foreign produced tradable goods that is produced according to the technology The corresponding price indices are and I T,t = (I H,t) γi H (IF,t ) γi F (γ I H )γi H (γ I F )γi F P I t = (P I T,t) γi T (P N,t ) γi N (11) P I T,t = (P H,t ) γi H (PF,t ) γi F (12) As the shares of non-tradable, domestically-produced tradable and imported goods in the investment and consumption composites differ, the price of final consumption goods, P t, will, in general, differ from the price of investment goods, P I,t, as will the price of tradable consumption goods, P T,t, differ from the price of tradable investment goods, P I T,t. 2.3 Intermediate goods producing firms There are four intermediate good producers: commodity firms, non-tradable firms, domestic tradable firms and importing firms. We describe each in turn Commodity-exporting firms Commodity firms produce an homogeneous good in a perfectly competitive market using the Cobb-Douglas production function: Y X,t = A t ZX,t (K X,t ) α X (Z t L X,t ) 1 α X (13) where Z t is a labour-augmenting technology shock, common to all producing sectors, whose growth rate, z t = Z t /Z t 1, follows the process below ln z t = (1 ρ z ) ln z + ρ z ln z t 1 + u z,t (14) and z > 1 determines the trend growth rate of real GDP, Y t. ρ z < 1 and u z,t is an iid random variable with mean zero and standard deviation σ z. The sector-specific productivity process, Z X,t, follows Z X,t = z t XZ X,t (15) 1 Ireland and Schuh [28] and Justiniano et al. [211] are examples of closed economy models with a trend in the price of investment goods and a wedge between the growth rates of real investment and real output. 8

9 where z X > determines the differential growth rate, along the balanced growth path, between Y X,t and Y t, that is between output in the commodity-exporting sector and real GDP. The stationary process Z X,t gives rise to temporary departures from the differential trend by ln Z X,t = ρ X ln Z X,t 1 + u X,t (16) In Equation (13) A t is a stationary technology shock, also common to all sectors, that follows the process ln A t = ρ a ln A t 1 + u A,t (17) where ρ A < 1 and u A,t is an iid random variable with mean zero and standard deviation σ A. Commodity producers take prices as given. These prices are set in foreign currency terms in world markets and are unaffected by domestic economic developments. Specifically, we assume that the price of commodities, in foreign currency terms, is equal to P X,t = κ t P t (18) where Pt is the foreign price level and κ t, which governs the relative price of commodities, follows the exogenous process: ( ) z t κ t = exp (κ t ) (19) zx where z is the differential growth rate of foreign output and zx is the differential growth rate of foreign production of commodities. The drift in the relative price of commodities reflects the relative productivity growth of the commodity sector and the foreign economy. 11 Transitory shocks to commodity prices follow κ t = (1 ρ κ )κ + ρ κ κ t 1 + u κ,t (2) where ρ κ < 1 and u κ,t is an iid shock with zero mean and standard deviation σ κ. For the stochastically detrended variables, κ determines the unconditional mean of the terms of trade and, in turn, is one of the determinants of the economy s steady state. In estimation, we allow for breaks in κ and in σ κ, possibly occurring at different dates in the sample. The law of one price holds for commodities, which means that their price in domestic currency terms is P X,t = S t P X,t (21) Non-tradeable goods producing firms Non-tradeable firms sell differentiated products, which they produce using the Cobb- Douglas production function: Y N,t (i) = A t ZN,t (K N,t (i)) α N (Z t L N,t (i)) 1 α N (22) 11 The productivity trend in the foreign production of commodities must equal the productivity trend in the domestic production of commodities for balanced growth, that is z X = z X. 9

10 Z N,t is sector-specific productivity process that follows Z N,t = z t NZ N,t where z N > and Z N,t are transitory deviations from the sector-specific trend that follows ln Z N,t = ρ N ln Z N,t 1 + u N,t (23) where ρ N < 1 and u N,t is an iid random variable with mean zero and standard deviation σ N. Firms can only change prices at some cost, following a Rotemberg [1982] pricing mechanism: 12 ( ) 2 ψ N PN,t (i) 2 Π N P N,t 1 (i) 1 P N,tY N,t where ψ N governs the size of the price adjustment cost and Π N is the steady state inflation rate of non-tradable goods prices. Aggregate non-tradable output is defined by the Dixit-Stiglitz aggregator: ( 1 Y N,t Y N,t (i) θ N 1 θ N di ) θ N θ N Domestic tradeable goods producing firms Domestic tradable firms produce differentiated products using the Cobb-Douglas production function Y H,t (i) = A t ZH,t (K H,t (i)) α H (Z t L H,t (i)) 1 α H (24) Z H,t is a stationary sector-specific TFP shock that follows Z H,t = z t HZ H,t where z H > and Z H,t are temporary deviations from that trend, ln Z H,t = ρ H ln Z H,t 1 + u H,t (25) where ρ H < 1 and u H,t is an iid random variable with mean zero and standard deviation σ H. Like their non-tradable counterparts, tradable firms can only change prices at some cost, following a Rotemberg [1982] pricing mechanism: ( ) 2 ψ H PH,t (i) 2 Π H P H,t 1 (i) 1 P H,tY H,t where ψ H governs the size of the price adjustment cost and Π H is the steady state inflation rate of domestic-tradable goods prices. Domestic tradable output, Y H,t is an aggregate of the output of each of the domestic tradable firms, ( 1 Y H,t Y H,t (i) θ H 1 θ H di ) θ H θ H 1 12 We assume that these price adjustment costs do not affect the cash flow of firms, but only affect their objective function (see De Paoli et al. [21] for a discussion of this approach). Therefore, they do not appear in the resource constraint or net export equations. Assuming instead that these adjustment costs are real costs would yield equivalent results as quadratic terms do not appear in the linearized system. 1

11 2.3.4 Importing Firms Importing firms purchase foreign good varieties at the price ςs t Pt and sell them in the domestic market at price P F,t (i). The parameter ς represents a subsidy to imported firms, funded by lump-sum taxation. We set the subsidy equal to ς = (θ F 1)/θ F, thereby ensuring that markups in this sector are zero in equilibrium. Importing firms can only change prices at some cost, following a Rotemberg [1982] pricing mechansim ψ F 2 ( PF,t (i) Π F P F,t 1 (i) 1 ) 2 P F,t Y F,t 2.4 Foreign sector, net exports and the current account Following Gertler et al. [27], we postulate a foreign demand function for domestically produced tradable goods, CH,t, of the form C H,t = γ H,t ( ) η PH,t S t P t Foreign output, Ỹ t, follows the non-stationary process Ỹ t = Z t (z ) t Y t Ỹ t (26) where z > captures the differential steady state growth rate between real GDP in the domestic and the rest of the world. Transitory deviations from foreign trend growth are captured by Yt which follow ln Y t = ρ Y ln Y t + u Y,t (27) where ρ Y < 1 and u Y,t is an iid random variable with mean zero and standard deviation σy. Foreign inflation is assumed to follow and the foreign interest rate follows ln Π t = (1 ρ Π) ln Π + ρ Π ln Π t 1 + u Π,t (28) ln R t = (1 ρ R) ln R + ρ R ln R t 1 + u R,t (29) where ρ Π < 1 and ρ R < 1 and the iid shocks u Π,t and u R,t standard deviations σπ and σ R. Net exports are given by: have zero mean and NX t = P H,t C H,t + P X,t Y X,t P F,t (C F,t + I F,t ) (3) and so the current account equation is given by: S t B t+1 = R F t 1S t B t + NX t (31) 11

12 2.5 Monetary Policy The domestic central bank follows a Taylor rule that responds to deviations of output growth and inflation from their steady-state levels ( ) ( ) [ ( ) ( )] Rt Rt 1 Πt Yt ln = ρ r ln + (1 ρ R ) φ π ln + φ y ln + u R,t (32) R R Π zy t 1 where Π t = P t /P t 1 is the inflation rate in terms of final consumption goods prices and Π is the central bank s inflation target. 2.6 Market Clearing Market clearing for investment goods requires that production of these goods equals to quantity demanded by the three domestic production sectors I t = I h,t + I n,t + I x,t (33) For the non-tradable, domestic tradable and import sectors, market clearing requires that the quantity produced equals the quantity demanded: Nominal GDP is defined as: and real GDP is defined as: 2.7 Balanced Growth Y N,t = C N,t + I N,t (34) Y H,t = C H,t + C H,t + I H,t (35) Y F,t = C F,t + I F,t (36) NGDP t = P N,t Y N,t + P H,t Y H,t + P X,t Y X,t (37) Y t = P N P Y N,t + P H P Y H,t + P X P Y X,t (38) A novel feature of this model as that of Rabanal [29] is the existence of trends in aggregate as well as sector-specific productivity. Next, we describe how the variables behave along a balanced growth path and the normalisations that induce stationarity. Along a balanced growth path aggregate variables, including GDP, consumption and the capital stock, grow at the rate of aggregate productivity, z. Sectoral variables, such as output of non-tradable goods, Y N,t, and the quantity of these goods that enter consumption and investment baskets, that is, C N,t and I N,t, grow at aggregate productivity adjusted by the sector specific trend. For example, in steady state the growth rate of non-tradable output is (1 + z)(1 + z N ). Balanced growth requires the shares of each sector in nominal GDP to be constant. For this to hold, the relative prices of each sector must trend by the reciprocal of the 12

13 sector-specific productivity growth rate. So, for example, the relative price of nontradable goods to the price of consumption goods, that is, P N,t /P t, must grow at (1+z N ) 1 along a balanced growth path. When bundles are Cobb-Douglas expenditure shares are constant and balanced growth is satisfied regardless of trends in relative prices because income and substitution effects are offsetting. However, in the more general CES specification for the bundles, balanced growth will be achieved provided that the weights satisfy γ the following processes: γ N,t = N γ (1+z N and γ ) η 1 T,t = T (1+z T. ) η 1 3 Empirical Strategy The structural parameters can be thought of in two categories: those that can only determine dynamics persistence parameters, adjustment cost parameters, policy rule parameters and standard deviations and parameters that, in addition to influencing the dynamics, pin down the steady state. Like Adolfson et al. [27], we calibrate most parameters that determine the steady state. The habits parameter, h, and the long-run level of commodity prices in the final steady state, 1 + κ, however, are estimated. We estimate the remaining parameters. 3.1 Calibration We calibrate for two reasons. First, not all parameters are well identified given the usual choice of observable variables. Second, estimation could imply a steady state at odds with the sample means in the data. We set these parameters so that the balanced growth path is in line with the first moments of the data. The traditional approach of matching sample means seems inappropriate in our case because we postulate a possible break in the long-run level of the terms of trade, which in turn leads to changes in unconditional means. We therefore focus on matching the features of the data over the first part of the sample, before commodity prices started to rise rapidly in the early 2s. To be precise, we calibrate the model s parameters to match means over the period 1993 to 22, which is a period of stability in the terms of trade. In the initial steady state, we first set κ to 1. Before other parameters are calibrated, this choice is a normalisation. After that, of course, a change in κ changes the steady state. For the data to be consistent with the model in estimation, the index of real commodity prices must be re-normalised to average 1 over the sub-sample. Our calibration strategy is as follows. We calibrate the model at a quarterly frequency. We assume that the steady-state rate of labour augmenting TFP growth, z, is 1.49, which matches the average growth rate of per capita GDP over our sample. 13 We set the central bank s target inflation rate, Π, equal to This delivers an average annual inflation rate of around 2.5 per cent, which is the middle of the central bank s stated 13 We calibrate this parameter using the average growth over our full sample of data rather than the shorter 1993 to 22 sample because the shorter sample featured an unusually rapid period of economic growth in Australia associated with a steep recovery from a deep recession in the early 199s and a period of rapid productivity growth due, in part, to a series of microeconomic reforms in the 198s. Consequently, the full-sample average is likely to better reflect the average long-run TFP growth rate. 13

14 inflation target. We set the household s discount rate, β, equal to Together, these three parameters match the steady state nominal interest rate to the sample of the Cash Rate of 6(?) per cent. We set the sector-specific productivity growth differentials, z N and z H so that the inflation rates of tradable and non-tradable goods match their rates in the data. So, we set z N = to ensure that, on average, non-tradable prices rise faster than the CPI. And we set z H to Given this value and the foreign productivity growth differential, z = 1.33, set to match the average growth rate of Australia s major trading partners at PPP, the steady state of tradables goods inflation in the model matches that in the data. We set the capital shares in each sector, α N, α H and α X to.358,.438 and.7, reflecting their average values in national accounts data. 14 The markup parameters, θ N, θ H and θ F are set so that each sector has an an average markup of 1 per cent. The price adjustment costs parameters that determine the slope of Phillips curves, however, are estimated. We set the parameter governing the elasticity of labour supply, η, we set to 2, which is a standard value in the literature. The parameter governing the willingness of workers to move between sectors, we set to 1, in line with Horvath [2]. We set the parameters ξ N, ξ H and ξ X to 1, 29 and This ensures that the share of hours worked in each sector in the model broadly matches that in the data. The shares in the Cobb-Douglas bundles are set to match averages in the data. Thus we set, γ F to.357, γ H to 1 γ F, γn I to.664, γi T to 1 γi N, γi F to.828 and γi H to 1 γi F. The parameters, γh, γ N and γ T, are set to approximate the share of exports in GDP and the share of non-tradable and tradable goods in the domestic consumption basket in the data. We set γh to.877 and γ N and γ T to.48 and.52. Table 2 compares the moments implied by the model s steady state to their empirical counterparts. At the calibrated parameters values of Table 1 the model s steady state does quite well. Investment growth in the model s steady state is somewhat lower than in our sample. Because investment is quite volatile and can fall significantly in recessions, it is likely that the growth rate of investment in our sample (which does not have a recession) is overstated. If we extend the sample to begin in 199:Q1 which includes a recession the average growth rate of investment is We set z v so as to match the rate of inflation of investment goods prices, which in turn, implies a growth rate of investment of 3.43 per cent. 3.2 Estimation We use Bayesian methods, as is common in the estimated DSGE literature. 15 Our case, however, is non standard because we allow for structural change and jointly estimate two sets of distinct parameters: the structural parameters of the model, ϑ, that have continuous support and the dates of structural changes, T = (T κ, T σκ ) that have discrete support; T κ is the date break in the mean and T σκ is the date break in the variance of 14 The data appendix provides additional detail regarding our classification of industries into tradable, non-tradable and commodity-exporting. 15 See An and Schorfheide [27] for a description of these techniques. 14

15 Table 1: Calibrated Parameters Parameter Description Value β Household discount factor δ Capital depreciation rate.5 ν Labour supply parameter 2 ω Intersectoral labour supply elasticity 1 ξ N Constant on non-tradable labor supply 1 ξ H Constant on tradable labour supply 29 ξ X Constant on commodities labour supply 4167 ψ b Risk premium.1 γ N Non-tradables consumption weight.48 γ H Home-produced tradables weight.643 γn I Non-tradables investment weight.664 γh I Home-produced tradables investment weight.172 γh Determinant of foreign demand.877 η Elasticity of substitution.8 η Elasticity of substitution.8 z Steady-state TFP growth 1.49 z v Investment growth rate differential 1.35 z N Non-tradable growth differential.999 z H Home tradable growth differential 1.2 z X Commodity growth differential 1. z Foreign growth differential 1.33 α N Capital share in non-tradables.358 α H Capital share in tradables.438 α X Capital share in commodities.7 Π Domestic inflation target 1.62 Π Foreign inflation target 1.55 θ N Markup in non-tradables 11 θ H Markup in home tradables 11 θ F Markup in imports 11 b Steady state net foreign assets Notes: 15

16 Table 2: Steady State Properties of the Model Average Target Model Macro Aggregates (annual per cent) Per capita output growth Per capita investment growth Inflation Tradable inflation Non-tradable inflation Investment deflator inflation Expenditure (per cent of GDP) Consumption Investment Exports Consumption basket ( per cent of consumption) Non-tradable consumption Home tradable consumption Imported tradable consumption Investment basket (per cent of investment) Non-tradable investment Home tradable investment Imported investment Exports (per cent of exports) Resource exports Other exports Employment (per cent of hours worked) Non-tradable Home tradable Mining Notes: Model ratios calculated at initial regime with κ = 1. and h =.5. 16

17 commodity prices. We set the trimming parameter for both date breaks to 25 per cent of the sample. This implies, in our case, the minimum length of a segment to be 2 observations. Next, we describe how we construct the joint posterior density of ϑ and T: p(ϑ, T Y) L(Y ϑ, T)p(ϑ, T), (39) where Y {yt obs } T t=1 is the data and yt obs is a n obs 1 vector of observable variables. The likelihood is given by L(Y ϑ, T), the priors for the structural parameters and the date breaks are taken to be independent, so that p(ϑ, T) = p(ϑ)p(t). We use a flat prior for T so p(t) 1, which is proper given its discrete support. Kulish and Pagan [212] discuss how to construct L(Y ϑ, T) in models with forward-looking expectations and structural changes. Appendix C describes the posterior sampler. We estimate the model using quarterly Australian macroeconomic data for the period 1993Q1 to 213Q4. The starting date coincides with the start of inflation targeting in Australia and represents a period over which the macroeconomic policy environment has been broadly stable. Our data series includes aggregate and sectoral variables and foreign variables. The aggregate data include real GDP, investment, consumption, net exports, hours worked, the cash rate, trimmed mean inflation and the percentage change in the nominal exchange rate. The national accounts variables and hours are all expressed in per capita terms and seasonally adjusted. Output, investment, consumption and hours all enter in percentage changes, while net exports enters as a share of nominal GDP. We also include two sectoral variables in the model: the inflation rate of non-tradable goods and the ratio of nominal non-tradable consumption to aggregate nominal consumption. The foreign variables that we include in the model are output growth, interest rates and inflation. We take the growth rate of the Australian major trading partner GDP series constructed by the Reserve Bank of Australia as the measure of foreign output growth. For interest rates we use the average of the policy rates in the US, the Euro area and Japan. 16 For the foreign inflation rate, we use the trade-weighted average inflation rate of Australia s major trading partners. The 14 series we use in estimation are shown in Figure 2. Appendix A contains a complete description of the data sources, calculations and transformations. We add measurement error in estimation as is standard in the literature. We calibrate the variance of the measurement errors to 5 per cent of the variance of each observable series. Macroeconomic data are measured with noise and the economic concepts in the model do not always match the measures in the data. Take real output for example. Real output is constructed using chain volume measures which are subject to revision whenever the reference period is changed. The model measure of real output, however, is constructed at steady state relative prices so the reference period does not change. Steady state relative prices change when the long-run level of the terms of trade changes, and our measurement equations change as well, this is not equivalent to chain-volume linking. 16 Prior to the introduction of the euro, we construct this series using the German policy rate. 17

18 Figure 2: Observable variables.4 Output growth.1 Investment growth.2 Consumption growth Net exports to GDP.45 Non tradable consumption to consumption.2 Nominal interest rate Nominal exchange rate x 1 3 Inflation Non tradable Inflation Commodity Prices.2 Hours worked.2 Foreign output growth x 1 3 Foreign inflation.15 Foreign nominal interest rate Priors For the parameter of most interest to us, the long-run level of commodity prices in the final regime, we choose a uniform prior over the domain.25 to 3.5 over the change in κ, that is, we put a flat prior over κ. Notice that, we allow the steady-state of relative commodity price to have declined by 25 per cent, increased by 35 per cent or taken any value in between. We choose the same prior for σ f κ and σ i κ, the standard deviations of shocks to commodity prices in the two regimes. We choose loose beta distributions on the autoregressive parameters and inverse gamma distributions on the standard deviations of the shocks. 17 For the parameters of the monetary policy rule we set a prior mean of 1.5 for the response of the Cash Rate to inflation and of.3 for the response to real output growth. These choice are in line with the literature. Table 4 summarises the priors. 17 These choices are standard in the literature. See An and Schorfheide [27]. 18

19 4 Results 4.1 Date breaks Figure 3 shows the cumulative posterior density of T κ, the date break in the unconditional mean, and cumulative posterior density of T σκ, the date break of the variance, that is the date break for 1 + κ and the date break for σ κ. The data strongly prefer 23:Q2 for the date break in the unconditional mean. The probability that the break occurred in this quarter is around 95 per cent and there is some probability that it occurred in the next few quarters. Our estimate of T κ is close to that of Gruen [211] who dates the start of boom to 22:Q2. Single equation Bai and Perron [1998] tests place the date break in κ a quarter later, that is 23:Q3. The date break in volatility, T σκ, shown in the bottom panel shows, is estimated to have occurred after the increase in the unconditional mean. The posterior density for T σκ is bi-modal. It peaks in 25:Q2 and then again in the second quarter of 28:Q2. Figure 3: Posterior cumulative distributions of date breaks 1 Date break in the mean.8 Cumulative probability q2 2q4 23q2 25q4 28q2 1 Date break in the variance.8 Cumulative probability q2 2q4 23q2 25q4 28q2 4.2 Structural parameters In estimation we allow for breaks in κ and σ κ because we want to give the model a chance to fit the data without necessarily having to resort to a change in κ. As it turns out, the data strongly prefer the specification in which both κ and σ κ increase. The estimation 19

20 Figure 4: Posterior distribution of κ κ could have well chosen to explain the fluctuations in commodity prices post-23 with an increase in volatility and no increase in the unconditional mean. Figure 4 shows the posterior distribution of κ. The density is bounded away from zero and the long-run level of commodity prices 1 + κ is estimated to have increased by around 4 per cent, with a distribution that ranges between 3 and 5 per cent. The posterior distribution significantly shrinks the uncertainty relative to the range of our uninformative prior on κ which ranges from -25 per cent to 35 per cent. Using the tests of Bai and Perron [1998] on the commodity price series points to a 9 per cent increase of the long-run level of commodity prices. But in forward-looking general equilibrium, a 9 per cent increase of the long-run level of commodity prices has implications which are not in the data of other observed domestic endogenous variables. Our estimate is 4 per cent and the single equation one is 9 per cent. Clearly, the other observables serve to moderate the estimated increase in the long-run mean. One may, therefore wonder, if our estimate of κ, would be any different from zero if we were to estimate our model after having removed real commodity prices from the set of observable variables. In fact, we have run this estimation and still find statistically significant evidence of a 2 per cent increase in κ. At a more general level this is an important result: cross-equations restrictions permits us to make inferences about structural breaks in unobservable series. Figure 5 shows the posterior distribution for the ratio of the standard deviations of shocks to commodity prices in the two regimes, that is σ κ/σ κ, where we use the notation that σ κ corresponds to the post-break one. The distribution has no mass at unity or values below. There is no likelihood that the standard deviation of commodity price 2

21 Figure 5: Posterior distribution of σ f κ/σ i κ σ f κ / σi κ shocks has fallen or stayed the same. In fact, the data point to the volatility of shocks to commodity prices having more than doubled. Below we study some of the macroeconomic implications of these changes, but before we briefly discuss estimates of other parameters. Table 3 also summarises the estimates of other parameters. The monetary policy rule parameters reveal that there is persistence in the setting of the policy rate and that the policy rate responds relatively more strongly to inflation than it does to output growth. Habits and investment adjust costs are important; the data prefer some additional persistence, relative to the priors, stemming from these parameters. We also find heterogeneity in the degree of price stickiness across sectors. At the mode the slope of the Phillips curve in the tradable sector is 5 times steeper than in the non-tradable sector which is in turn steeper than in the importing goods producing sector. The parameters of the exogenous process are reported in Table Estimated transitional dynamics To get a sense of the magnitudes involved we compute the transitional dynamics implied by the posterior distribution of κ for real commodity prices and for the price of nontradable goods. We sample from the joint posterior distribution of date breaks and structural parameters. Then at each sampled value, we compute the path of the nonstochastic steady state: this is the path the economy would have taken in the absence of shocks but in the presence of κ occurring at some T κ. Notice that according to Equation (2) a change in κ induces a slow transition towards the new long-run value because the process is persistent. In fact the contemporaneous impact is attenuated by the persistence of the process, is given by (1 ρ κ ) κ. Figure 6 shows the observed real 21

22 Table 3: Prior and Posterior Distribution of Structural Parameters Prior Distribution Posterior Distribution Variable Shape Mean Std Dev. Mode Mean 5 % 95 % Commodity Prices κ Uniform [-.25,3.] σ κ Inv. Gamma σ κ Inv. Gamma ρ κ Beta Monetary Policy Rule ρ R Beta φ π Normal φ y Normal Frictions h Beta Υ Normal Slope N Gamma Slope H Gamma Slope F Gamma Notes: Slope N = 1(θ N 1)/ψ N, Slope H = 1(θ H 1)/ψ H, Slope F = 1(θ F 1)/ψ F 22

23 Table 4: Prior and Posterior Distribution of Shock Processes Prior Distribution Posterior Distribution Variable Shape Mean Std Dev. Mode Mean 5 % 95 % ρ H Beta ρ N Beta ρ X Beta ρ ζ Beta ρ v Beta ρ L Beta ρ z Beta ρ A Beta ρ ψ Beta ρ y Beta ρ r Beta ρ π Beta σ H Inv. Gamma σ N Inv. Gamma σ X Inv. Gamma σ ζ Inv. Gamma σ v Inv. Gamma σ L Inv. Gamma σ z Inv. Gamma σ A Inv. Gamma σ r Inv. Gamma σ ψ Inv. Gamma σ y Inv. Gamma σ r Inv. Gamma σ π Inv. Gamma Notes: 23

24 Figure 6: Observed and long-run commodity prices Observed real commodity prices Long run real commodity prices commodity price series we use in estimation (in levels) and the distribution of the nonstochastic path of real commodity prices implied by our posterior estimates. Most date breaks happen in 23:Q2 and from that time, the grey paths are anticipated (because the process is persistence) even when the shock to κ in 23:Q2 is not. After the break, the forecasts for commodity prices in each quarter, for the most part, implies significant falls in commodity prices. This is consistent with the Reserve Bank of Australia s terms of trade forecast since The difference between observed commodity prices and the implied fundamental level, so to speak, is the result of an increase in the volatility of shocks to commodity prices. What we find remarkable is that we have not insisted that the long-run level had to change, all the variation could have been picked up by volatility, but all observables (including commodity prices) point to an increase in the unconditional mean. It is interesting to look at similar implication for the price of non-tradable goods. Although our model does not have housing sector, an important determinant of nontradable inflation in the data comes from the housing sector. 19 Figure 7 shows the observed relative price of non-tradables goods and the posterior distribution implied by the transition induced by κ. Recall that because there is wedge between non-tradable inflation and inflation, this relative price trends and the rate at which it trends is the same for both balanced growth paths. According to Figure 7, the relative price of nontradables goods is well explained by the shift in the long-run level of the terms of trade. 18 See Figure 4 in Plumb et al. [213]. 19 Future research could extend the model to include a housing sector and study the implication for housing prices. 24

25 Figure 7: Observed and long-run non-tradable prices Long run P N / P Observed P N / P Variance Decompositions The estimated changes in the unconditional mean and volatility bring about changes in the contributions of the various shocks. The change in κ changes the steady state, in particular, it changes the relative size of the sectors. For instance, the commodity sector s share of exports increases from 35 to 52 per cent. This change alone alters the relative contribution of shocks to the business cycle, even if the standard deviation of the shocks does not change. But in our case, shocks to commodity prices become more important. To measure the implications of these changes we compare variance decomposition at the mode for some variables of interest in two regimes: a low regime, κ = 1 and σ κ =.5) and a high regime, κ = 1.42 and σ κ = Shocks to commodity prices and shocks to the productivity of the commodity-exporting sector explain little of the fluctuations in inflation. However, shocks to the productivity of the commodity-exporting sector explain 27 per cent of the variance of output growth in the low regime and around half of the variance post 27. Shocks to real commodity prices explain in the high regime over 5 per cent of the variance of net exports. Many other results are well-known in the literature but we point them out. The nominal exchange rate is mostly driven by risk-premium shocks. However, it is noticeable that the contribution of σ κ increases from half a percent to about 5 per cent. Three quarters of investment growth is explained by shocks to the marginal efficiency of investment. 2 We do not report variance decompositions for the high-κ low-σ κ -regime because the joint posterior implies a low probability for this regime. 25

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Pavel Herber 1 and Daniel Němec 2 1 Masaryk University, Faculty of Economics and Administrations Department of Economics Lipová 41a, 602 00 Brno,

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy Iklaga, Fred Ogli University of Surrey f.iklaga@surrey.ac.uk Presented at the 33rd USAEE/IAEE North American Conference, October 25-28,

More information

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound Timothy Hills Taisuke Nakata Sebastian Schmidt New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank 1 September 2016 1 The views expressed

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Do Central Banks Respond to Exchange Rate Movements? Some New Evidence from Structural Estimation

Do Central Banks Respond to Exchange Rate Movements? Some New Evidence from Structural Estimation Do Central Banks Respond to Exchange Rate Movements? Some New Evidence from Structural Estimation Wei Dong International Department Bank of Canada January 4, 8 Abstract This paper investigates whether

More information

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Giancarlo Corsetti Luca Dedola Sylvain Leduc CREST, May 2008 The International Consumption Correlations Puzzle

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data Proceedings of 3th International Conference Mathematical Methods in Economics DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data Introduction Miroslav Hloušek Abstract. Czech data shows positive

More information

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility Comment Martín Uribe, Columbia University and NBER This paper represents the latest installment in a highly influential series of papers in which Paul Beaudry and Franck Portier shed light on the empirics

More information

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK Stefania Villa a Jing Yang b a Birkbeck College b Bank of England Cambridge Conference - New Instruments of Monetary Policy: The Challenges

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44 TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy Roberto Pancrazi Toulouse School of Economics Marija Vukotić Banque de France NBS, April 27, 2012 NBS, April 27, 2012 1 / 44 Motivation 1 Well Known Facts about the

More information

Endogenous Money or Sticky Wages: A Bayesian Approach

Endogenous Money or Sticky Wages: A Bayesian Approach Endogenous Money or Sticky Wages: A Bayesian Approach Guangling Dave Liu 1 Working Paper Number 17 1 Contact Details: Department of Economics, University of Stellenbosch, Stellenbosch, 762, South Africa.

More information

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe August 2 211 This document contains supplementary material to Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (211). 1 A Two Sector

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration Takashi Kano Hitotsubashi University @HIAS, IER, AJRC Joint Workshop Frontiers in Macroeconomics and Macroeconometrics November 3-4, 2017

More information

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy Yusuf Soner Başkaya Timur Hülagü Hande Küçük 6 April 212 Oil price volatility is high and it varies over time... 15 1 5 1985 199 1995 2 25 21 (a) Mean.4.35.3.25.2.15.1.5 1985 199 1995 2 25 21 (b) Coefficient

More information

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1 Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1 Chun Chang a Zheng Liu b Mark Spiegel b a Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance b Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco International Monetary Fund

More information

WORKING PAPER NO NONTRADED GOODS, MARKET SEGMENTATION, AND EXCHANGE RATES. Michael Dotsey Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

WORKING PAPER NO NONTRADED GOODS, MARKET SEGMENTATION, AND EXCHANGE RATES. Michael Dotsey Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. WORKING PAPER NO. 06-9 NONTRADED GOODS, MARKET SEGMENTATION, AND EXCHANGE RATES Michael Dotsey Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia and Margarida Duarte Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond May 2006 Nontraded

More information

Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade

Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade Money Macro and Finance Research Group 47 th Annual Conference Jonathan Benchimol 1 This presentation does not necessarily reflect the views of

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen June 15, 2012 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations June 15, 2012 1 / 59 Introduction We construct

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Part A (Prof. Laibson): 60 minutes Part B (Prof. Barro): 60

More information

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Shutao Cao 1 Yahong Zhang 2 1 Bank of Canada 2 Western University October 21, 2014 Motivation The US experience suggests that the collapse

More information

DSGE Reno: Housing and Commodity Investment Booms in a Multisector Small Open-Economy Model

DSGE Reno: Housing and Commodity Investment Booms in a Multisector Small Open-Economy Model DSGE Reno: Housing and Commodity Investment Booms in a Multisector Small Open-Economy Model Christopher G. Gibbs University of Sydney Gabriela Nodari Reserve Bank of Australia Jonathan Hambur Reserve Bank

More information

Asset Price Bubbles and Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy

Asset Price Bubbles and Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy Asset Price Bubbles and Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy Martha López Central Bank of Colombia Sixth BIS CCA Research Conference 13 April 2015 López (Central Bank of Colombia) (Central A. P. Bubbles

More information

The New Keynesian Model

The New Keynesian Model The New Keynesian Model Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 1 / 37 Research strategy policy as systematic and predictable...the central bank s stabilization

More information

Nontradable Goods, Market Segmentation, and Exchange Rates

Nontradable Goods, Market Segmentation, and Exchange Rates Nontradable Goods, Market Segmentation, and Exchange Rates Michael Dotsey Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Margarida Duarte Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond September 2005 Preliminary and Incomplete

More information

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model Glenn D. Rudebusch Eric T. Swanson Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco John Taylor s Contributions to Monetary Theory and Policy Federal

More information

On the new Keynesian model

On the new Keynesian model Department of Economics University of Bern April 7, 26 The new Keynesian model is [... ] the closest thing there is to a standard specification... (McCallum). But it has many important limitations. It

More information

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis S. Gilchrist 1 R. Schoenle 2 J. W. Sim 3 E. Zakrajšek 3 1 Boston University and NBER 2 Brandeis University 3 Federal Reserve Board Theory and Methods in Macroeconomics

More information

The science of monetary policy

The science of monetary policy Macroeconomic dynamics PhD School of Economics, Lectures 2018/19 The science of monetary policy Giovanni Di Bartolomeo giovanni.dibartolomeo@uniroma1.it Doctoral School of Economics Sapienza University

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Advanced Macroeconomics II Professor Lorenza Rossi/Jordi Gali T.A. Daniël van Schoot, daniel.vanschoot@upf.edu Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Schedule: 28th of May (seminar 4): Exercises 1, 2 and

More information

Global commodity price uncertainty

Global commodity price uncertainty Global commodity price uncertainty ACE 218 - Canberra Brian Tran July 13, 218 1 Background and Motivation World Energy Council (217): Commodity price uncertainty is the global number one insomnia issue

More information

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks: Comment

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks: Comment Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks: Comment Johannes Pfeifer (University of Cologne) 1st Research Conference of the CEPR Network on Macroeconomic Modelling and Model Comparison (MMCN) June 2, 217

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen March 15, 2013 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations March 15, 2013 1 / 60 Introduction The

More information

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Andrea Prestipino NYU, Princeton, Federal Reserve Board 1 September 218 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the

More information

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 2013 North American Summer Meeting Ralph Lütticke 13.06.2013 1 Joint-work with Christian Bayer, Lien Pham, and Volker Tjaden 1 / 30 Research

More information

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux Online Appendix: Non-cooperative Loss Function Section 7 of the text reports the results for

More information

Euro Area and U.S. External Adjustment: The Role of Commodity Prices and Emerging Market Shocks

Euro Area and U.S. External Adjustment: The Role of Commodity Prices and Emerging Market Shocks Euro Area and U.S. External Adjustment: The Role of Commodity Prices and Emerging Market Shocks Massimo Giovannini (European Commission, Joint Research Centre) Robert Kollmann (ECARES, Université Libre

More information

Money and monetary policy in the Eurozone: an empirical analysis during crises

Money and monetary policy in the Eurozone: an empirical analysis during crises Money and monetary policy in the Eurozone: an empirical analysis during crises Money Macro and Finance Research Group 46 th Annual Conference Jonathan Benchimol 1 and André Fourçans 2 This presentation

More information

GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy

GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy Barbara Annicchiarico* Fabio Di Dio** *Department of Economics and Finance University of Rome Tor Vergata **IT Economia - SOGEI S.P.A Workshop on Central Banking,

More information

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba 1 / 52 Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba 2 / 52 Policy Practice Motivation Standard policy practice: Fiscal expansions during recessions as a means of stimulating

More information

1.3 Nominal rigidities

1.3 Nominal rigidities 1.3 Nominal rigidities two period economy households of consumers-producers monopolistic competition, price-setting uncertainty about productivity preferences t=1 C it is the CES aggregate with σ > 1 Ã!

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. Monetary policy, incomplete asset markets, and welfare in a small open economy

Volume 35, Issue 1. Monetary policy, incomplete asset markets, and welfare in a small open economy Volume 35, Issue 1 Monetary policy, incomplete asset markets, and welfare in a small open economy Shigeto Kitano Kobe University Kenya Takaku Aichi Shukutoku University Abstract We develop a small open

More information

Escaping the Great Recession 1

Escaping the Great Recession 1 Escaping the Great Recession 1 Francesco Bianchi Duke University Leonardo Melosi FRB Chicago ECB workshop on Non-Standard Monetary Policy Measures 1 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility

More information

On the Implications of Structural Transformation for Inflation and Monetary Policy (Work in Progress)

On the Implications of Structural Transformation for Inflation and Monetary Policy (Work in Progress) On the Implications of Structural Transformation for Inflation and Monetary Policy (Work in Progress) Rafael Portillo and Luis Felipe Zanna IMF Workshop on Fiscal and Monetary Policy in Low Income Countries

More information

International Trade Fluctuations and Monetary Policy

International Trade Fluctuations and Monetary Policy International Trade Fluctuations and Monetary Policy Fernando Leibovici York University Ana Maria Santacreu St. Louis Fed and INSEAD August 14 Abstract This paper studies the role of trade openness for

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) MACRO-LINKAGES, OIL PRICES AND DEFLATION WORKSHOP JANUARY 6 9, 2009 Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) Credit Frictions and

More information

Macro Modelling: From the Financial Crisis to the Long Slump in the EA

Macro Modelling: From the Financial Crisis to the Long Slump in the EA Macro Modelling: From the Financial Crisis to the Long Slump in the EA Werner Roeger (European Commission, DG ECFIN) April 216 The views expressed in this presentation are those of the author and should

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles 2. Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March Main idea: introduce nominal rigidities Why? in classical monetary models the price level ensures money

More information

Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model

Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model 1 / 29 Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model Chiara Forlati 1 Luisa Lambertini 1 1 École Polytechnique Fédérale de Lausanne CMSG November 6, 21 2 / 29 Motivation The global financial crisis started with an increase

More information

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Mitsuru Katagiri International Monetary Fund October 24, 2017 @Keio University 1 / 42 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions A. Notarpietro S. Siviero Banca d Italia 1 Housing, Stability and the Macroeconomy: International Perspectives Dallas Fed

More information

Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model

Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model Bundesbank and Goethe-University Frankfurt Department of Money and Macroeconomics January 24th, 212 Bank of England Motivation

More information

Multistep prediction error decomposition in DSGE models: estimation and forecast performance

Multistep prediction error decomposition in DSGE models: estimation and forecast performance Multistep prediction error decomposition in DSGE models: estimation and forecast performance George Kapetanios Simon Price Kings College, University of London Essex Business School Konstantinos Theodoridis

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Cúrdia FRB New York Michael Woodford Columbia University Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial Frictions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions

More information

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013 .. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective Gary Hansen (UCLA) and Selo İmrohoroğlu (USC) May 10, 2013 Table of Contents.1 Introduction.2 Model Economy.3 Calibration.4 Quantitative

More information

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle: Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia May 31, 214 Midwest Macro Conference Raju Huidrom Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle Background

More information

a Small Uganda Francis Monetary Policy Open-Economy Model for Tel: +27 Working February

a Small Uganda Francis Monetary Policy Open-Economy Model for Tel: +27 Working February University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series Monetary Policy and Financial Frictions in a Small Uganda Francis Leni Anguyo University of Cape Town Rangann Gupta University of Pretoria

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

Terms of Trade Shocks and Investment in Commodity-Exporting Economies 1

Terms of Trade Shocks and Investment in Commodity-Exporting Economies 1 Terms of Trade Shocks and Investment in Commodity-Exporting Economies Jorge Fornero Markus Kirchner Andrés Yany Research Division Central Bank of Chile XXXII Economist Meeting of the Central Bank of Peru

More information

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility Luca Dedola and Anton Nakov ECB and CEPR May 24 Dedola and Nakov (ECB and CEPR) SDP and the Paradox of Flexibility 5/4 / 28 Policy rates in major

More information

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

Asset Pricing in Production Economies Urban J. Jermann 1998 Presented By: Farhang Farazmand October 16, 2007 Motivation Can we try to explain the asset pricing puzzles and the macroeconomic business cycles, in one framework. Motivation: Equity

More information

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis S. Gilchrist 1 1 Boston University and NBER MFM Summer Camp June 12, 2016 DISCLAIMER: The views expressed are solely the responsibility of the authors and

More information

MONETARY POLICY REGIMES AND CAPITAL ACCOUNT RESTRICTIONS IN A SMALL OPEN ECONOMY

MONETARY POLICY REGIMES AND CAPITAL ACCOUNT RESTRICTIONS IN A SMALL OPEN ECONOMY MONETARY POLICY REGIMES AND CAPITAL ACCOUNT RESTRICTIONS IN A SMALL OPEN ECONOMY ZHENG LIU AND MARK M. SPIEGEL Abstract. The recent financial crisis has led to large declines in world interest rates and

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Economics 3307 - Intermediate Macroeconomics Aaron Hedlund Baylor University Fall 2013 Econ 3307 (Baylor University) The Real Business Cycle Model Fall 2013 1 / 23 Business

More information

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates at the effective lower bound for interest rates Bank of England 12 March 2010 Plan Introduction The model The policy problem Results Summary & conclusions Plan Introduction Motivation Aims and scope The

More information

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability Hilde C. Bjørnland Vegard H. Larsen Centre for Applied Macro- and Petroleum Economics (CAMP) BI Norwegian Business School CFE-ERCIM December 07, 2014 Bjørnland and Larsen

More information

Learning About Commodity Cycles and Saving-Investment Dynamics in a Commodity-Exporting Economy

Learning About Commodity Cycles and Saving-Investment Dynamics in a Commodity-Exporting Economy Learning About Commodity Cycles and Saving-Investment Dynamics in a Commodity-Exporting Economy Jorge Fornero Markus Kirchner Central Bank of Chile, Macroeconomic Analysis Division Fifth BIS CCA Research

More information

Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB

Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB Charles Brendon (Cambridge) Matthias Paustian (Board of Governors) Tony Yates (Birmingham) August 2016 Introduction This paper is about recession dynamics at the ZLB

More information

Do Central Banks Respond to Exchange Rate Movements? Some New Evidence from Structural Estimation

Do Central Banks Respond to Exchange Rate Movements? Some New Evidence from Structural Estimation Do Central Banks Respond to Exchange Rate Movements? Some New Evidence from Structural Estimation Wei Dong International Department Bank of Canada June 3, 28 Abstract This paper investigates the impact

More information

Welfare Effects of Commodity Price and Exchange Rate Volatilities in a Multi-Sector SOE Model

Welfare Effects of Commodity Price and Exchange Rate Volatilities in a Multi-Sector SOE Model Welfare Effects of Commodity Price and Exchange Rate Volatilities in a Multi-Sector SOE Model Ali Dib May 24, 26 Preliminary and incomplete version. Comments are very welcomed. Please, do not quote. Abstract

More information

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Reforms in a Debt Overhang Structural Javier Andrés, Óscar Arce and Carlos Thomas 3 National Bank of Belgium, June 8 4 Universidad de Valencia, Banco de España Banco de España 3 Banco de España National Bank of Belgium, June 8 4

More information

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles Conférence organisée par la Chaire des Amériques et le Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne, Université Paris I Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles Sarquis J. B. Sarquis

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Andrea Prestipino NYU, Princeton, Federal Reserve Board 1 March 218 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors

More information

Investment Specific Technology Shocks and Emerging Market Business Cycle Dynamics

Investment Specific Technology Shocks and Emerging Market Business Cycle Dynamics Col.lecció d Economia E17/359 Investment Specific Technology Shocks and Emerging Market Business Cycle Dynamics Aydan Dogan UB Economics Working Papers 2017/359 Investment Specific Technology Shocks and

More information

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment Chapter 6 Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment In Romer s IS/MP/IA model, we assume prices/inflation adjust imperfectly when output changes. Empirically, there is a negative relationship

More information

A Model with Costly-State Verification

A Model with Costly-State Verification A Model with Costly-State Verification Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania December 19, 2012 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 1 / 47 A Model with Costly-State

More information

WORKING PAPER SERIES 15. Juraj Antal and František Brázdik: The Effects of Anticipated Future Change in the Monetary Policy Regime

WORKING PAPER SERIES 15. Juraj Antal and František Brázdik: The Effects of Anticipated Future Change in the Monetary Policy Regime WORKING PAPER SERIES 5 Juraj Antal and František Brázdik: The Effects of Anticipated Future Change in the Monetary Policy Regime 7 WORKING PAPER SERIES The Effects of Anticipated Future Change in the Monetary

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations in a SOE model with Segmented Labour Markets: the case of Canada

Unemployment Fluctuations in a SOE model with Segmented Labour Markets: the case of Canada Unemployment Fluctuations in a SOE model with Segmented Labour Markets: the case of Canada Yahong Zhang March 17, 213 Abstract A distinct feature of recent financial crisis in Canada is that the job loss

More information

Lecture 4. Extensions to the Open Economy. and. Emerging Market Crises

Lecture 4. Extensions to the Open Economy. and. Emerging Market Crises Lecture 4 Extensions to the Open Economy and Emerging Market Crises Mark Gertler NYU June 2009 0 Objectives Develop micro-founded open-economy quantitative macro model with real/financial interactions

More information

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont) Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont) 1 New Keynesian Model Demand is an Euler equation x t = E t x t+1 ( ) 1 σ (i t E t π t+1 ) + u t Supply is New Keynesian Phillips Curve π

More information

Volatility Risk Pass-Through

Volatility Risk Pass-Through Volatility Risk Pass-Through Ric Colacito Max Croce Yang Liu Ivan Shaliastovich 1 / 18 Main Question Uncertainty in a one-country setting: Sizeable impact of volatility risks on growth and asset prices

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice. for Emerging Market Countries

Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice. for Emerging Market Countries Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice for Emerging Market Countries Masato Takahashi Master of Philosophy University of York Department of Economics and Related Studies July 2011 Abstract This thesis includes

More information

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture Barbara Annicchiarico BBLM del Dipartimento del Tesoro 2 Giugno 2. Annicchiarico (Università di Tor Vergata) (Institute) Microfoundations of DSGE Models 2 Giugno

More information

Housing Prices and Growth

Housing Prices and Growth Housing Prices and Growth James A. Kahn June 2007 Motivation Housing market boom-bust has prompted talk of bubbles. But what are fundamentals? What is the right benchmark? Motivation Housing market boom-bust

More information

Long run rates and monetary policy

Long run rates and monetary policy Long run rates and monetary policy 2017 IAAE Conference, Sapporo, Japan, 06/26-30 2017 Gianni Amisano (FRB), Oreste Tristani (ECB) 1 IAAE 2017 Sapporo 6/28/2017 1 Views expressed here are not those of

More information

Booms and Banking Crises

Booms and Banking Crises Booms and Banking Crises F. Boissay, F. Collard and F. Smets Macro Financial Modeling Conference Boston, 12 October 2013 MFM October 2013 Conference 1 / Disclaimer The views expressed in this presentation

More information

Evolving Macroeconomic dynamics in a small open economy: An estimated Markov Switching DSGE model for the UK

Evolving Macroeconomic dynamics in a small open economy: An estimated Markov Switching DSGE model for the UK Evolving Macroeconomic dynamics in a small open economy: An estimated Markov Switching DSGE model for the UK Philip Liu Haroon Mumtaz April 8, Abstract This paper investigates the possibility of shifts

More information

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II ECON 815 A Basic New Keynesian Model II Winter 2015 Queen s University ECON 815 1 Unemployment vs. Inflation 12 10 Unemployment 8 6 4 2 0 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 Core Inflation 14 12 10 Unemployment

More information

Endogenous Trade Participation with Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass-Through

Endogenous Trade Participation with Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass-Through Endogenous Trade Participation with Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass-Through Yuko Imura Bank of Canada June 28, 23 Disclaimer The views expressed in this presentation, or in my remarks, are my own, and do

More information