Unemployment Fluctuations in a SOE model with Segmented Labour Markets: the case of Canada

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Unemployment Fluctuations in a SOE model with Segmented Labour Markets: the case of Canada"

Transcription

1 Unemployment Fluctuations in a SOE model with Segmented Labour Markets: the case of Canada Yahong Zhang March 17, 213 Abstract A distinct feature of recent financial crisis in Canada is that the job loss is not evenly distributed across industries. Manufacturing industries have been more affected than others: despite employing only about 2% of the total labour force, they account for over one-half of the total job loss during the financial crisis. To capture the labour market differences at the industry level, I introduce a segmented labour market structure to a medium-scale DSGE model with financial and labour market frictions. I estimate the model using Canadian data from 1991Q1 to 21Q4. I find that the degrees of labour and financial market frictions are indeed different between tradable and non-tradable sectors. Compared with the tradable sector, the elasticity of external finance for the non-tradable sector is almost 1 times higher; and the average wage contract is about 2 times longer. I also find the significant sectoral differences are mainly explained by sectoral specific technology and financial shocks. Overall, the technology and financial shocks in the two sectors explain more than a half of the fluctuations in unemployment in the Canadian labour market. JEL: classification: E32;E44; J6 Keywords: Segmented labour market; Unemployment; Financial frictions and shocks; 1

2 1 Introduction The recent financial crisis and the following recession have induced great interests in searching for the sources of unemployment fluctuations, particularly in exploring the importance of the frictions and shocks in the financial sector for explaining labour market dynamics. Recent works, Christiano, Trabandt and Walentin (211) and Zhang (211a and b), have applied Baynesian maximum likelihood method to estimate medium scale DSGE models to assess the contribution of a variety of shocks to unemployment fluctuations, with the focus on the contribution of financial shocks relatively to other shocks. Christiano, Trabandt and Walentin (211) find that domestic markup shock is the most important shock, explaining more than 2 per cent of unemployment fluctuations in the Swedish economy, and that financial wealth shock explains about 1 per cent; Zhang (211a and b) find that technology, investment and financial wealth shocks account for most of the unemployment fluctuations in the US and Canada, with financial wealth shocks explaining about 3 per cent of the fluctuations. In these studies, there is one aggregate labour market. However, economies consist of multiple sectors, and different sectors of the economy behave differently over the course of business cycles. In fact, one distinct feature related to the recent recession is that job loss is not evenly distributed across sectors. In Canada, during the financial crisis, unemployment rate rose from 6.3% to 8.6%, and total job loss amounted to 4,. Manufacturing industries have been more affected than others: despite employing only about 2% of the total labour force, they account for over onehalf of the total job loss. There is also a significant difference in employment dynamics between manufacturing and the services industries: employment in the manufacturing sector is almost 3 times as volatile as in the non-tradable sector. These facts point to significant differences in labour flows across Canadian industries. Shocks at the sectoral level may require resource to move from the contracting sectors to expanding sectors. If resources are not fully mobile between sectors, sectoral specific shocks will play an important role in shaping the movements in unemployment at the aggregate level. The standard one-sector, one-good models with one aggregate labour market are not equipped to address this issue since they assume away sectoral differences. In order to capture the sectoral differences, I introduce a segmented labour market structure into a multiple sector small open economy model with both financial land labour market frictions. I model the financial and labour market frictions in a similar way as Christiano, Trabandt and Walentin (211) and Zhang (211a and b): financial frictions are introduced a la Bernarke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1999) to finance capital acquisition, entrepreneurs in each sector need to pay risk premium in order to obtain external funds from financiers, and the risk premium depends on entrepreneurs balance-sheet positions; labour market frictions are modeled using Mortensen- Passiridis-Diamond framework which assumes that there are search frictions in the labour market and unemployment is an equilibrium outcome. The new feature of the model is the segmented labour market structure. There are two separate labour markets in the model: one for manufacturing industries (tradable sector), and one for services industries (non-tradable sector). The labour market

3 parameters are sector-specific. As a result, in one sector, the labour market may be tighter than the other (higher vacancy to unemployment ratio), and wage contract may be less sticky than the other. These features, from unemployed workers perspective, make the labour market in this sector less frictional, because it is easier for them to find jobs. In addition, the frictions related to labour mobility are modeled in the following way: For the workers who are willing to move across sectors, they have to be separated from jobs in one sector first to become unemployed. The separation rate is exogenously given. Once unemployed, they have the chance to search for jobs in the other sector and the probability of finding a job depends on the labour market tightness in that sector. I estimate the model using Canadian data from 1991Q1 to 21Q4. The main findings are as follows: First, given that none of the labour market variables is used in the estimation, the model performs particularly well in terms of matching the key features in the labour market: it not only matches the fact that aggregate unemployment is much more volatile than output; but also generates labour market dynamics differences in the sectoral level. In particular, the model is able to capture the fact that both employment and wages in the tradable sector are more volatile than that in the non-tradable sector. Second, the estimation results show that the degree of frictions in the labour and financial markets are indeed different for the two sectors: Compared to the tradable sector, the elasticity of external finance for the non-tradable sector is almost 1 times higher; and the average wage contract is about 2 times longer. Third, I find that unemployment fluctuations in the Canadian labour market are mainly driving by the technology shock in the non-tradable sector and financial wealth shocks in both sectors. Technology shock in the non-tradable sector is much more persistent than the tradable sector and explains almost 3 percent of the unemployment fluctuations in the Canadian labour market. Financial wealth shock in the tradable sector is more volatile but less persistent than in the non-tradable sector. Together, financial wealth shocks in the two sectors explain about 25 per cent of total unemployment variations. The paper is organized as follows. In the next section, I document some empirical facts regarding sectoral differences. In section 3, I describe the model. In section 4 I discuss the data and estimation strategy. In section 5, I present the estimation results and discuss the effect of the sectoral specific shocks on aggregate unemployment fluctuations. In section 6 I offer some concluding remarks. 2 Sectoral Difference: Some Empirical Facts 2.1 Output, employment and wage Throughout the paper, the tradable sector refers to manufacturing industries, and the non-tradable sector refers to the rest of the economy but excludes agriculture and natural resources. 1 The data used in this section and estimation are from the Statistics Canada. Output is measured by real GDP and expressed in per capita terms using the civilian population aged 15 and up. Wage is measured 1 The non-tradable sector includes utility, construction, wholesale and retail trade, transportation, information, finance and insurance, professional services, administrative and support, waste management, education and health and arts. 2

4 Table 1: Standard Deviations: tradable vs non-tradable Output Employment Wage Tradable Non-tradable Relative volatility using index of average hourly earnings. All the three series are logged and detrended using an HP filter with smoothing parameter 16. Figures 1-2 plot the output, employment and wage for the tradable and non-tradable sectors for the sample period 1991Q1 to 21Q4, and they clearly show all three variables are more volatile in the tradable sector than that in the non-tradable sector. Table 1 provides the standard deviations of output, employment and wages for the two sectors. The relative volatility in the third row is computed by normalizing the standard deviations of the three variables in the tradable sector to their non-tradable counterparts. Table 1 further quantifies the difference in volatilities across the two sectors: output in the tradable sector is about 4 times as volatile as that in the non-tradable sector; employment is about 3 times, and wage is about 2 times. 3 The Model I consider a small open economy which consists of three sectors: tradable, non-tradable and imported-goods sectors. Labour markets for the tradable and non-tradable sectors are segmented. In each labour market, employment agencies post vacancies and hire workers seeking jobs in that sector. The sector-specific employment agencies supply labour services to the entrepreneurs in that sector, who produce sector-specific intermediate goods using labour services and capital. Since entrepreneurs need to borrow to finance capital purchases, they are subject to financial frictions. Entrepreneurs supply intermediate goods to retailers in each sector, which produce final goods. A representative household with a large family structure has a fraction of its members are unemployed, the rest are either employed in the tradable or non-tradable sector. The household consumes, saves both in domestic bonds and foreign bonds, pays tax and receives profits from retailers in each sector. In addition, there are capital producers, a government that balances the budget, and a central bank that implements a simple interest rate rule. In what follows, I describe the role of each agent in the model. 3.1 Household Each member in the household consumes, holds both nominal domestic bonds B t and foreign bonds Bt which are denominated in foreign currency, receives dividends from retailers Π t, and pays taxes T t. At time t, a fraction of household members are employed, n t, and a fraction of household members are unemployed u t = 1 n t. For the employed household members, n T t of them are employed in the tradable sector, and n N t of them are employed in the non-tradable sector. For the 3

5 unemployed household members, u T t of them search for jobs in the tradable sector, and u N t of them search for jobs in the non-tradable sector. The employed family members earn nominal wages Wt T and Wt N respectively. The unemployed members receive unemployment benefits ub t. Following Andolfatto (1996) and Merz (1995), family members are assumed to be perfectly insured against the risk of becoming unemployed. Thus consumption is the same for each family member. The budget constraint for the representative household is where both W T t P t c t + B t + e tb t κ t R t and W N t + T t W T,t n T,t + W N,t n N,t + ub t (1 n t ) + R t 1 B t 1 + e t R t 1B t 1 + Π t, (1) are determined by Nash bargaining between employment agencies and workers. The labour supply n T t and n N t are determined by a search and match process. e t is nominal exchange rate. The return on the foreign bonds, κ t R t, depends on the foreign interest rate R t and a country-specific risk premium κ t, which is assumed to be an increasing function of the net foreign-debt-to-gdp ratio: κ t = exp ( υ e t B t P t y t where υ >, y t is real GDP and B t is the total level of indebtedness of the economy. Given the budget constraint equation (1), the representative household chooses c t, B t, and Bt to maximize the lifetime utility with E t= β t u(c t ), c 1 σ t u(c t ) = µ t 1 σ, where c t is consumption of final goods in period t and where µ t is a preference shock which follows The first-order conditions yield: log µ t = ρ µ log µ t 1 + ɛ µ t, ɛ µ t i.i.d. N(, σ 2 ɛ µ). ), [ ] Rt λ t+1 µ t+1 λ t µ t = βe t, (2) π t+1 [ ] R λ t µ t = βe t κ t s t+1 λ t+1 µ t+1 t, (3) s t πt+1 where π t = P t /P t 1 is the CPI inflation rate and s t = e t Pt /P t is the real exchange rate, where is a foreign price index. Equations (2) and (3) imply the uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) P t 4

6 condition: 3.2 Employment agencies R t κ t R t = e t+1 e t. Following Christiano, Trabandt and Waletin (211), I model employment agencies as intermediaries between the representative household (who supply labour) and entrepreneurs (who demand labour to produce wholesale goods). 2 The labour market is modeled using a standard search framework. On the one hand, the employment agencies post vacancies, and bargain wages with workers; on the other hand, they combine labour supplied by households into homogeneous labour services and supply them to entrepreneurs at a competitive price. The labour market is segmented. Employment agencies in the tradable sector (non-tradable) only post vacancies in the tradable (non-tradable) sector. Unemployed workers need to decide which sector jobs to search. Unemployed workers seeking for tradable sector jobs are denoted as u T,t, and those seeking for non-tradable sector jobs are denoted as u N,t. In equilibrium, searching for jobs in each sector gives the same expected payoff. In the beginning of period t, in each sector i, employment agency j employs n i,t (j) workers, and posts v i,t (j) vacancies to attract new workers. The total number of vacancies and the number of employed workers are denoted as v i,t = v i,t (j)dj and n i,t = n i,t (j)dj. The number of unemployed workers at the beginning of period t is u t = 1 n t = 1 n T,t n N,t = u T,t + u N,t. The number of new hires m i,t is given by a standard Cobb-Douglas aggregate matching technology m i, t = µ i,m u σm i,t v1 σm i,t. For an employment agency, the value of adding another worker at time t is the price of selling one unit of labour service p l i,t, minus the wage cost wn i,t (i) p i,t and vacancy costs κ i x 2 i,t(j) 2, plus the continuation value of a filled vacancy: J i,t (j) = p l i,t wn i,t(j) p i,t κ i, 2 x i,t(j) 2 + (ρ i + x i,t (j))βe t Λ t,t+1 J i,t+1 (j), where x i,t (j) is the hiring rate for employment agency j, and ρ i is the probability of a match that survives to the next period. The value of employment, V i,t (j), is V i,t (j) = w i,t (j) + βe t Λ t,t+1 [ρv i,t+1 (j) + (1 ρ)u i,t+1 ], 2 This leaves the equilibrium conditions associated with the production of wholesale goods unaffected, although the labour market is frictional. 5

7 where w i,t (j) is the real wage. The value of unemployment, U i,t, is U i,t = ub t + βe t Λ t,t+1 [s l i,t+1v i,t+1 + (1 s l i,t+1)u i,t+1 ], where ub t is the unemployment benefit, s l i,t+1 is the probability of finding a job next period, and V i,t is the average value of employment for a new worker at time t. 3 The workers surplus for having a job at employment agency j, H i,t (j), is H i,t (j) = V i,t (j) U i,t. Given that it implies that U T,t = U N,t, βe t Λ t,t+1 s l T,t+1H T,t (j) = βe t Λ t,t+1 s l N,t+1H N,t (j). Thus, for an unemployed worker, the expected payoff of searching for either sector jobs must be equal. In equilibrium, a lower job finding rate in one sector must be compensated by a relatively higher surplus of having a job in that sector. Employment agencies and workers negotiate a nominal wage w n i,t(j) to maximize the joint product of the workers surplus H i,t (j) and the employment agencies surplus J i,t (j). However, every period, each employment agency only has a fixed probability 1 λ to negotiate with workers. Thus, the Nash bargaining problem between employment agencies and workers is s.t. max H i,t (j) η J i,t (j) 1 η, w n i,t(j) = w n i,t with probability 1 λ = w n i,t 1π with probability λ, where π is the steady-state inflation rate. The equation for the real wage w i,t derived from this staggered contracting is: t w i,t = η(p l i,t + κ i 2 x2 i,t(i)) + (1 η)( b + s i,t+1 βλ t,t+1 H i,t+s+1 ) +λρβe t Λ t,t+1 t+1 w i,t+1. (4) The first term of equation (4) is the worker s contribution to the match, and the second is the worker s opportunity cost. These are conventional components for Nash bargaining solutions for wages. The third term is from the staggered multi-period contracting. Finally, the aggregate real wage w i,t can 3 See Gertler and Trigari (29) for details about the average value of employment. 6

8 be expressed as w i,t = (1 λ)w i,t + λπ 1 π i,t w i,t Entrepreneurs There are entrepreneurs in both the tradable and non-tradable sectors. Following Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1999), entrepreneurs are risk-neutral and have a finite life. In each sector i, at each period t, entrepreneur j uses capital k i, t and labour services l i,t to produce wholesale goods y i, t using a Cobb-Douglas technology: where z i,t is the technology shock which follows y i,t (j) = z i,t (k i,t (j)) α (l i, t (j)) 1 α. log z i,t = ρ z,i log z i,t 1 + ɛ z i t, ɛ z i i,t i.i.d.n(, σ2 ɛ z i). Entrepreneurs purchase capital at price q i,t from capital producers, using both their own net worth N i,t and bank loans. Bank loans can be from domestic market, B i,t, or from international market B i,t. 4 Entrepreneurs can default due to idiosyncratic shocks. Since only entrepreneurs observe the realization of the idiosyncratic shocks, the optimal loan contract in Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1999) is such that entrepreneurs pay a risk premium on loans. Thus for domestic loans, the external finance premium, s(.), depends on the entrepreneur s balance-sheet position. At the aggregate level it can be characterized by ( ) qi,t k i,t+1 rp i,t = s, (5) N i,t+1 where rp (.) > and rp(1) = 1. Equation (5) expresses that in each sector, the external finance premium increases with leverage. For the loans from the international market, the entrepreneurs are subject to country-specific risk premium κ i,t : ( κ i,t = exp υ i e t B i,t q i,t k i,t+1 N i,t where υ i > is a parameter determining the relative size of b i,t (j) and b i,t(j) for each sector. The one-period profit function for entrepreneurs j is: 4 IMF country report (28) suggests that a quarter of financing of Canadian corporations is raised in the U.S. Data source from Statistic Canada also suggests the same. The survey of suppliers of business financing suggests that in 28, almost 2 per cent of the total debt is foreign debt. For the manufacturing industries, the fraction is even higher close to 3 per cent. Although there is a slight decrease after 28, foreign debt remains a significant portion of total debt financing for Canadian corporations, especially for manufacturing industry. ), 7

9 π i,t (j) = B i,t(j) + e tbi,t(j) + p w P t P i,ty j i,t + q i,t(1 δ)k i,t (j) t p l B i,t 1 (j) e i,tl i,t (j) R t 1 rp i,t 1 R t Bi,t 1(j) P t 1κ i,t 1 t P t q i,t k i,t+1 (j), (6) where p w i,t is the relative price for the wholesale goods in sector i, and p l i,t is the labor service price. The entrepreneur j chooses l i,t (j), k i,t+1 (j), b i,t (j) and b i,t(j) to maximize E t= β t π i,t (j). The first order conditions yields: and l i,t (j) : p w y i,t (j) i,t l i,t (j) = pl i,t, (7) k i,t+1 (j) : q i,t + E t β[p w y i,t+1 (j) i,t+1 k i,t+1 (j) + q i,t+1(1 δ)] =, (8) Define the expected return on capital in each sector as b i,t (j) : 1 E t β[ R trp i,t π t+1 ] =. (9) b i,t(j) : 1 E t β[ s t+1rt κ i,t ] =. (1) s t πt+1 E t r k i,t+1 = E t[p w i,t+1α yi,t+1 k i,t+1 + q i,t+1 (1 δ)] q i,t. In each sector, the expected return on capital must equal to the expected costs of external finance E t r k i,t+1 = E t β[ R trp i,t π t+1 ]. The demand for foreign debt for each sector is determined by E t ri,t+1 k = E t β[ s t+1rt κ i ]. s t πt+1 Finally, the aggregate net worth in each sector is given by N i,t+1 = γ i,t η e i (r k i,tq i,t 1 k i,t R t 1rp i,t 1 π t b i,n,t 1 s trt 1κ i,t 1 b s t 1 π i,t 1), t 8

10 where η e i is the survival rate of entrepreneurs for each sector. γ i,t is a financial wealth shock, an exogenous shock to the survival probability of entrepreneurs in sector i. It follows an AR(1) process: log γ i,t = ρ γ log γ i,t 1 + ɛ γ t, ɛ γ i,t i.i.d. N(, σ2 ɛ z). For the entrepreneurs that are going out of business, they consume their residue equity: ce i,t+1 = (1 γ i,t η e i )(r k i,tq i,t 1 k i,t R t 1rp i,t 1 π t b i,t 1 s trt 1κ i,t 1 rp i,t b s t 1 π i,t 1), t The aggregate demand for labour services is relatively simple. Given that the aggregate production function is constant returns to scale, y i,t = k i,t α (z i,t l i,t ) 1 α, the aggregate labour demand equation can be written as p w i,t(1 α) y i,t l i,t = p l i,t, where l i,t is the labour services supplied by employment agencies in sector i, (1 α) y i,t l i,t is the marginal product of labour services, p w i,t is the relative price for wholesale goods and p l i,t is the relative price for labour services. 3.4 Capital producers Capital producers use investment goods to produce new capital purchased from entrepreneurs. At the end of the period t, they buy investment goods I t, at real price p I,t = P I,t /P t to produce sectorspecific capital that can be used by entrepreneurs at time t + 1. Capital production in each sector is assumed to be subject to an investment-specific shock, τ i,t, which follows an AR(1) process log τ i,t = ρ i,x log τ i,t 1 + ɛ τ i,t, ɛ τ i,t i.i.d.n(, σ 2 ɛ τ i ). Following Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (25), we assume that capital producers in sector i = {T, N} face investment adjustment costs S(I i,t, I i,t 1 ), such that in steady state S = S = and S >, and ξ i > is an investment adjustment cost parameter. The production of each capital stock yields the following time-t profit function The aggregate stock of capital evolves as follows: Π i t = q i,t I i,t τ i,t q i,t I i,t S(I i,t, I i,t 1 ) p I,t I i,t. (11) K i,t+1 = I i,t τ i,t I i,t S(I i,t, I i,t 1 ) + (1 δ)k i,t. (12) 9

11 3.5 Sectoral good producers There are sectoral good producers in all three sectors: tradable, non-tradable and imported good sectors. The sectoral good producers in the tradable and non-tradable sectors buy tradable, nontradable input from entrepreneurs, and those in imported good sector buy foreign homogeneous intermediate inputs, and differentiate them slightly into z i,t (j) and sell the product at price p i,t (j). The final good for each sector i, z i,t, is the composite of individual variety, [ 1 z i,t = ] ε y i,t (j) ε 1 ε 1 ε dj. The price index that minimizes the sectoral good producers cost function is [ 1 p i,t = ] 1 p i,t (j) 1 ε 1 ε dj. Following Calvo (1983), in each period, only a fraction 1 ν i of retailers reset their prices, while the remaining retailers keep their prices unchanged. The retailer chooses p i,t (j) to maximize its expected real total profit over the periods during which its prices remain fixed: [( ) ] E t Σ i=ν p pi,t (j) i,t+i y i,t+i (j) mc i,t+i y i,t+i (j), p i,t+i where mc i,t is the real marginal cost, which is the price of wholesale goods relative to the price of sectoral final goods (p i,w,t /p i,t ). The real marginal cost for imported intermediate goods is e t Pt for a given nominal exchange rate, e t, and foreign price level, Pt. p t,i βi c t+i /c t is the stochastic discount factor. Let p t be the optimal price chosen by all firms adjusting at time t. The first-order condition is: ( ) ε Et p s= i,t = νs p 1 s,t+smc i,t+1 y i,t+i ( p i,t+i ) ε ε 1 E t s= νs p 1. s,t+sy i,t+i ( p i,t+i ) 1 ε The aggregate price evolves according to: p i,t = [ν i p 1 ε i,t 1 + (1 ν i)(p i,t) 1 ε ] 1 1 ε. Retailers in the tradable sector produce goods for domestic use, zt,t d, and exports, ze T,t, so that z T,t = zt,t d +ze T,t. Following Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995), we assume the producers currency pricing behavior in the manufacturing sector. Thus, the law of one price holds for exported domestic goods. However, due to the presence of nominal rigidities in the import sector, exchange rate movements are partially passed through to domestic prices. The aggregate foreign demand function for exports 1

12 of manufactured goods is ( zt,t e et P T,t = ϖ P t ) ν Y t, (13) where Yt is foreign output. The elasticity of demand for domestic manufactured goods among foreigners is ν, and ϖ > is a parameter determining the fraction of domestic manufacturedgoods exports in foreign spending. 3.6 Aggregate final goods producers There is a representative firm that acts in a perfectly competitive market and uses sectoral output to produce final consumption and investment goods, x j t, with j = {C, I}, according to the following CES technology: x j t = [ (ω j T ) 1 ) ν j (z ν j 1 d,j ν j T,t ( ) 1 + ω j ν j N ( ) z j ν j 1 ν j N,t + ( ) ω j 1 ν j F ( z j F,t ) ν j 1 ν j ] νj ν j 1, (14) where ω j T, ωj N, and ωj F denote the shares of domestically-used tradable, non-tradable, and imported composite sectoral goods, z d,j N,t,zj N,t,zj F,t, respectively, in the final good, where ωj T + ωj T + ωj F = 1, and ν j > is the elasticity of substitution between sectoral goods. p j t = [ (ω j T ) 1 ν j ( ) p j 1 νj ( ) 1 T,t + ω j ν j N ( ) p j 1 νj ( ) 1 N,t + ω j ν j F ] ( ) p j 1 ν 1 j 1 ν j F,t. (15) 3.7 Government The government is assumed to balance its budget, where g t follows an AR(1) process, g t = T t, log g t = (1 ρ x ) log g ss + ρ x log g t 1 + ɛ g t, ɛ g t i.i.d.n(, σ 2 ɛ g). 3.8 Monetary policy rules The central bank adjusts the nominal interest rate r n t according to a simple interest rate rule: r n t r n = (rn t 1 r n )ρr (( π t π )ρπ ( y t y )ρy ) 1 ρr e ɛm t, where r n, π and y are the steady-state values of rt n, π t and y t, and ε m t that follows i.i.d. N(, σ ε m). ε m t is a monetary policy shock 11

13 ρ π, ρ y and ρ r are policy coefficients chosen by the central bank. 3.9 Rest of the world Given that Canada is a small open economy, I assume that domestic developments do not affect the rest of the world. However, the foreign economy has an impact on the Canadian economy. Following Dib, Mendicino and Zhang (28), for simplicity, I assume that the foreign output, foreign interest rate, and inflation exogenous and follow AR(1) processes. 3.1 Aggregation and equilibrium The resource constraint is z t k α t l t 1 α = c t + i t + g t + κ N 2 x2 N,tn N,t + κ T 2 x2 T,tn T,t + ce T + ce N. Furthermore, for the labour market, l T,t = n T,t, and 4 Estimation 4.1 Calibrated values l N,t = n N,t. I use Bayesian techniques to estimate the model for the Canadian economy. I use and the data sample spans from 1991Q1 to 21Q4. Some parameters need to be calibrated to match the salient features of the Canadian economy, Table 2 reports these parameters and their calibrated values. For most of the parameters that govern the sectoral shares, I use the calibrated values in Dib, Mendicino and Zhang (28). The calibrated value for the discount factor, β, is set to.99, which implies an annual steady-state real interest rate of 4 percent which matches the average observed in the estimation sample. The curvature parameter in the utility function, γ, is set to 2, implying an elasticity of intertemporal substitution of.5. The capital shares in the production of tradable and non-tradable goods, α T and α N, are set to.35 and.3, which are close to the values suggested by Macklem et al. (2). The capital depreciation rate, δ, is assumed to be common to both tradable and non-tradable sectors and set to.25, a value commonly used in the literature. The shares of tradable, non-tradable, and imported goods in the production of consumption good, ωt C, ωc N, and ωf C, equal.1,.57 and.33, respectively, to match the average ratios observed in the data for the estimation period. Since the share of imported good in the production of the investment good is higher than that in consumption good production. I set ωt I, ωi N, and ωi F equal to.2,.4 and.4, respectively. 12

14 The parameter measuring the degree of monopoly power in the intermediate-goods markets, θ, is set to be equal to 6, which implies a 2 percent markup in the steady-state. Based on Dib (23), both the elasticity of substitution between tradable, non-tradable and imported goods in the production of final consumption goods, ν C, and the elasticity of demand for domestic manufacturedgoods among foreigners, ν, are set equal to.8. The elasticity of substitution between tradable, non-tradable and imported goods in the production of final investment goods, ν I, is set equal to.6, implying that imported goods are less substitutable in producing investment than against the consumption good production. The steady-state gross domestic and foreign inflation rates, π and π, equal 1.48 and 1.52, respectively, which are the historical averages over the estimation sample for Canada and the U.S. Following Dib, Mendicino and Zhang (28), I calibrate the parameter υ to match a foreign-debtto-gdp of about 3 percent as in the data. The parameters determining the steady-state leverage ratios for tradable and non-tradable sectors, k T and k N, are set to.7 and.6, respectively, which is suggested by King and Santor (28). In calibration, the following functional form is used for the external finance premium: ( ) χ qt k t+1 s t =, (16) N t+1 where χ is the elasticity of the external risk premium with respect to leverage and χ >. χ can be viewed as a reduced-form parameter capturing financial market frictions. For most of labour market parameters, I use values from Zhang (211a and b). The bargaining power parameter, η, is set to.5, which is commonly used in the literature. The elasticity of matches to unemployment, σ m, is set to.5, the midpoint of values typically used. Following the suggestion of Zhang (28), the job-separation rate, 1 ρ, is set to.9, matching the average job duration of 2.8 years in Canada; the job-finding rate s l is set to.927, matching the fact that one-third of the unemployed workers find jobs within one month. I normalize the mean of market tightness to 1, which implies that the value of µ m in the matching function equals the quarterly job-finding rate. Following Gertler, Sala and Trigari (28), I express b, the steady-state flow value of unemployment, as b = b(p l + κ 2 x2 ), (17) where b is the fraction of the worker s contribution to the job. Following Shimer (25), I set b to.4. There are several new parameters that arise from the fact that the labor market is segmented and entrepreneurs can borrow from both domestic and foreign lenders. The survival rate of jobs in tradable sector, ρ T, is set to.94, which is taken from Tapp (211). The steady-state unemployment rate for tradable sector u ss,t, and the ratio of employed workers in tradable sector is set to θ are set to.19 and.2 respectively to match the data. I use debt allocation data from survey of suppliers of business financing to calibrate υ T and υ N. This survey suggests that from 28 to 21, the average ratio of foreign debt to total debt is 25% for tradable sector; and 17% for non-tradable sector. I 13

15 Table 2: Calibration of the parameters Param. Definition Values β discount factor.99 γ inverse of intertemporal substitution of consumption 2 ν C elasticity of substitution between sectors, consumption.8 ν I elasticity of substitution between sectors, investment.6 θ intermediate good elasticity of substitution 6 α T capital share, tradable.35 α N capital share, non-tradable.3 δ T capital depreciation rate, tradable.25 δ N capital depreciation rate, non-tradable.25 ωt C share of tradable good, consumption.1 ωn C share of non-tradable good, consumption.57 ωt I share of tradable good, investment.2 ωn I share of non-tradable good, investment.4 υ parameter of country-specific risk premium.41 k T steady-state leverage, tradable.7 k N steady-state leverage, non-tradable.6 π steady-state domestic inflation rate 1.48 π steady-state foreign inflation rate 1.52 ρ aggregate survival rate of jobs.91 ρ T survival rate of jobs in tradable sector.94 s l aggregate job-finding rate.927 η bargaining power of workers.5 b parameter for unemployment flow value.4 σ m elasticity in matches to unemployment.5 u ss,t steady-state unemployment rate for tradable.19 θ ratio of employed workers in tradable sector.2 14

16 Table 3: Estimation Results: Foreign Shock Processes Prior Posterior Coef. Description Density Mean Std Mode Autoregressive parameters ρ R Foreign interest rate B ρ π Foreign inflation B ρ y Foreign output B Standard deviations σ R Foreign interest rate I σ π Foreign inflation I σ Y Foreign output I calibrate υ T and υ N to match these ratios. 4.2 Data and priors Bayesian techniques are used to estimate the model. Since the dynamics of the key variables for the rest of the world are exogenous to the Canadian economy, I assume that foreign output, inflation and nominal interest rate all follow an AR(1) process and estimate the parameters governing these processes separately. Following the literature, I assume foreign shocks autoregressive coefficients to follow a beta distribution with mean.6; and the standard deviations of the shocks to follow an Inverted Gamma distribution with mean.5 percent and standard deviation 2. I use U.S. quarterly real GDP per capita for foreign output, federal funds rate in quarterly term for foreign interest rate, and the quarter to quarter growth rate of the GDP deflator for foreign inflation. Foreign output is logged and HP-filtered. Foreign nominal interest rate and inflation are demeaned. Table 4 reports the priors and the modes for the posterior distribution. Taking the estimated foreign shocks as given, I then estimate the main model using nine series of quarterly Canadian data from 1991Q1 to 21Q4: output in tradable sector, output in non-tradable sector, consumption, investment, government spending, nominal interest rate, inflation, risk premium and real exchange rate. Output is measured by real GDP. Consumption is measured by real expenditures of non-durable goods, semi-durable goods and services. Investment is measured by the sum of business gross fixed capital formation, investment in inventories and real expenditure of durable goods. Data on these real variables are expressed in per capita terms using the civilian population aged 15 and up. The nominal interest rate is measured by the overnight rate in quarterly terms. Inflation is the quarter-to-quarter growth rate of the core CPI. Risk premium is measured by difference between business prime lending rates and nominal interest rate. The real exchange rate is measured by multiplying the nominal U.S./CAN exchange rate by the ratio of U.S. to Canadian prices. The series of tradable output, non-tradable output, consumption, investment, government spending and real exchange rate are logged and detrended using an HP filter with smoothing param- 15

17 Table 4: Estimation Result: Behavior Parameters Prior distribution Posterior distribution Mode Mean 5 percent 95 percent Risk premium elas., T χ T gamma (.5,.2) Risk premium elas., N χ N gamma (.5,.2) Calvo wage, T λ T beta (.75,.1) Calvo wage, N λ N beta (.75,.1) Calvo price, T ν T beta (.75,.1) Calvo price, N ν N beta (.75,.1) Calvo price, F ν F beta (.75,.1) Inv. adj. cost, T ξ T norm (1,.5) Inv. adj. cost, N ξ N norm (1,.5) Taylor rule inertia ρ r beta (.5,.25) Taylor rule inflation ρ π gamma(.5,.5) Taylor rule output gap ρ y norm (.125,.15) Table 5: Estimation Results: Shocks Processes eter 16. The series of domestic nominal interest rate, inflation, and risk premium are demeaned. There are twelve behavioral parameters to estimate: the elasticity of the external risk premium for both tradable and non-tradable sectors χ T and χ N ; the investment adjustment cost parameter for both tradable and non-tradable sectors ξ T and ξ N ; the Calvo price parameters for both tradable, nontradable and imported good sectors ν T, ν N and ν F ; the Calvo wage parameters for both tradable and non-tradable sectors λ T and λ N ; and the Taylor rule parameters ρ π, ρ y and ρ r. I also estimate the first-order autocorrelations of all the exogenous shocks and their respective standard deviations. For most of the priors, I follow the literature. I use Beta distributions for all parameters bounded in the [,1] range. This applies to the shocks autoregressive coefficient, whose mean I set to.6. The parameters of nominal rigidities for price and wages are also assumed to follow a beta distribution with mean.75, which corresponds to changing prices and wages every 4 quarters on average. Gamma and Inverted Gamma distributions are assumed for parameters that are supposed to be positive. The priors on the investment adjustment cost and risk-premium elasticity are in line with previous literature. For the standard deviation of the shocks I assume an Inverted Gamma distribution with mean.5 percent and standard deviation 2. The prior assumptions on the monetary policy parameters allow for a range of interest-rate inertia between and 1, and a positive response to inflation. I use a normal distribution for the reaction to output in order to allow for a negative response. The priors are reported in Tables 4 and 5. 16

18 Prior distribution Posterior distribution Autoregressive parameters Mode Mean 5 percent 95 percent Technology, T ρ z,t beta (.6,.2) Technology, N ρ z,n beta (.6,.2) Preference ρ e beta (.6,.2) Investment, T ρ τ,t beta (.6,.2) Investment, N ρ τ,n beta (.6,.2) Government ρ g beta (.6,.2) Financial,T ρ γ,t beta (.6,.2) Financial, N ρ γ,n beta (.6,.2) Standard deviations Technology, T σ ɛ z,t invg (.5,2) Technology, N σ ɛ z,n invg (.5,2) Monetary σ ɛ m invg (.5,2) Preference σ ɛ e invg (.5,2) Investment,T σ ɛ τ,t invg (.5,2) Investment,N σ ɛ τ,n invg (.5,2) Government σ ɛ g invg (.5,2) Financial,T σ ɛ γ,t invg (.5,2) Financial,N σ ɛ γ,n invg (.5,2) I use Dynare 3.65 to estimate the model and use Metropolis-Hastings algorithm to perform simulations. The total number of draws is 1, and the first 2 percent draws are neglected. A step size of.36 results in a acceptance rate of.27. The log data density is Results 5.1 Estimates Table 4 reports the mode, the mean and the 5 and 95 percentiles of the posterior distribution of the behavioral parameters. The estimates indicate significant heterogeneity across sectors. In the follows, I focus on the estimates of parameters that reflect the sectoral differences. The estimates of risk premium elasticity parameter, χ T and χ N, are quite different for the two sectors: χ T is estimated to be.15; while χ N is estimated to be The external finance costs are 1 times more responsive to balance-sheet positions in the non-tradable sector, suggesting that the degree of financial frictions is higher for the firms in the non-tradable sector. The staggering wage contract parameters, λ T and λ N, are estimated at.55 and.83 respectively, suggesting that wages remain unchanged on average about 2 quarters in the tradable sector and about 6 quarters in the non-tradable sector. The sectoral difference is also captured by the sticky price parameters. For the tradable sector, ν T, is estimated to be.73, implying that the expected price duration is 3.7 quarters. For the non-tradable sector, ν N is estimated at.57, suggesting the the expected price duration is 2.33 quarters. The estimates of the rest of the parameters are also consistent with the existing studies in the literature. 5 The estimated values reported in this section are the modes of the posterior distribution. 17

19 Table 5 reports the mode, the mean and the 5 and 95 percentiles of the posterior distribution of the shock processes. The estimates also suggest significant heterogeneity across sectors. For example, the technology shock in the tradable sector is almost 4 times as volatile as that in the nontradable sector (1.73 versus.4). The financial wealth shocks are quite different for the two sectors as well: the shock in the tradable sector is about 3 times as volatile (.82 versus.3) as that in the non-tradable sector, although it is less persistent (.66 versus.77). Among all the shocks, the technology shock in the non-tradable sector is estimated to be most persistent, with a coefficient of.97. The preference shock is the most volatile, with a coefficient of Fit of the model I first examine how well the model economy is able to account for the overall volatility in the data. Table 6 reports the standard deviations (normalized relative to output) for the nine key variables. Overall, the model appears to capture well the basic features of the data. The model comes quite close in terms of matching the volatility in aggregate investment i, risk premium rp; it captures almost half of the relative volatility in consumption c, real exchange rate s, and inflation π. The model also captures about 4 percent of the relative volatility in nominal interest rate r. For the key labour market variables, the model is able to capture the fact that unemployment is much volatile than output, although it slightly overestimates the relative volatilities for both employment and unemployment. Table 6: Standard Deviations for the Key Macro Variables: Model vs. Data y c i r π rp s u n Data Model I next study whether the model economy is able to capture the sectoral differences in output, employment and wages observed in the data. For each variable, I normalize the standard deviations in the tradable sector to these in the non-tradable sector and report the relative volatilities in the data and model in Table 7. In the data, output in the tradable sector is about 4 times as volatile as that in the non-tradable sector. The model is able to capture half of it (2.9 vs 3.95). The model is also able to capture about 4 per cent of the relative volatility in employment. For real wage, the model comes very close to the data, although it slightly overestimates its value (1.98 vs 1.71). Table 7: Relative Volatilities: Model vs. Data Output Employment Wage Data Model

20 5.3 Sources of unemployment fluctuations Table 8 reports the forecast error variance decomposition based on the mode of the model s posterior distribution for 9 key macroeconomic variables, including unemployment, output for both the tradable and non-tradable sectors, employment for the tradable and non-tradable sectors, consumption, investment, nominal interest rate, inflation and real exchange rate. Fluctuations in unemployment are primarily driven by domestic technology and financial wealth shocks. Together these two types of shocks account for more than half of the variations in unemployment (54%). Notice although the tradable sector is only about one quarter of the size of the non-tradable sector, the financial shock in the tradable sector accounts for about the same fraction of the fluctuations (12%) in the aggregate unemployment rate as that in the non-tradable sector. The rest of the variations in unemployment are explained by foreign shocks (29%), monetary policy shock (9%), preference shock (5%), and investment-specific shocks (3%). Technology and financial wealth shocks are also the most important shocks explaining output and employment fluctuations at the sectoral level. For the tradable sector, about 85% of the variations in output, and 56% in employment are accounted by the sector-specific technology and financial wealth shocks. For the non-tradable sector, we observe a similar pattern: about 5% of the variations in output and 34% in employment are explained by the technology and financial wealth shocks. Financial wealth shocks in the two sectors also contribute significantly to the other key macro variables. Financial wealth shocks in the tradable sector account for about 31% of the volatility in consumption, 1% in investment, 5% in nominal interest rate and 38% in inflation; financial wealth shocks in the non-tradable sector explain about 64% of the variations in investment and 1% in inflation. The financial wealth shocks seem to crowd out the investment-specific shocks, which have limited importance for all the variables. For the rest of the shocks, technology shocks in the non-tradable sector also contributes significantly to consumption (2%). Monetary policy shocks contribute significantly to inflation (32%). Foreign interest rate shocks are important in explaining for the variations in exchange rate (76%). 5.4 Model dynamics Given the importance of the sectoral specific technology and financial wealth shocks in explaining the movements in aggregate unemployment, in this subsection I discuss how the key variables of the model economy response to these two types of shocks. I use the technology and financial wealth shocks in the tradable sector as an example. Figure 3 illustrate the responses of the key variables in the model to a one-standard-deviation increase in financial wealth in the tradable sector. The solid line in each panel illustrates the response of the respective variable in the sector where the shocks occurs (tradable sector); and the dotted line reports the responses of the same variables in the other sector (non-tradable sector). The last 19

21 Table 8: Variance Decomposition of the Key Variables Tech. Tech. Fin. Fin. Money Invest Invest Govern. Prefer. Int. rate Inflation Output shock shock shock shock shock shock shock shock shock shock shock shock T N T N T N foreign foreign foreign U rate Output, T Output, N Empl,T Empl,N Cons Inv Int. rate Inf Exch. rate

22 two panels report the responses of aggregate employment and unemployment. A positive financial wealth shock increases entrepreneurs net worth in the tradable sector. On one hand, in the tradable sector, the rise in net worth pushes down the external finance premium, leading entrepreneurs to increase their demand for capital. However, the rise in demand for capital is not accompanied by a rise in demand for labour (although labour demand rises in the initial periods). Instead, entrepreneurs in the tradable sector substitute labour services with capital, and the demand for labour services declines. Hiring rate in in the tradable sector declines after the initial rise, leading the decline in employment. On the other hand, in the non-tradable sector, the hiring rate and employment rise. This is because the rise in capital demand from the tradable sector push up the capital prices, forcing the entrepreneurs in the non-tradable sector to face a higher leverage. Risk premium rises significantly in the non-tradable sector given that the value of elasticity of external finance is very high χ N =.22. The demand for capital drops. Entrepreneurs in the non-tradable sector substitute capital with labour, thus the demand for labor rises in the non-tradable sector. The rise in hiring rate in the non-tradable sector not only absorbs the unemployed workers from the non-tradable sector, but also attracts unemployed workers in the tradable sector. Both unemployment rates in the tradable and non-tradable sectors drop, leading a decline in aggregate unemployment rate. Figure 4 shows the response of the model to a positive technology shock in the tradable sector. On the one hand, output in the tradable sector rises after the shock. Different from the case with the financial wealth shock, the rise in output demands more labour services instead of capital. Hiring rate rises and the tradable sector employs more workers. On the other hand, the rise in labour demand drives up wages, leading a decline in labour demand in the non-tradable sector. More unemployed workers in the non-tradable sector moves to the tradable sector to look for jobs, causing the initial rise in unemployment rate in the tradable sector. The movement in the aggregate unemployment rate is mitigated by the fact that the decline in employment in the non-tradable sector partly cancels out the rise in the tradable sector.. 6 Conclusions Are sector-specific shocks important in shaping unemployment fluctuations in the Canadian labour market? The analysis of the paper suggests that they are. In this paper I introduce a segmented labour market structure into a small open economy model with financial and labour market frictions. Estimation results suggest that there are a lot of heterogeneity across sectors: compared to the non-tradable sector, prices are more rigid but wages are more flexible in the tradable sector, and external finance costs are less responsive to firms balance-sheet position. In addition, shocks are different at the sectoral level. The technology shock is more persistence in the non-tradable sector, and it accounts for almost 3 per cent of the unemployment fluctuations in the Canadian labour market. Financial wealth shocks in both tradable and non-tradable sectors contribute significantly to the movements in unemployment. Together, they explain about 25 per cent of the variations in unemployment. 21

Financial Shocks, Two Sector Labour Markets, and Unemployment

Financial Shocks, Two Sector Labour Markets, and Unemployment Financial Shocks, Two Sector Labour Markets, and Unemployment Yahong Zhang July 23, 212 Abstract After the recent financial crisis, it is becoming increasingly important to understand how the Canadian

More information

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Shutao Cao 1 Yahong Zhang 2 1 Bank of Canada 2 Western University October 21, 2014 Motivation The US experience suggests that the collapse

More information

Financial Factors and Labor Market Fluctuations

Financial Factors and Labor Market Fluctuations Financial Factors and Labor Market Fluctuations Yahong Zhang January 25, 215 Abstract What are the effects of financial market imperfections on fluctuations in unemployment and vacancies for the US economy?

More information

A Model with Costly-State Verification

A Model with Costly-State Verification A Model with Costly-State Verification Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania December 19, 2012 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 1 / 47 A Model with Costly-State

More information

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK Stefania Villa a Jing Yang b a Birkbeck College b Bank of England Cambridge Conference - New Instruments of Monetary Policy: The Challenges

More information

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data Proceedings of 3th International Conference Mathematical Methods in Economics DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data Introduction Miroslav Hloušek Abstract. Czech data shows positive

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010 Monetary Economics Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model Nicola Viegi September 2010 Monetary Economics () Lecture 7 September 2010 1 / 35 Introduction Conventional Model

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Pavel Herber 1 and Daniel Němec 2 1 Masaryk University, Faculty of Economics and Administrations Department of Economics Lipová 41a, 602 00 Brno,

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

Financial Factors and Labour Market Fluctuations

Financial Factors and Labour Market Fluctuations Working Paper/Document de travail 2011-12 Financial Factors and Labour Market Fluctuations by Yahong Zhang Bank of Canada Working Paper 2011-12 May 2011 Financial Factors and Labour Market Fluctuations

More information

Lecture 4. Extensions to the Open Economy. and. Emerging Market Crises

Lecture 4. Extensions to the Open Economy. and. Emerging Market Crises Lecture 4 Extensions to the Open Economy and Emerging Market Crises Mark Gertler NYU June 2009 0 Objectives Develop micro-founded open-economy quantitative macro model with real/financial interactions

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2521 Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model Vincent Bodart Olivier Pierrard Henri R. Sneessens December 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) MACRO-LINKAGES, OIL PRICES AND DEFLATION WORKSHOP JANUARY 6 9, 2009 Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) Credit Frictions and

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy Iklaga, Fred Ogli University of Surrey f.iklaga@surrey.ac.uk Presented at the 33rd USAEE/IAEE North American Conference, October 25-28,

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

Adjustment Costs, Agency Costs and Terms of Trade Disturbances in a Small Open Economy

Adjustment Costs, Agency Costs and Terms of Trade Disturbances in a Small Open Economy Adjustment Costs, Agency Costs and Terms of Trade Disturbances in a Small Open Economy This version: April 2004 Benoît Carmichæl Lucie Samson Département d économique Université Laval, Ste-Foy, Québec

More information

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312/702 Basic New Keynesian Model of Transmission Can be derived from primitives:

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring Introduction The recent Great Recession has highlighted the potential importance of financial market

More information

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound Timothy Hills Taisuke Nakata Sebastian Schmidt New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank 1 September 2016 1 The views expressed

More information

New Business Start-ups and the Business Cycle

New Business Start-ups and the Business Cycle New Business Start-ups and the Business Cycle Ali Moghaddasi Kelishomi (Joint with Melvyn Coles, University of Essex) The 22nd Annual Conference on Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies Banking Supervision

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Cúrdia FRB New York Michael Woodford Columbia University Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial Frictions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles 2. Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March Main idea: introduce nominal rigidities Why? in classical monetary models the price level ensures money

More information

On the new Keynesian model

On the new Keynesian model Department of Economics University of Bern April 7, 26 The new Keynesian model is [... ] the closest thing there is to a standard specification... (McCallum). But it has many important limitations. It

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s

TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s Julen Esteban-Pretel Ryo Nakajima Ryuichi Tanaka GRIPS Tokyo, June 27, 2008 Japan in the 1990s The performance of the Japanese economy in the 1990s was

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

Labour market frictions in a small open economy model of the Czech Republic

Labour market frictions in a small open economy model of the Czech Republic Labour market frictions in a small open economy model of the Czech Republic Daniel Němec 1 Abstract. This contribution examines the impacts of introducing search and matching frictions in an open economy

More information

Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model

Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model 1 / 29 Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model Chiara Forlati 1 Luisa Lambertini 1 1 École Polytechnique Fédérale de Lausanne CMSG November 6, 21 2 / 29 Motivation The global financial crisis started with an increase

More information

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis S. Gilchrist 1 R. Schoenle 2 J. W. Sim 3 E. Zakrajšek 3 1 Boston University and NBER 2 Brandeis University 3 Federal Reserve Board Theory and Methods in Macroeconomics

More information

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles Conférence organisée par la Chaire des Amériques et le Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne, Université Paris I Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles Sarquis J. B. Sarquis

More information

Endogenous Money or Sticky Wages: A Bayesian Approach

Endogenous Money or Sticky Wages: A Bayesian Approach Endogenous Money or Sticky Wages: A Bayesian Approach Guangling Dave Liu 1 Working Paper Number 17 1 Contact Details: Department of Economics, University of Stellenbosch, Stellenbosch, 762, South Africa.

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Credit and hiring. Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California.

Credit and hiring. Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California. Credit and hiring Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California November 14, 2013 CREDIT AND EMPLOYMENT LINKS When credit is tight, employers

More information

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Andrea Prestipino NYU, Princeton, Federal Reserve Board 1 March 218 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors

More information

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 2013 North American Summer Meeting Ralph Lütticke 13.06.2013 1 Joint-work with Christian Bayer, Lien Pham, and Volker Tjaden 1 / 30 Research

More information

Energy and Capital in a New-Keynesian Framework

Energy and Capital in a New-Keynesian Framework Energy and Capital in a New-Keynesian Framework Verónica Acurio Vásconez, Gaël Giraud, Florent Mc Isaac, Ngoc Sang Pham CES, PSE, University Paris I March 27, 2014 Outline Goals Model Household Firms The

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions A. Notarpietro S. Siviero Banca d Italia 1 Housing, Stability and the Macroeconomy: International Perspectives Dallas Fed

More information

Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model

Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model Bundesbank and Goethe-University Frankfurt Department of Money and Macroeconomics January 24th, 212 Bank of England Motivation

More information

Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade

Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade Money Macro and Finance Research Group 47 th Annual Conference Jonathan Benchimol 1 This presentation does not necessarily reflect the views of

More information

Lecture Notes. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University

Lecture Notes. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University Lecture Notes Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1 1 The Ohio State University BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University Insight The textbook Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides

More information

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions DSGE Models with Financial Frictions Simon Gilchrist 1 1 Boston University and NBER September 2014 Overview OLG Model New Keynesian Model with Capital New Keynesian Model with Financial Accelerator Introduction

More information

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence Insu Kim University of California, Riverside October 29 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/18345/ MPRA Paper No.

More information

Product Cycles and Prices: Search Foundation

Product Cycles and Prices: Search Foundation Product Cycles and Prices: Search Foundation Mei Dong 1 Yuki Teranishi 2 1 University of Melbourne 2 Keio University and CAMA, ANU April 2018 1 / 59 In this paper, we Show a fact for product cycles and

More information

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy Yusuf Soner Başkaya Timur Hülagü Hande Küçük 6 April 212 Oil price volatility is high and it varies over time... 15 1 5 1985 199 1995 2 25 21 (a) Mean.4.35.3.25.2.15.1.5 1985 199 1995 2 25 21 (b) Coefficient

More information

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates at the effective lower bound for interest rates Bank of England 12 March 2010 Plan Introduction The model The policy problem Results Summary & conclusions Plan Introduction Motivation Aims and scope The

More information

Unemployment and Business Cycles. Lawrence J. Christiano Martin Eichenbaum Mathias Trabandt

Unemployment and Business Cycles. Lawrence J. Christiano Martin Eichenbaum Mathias Trabandt Unemployment and Business Cycles Lawrence J. Christiano Martin Eichenbaum Mathias Trabandt Background Key challenge for business cycle models. How to account for observed volatility of labor market variables?

More information

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description Carlos de Resende, Ali Dib, and Nikita Perevalov International Economic Analysis Department

More information

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks: Comment

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks: Comment Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks: Comment Johannes Pfeifer (University of Cologne) 1st Research Conference of the CEPR Network on Macroeconomic Modelling and Model Comparison (MMCN) June 2, 217

More information

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture Barbara Annicchiarico BBLM del Dipartimento del Tesoro 2 Giugno 2. Annicchiarico (Università di Tor Vergata) (Institute) Microfoundations of DSGE Models 2 Giugno

More information

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility Luca Dedola and Anton Nakov ECB and CEPR May 24 Dedola and Nakov (ECB and CEPR) SDP and the Paradox of Flexibility 5/4 / 28 Policy rates in major

More information

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis Answer each question in three or four sentences and perhaps one equation or graph. Remember that the explanation determines the grade. 1. Question

More information

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Mitsuru Katagiri International Monetary Fund October 24, 2017 @Keio University 1 / 42 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of

More information

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan Mathilde Le Moigne 1 Francesco Saraceno 2,3 Sébastien Villemot 2 1 École Normale Supérieure 2 OFCE Sciences Po 3 LUISS-SEP

More information

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance (J.Gali et al., JME 2003) Miguel Angel Alcobendas, Laura Desplans, Dong Hee Joe March 5, 2010 M.A.Alcobendas, L. Desplans, D.H.Joe

More information

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model Glenn D. Rudebusch Eric T. Swanson Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco John Taylor s Contributions to Monetary Theory and Policy Federal

More information

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1 Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1 Chun Chang a Zheng Liu b Mark Spiegel b a Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance b Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco International Monetary Fund

More information

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending Michael Reiter 1 Leopold Zessner 2 1 Instiute for Advances Studies, Vienna 2 Vienna Graduate School of Economics Barcelona GSE Summer Forum ADEMU,

More information

The New Keynesian Model

The New Keynesian Model The New Keynesian Model Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 1 / 37 Research strategy policy as systematic and predictable...the central bank s stabilization

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model

The Basic New Keynesian Model Jordi Gali Monetary Policy, inflation, and the business cycle Lian Allub 15/12/2009 In The Classical Monetary economy we have perfect competition and fully flexible prices in all markets. Here there is

More information

Asset Price Bubbles and Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy

Asset Price Bubbles and Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy Asset Price Bubbles and Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy Martha López Central Bank of Colombia Sixth BIS CCA Research Conference 13 April 2015 López (Central Bank of Colombia) (Central A. P. Bubbles

More information

Credit Disruptions and the Spillover Effects between the Household and Business Sectors

Credit Disruptions and the Spillover Effects between the Household and Business Sectors Credit Disruptions and the Spillover Effects between the Household and Business Sectors Rachatar Nilavongse Preliminary Draft Department of Economics, Uppsala University February 20, 2014 Abstract This

More information

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University March 2013 Idiosyncratic risk and the business cycle How much and what types

More information

UNCERTAINTY SHOCKS ARE AGGREGATE DEMAND SHOCKS. I. Introduction

UNCERTAINTY SHOCKS ARE AGGREGATE DEMAND SHOCKS. I. Introduction UNCERTAINTY SHOCKS ARE AGGREGATE DEMAND SHOCKS SYLVAIN LEDUC AND ZHENG LIU Abstract. We study the macroeconomic effects of diverse uncertainty shocks in a DSGE model with labor search frictions and sticky

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Macroeconomic Models. with Financial Frictions

Macroeconomic Models. with Financial Frictions Macroeconomic Models with Financial Frictions Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania May 31, 2010 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Macro-Finance May 31, 2010 1 / 69 Motivation I Traditional

More information

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases Vincent Sterk and Silvana Tenreyro UCL, LSE September 2015 Sterk and Tenreyro (UCL, LSE) OMO September 2015 1 / 28 The

More information

Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification

Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification General Idea Standard dsge model assumes borrowers and lenders are the same people..no conflict of interest. Financial friction

More information

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk Javier Bianchi 1 César Sosa-Padilla 2 2018 SED Annual Meeting 1 Minneapolis Fed & NBER 2 University of Notre Dame Motivation EMEs with

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba 1 / 52 Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba 2 / 52 Policy Practice Motivation Standard policy practice: Fiscal expansions during recessions as a means of stimulating

More information

Unconventional Monetary Policy

Unconventional Monetary Policy Unconventional Monetary Policy Mark Gertler (based on joint work with Peter Karadi) NYU October 29 Old Macro Analyzes pre versus post 1984:Q4. 1 New Macro Analyzes pre versus post August 27 Post August

More information

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism Árpád Ábrahám João Brogueira de Sousa Ramon Marimon Lukas Mayr European University Institute and Barcelona GSE - UPF, CEPR & NBER ADEMU Galatina

More information

WORKING PAPER NO NONTRADED GOODS, MARKET SEGMENTATION, AND EXCHANGE RATES. Michael Dotsey Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

WORKING PAPER NO NONTRADED GOODS, MARKET SEGMENTATION, AND EXCHANGE RATES. Michael Dotsey Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. WORKING PAPER NO. 06-9 NONTRADED GOODS, MARKET SEGMENTATION, AND EXCHANGE RATES Michael Dotsey Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia and Margarida Duarte Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond May 2006 Nontraded

More information

Financial markets and unemployment

Financial markets and unemployment Financial markets and unemployment Tommaso Monacelli Università Bocconi Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Antonella Trigari Università Bocconi October 14, 2010 PRELIMINARY Abstract We

More information

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools Andrea Ferrero Richard Harrison Benjamin Nelson University of Oxford Bank of England Rokos Capital 20 th Central Bank Macroeconomic Modeling

More information

Understanding the Great Recession

Understanding the Great Recession Understanding the Great Recession Lawrence Christiano Martin Eichenbaum Mathias Trabandt Ortigia 13-14 June 214. Background Background GDP appears to have suffered a permanent (1%?) fall since 28. Background

More information

Do Central Banks Respond to Exchange Rate Movements? Some New Evidence from Structural Estimation

Do Central Banks Respond to Exchange Rate Movements? Some New Evidence from Structural Estimation Do Central Banks Respond to Exchange Rate Movements? Some New Evidence from Structural Estimation Wei Dong International Department Bank of Canada January 4, 8 Abstract This paper investigates whether

More information

Macro Modelling: From the Financial Crisis to the Long Slump in the EA

Macro Modelling: From the Financial Crisis to the Long Slump in the EA Macro Modelling: From the Financial Crisis to the Long Slump in the EA Werner Roeger (European Commission, DG ECFIN) April 216 The views expressed in this presentation are those of the author and should

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

Credit Risk and the Macroeconomy

Credit Risk and the Macroeconomy and the Macroeconomy Evidence From an Estimated Simon Gilchrist 1 Alberto Ortiz 2 Egon Zakrajšek 3 1 Boston University and NBER 2 Oberlin College 3 Federal Reserve Board XXVII Encuentro de Economistas

More information

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete R. Anton Braun Tomoyuki Nakajima 2 University of Tokyo, and CREI 2 Kyoto University, and RIETI December 9, 28 Outline Introduction 2 Model Individuals

More information

Financial Factors in Business Cycles

Financial Factors in Business Cycles Financial Factors in Business Cycles Lawrence J. Christiano, Roberto Motto, Massimo Rostagno 30 November 2007 The views expressed are those of the authors only What We Do? Integrate financial factors into

More information

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014 External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ali Shourideh Wharton Ariel Zetlin-Jones CMU - Tepper November 7, 2014 Introduction Question: How

More information

Fiscal Multipliers and Financial Crises

Fiscal Multipliers and Financial Crises Fiscal Multipliers and Financial Crises Miguel Faria-e-Castro New York University June 20, 2017 1 st Research Conference of the CEPR Network on Macroeconomic Modelling and Model Comparison 0 / 12 Fiscal

More information

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Reforms in a Debt Overhang Structural Javier Andrés, Óscar Arce and Carlos Thomas 3 National Bank of Belgium, June 8 4 Universidad de Valencia, Banco de España Banco de España 3 Banco de España National Bank of Belgium, June 8 4

More information

Sticky Wages and Financial Frictions

Sticky Wages and Financial Frictions Sticky Wages and Financial Frictions Alex Clymo 1 1 University of Essex EEA-ESEM, August 2017 1 / 18 Introduction Recent work highlights that new wages more flexible than old: Pissarides (2009), Haefke,

More information

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment Margarita Rubio 1 Fang Yao 2 1 University of Nottingham 2 Reserve Bank of New Zealand. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect

More information

A Model of Financial Intermediation

A Model of Financial Intermediation A Model of Financial Intermediation Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania December 25, 2012 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) A Model of Financial Intermediation December 25, 2012 1 / 43

More information

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada Motivation A large literature quantitatively studies the role of financial

More information

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Giancarlo Corsetti Luca Dedola Sylvain Leduc CREST, May 2008 The International Consumption Correlations Puzzle

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand Susanto Basu Boston College NBER Brent Bundick Boston College Preliminary Can Higher Uncertainty Reduce Overall Economic Activity? Many think it is an

More information

Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates

Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates Martin Eichenbaum Ben Johannsen Sergio Rebelo Disclaimer: The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect

More information

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk Daniel Cohen 1,2 Mathilde Viennot 1 Sébastien Villemot 3 1 Paris School of Economics 2 CEPR 3 OFCE Sciences Po PANORisk workshop 7

More information