Reputation, Volatility and Performance Persistence of Private Equity. Yi Li

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Reputation, Volatility and Performance Persistence of Private Equity. Yi Li"

Transcription

1 Reputation, Volatility and Performance Persistence of Private Equity Yi Li Federal Reserve Board This version: April 2014 Abstract This paper develops a learning model with managers reputation concerns to shed new light on performance persistence for private equity funds. The model predicts: When the exogenous shock on fund performance is less volatile, performance persistence is more pronounced, the reputation mechanism works better, and fund managers have more incentive to control fund sizes. On the premise that buyout funds are subject to less volatile shocks than venture capital (VC) funds, I hypothesize that the model mechanism is stronger among buyout funds. Using a comprehensive dataset of private equity funds, I document evidence consistent with the model prediction: (i) Buyout funds exhibit strong long-term (over ten years) performance persistence across different funds raised by the same manager, while VC funds show weak short-run persistence. (ii) The size of buyout managers new funds is strongly related to the performance of their previous funds, while the size of VC managers new funds is highly associated with recent VC industry performance rather than individual managers. (iii) Top buyout managers raise smaller funds than they could have, while no such behavior is found for VC managers. This paper is a revised version of a chapter from my doctoral dissertation at Princeton University. I am indebted to my advisors Wei Xiong and David Sraer for their advice and encouragement. For helpful comments and discussions, I would like to thank Valentin Haddad, Zhiguo He, Jakub W. Jurek, Hyun Song Shin, Ming Yang, as well as seminar participants at Chinese University of Hong Kong, City University of Hong Kong, Durham University, Federal Reserve Board, Moody s Analytics, Nanyang Technological University, Princeton University and University of Warwick. All errors are mine. The views expressed in this paper are mine and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Board of Governors or other Federal Reserve staff. Corresponding address: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 20th Street and Constitution Avenue, Washington, DC, yi.li@frb.gov. 1

2 1 Introduction At the end of March 2012, private equity (PE) funds in total managed over $2 trillion of capital 1, primarily in the form of venture capital (VC) and leveraged buyouts. 2 PE investment is generally made through a limited partnership structure, in which PE firms serve as general partners (GPs), and institutional investors and wealthy individuals serve as limited partners (LPs). LPs provide capital to GPs, and GPs use the capital under management to make investments. Kaplan and Schoar (2005) first document that returns persist strongly across different PE funds raised by the same GP, especially for funds that outperform the industry. Such long-run performance persistence driven by outperformance has not been documented for other investment funds, such as mutual funds 3 and hedge funds. 4 Taking into account the institutional structure of PE funds, I propose a learning model with managers (i.e. GPs ) reputation concerns to explain performance persistence for PE funds, and test the theory with data. In the benchmark model without reputation concerns, fund managers with various ability levels optimally choose fund sizes that increase with their perceived ability levels, and generate the same expected return to investors. This result resembles that of Berk and Green (2004), who show that in the context of mutual funds, with the assumption of decreasing returns to scale, skillful managers do not outperform passive benchmarks because of the infinitely elastic supply of capital. However, the mechanism underlying my model differs from theirs. While fund managers in their model passively experience capital inflows and outflows that respond to recent fund performance (which is true with open-end mutual funds), fund managers in my model choose their fund sizes optimally. This sharp distinction in modeling is driven by the unique institutional structure of PE funds. 5 In the model with reputation concerns, fund managers future payoffs depend on their reputation. In equilibrium, expected fund returns increase with fund managers ability levels, and the 1 Source: Private Equity Report TheCityUK. 2 Other PE strategies include: growth capital, mezzanine capital, distressed, special situations, secondaries, and fund of funds, etc. 3 Long-run persistence in mutual fund performance has been difficult to detect. When detected, it is mostly driven by persistent underperformance. See Carhart et al. (2002), Bollen and Busse (2005), and Sirri and Tufano (1998). 4 Studies on persistence in hedge fund performance have obtained mixed results. Early research provides little evidence of long-run persistence. See, for example, Bares et al. (2003), Edwards and Caglayan (2001), and Brown et al. (2001). Recent research, however, finds some evidence of longer-term (1 to 3 years) performance persistence. See Fung et al. (2008), Jagannathan et al. (2010), and Kosowski et al. (2007). 5 A typical PE fund has a lifespan of years. At the outset, fund managers (i.e. GPs) set a target fund size and start raising capital. Once the fund-raising phase ends, the fund is closed. Investors (i.e. LPs) commit their capital to fund managers for the next years, and fund managers promise not to accept new capital for that fund. 2

3 strength of this relationship captures the level of performance persistence. 6 Moreover, this model predicts that when the exogenous shock on fund performance is less volatile, performance is more persistent, the reputation mechanism is stronger, and fund managers have more incentive to control fund sizes. 7 By identifying two groups of PE funds exposed to shocks of different volatilities, I test these predictions with data. The main source of data for the empirical study is Preqin, which provides data on fund characteristics such as type, sequence number, size (the amount of committed capital), vintage year (the year in which the fund starts to make its first investment), the identity of the GP behind each fund, and most importantly, fund performance measures, in forms of internal rate of return (IRR) and multiple. Preqin obtains performance data from both public filings by pension funds 8 and voluntary disclosures by GPs and LPs. It has detailed cash flow data for over 1,600 PE funds, and is currently one of the most comprehensive PE datasets, covering 60% of total capital commitment in the 1990s and over 70% in the 2000s, as discussed by Harris et al. (2012). The sample comprises 590 buyout funds and 842 VC funds. The average returns for buyout funds and VC funds are close, while the standard deviation of fund returns is 18.6% for buyouts and 48.9% for VC. This difference between the standard deviation of buyout fund returns and that of VC fund returns motivates the following hypotheses: 9 For buyout funds, performance is more persistent, the reputation mechanism is stronger, and fund managers have more incentive to limit fund sizes. First, I examine the hypothesis on performance persistence for buyout funds and VC funds. I document strong long-term persistence in buyout fund returns across different funds raised by the same GP. Not only the previous fund return and the second previous fund return, but the third previous fund return also has significant explanatory power (at the 1% level significance) for the current fund return. Since a typical buyout GP raises a new fund about every 4 years, the test results indicate that the persistence in buyout fund performance lasts at least 10 years. The 6 Intuitively, the level of performance persistence across different funds raised by the same manager depends on the extent to which the manager s intrinsic ability is reflected by returns of each fund. 7 In the extreme case when the shock is infinitely volatile, all fund managers revert to their benchmark choices, i.e., homogenous fund return among different managers and no performance persistence across funds raised by the same manager. 8 Pension funds are among the major investors (i.e. LPs) of private equity funds. According to FOIA (Freedom of Information Act), pension funds are required to report the performance of their holding assets. 9 The standard deviation of fund returns potentially comes from two sources: the variation in fund managers ability levels, as well as exogenous shocks beyond the control of fund managers, such as macroeconomic factors, equity and debt market conditions, technology revolutions, etc. By assuming that the variation in fund managers ability is almost the same for VC and buyout funds, the standard deviation of fund returns effectively represents the volatility of exogenous shocks. 3

4 case with VC funds is substantially different. Although I find some evidence of persistence in VC fund performance, this persistence is completely between two consecutive funds raised by the same GP. In light of the fact that the average interval between two consecutive VC funds is 3 years, it is possible that this short-term persistence among VC funds is driven by overlapping investment projects (i.e. portfolio companies) rather than the GP s intrinsic ability. In sum, the baseline results on performance persistence for buyout funds and VC funds support the hypothesis that the performance of buyout funds is more persistent, compared to VC funds. To address a potential concern that these results on performance persistence are biased by outliers, 10 I perform a robustness check with data excluding the 1% of funds with the highest IRRs. Test results using these winsorized data show even stronger persistence for buyout funds and even weaker persistence for VC funds, compared to the baseline results. For VC funds in particular, the previous fund return loses its explanatory power for current fund return in some specifications. This robustness check rules out the doubt that the long-term performance persistence of buyout funds is driven by a few funds with extremely good performance. In addition, it reveals that for VC funds, even the short-run performance persistence is vulnerable and likely driven by the top 1% VC funds. I also conduct a series of robustness checks using an alternative performance measure, multiple, and obtain similar results. Second, I study how the reputation mechanism works differently for buyout funds and VC funds. Strength of the reputation mechanism is captured by the extent to which the current fund size depends on performance of past funds raised by the same GP. 11 Test results show that for buyout GPs, the relationship between previous fund performance and the current fund size is strongly positive and significant at the 1% level, while for VC GPs, this relationship is not significant at all, indicating that buyout GPs with better past performance are very likely to be favored when they raise their follow-on funds, and this reputation mechanism does not work for VC GPs. To explore what factors predict VC fund sizes, I include VC industry performance as an additional explanatory variable. 12 While VC fund sizes do not respond to individual GP s past performance, they are positively and significantly associated with the recent performance of the VC industry. These results show that for a buyout GP, its new fund size is strongly related to its 10 While the average annual return on PE investment is about 15%, some star funds yield exceptional annual returns as high as 200%. These outliers can potentially bias regression results in a significant way. 11 Higher payoffs are associated with larger funds, since a great portion of GP s income derives from the sum of annual management fees, approximately 18% of total committed capital (i.e. fund size). See Metrick and Yasuda (2010) and Chung et al. (2012). 12 VC industry performance is defined as the average of IRRs of all VC funds raised 2-4 years earlier, 3-5 years or 4-6 years earlier. 4

5 performance in previous funds. In contrast, for a VC GP, its new fund size depends on recent VC industry performance. Third, I test whether top buyout GPs are more likely to limit their fund sizes than top VC GPs. I capture GP s ability level by calculating the average return across all funds raised by the same GP, 13 and sort GPs into ability terciles: top, medium and bottom. Test results are consistent with my hypotheses. In particular, controlling for characteristics of previous funds, a top buyout GP raises a new fund with size 24% smaller than a medium buyout GP, and a top GP s new fund size is significantly less sensitive to the previous fund return, compared to a medium buyout GP s. These results suggest that top buyout GPs raise smaller funds than they could have and are less likely to exploit on good past performance when raising new capital, compared to medium buyout GPs. For top VC GPs, however, no such behavior is found. Specifically, neither the coefficient on the top dummy nor the coefficient on the interaction term between top dummy and the previous fund return is significant. Last, I test a key assumption of the model, decreasing returns to scale. 14 Existing literature, such as Kaplan and Schoar (2005) and Harris et al. (2012), has not reached a unanimous conclusion on the relationship between PE fund performance and the fund size. 15 In this study, I document a strongly negative relationship between the two after controlling for the number of partners of each GP. 16 This result validates the assumption of decreasing returns to scale and therefore supports the model setup. This paper is closely related to the empirical literature on private equity fund performance. Kaplan and Schoar (2005) are the first to document performance persistence for PE funds. However, they neither provide testable explanations for the persistence nor document the difference between buyouts and VC. 17 Phalippou (2010) finds that VC funds backed by more skilled investors show little performance persistence. Ljungqvist and Richardson (2003), Robinson and Sensoy (2011) and Harris et al. (2012) use cash flow data to study the relative performance of PE funds to the public market, as well as risk characteristics of PE funds. Cochrane (2005), Phalippou and Gottschalg 13 GPs who have raised only one fund are excluded from the sample of this test. 14 By adopting a concave profit-generating function in the model, I implicitly assume decreasing returns to scale, i.e., the larger the fund is, the lower the expected fund return will be. 15 Kaplan and Schoar (2005) document a positive relationship between fund performance and the fund size in the cross-section, however the sign of the coefficient on fund size switches from positive to negative when GP fixed effects are included. Harris et al. (2012) repeat the exercise and find no significant relationship between fund performance and the fund size. 16 The idea of controlling for the number of partners of each GP stems from the fact that these partners skills are highly unscalable. 17 Kaplan and Schoar (2005) do not find differences between buyout funds and VC funds in levels of performance persistence probably because of their much shorter data period ( ) and much lower fund sequence number. 5

6 (2009), Jegadeesh et al. (2009) and Korteweg and Sorensen (2010) estimate and analyze risks and returns of PE investments. Gompers and Lerner (1999) and Metrick and Yasuda (2010) study the economics of the PE industry and estimate compensation schemes to GPs. Using Metrick and Yasuda (2010) s framework, Chung et al. (2012) find evidence of additional payoffs for good performance from future fund flows. Lerner et al. (2007) use Preqin as their source of performance measures and document a significant variation in levels of returns that different institutional investors realize from PE. Lopez de Silanes et al. (2009) provide evidence for decreasing returns to scale : investments made at times of a high number of simultaneous investments underperform. Existing literature on modeling performance persistence in PE funds is sparse. One exception is Hochberg et al. (2010), who propose a theory of learning that leads to information hold-up in the VC market. The mechanism of their model is: Investors of a fund learn inside information about the GP of that fund, and use it as hold-up power when the GP raises its next fund. This holdup power diminishes the GP s capability to increase fees in line with performance and therefore generates performance persistence. While their model focuses on the bargaining game between GPs and informed LPs, my model explains how reputation concerns alone lead to performance persistence and how exogenous shocks erode the mechanism. This study also contributes to the more general literature on reputation/career concerns of fund mangers. Demiroglu and James (2010) discuss the role of PE group s reputation in leveraged buyout financing and find that reputable GPs get better loan terms. Guerrieri and Kondor (2012) develop a model to explain how fund mangers career concerns generate a countercyclical reputational premium. Malliaris and Yan (2012) show how fund managers reputation concerns induce a preference over the skewness of strategy returns. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the model. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 conducts empirical analysis. Section 5 concludes. 2 Model Before presenting the model, I briefly discuss the nature of private equity (PE) investments. PE funds are structured as limited partnerships, in which professional managers serve as general partners (GPs), and limited partners (LPs) are largely composed of institutional investors and wealthy individuals, who commit a certain amount of capital (namely, committed capital) to funds. PE funds are categorized into venture capital (VC), buyouts, etc., based on investment types. 6

7 The lifespan of a typical PE fund is years. Fund managers (i.e. GPs) select portfolio companies and invest the majority of the committed capital to them in an agreed time period (usually the first 3-5 years of a fund). When portfolio companies start to make profits, GPs return committed capital and the majority of the excess profits to investors (i.e. LPs). PE fund managers receive both fixed and variable compensation: Management fees are fixed annual payments, typically 1-2% of the committed capital of the fund, 18 and carried interests are performance-based revenue, typically 20% of the excess profits of the fund s investment. 2.1 Model Setup The model features symmetric information among fund managers and investors. Fund managers are heterogenous in their ability levels, denoted as θ i. At t = 0, the prior distribution of θ i is the same across all fund managers, and each fund manager is assigned a fund with the same amount of committed capital to manage. After observing the realized return on the incubation fund, all agents make inferences about the fund manager s ability level, and fund managers are allowed to choose the size of their second funds. The question of interest is whether there is performance persistence across the incubation fund and the second fund raised by the same fund manager. Figure 1 establishes the timing of the model. At t = 0, all fund managers are ex-ante homogeneous, and the prior distribution of their ability level θ i is normal with a mean of µ 0 and a variance of σ 2 0. Each manager is assigned a fund of an identical size S 1. At t = 1, the return on the first fund is realized, denoted as r1 i, which is subject to an i.i.d. exogenous shock. Both fund managers and investors observe the fund return r1 i, and apply Bayes rule to update their beliefs about manager i s ability level. Fund managers are allowed to decide on the size of their second funds, S2 i, and they optimally choose it to maximize their expected future payoffs. 19 At t = 2, the return on the second fund is realized, denoted as r2 i, which is also subject to an i.i.d. exogenous shock. All agents observe the fund return r2 i as well as the fund size Si 2, and apply Bayes rule to update their beliefs about the manager s ability level. Fund managers reputation is defined as their ability levels perceived by investors. Therefore, the reputation of fund manager i 18 Metrick and Yasuda (2010) estimate that the sum of discounted annual management fees is approximately 18% of total committed capital. 19 My model assumes that when GPs raise a new fund, investors do not have negotiation power over the fund size, based on the fact that the target fund size is usually set by GPs and most of the time the target is met. See Hochberg et al. (2010) for an alternative setting in which some informed investors possess a hold-up power and can bargain on the fund size with GPs. My model shows that even without asymmetric information and bargaining power of investors, performance persistence can be generated if fund managers reputation concerns are strong enough. 7

8 at t = 2 is µ i 2 = E 2[θ i r1 i, ri 2 ], on which fund managers expected future payoffs after t = 2 depend. Figure 1: Model Timeline 1 st Fund 2 nd Fund Future Funds t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 t = 3 θ i ~ N (µ 0, σ 02 ), S 1 assigned r i 1 realized Update belief θ i ~ N (µ i 1, (σ i 1) 2 ) Choose S i 2 r i 2 realized Update belief θ i ~ N (µ i 2, (σ i 2) 2 ) Future payoffs depend on µ i 2 Fund managers vary in their skills in generating net profits. Let Π i t denote net profits of fund-t run by fund manager i: Π i t = θ i (St) i 1 γ + ɛ i tst, i (2.1) where 0 < γ < 1, ɛ i t N(0, σɛ 2 t ), and S1 i = S 1. The concavity of this function implies that for a given fund manager, the more assets under management, the lower the fund return will be. 20 ɛ i t captures the exogenous shock, which is i.i.d. across fund managers, and σ 2 ɛ t is the volatility of the exogenous shock. Fund manager i s net income from fund t is a combination of management fees and performancebased bonus (namely, carried interests), net of management costs of the fund: I i t = αs i t + βπ i t λs i t, (2.2) 20 In the empirical part of this paper, I formally test whether PE funds show decreasing returns to scale. 8

9 where α stands for management fees per dollar of committed capital, β is the carry level, and λ represents costs per dollar of committed capital. 21 I assume that λ > α, so that management fees alone are not sufficient to cover management costs. By definition, the net-of-fee return of fund t run by manager i can be written as rt i = (1 β)π i t/st, i i.e. rt i = (1 β)(θ i (St) i γ + ɛ i t). (2.3) This function shows that the fund return is a combination of the fund manager s ability level (scaled down by the fund size) and an i.i.d. exogenous noise. Less information on the fund manager s ability level is inferred when the fund size is larger and the exogenous shock is noisier. 2.2 Benchmark Model without Reputation Concerns Before delving into the model with fund managers reputation concerns, I first solve the simple model without reputation concerns and use it as a benchmark. If fund managers have no reputation concerns, i.e., if their future payoffs after t = 2 do not depend on how they perform in their first two funds, they simply choose S i 2 to maximize their expected payoffs from the second fund: where I i 2 is defined in (2.2). max E 1 [I2] i S2 i The first-order condition generates the benchmark fund-2 size for manager i: Ŝ i 2 = [ β(1 γ)µ i 1 λ α ] 1 γ, (2.4) where µ i 1 = E 1[θ i r1 i ]. Plugging (2.4) into (2.3), I obtain the benchmark fund-2 return for manager i: Taking expectations on (2.5), I have r 2 [θ i = (1 β) i λ α ] β(1 γ)µ i + ɛ i 2. (2.5) 1 ˆr E 1 [ r i 2 (1 β)(λ α) ] =. (2.6) β(1 γ) When fund managers are not concerned about their reputation, (2.4) shows that the optimal 21 Since GP skills are highly unscalable in PE investments, larger funds demand proportionally more efforts from GPs, including attracting capital, evaluating investment projects, cultivating and restructuring portfolio companies, and exiting. These additional efforts can be taken either by fund managers themselves, which incurs proportionally more opportunity costs of entrepreneurship, or by hiring more employees, which incurs proportionally more costs of labor. Either way it implies that costs of managing a PE fund is approximately proportional to its size. 9

10 size that they choose for their second fund is an increasing function of their perceived ability levels, specifically, proportional to (µ i 1 ) 1 γ. While fund managers with higher perceived ability levels raise larger funds, they do not generate higher expected returns for their investors. As is shown in (2.6), fund managers with different ability levels are expected to yield the same level of return on their second fund, and the expected return on the second fund is independent of the realized return on the first fund. In sum, without fund managers reputation concerns, there is no performance persistence across different funds raised by the same fund manager. 2.3 Model with Reputation Concerns In the model with reputation concerns, fund managers future payoffs after t = 2 depend on their reputation at t = 2, which is defined as their perceived ability level µ i 2. In the setting of symmetric information, both managers and investors follow Bayes rule to update their beliefs on managers ability. update their beliefs on θ i to be θ i N(µ i 1, (σi 1 )2 ), where µ i 1 = µ 0 + (σ i 1) 2 = At t = 1, after observing the realized r1 i, all agents σ 2 0 σ S2γ 1 σ2 ɛ 1 ( S γ 1 1 β ri 1 µ 0 ) (2.7) σ 2 0 σ2 ɛ 1 S 2γ 1 σ σ2 ɛ 1. (2.8) Since (σ i 1 )2 is the same across all fund managers, I denote (σ i 1 )2 σ At t = 2, after observing S i 2 and the realized ri 2, all agents update their beliefs of θi to be θ i N(µ i 2, (σi 2 )2 ): µ i 2 = µ i 1 + σ1 2 ( (S i 2 ) γ ) σ1 2 + (Si 2 )2γ σɛ β ri 2 µ i 1 (2.9) (σ i 2) 2 = σ 2 1 σ2 ɛ 2 (S i 2 ) 2γ σ σ2 ɛ 2, (2.10) Plugging (2.3) into the equations above, µ i 2 can be written as µ i 2 = µ i 1 + σ1 2 [ (θ i σ1 2 + (Si 2 )2γ σɛ 2 µ i 1) + (S2) i γ ɛ i ] 2 2 (2.11) Fund managers future payoffs after t = 2 depend on their perceived ability levels at t = 2 and take a cubic form: Calculation of µ i t and (σ i t) 2 is provided in appendix. 23 This future payoff function features a convex reward (punishment) to good (bad) reputation, which can be justified by the following reasons. Reputation not only affects future fund sizes, but also determines whether fund managers 10

11 V i 3 = V (µ i 2 ˆµ) 3, (2.12) where V and ˆµ are constants. ˆµ is the reputation threshold under which managers future payoffs turn negative. Therefore, at t = 1 fund managers solve the following problem: where I i 2 and V i 3 max E 1 [I i S2 i 2 + V3 i ], (2.13) are defined by (2.2) and (2.12), respectively. The first-order condition yields β(1 γ)µ i 1(S i 2) γ = (λ α) + (µ i 1 ˆµ) 6γσ2 1 κv (Si 2 )2γ 1 [1 + κ(s i 2 )2γ ] 2, (2.14) where κ σɛ 2 2 /σ1 2, representing the relative volatility of exogenous shocks. Comparing (2.14) to the first-order condition in the benchmark model: β(1 γ)µ i 1(S i 2) γ = λ α, (2.15) I derive the following lemma: Lemma 1. In the model with fund managers reputation concerns, at t = 1, (i) For managers with perceived ability level µ i 1 > ˆµ, Si 2 (µi 1 ) < Ŝi 2 (µi 1 ), and E 1[r2 i (µi 1 )] > ˆr. (ii) For managers with perceived ability level µ i 1 < ˆµ, Si 2 (µi 1 ) > Ŝi 2 (µi 1 ), and E 1[r2 i (µi 1 )] < ˆr. Lemma 1 shows that fund managers with perceived ability levels higher than the threshold choose to raise smaller-than-benchmark funds and consequently generate expected returns higher than the benchmark level, while fund managers with perceived ability levels lower than the threshold choose to raise larger-than-benchmark funds and hence generate expected returns lower than the benchmark level. Proposition 1 summarizes main results of the model with managers reputation concerns. It presents the existence of performance persistence across the incubation fund and the follow-on fund, and shows how performance persistence and the reputation mechanism evaporate as the volatility of exogenous shocks increases. are able to raise future funds. Reputation also influences costs of raising capital from investors (fund managers with good reputation can raise capital for a new fund very quickly and capture transient investment opportunities, while it may take several years and a lot more effort for low-reputation fund managers to close a new fund), the bargaining power in purchasing portfolio companies, and costs of getting loans from banks (especially for buyouts, as documented by Demiroglu and James (2010)). Furthermore, reputation plays a role in fund managers future employment opportunities, even after they leave the PE industry. 11

12 Proposition 1. With Assumption 1 and 2 provided in appendix, at t = 1, for fund manager i with perceived ability level µ i 1 [µ, µ]:24 (i) The expected return of the second fund increases with the realized return of the first (i.e. incubation) fund, i.e. de 1[r i 2 ] dr i 1 > 0. (ii) The more volatile the exogenous shock is, the closer the expected fund-2 return is to the benchmark level, i.e., d E 1[r i 2 ] ˆr dκ < 0. As κ, E 1 [r2 i (µi 1 )] ˆr. The first part of Proposition 1 shows a positive relationship between the expected return on the second fund and the realized return on the incubation fund, which proves performance persistence across different funds raised by the same fund manager. The second part of Proposition 1 addresses how exogenous shocks influence the effectiveness of the reputation mechanism and levels of performance persistence. It shows that the expected return on the second fund gradually approaches the benchmark level as the volatility of exogenous shocks increases. Intuitively, as exogenous shocks become more volatile, fund returns become weaker signals of managers ability levels. Hence, future payoffs depend less on perceived ability levels, and fund managers incentive to deviate from their benchmark choice diminishes. When the volatility of exogenous shocks becomes extremely high relative to the variation in fund managers ability levels (i.e. as κ ), even with reputation concerns, all fund managers choices revert to benchmark, and performance persistence disappears. Figure 2 illustrates how the relationship between expected fund-2 return and the fund manager s perceived ability level (µ i 1 ) wears off as κ, the ratio of σ2 ɛ 2 to σ1 2, gradually rises from 0.2 to 100. Since µ i 1 is a linear function of the realized fund-1 return ri 1, Figure 2 also shows how the relationship between expected fund-2 return and realized fund-1 return gets weaker as κ increases. Specifically, when κ rises, expected returns on the second funds of higher-ability managers (those with µ i 1 > ˆµ) shift down towards the benchmark, while expected returns on the second funds of of lower-ability managers (those with µ i 1 < ˆµ) shifts up towards the benchmark. When κ approaches 100 (i.e., when exogenous shocks become extremely volatile), fund managers with various ability levels generate almost the same level of expected return. Proposition 1 also implies that reputation concerns incentivize higher-ability fund managers to limit their fund sizes and lower-ability fund managers to increase their fund sizes, and these incentives decrease with the volatility of exogenous shocks. An intuitive explanation is that the 24 Expressions of µ and µ are given in (D.1). 12

13 information content of fund returns decreases with the fund size. While higher-ability managers have incentives to manifest their ability levels (hence rasing smaller-than-benchmark funds), lowerability managers have incentives to prevent investors from learning (hence raising larger-thanbenchmark funds). Figure 3 depicts how fund sizes gradually approach benchmark levels as the volatility of exogenous shocks increases (i.e., as κ increases from 0.2 to 100). With reputation concerns, fund managers with higher-than-threshold ability levels (i.e. those with µ i 1 > ˆµ) raise smaller-thanbenchmark funds, and the more volatile exogenous shocks are, the less likely are these top managers to limit their fund sizes. On the other hand, fund managers with lower-than-threshold ability levels (i.e. those with µ i 1 < ˆµ) raise larger-than-benchmark funds, and the more volatile exogenous shocks are, the less incentive these bottom managers have to expand their funds. In sum, the model with fund managers reputation concerns predicts that when the exogenous shock on fund performance is less volatile, performance persistence is stronger, the reputation mechanism works better, and top fund managers have more incentive to limit their fund sizes. 3 The Data 3.1 Data Sources The main data source for the empirical study is Preqin. It provides PE fund characteristics, such as vintage year (the year in which the fund made its first investment), size (the amount of committed capital), type (venture capital, buyout, mezzanine, growth, distressed and special situation, secondaries, fund of funds, etc.), sequence number, and most importantly, performance measures. It also provides GP profiles, such as firm location and number of partners/employees. 25 As described by Harris et al. (2012) and Lerner et al. (2007), Preqin collects data primarily from public filings by pension funds, from FOIA requests to public pension funds, and from voluntary disclosures by both GPs and LPs. With access to full cash flow data for over 1,600 PE funds, Preqin makes its own assessment of the reliability of the different sources of performance data available, and provides the number considered most reliable. The performance measure I use in this study is the internal rate of return (IRR), which is the discount rate at which the net present value of all the cash inflows equals the net present value of 25 The data on the number of partners, however, are only partially available from Preqin. For missing values, I hand collect them from PE firms websites. 13

14 all cash outflows of the investment. IRRs are directly provided by Preqin, net of management fees and carried interests. 26 Preqin also reports an alternative measure of fund performance, Multiple, which is the ratio between the total value that investors have derived from their investments - i.e. distributed cash and securities plus the value of the remaining capital in the fund and their total cash investment. 27 The correlation between IRR and Multiple is 81%. In some tests, I employ Multiple to check the robustness of the baseline results. For most tests involving fund returns, I only include funds raised before 2005, considering the fact that younger funds are associated with more unrealized valuations and therefore more inaccurate IRRs. For funds with the vintage year 2004 or earlier, at least 8-9 years of cash flows have been realized, and I consider IRRs of these funds are accurate enough in measuring the final performance, even though some of the funds have not fully exited yet. 28 As reviewed by Harris et al. (2012), in addition to Preqin, three other commercial datasets also provide PE performance data: Venture Economics (VE), Cambridge Associates (CA), and Burgiss. In terms of data quality, Harris et al. (2012) suggest that it is highly likely that VE returns understate fund performance, while CA and Burgiss, as well as Preqin, provide consistent fund returns despite different sample selection criteria. In terms of data coverage, Preqin catches up substantially over time. While in the 1980s, funds documented by Preqin only covers about 40% of total capital commitments in PE industry, it covers about 60% in the 1990s and over 70% in the 2000s, which makes itself currently one of the most comprehensive datasets. Therefore, even though data obtained from Preqin may suffer from the possibility of selection bias, like any other dataset, the selection bias is likely to be minimal Ideally, I would like to calculate IRRs myself using fund-level cash flow data, but unfortunately these data are not available to me. However, the quality of the Preqin data has been cross-checked by Harris et al. (2012) and Lerner et al. (2007). 27 The shortcoming of Multiple is that it does not reflect the time value of money, and therefore will not show whether one partnership has returned value to investors more quickly or more slowly than another. 28 Lerner et al. (2007) use funds with at least 5 years of realized cash flows for their performance analysis. Kaplan and Schoar (2005) justify this criteria by arguing that the estimated IRR at the end of 5 years after the fund is established is highly correlated with realized IRR when the fund exits, with an correlation coefficient of Preqin collects most of the fund performance data through third-party disclosure, i.e. disclosure by public pension funds. If public pension funds had superior abilities in choosing which PE funds to invest in, fund performance recorded by Preqin would have an upward bias. According to Lerner et al. (2007), public pension funds do not outperform other institutional investors in terms of PE investment (while university endowments do), which suggests that Preqin does not have a significant selection bias. 14

15 3.2 Descriptive Statistics Table 1 reports descriptive statistics of the 1432 PE funds raised by 502 GPs between 1980 and Among these 1432 funds, 590 are buyout funds, and 842 are VC funds. Other types of PE funds, such as mezzanine, growth, distressed and special situation, secondaries, fund of funds, are excluded from the sample. Also, this study centers on U.S. funds with an investment focus inside America. 30 Panel A of Table 1 summarizes fund-level characteristics. The typical fund in my sample is a third fund 31 with a size of $362.7 million and an IRR of 15.5%, and there is substantial variation across funds. Buyout funds are much larger than VC funds, with an average size of $639.4 million compared to $168.9 million. The average performance of buyout funds and VC funds, in terms of IRR or Multiple, is close, 32 although VC fund performance is much more volatile. The standard deviation of IRR is 18.6% for buyout funds and 48.9% for VC funds. Moreover, for VC funds the mean of any performance measure is much higher than the median, suggesting that the sample includes some VC funds that perform exceptionally well. Figure 4 illustrates a comparison in IRR distribution between buyout funds and VC funds. The average sequence number is 3.1 for buyout funds and 3.6 for VC funds. Although the sample includes funds raised as late as 2008, on average more than 90% of the committed capital have already been drawn by GPs to make investments. Panel B of Table 1 presents firm-level (i.e. GP-level) characteristics. In general, buyout firms have slightly larger management teams than VC firms. A typical buyout firm has 8 partners, and a typical VC firm has 6 partners. On average, each firm raises 3 funds during the sample period, regardless of the GP type. Also, a typical buyout firm raises a new fund every 4 years, while a typical VC firm raises a new fund every 3 years. Table 2 reports average fund sizes and returns, broken down into vintage years. For both buyouts and VC, the number of funds in the sample increases over the 1980s and the 1990s, peaks in 2000, declines afterwards, and picks up since Figure 5 illustrates the evolution of PE fund sizes, broken down into buyout funds and VC funds. The average buyout fund size gains steadily before 2005, and shoots up afterwards because 30 Preqin provides locations of PE firms (i.e. GPs ) headquarters. However, it does not provide locations of portfolio companies of each fund. I require that all funds in the sample have their GPs headquarters inside America. Among these U.S.-based funds, I exclude funds with their committed capital shown in currencies other than U.S. dollars, as well as funds with their names indicating an investment focus outside America, such as European Fund I, or Asian Fund IV. 31 The average sequence number is The equal-weighted average IRR is 15.2% for buyout funds and 15.8% for VC funds. The equal-weighted average multiple is 1.8 for buyout funds and 1.9 for VC funds. 15

16 of the boom of mega-buyouts, exceeding $1 billion. 33 The average VC fund size peaks at $285 million in 2001, retreats to its 1990s level afterwards, and starts to edge up since 2005, reaching $278 million in Figure 6 depicts how PE fund performance changes over time, broken down into buyout funds and VC funds. 34 Buyout funds raised in 1980s and early 2000s on average perform better than funds raised in 1990s and late 2000s. VC funds raised in 1980s on average deliver steady performance, and those raised in 1990s (except 1999) achieve spectacular average returns because of the internet bubble, whose burst leaves VC funds raised in 2000s struggling. Most of my analysis on fund performance is restricted to funds with vintage years 2004 and earlier. Table 3 presents the fraction of first-, second-, third-, fourth-, and fifth-time funds in this subsample. Among the 1026 funds in the subsample, 26.7% are first-time funds, 22.0% are secondtime funds, 16.4% are third-time funds, 12.8% are fourth-time funds, 7.9% are fifth-time funds, and the remaining 14.2% are funds with sequence numbers higher than 5. The highest sequence number for buyout funds is 10, and the highest sequence number for VC funds is 12. Compared to the sample used by Kaplan and Schoar (2005), my sample has much longer time horizon and higher average sequence number. While in their sample, only 22% are funds with sequence numbers higher than 3, in my subsample this proportion is 35%. The longer sample period and the higher sequence number facilitate the test of long-term performance persistence for PE funds. 4 Empirical Results The model predicts that when exogenous shocks are less volatile, fund performance is more persistent, the reputation mechanism works better, and top fund managers have more incentive to limit fund sizes. On the premise that buyout funds are subject to less volatile shocks than VC funds, I establish the conjecture that the model mechanism is stronger among buyout funds. In particular, I test the following hypotheses: Hypothesis 1. While buyout funds exhibit strong long-term performance persistence across different funds raised by the same GP, VC funds show weak short-run persistence. Hypothesis 2. The size of a buyout GP s new fund is strongly related to the performance of its 33 Fund sizes have been adjusted by annual CPIs, with CPI in 1983 equal to 100. Because CPI after 2005 is higher than 200, the average buyout fund size after 2005, in nominal term, is over $2 billions. 34 Note that performance measures of funds raised in the late 2000s are less accurate than those of funds raised earlier. 16

17 previous funds, whereas the size of a VC GP s new fund is highly associated with the recent VC industry performance rather than the individual GP s. Hypothesis 3. Top buyout GPs raise smaller funds than they could have, while top VC GPs do not limit their fund sizes. 4.1 Performance Persistence To test for the effect of performance persistence, as described in Hypothesis 1, I use performance measure (IRR) as dependent variable and lagged performance measures as explanatory variables, while controlling for a host of other fund characteristics including the fund size, the sequence number, and the year fixed effect: F undirr i t = β β τ F undirrt τ i + η log(f undsize i t) + γsequence i t + F E year, (4.1) τ=1 where F undirr i t is the IRR of the t-th fund raised by PE firm i. 35 Table 4 reports test results for buyout funds. In sum, I find strong persistence in buyout fund returns across different funds raised by the same firm. Column (1) tests the simplest permutation of (4.1), a regression of current fund IRR on lagged fund IRR, controlling for year fixed effect. The coefficient on lagged IRR is positive and strongly significant (at 1% level), and the point estimate is 0.27 with a standard error of This coefficient implies that a 1% increase of return in the previous fund is associated with a 27 basis point better performance in current fund. Because two consecutive funds raised by the same GP are likely to share investment in some portfolio companies, a potential concern arises that the performance persistence shown in column (1) is driven by overlapping investment projects rather than GPs ability. To address this concern, column (2) reports a regression of the current fund return on the second previous fund return. The coefficient remains positive and significant, with the point estimate of 0.10 and a standard error of Column (3) runs the regression on the third previous fund return. The coefficient on F undirrt 3 i is positive and significant at the 1% level; The point estimate is 0.13 with a standard 35 Testing performance persistence for PE funds is distinct from testing performance persistence for mutual funds or hedge funds. PE funds invest in long-term projects that usually start generating profits several years after, their returns exhibit a pronounced life-cycle pattern, which makes examining returns across years within a single fund pointless in determining whether there is performance persistence for the underlying PE firm (i.e. GP). Therefore, we employ the (final) returns of several funds raised by the same GP to test performance persistence for PE funds. 36 Standard errors are calculated by clustering at the firm (i.e. GP) level to adjust for serial correlation and heteroskedasticity. I also run unreported regressions with standard errors clustered by vintage year and obtain similar results. 17

18 error of The fact that an average buyout GP raises a new fund every 4 years implies that a third previous fund is usually raised more than 10 years ago. Nevertheless, a 1% increase of return in that fund is associated with a 13 basis point higher return in current fund. Column (5) shows that the coefficient on the third previous fund return remains its significance even after I control for the previous fund return. Columns (6)-(9) of Table 4 further control for fund sizes and fund sequence numbers. Coefficients on the fund size and the sequence number are both insignificant, while coefficients on all previous fund returns remain the same. Results in column (9) show that a 1% increase in previous fund returns is associated with a combined 64 basis point increase in current fund return, which is obtained by summing all the significant coefficients on previous fund returns. Table 5 presents test results for VC funds. In sum, I find short-run performance persistence in VC fund returns across different funds raised by the same GP. Column (1) in Table 5 contains the regression of current fund return on the lagged fund return. The coefficient on the lagged IRR is positive and significant, with the point estimate of 0.23 and a standard error of However, in Columns (2) and (3), when current fund IRR is regressed on IRRs of the second and the third previous fund, respectively, coefficients on lagged fund returns do not significantly differ from zero. The point estimates of these two coefficients are 0.02 and -0.01, respectively. Adding the previous fund return to explanatory variables does not improve the significance of the coefficient on the second or third previous fund return, but drives the coefficient negative, as shown in Columns (4) and (5). These results show that performance persistence in VC funds lasts only for two consecutive funds, the interval of which is on average 3 years. Therefore, it is possible that the short-run performance persistence in VC funds is driven by overlapping portfolio companies in the two consecutive funds rather than GPs ability. Columns (6)-(9) of Table 5 further control for fund sizes and sequence numbers. Coefficients on all previous fund returns are basically unchanged compared to Columns (2)-(5). My results on performance persistence for VC funds differs from Kaplan and Schoar (2005), who document strong performance persistence for VC funds. While their sample comprises funds raised before 1996, my sample consists of funds raised before Given that VC fund performance is in general much more steady before 1996 than after that, it is not surprising to find much less performance persistence for VC funds with data of longer period and higher average sequence number. The persistence of buyout fund performance, on the other hand, improves compared to the findings of Kaplan and Schoar (2005). 18

19 4.2 Robustness of Performance Persistence Some PE funds have exceptionally high returns. 37 To address the concern that a few outlying funds with abnormally high returns bias the results, I repeat all the exercises in Table 4 and Table 5 with data excluding the 1% of funds with the highest IRRs. Table 6 reports test results for buyout funds with the winsorized data. Compared to the baseline results in Table 4, in general the explanatory power of previous fund returns for current fund performance improves. Specifically, the point estimate of the coefficient on the second previous fund return increases from 0.10 to 0.24, and the point estimate of the coefficient on the third previous fund return increases from 0.13 to 0.26, without losing their significance. These results show that the long-term performance persistence of buyout funds is not driven by a few outliers. Table 7 presents test results for VC funds with the winsorized data. Compared to the baseline results in Table 5, the explanatory power of previous fund returns for current fund performance significantly weakens. In particular, the point estimate of the coefficient on the first previous fund return decreases from 0.23 to 0.17, and loses its significance when other fund characteristics are controlled for, as shown in Columns (7)-(9) of Table 7. Meanwhile, the coefficients on the second and third previous fund returns remain insignificant. These results suggest that the top 1% of VC funds significantly contribute to the existence of short-run performance persistence documented in Table 5. In addition to using the winsorized data to check the robustness, I also extend the sample to include all funds raised before 2008 and repeat the exercise. The results are basically unchanged. So far, IRR is the only performance measure I use in the analysis. To test whether the results on performance persistence survive an alternative performance measure, I repeat all the tests in Table 6 and Table 7, replacing IRR with Multiple : 38 F undmultiple i t = β β τ F undmultiple i t τ + η log(f undsize i t) + γsequence i t + F E year, (4.2) τ=1 where F undmultiple i t is the Multiple of the t-th fund raised by PE firm i. Table 8 presents test results for buyout funds when Multiple is used as the performance measure. Columns (1)-(3) show that coefficients on all three previous fund multiple s are positive 37 For instance, a few VC funds yield annual returns as high as over 200%. 38 Another performance measure of interest is PME (public market equivalent), which is the fund performance relative to public markets. Calculation of PME requires detailed cash flow data, which I do not have. However, as pointed out by Harris et al. (2012), this relative performance measure can be well predicted by absolute performance measures like IRR and Multiple. 19

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know?

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? Preliminary Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? by Robert Harris*, Tim Jenkinson** and Steven N. Kaplan*** This Draft: September 9, 2011 Abstract We present time series evidence on the performance

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRIVATE EQUITY PERFORMANCE: RETURNS PERSISTENCE AND CAPITAL. Steven Kaplan Antoinette Schoar

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRIVATE EQUITY PERFORMANCE: RETURNS PERSISTENCE AND CAPITAL. Steven Kaplan Antoinette Schoar NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRIVATE EQUITY PERFORMANCE: RETURNS PERSISTENCE AND CAPITAL Steven Kaplan Antoinette Schoar Working Paper 9807 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9807 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

MIT Sloan School of Management

MIT Sloan School of Management MIT Sloan School of Management Working Paper 4446-03 November 2003 Private Equity Performance: Returns, Persistence and Capital Flows Steve Kaplan and Antoinette Schoar 2003 by Steve Kaplan and Antoinette

More information

Has Persistence Persisted in Private Equity? Evidence From Buyout and Venture Capital Funds

Has Persistence Persisted in Private Equity? Evidence From Buyout and Venture Capital Funds Has Persistence Persisted in Private Equity? Evidence From Buyout and Venture Capital s Robert S. Harris*, Tim Jenkinson**, Steven N. Kaplan*** and Ruediger Stucke**** Abstract The conventional wisdom

More information

Skill and Luck in Private Equity Performance

Skill and Luck in Private Equity Performance Skill and Luck in Private Equity Performance Arthur Korteweg Morten Sorensen February 2014 Abstract We evaluate the performance of private equity ( PE ) funds, using a variance decomposition model to separate

More information

Private Equity: Past, Present and Future

Private Equity: Past, Present and Future Private Equity: Past, Present and Future Steve Kaplan University of Chicago Booth School of Business 1 Steven N. Kaplan Overview What is PE? What does PE really do? What are the cycles of fundraising and

More information

Private Equity Performance: Returns, Persistence, and Capital Flows

Private Equity Performance: Returns, Persistence, and Capital Flows THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LX, NO. 4 AUGUST 2005 Private Equity Performance: Returns, Persistence, and Capital Flows STEVEN N. KAPLAN and ANTOINETTE SCHOAR ABSTRACT This paper investigates the performance

More information

Private Equity performance: Can you learn the recipe for success?

Private Equity performance: Can you learn the recipe for success? Private Equity performance: Can you learn the recipe for success? Bachelor s thesis, Finance Aalto University School of Business Fall 2017 Tommi Nykänen Abstract In this thesis, I study the relationship

More information

Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital

Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital Hung-Chia Hsu, Vikram Nanda, Qinghai Wang November, 2016 Abstract We study venture capital investment decision within and across successive VC funds

More information

Evaluating Private Equity Returns from the Investor Perspective - are Limited Partners Getting Carried Away?

Evaluating Private Equity Returns from the Investor Perspective - are Limited Partners Getting Carried Away? Evaluating Private Equity Returns from the Investor Perspective - are Limited Partners Getting Carried Away? HEDERSTIERNA, JULIA SABRIE, RICHARD May 15, 2017 M.Sc. Thesis Department of Finance Stockholm

More information

PE: Where has it been? Where is it now? Where is it going?

PE: Where has it been? Where is it now? Where is it going? PE: Where has it been? Where is it now? Where is it going? Steve Kaplan 1 Steven N. Kaplan Overview What does PE do at the portfolio company level? Why? What does PE do at the fund level? Talk about some

More information

Performance and Capital Flows in Private Equity

Performance and Capital Flows in Private Equity Performance and Capital Flows in Private Equity Q Group Fall Seminar 2008 November, 2008 Antoinette Schoar, MIT and NBER Overview Is private equity an asset class? True story lies beyond the aggregates

More information

Cyclicality, Performance Measurement, and Cash Flow Liquidity in Private Equity

Cyclicality, Performance Measurement, and Cash Flow Liquidity in Private Equity Cyclicality, Performance Measurement, and Cash Flow Liquidity in Private Equity David T. Robinson Duke University and NBER Berk A. Sensoy Ohio State University September 2, 2011 Abstract Public and private

More information

A Portrait of Hedge Fund Investors: Flows, Performance and Smart Money

A Portrait of Hedge Fund Investors: Flows, Performance and Smart Money A Portrait of Hedge Fund Investors: Flows, Performance and Smart Money Guillermo Baquero and Marno Verbeek RSM Erasmus University Rotterdam, The Netherlands mverbeek@rsm.nl www.surf.to/marno.verbeek FRB

More information

American Finance Association

American Finance Association American Finance Association Private Equity Performance: Returns, Persistence, and Capital Flows Author(s): Steven N. Kaplan and Antoinette Schoar Source: The Journal of Finance, Vol. 60, No. 4 (Aug.,

More information

Limited Partner Performance and the Maturing of the Private Equity Industry

Limited Partner Performance and the Maturing of the Private Equity Industry Limited Partner Performance and the Maturing of the Private Equity Industry Berk A. Sensoy Ohio State University Yingdi Wang California State University, Fullerton Michael S. Weisbach Ohio State University,

More information

On Venture Capital Fund Returns: The Impact of Sector and Geographic Diversification

On Venture Capital Fund Returns: The Impact of Sector and Geographic Diversification On Venture Capital Fund Returns: The Impact of Sector and Geographic Diversification Adley Bowden PitchBook Data, Inc. Maretno Harjoto Pepperdine University John K. Paglia Pepperdine University Mark Tribbitt

More information

THE HISTORIC PERFORMANCE OF PE: AVERAGE VS. TOP QUARTILE RETURNS Taking Stock after the Crisis

THE HISTORIC PERFORMANCE OF PE: AVERAGE VS. TOP QUARTILE RETURNS Taking Stock after the Crisis NOVEMBER 2010 THE HISTORIC PERFORMANCE OF PE: AVERAGE VS. TOP QUARTILE RETURNS Taking Stock after the Crisis Oliver Gottschalg, info@peracs.com Disclaimer This report presents the results of a statistical

More information

The Return Expectations of Institutional Investors

The Return Expectations of Institutional Investors The Return Expectations of Institutional Investors Aleksandar Andonov Erasmus University Joshua Rauh Stanford GSB, Hoover Institution & NBER January 2018 Motivation Considerable attention has been devoted

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Center for Analytical Finance University of California, Santa Cruz. Working Paper No. 30

Center for Analytical Finance University of California, Santa Cruz. Working Paper No. 30 Center for Analytical Finance University of California, Santa Cruz Working Paper No. 30 Private Equity Performance, Fund Size and Historical Investment Wentao Su Bank of America, wentao.su@bankofamerica.com

More information

Measuring Institutional Investors Skill from Their Investments in Private Equity

Measuring Institutional Investors Skill from Their Investments in Private Equity Measuring Institutional Investors Skill from Their Investments in Private Equity Daniel R. Cavagnaro California State University, Fullerton Berk A. Sensoy Ohio State University Yingdi Wang California State

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring Holmstrom and Tirole (JPE, 1993) The main idea A firm would like to issue shares in the capital market because once these shares are publicly traded, speculators

More information

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed Snehal Banerjee (Northwestern) Brett Green (UC-Berkeley) AFA 2014 Meetings July 2013 Learning about other traders Trade motives

More information

Interim Fund Performance and Fundraising in Private Equity

Interim Fund Performance and Fundraising in Private Equity Interim Fund Performance and Fundraising in Private Equity Brad M. Barber bmbarber@ucdavis.edu Graduate School of Management University of California, Davis Ayako Yasuda asyasuda@ucdavis.edu Graduate School

More information

The Investment Behavior of Buyout Funds: Theory & Evidence

The Investment Behavior of Buyout Funds: Theory & Evidence The Investment Behavior of Buyout Funds: Theory & Evidence Alexander Ljungqvist, Matt Richardson & Daniel Wolfenzon Q Group Presentation: October 15th STORY Assume the optimal transaction is a buyout In

More information

Adverse Selection and the Performance of Private Equity Co-Investments

Adverse Selection and the Performance of Private Equity Co-Investments Adverse Selection and the Performance of Private Equity Co-Investments Reiner Braun Technical University of Munich (TUM), Germany * Tim Jenkinson Saïd Business School, Oxford University, UK Christoph Schemmerl

More information

Understanding Risk and Return in Private Equity

Understanding Risk and Return in Private Equity Understanding Risk and Return in Private Equity David T. Robinson J. Rex Fuqua Distinguished Professor Fuqua School of Business Duke University Private Equity for Large Institutional Investors David T.

More information

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix Conrad Miller Contents A Extensions and Robustness Checks 2 A. Heterogeneity by Employer Size.............................. 2 A.2

More information

Speculative Betas. Harrison Hong and David Sraer Princeton University. September 30, 2012

Speculative Betas. Harrison Hong and David Sraer Princeton University. September 30, 2012 Speculative Betas Harrison Hong and David Sraer Princeton University September 30, 2012 Introduction Model 1 factor static Shorting OLG Exenstion Calibration High Risk, Low Return Puzzle Cumulative Returns

More information

Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital

Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital Scott Hsu, Vikram Nanda, Qinghai Wang February, 2018 Abstract We study venture capital investment decisions within and across funds of VC firms.

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURING INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS SKILL FROM THEIR INVESTMENTS IN PRIVATE EQUITY

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURING INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS SKILL FROM THEIR INVESTMENTS IN PRIVATE EQUITY NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURING INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS SKILL FROM THEIR INVESTMENTS IN PRIVATE EQUITY Daniel R. Cavagnaro Berk A. Sensoy Yingdi Wang Michael S. Weisbach Working Paper 22547 http://www.nber.org/papers/w22547

More information

Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics

Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics Fisher College of Business Working Paper Series Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics Private Equity Performance: A Survey Steven N. Kaplan University of Chicago and NBER Berk A. Sensoy

More information

AN ALM ANALYSIS OF PRIVATE EQUITY. Henk Hoek

AN ALM ANALYSIS OF PRIVATE EQUITY. Henk Hoek AN ALM ANALYSIS OF PRIVATE EQUITY Henk Hoek Applied Paper No. 2007-01 January 2007 OFRC WORKING PAPER SERIES AN ALM ANALYSIS OF PRIVATE EQUITY 1 Henk Hoek 2, 3 Applied Paper No. 2007-01 January 2007 Ortec

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Indexing and Price Informativeness

Indexing and Price Informativeness Indexing and Price Informativeness Hong Liu Washington University in St. Louis Yajun Wang University of Maryland IFS SWUFE August 3, 2017 Liu and Wang Indexing and Price Informativeness 1/25 Motivation

More information

Financial Intermediation in Private Equity: How Well Do Funds of Funds Perform?

Financial Intermediation in Private Equity: How Well Do Funds of Funds Perform? Financial Intermediation in Private Equity: How Well Do Funds of Funds Perform? Robert S. Harris* Tim Jenkinson** Steven N. Kaplan*** and Ruediger Stucke**** Abstract This paper focuses on funds of funds

More information

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Miguel Antón, Florian Ederer, Mireia Giné, and Martin Schmalz August 13, 2016 Abstract This internet appendix provides

More information

The Performance of Private Equity

The Performance of Private Equity The Performance of Private Equity Chris Higson London Business School Rüdiger Stucke University of Oxford Abstract We present conclusive evidence on the performance of private equity, using a high quality

More information

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination Carl E. Walsh March 8, 017 Contents 1 Policy Coordination 1 1.1 The Basic Model..................................... 1. Equilibrium with Coordination.............................

More information

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models Preliminary Lecture Notes Hongbin Cai and Xi Weng Department of Applied Economics, Guanghua School of Management Peking University November 2014 Contents 1 Static Moral Hazard

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 2/28/2012 Abstract We

More information

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea Hangyong Lee Korea development Institute December 2005 Abstract This paper investigates the empirical relationship

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

Measuring Institutional Investors Skill at Making Private Equity Investments

Measuring Institutional Investors Skill at Making Private Equity Investments Measuring Institutional Investors Skill at Making Private Equity Investments Daniel R. Cavagnaro California State University, Fullerton Berk A. Sensoy Vanderbilt University Yingdi Wang California State

More information

Asset Pricing Implications of Social Networks. Han N. Ozsoylev University of Oxford

Asset Pricing Implications of Social Networks. Han N. Ozsoylev University of Oxford Asset Pricing Implications of Social Networks Han N. Ozsoylev University of Oxford 1 Motivation - Communication in financial markets in financial markets, agents communicate and learn from each other this

More information

Socially-Optimal Design of Crowdsourcing Platforms with Reputation Update Errors

Socially-Optimal Design of Crowdsourcing Platforms with Reputation Update Errors Socially-Optimal Design of Crowdsourcing Platforms with Reputation Update Errors 1 Yuanzhang Xiao, Yu Zhang, and Mihaela van der Schaar Abstract Crowdsourcing systems (e.g. Yahoo! Answers and Amazon Mechanical

More information

The private equity return gap

The private equity return gap The private equity return gap Stephannie Larocque, Sophie Shive and Jennifer Sustersic Stevens November 1, 2018 Abstract Investors in private equity funds do not control the timing of their cash flows

More information

Online Appendix (Not For Publication)

Online Appendix (Not For Publication) A Online Appendix (Not For Publication) Contents of the Appendix 1. The Village Democracy Survey (VDS) sample Figure A1: A map of counties where sample villages are located 2. Robustness checks for the

More information

Reading the Tea Leaves: Model Uncertainty, Robust Foreca. Forecasts, and the Autocorrelation of Analysts Forecast Errors

Reading the Tea Leaves: Model Uncertainty, Robust Foreca. Forecasts, and the Autocorrelation of Analysts Forecast Errors Reading the Tea Leaves: Model Uncertainty, Robust Forecasts, and the Autocorrelation of Analysts Forecast Errors December 1, 2016 Table of Contents Introduction Autocorrelation Puzzle Hansen-Sargent Autocorrelation

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring?

Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring? Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring? Peter L. Swan ACE Conference, July 13, 2018, Canberra UNSW Business School, Sydney Australia July 13, 2018 UNSW Australia, Sydney, Australia 1 /

More information

Is There a Size Disadvantage in the European Private Equity Market? Measuring the Impact of Committed Capital on Net Buyout Fund Returns

Is There a Size Disadvantage in the European Private Equity Market? Measuring the Impact of Committed Capital on Net Buyout Fund Returns Is There a Size Disadvantage in the European Private Equity Market? Measuring the Impact of Committed Capital on Net Buyout Fund Returns Emil Mahjoub (23004)* Filiph Nilsson (23038)** Tutor: Assistant

More information

Internet Appendix for. A new method to estimate risk and return of. non-traded assets from cash flows: The case of. private equity funds

Internet Appendix for. A new method to estimate risk and return of. non-traded assets from cash flows: The case of. private equity funds Internet Appendix for A new method to estimate risk and return of non-traded assets from cash flows: The case of private equity funds Joost Driessen Tse-Chun Lin Ludovic Phalippou February 2011 1 Internet

More information

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure Yosuke Kimura Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo March 20, 2017 Abstract This paper considers the relationship between stock

More information

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes Syed M. Hussain Samreen Malik May 9,. Online Appendix.. Anticipated versus Unanticipated Tax changes Comparing our estimates with the estimates

More information

Performance of Private Equity Funds: Another Puzzle?

Performance of Private Equity Funds: Another Puzzle? Performance of Private Equity Funds: Another Puzzle? September 2005 Using a unique and comprehensive dataset, we report that investing in the overall private equity portfolio has been a highly negative

More information

Asymmetric Information and the Impact on Interest Rates. Evidence from Forecast Data

Asymmetric Information and the Impact on Interest Rates. Evidence from Forecast Data Asymmetric Information and the Impact on Interest Rates Evidence from Forecast Data Asymmetric Information Hypothesis (AIH) Asserts that the federal reserve possesses private information about the current

More information

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality DORON NISSIM* Corporate disclosures are an important source of information for investors. Many studies have documented strong price

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility and Coordination Failures What makes financial systems fragile? What causes crises

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1.1 WHAT IS VOLATILITY? It is useful to start with an explanation of what volatility is, at least for the purpose of clarifying the scope of this book. Volatility

More information

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market? International Review of Finance, 2017 Can Hedge Funds Time the Market? MICHAEL W. BRANDT,FEDERICO NUCERA AND GIORGIO VALENTE Duke University, The Fuqua School of Business, Durham, NC LUISS Guido Carli

More information

Game Theory Fall 2003

Game Theory Fall 2003 Game Theory Fall 2003 Problem Set 5 [1] Consider an infinitely repeated game with a finite number of actions for each player and a common discount factor δ. Prove that if δ is close enough to zero then

More information

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES KRISTOFFER P. NIMARK Lucas Island Model The Lucas Island model appeared in a series of papers in the early 970s

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PAY FOR PERFORMANCE FROM FUTURE FUND FLOWS: THE CASE OF PRIVATE EQUITY

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PAY FOR PERFORMANCE FROM FUTURE FUND FLOWS: THE CASE OF PRIVATE EQUITY NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PAY FOR PERFORMANCE FROM FUTURE FUND FLOWS: THE CASE OF PRIVATE EQUITY Ji-Woong Chung Berk A. Sensoy Lea H. Stern Michael S. Weisbach Working Paper 16369 http://www.nber.org/papers/w16369

More information

A Model Calibration. 1 Earlier versions of this dataset have, for example, been used by Krohmer et al. (2009), Cumming et al.

A Model Calibration. 1 Earlier versions of this dataset have, for example, been used by Krohmer et al. (2009), Cumming et al. A Model Calibration This appendix illustrates the model calibration. Where possible, baseline parameters are chosen in the following such that they correspond to an investment in an average buyout fund.

More information

Are U.S. Companies Too Short-Term Oriented? Some Thoughts

Are U.S. Companies Too Short-Term Oriented? Some Thoughts Are U.S. Companies Too Short-Term Oriented? Some Thoughts Steve Kaplan University of Chicago Booth School of Business 1 Steven N. Kaplan Overview Much criticism of U.S. economy / companies as too short-term

More information

Alternative Investment Vehicles: Issues in Private Equity Management

Alternative Investment Vehicles: Issues in Private Equity Management Alternative Investment Vehicles: Issues in Private Equity Management Axel Buchner and Niklas Wagner University of Passau, Germany EUROPEAN INVESTMENT BANK, Luxembourg, January 30, 2014 Axel Buchner and

More information

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4 Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4.1 Introduction Modelling and predicting financial market volatility has played an important role for market participants as it enables

More information

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam Optimal Financial Education Avanidhar Subrahmanyam Motivation The notion that irrational investors may be prevalent in financial markets has taken on increased impetus in recent years. For example, Daniel

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LOCAL OVERWEIGHTING AND UNDERPERFORMANCE: EVIDENCE FROM LIMITED PARTNER PRIVATE EQUITY INVESTMENTS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LOCAL OVERWEIGHTING AND UNDERPERFORMANCE: EVIDENCE FROM LIMITED PARTNER PRIVATE EQUITY INVESTMENTS NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LOCAL OVERWEIGHTING AND UNDERPERFORMANCE: EVIDENCE FROM LIMITED PARTNER PRIVATE EQUITY INVESTMENTS Yael V. Hochberg Joshua D. Rauh Working Paper 17122 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17122

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow, Co-movements of Shanghai and New York stock prices by time-varying regressions Gregory C Chow a, Changjiang Liu b, Linlin Niu b,c a Department of Economics, Fisher Hall Princeton University, Princeton,

More information

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 9

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 9 Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 9 Quantitative Equity Portfolio Management Haksun Li haksun.li@numericalmethod.com www.numericalmethod.com Outline Alpha Factor Models References

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Internet Appendix for Private Equity Firms Reputational Concerns and the Costs of Debt Financing. Rongbing Huang, Jay R. Ritter, and Donghang Zhang

Internet Appendix for Private Equity Firms Reputational Concerns and the Costs of Debt Financing. Rongbing Huang, Jay R. Ritter, and Donghang Zhang Internet Appendix for Private Equity Firms Reputational Concerns and the Costs of Debt Financing Rongbing Huang, Jay R. Ritter, and Donghang Zhang February 20, 2014 This internet appendix provides additional

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes *

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes * Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes * E. Han Kim and Paige Ouimet This appendix contains 10 tables reporting estimation results mentioned in the paper but not

More information

Investor Flows and Fragility in Corporate Bond Funds. Itay Goldstein, Wharton Hao Jiang, Michigan State David Ng, Cornell

Investor Flows and Fragility in Corporate Bond Funds. Itay Goldstein, Wharton Hao Jiang, Michigan State David Ng, Cornell Investor Flows and Fragility in Corporate Bond Funds Itay Goldstein, Wharton Hao Jiang, Michigan State David Ng, Cornell Total Net Assets and Dollar Flows of Active Corporate Bond Funds $Billion 2,000

More information

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation Tao Wang Queens College and the Graduate Center of the City University of New York Abstract Stock return volatilities are related to firms' financial

More information

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation ECONOMIC BULLETIN 3/218 ANALYTICAL ARTICLES Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation Ángel Estrada and Francesca Viani 6 September 218 Following

More information

AMERICAN INVESTMENT COUNCIL. Performance Update 2017 Q3

AMERICAN INVESTMENT COUNCIL. Performance Update 2017 Q3 AMERICAN INVESTMENT COUNCIL Performance Update 2017 Q3 Private Equity Performance Benchmarks (as of September 30, 2017) Private Equity Benchmark Returns (Horizon IRR) 1 1-Year 3-Year 5-Year 10-Year BISON

More information

Commodity price movements and monetary policy in Asia

Commodity price movements and monetary policy in Asia Commodity price movements and monetary policy in Asia Changyong Rhee 1 and Hangyong Lee 2 Abstract Emerging Asian economies typically have high shares of food in their consumption baskets, relatively low

More information

CORPORATE ANNOUNCEMENTS OF EARNINGS AND STOCK PRICE BEHAVIOR: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

CORPORATE ANNOUNCEMENTS OF EARNINGS AND STOCK PRICE BEHAVIOR: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE CORPORATE ANNOUNCEMENTS OF EARNINGS AND STOCK PRICE BEHAVIOR: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE By Ms Swati Goyal & Dr. Harpreet kaur ABSTRACT: This paper empirically examines whether earnings reports possess informational

More information

Real Estate Crashes and Bank Lending. March 2004

Real Estate Crashes and Bank Lending. March 2004 Real Estate Crashes and Bank Lending March 2004 Andrey Pavlov Simon Fraser University 8888 University Dr. Burnaby, BC V5A 1S6, Canada E-mail: apavlov@sfu.ca, Tel: 604 291 5835 Fax: 604 291 4920 and Susan

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using SV Model In this chapter, the empirical performance of GARCH(1,1), GARCH-KF and SV models from

More information

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment Avihai Lifschitz Tel Aviv University This Draft: October 2015 Abstract This paper develops a dynamic model of the labor market, in which the employed workers,

More information

Asia Private Equity Institute (APEI) Private Equity Insights Q3 2012

Asia Private Equity Institute (APEI) Private Equity Insights Q3 2012 Asia Private Equity Institute (APEI) Private Equity Insights Q3 212 Contents An Introduction to the APEI The Geography of Private Equity by Melvyn Teo Update on the Institute s Activities An Introduction

More information

Buy Low, Sell High? Do Private Equity Fund Managers Have Market Timing Abilities?

Buy Low, Sell High? Do Private Equity Fund Managers Have Market Timing Abilities? P Buy Low, Sell High? Do Private Equity Fund Managers Have Market Timing Abilities? Tim Jenkinson*, Stefan Morkoetter**, and Thomas Wetzer*** March 2018 Abstract When investors commit capital to a private

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

AMERICAN INVESTMENT COUNCIL. Performance Update 2017 Q4

AMERICAN INVESTMENT COUNCIL. Performance Update 2017 Q4 AMERICAN INVESTMENT COUNCIL Performance Update 07 Q4 Private Equity Performance Benchmarks (as of December 3, 07) Private Equity Benchmark Returns (Horizon IRR) -Year 3-Year 5-Year 0-Year BISON Private

More information