The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement 1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement 1"

Transcription

1 The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement 1 By Richard O. Michaud, Robert O. Michaud, and David N. Esch 2 Draft: September An earlier version with the same title by Richard Michaud and Robert Michaud was published as a New Frontier Advisors Newsletter, July Richard O. Michaud is CEO of New Frontier Advisors, LLC, Boston, MA Robert O. Michaud is CIO of New Frontier Advisors, LLC. David N. Esch is Managing Director of Research, New Frontier Advisors, LLC.

2 2015 New Frontier Advisors, LLC. All rights reserved. Please do not copy or reproduce in any form without permission of the authors. Abstract Grinold (1989) posits that the theoretical value added of an optimal investment strategy is approximately proportional to the product of the square root of breadth and skill. Principles derived from Grinold s Law are often used for designing a quantitative active investment fund. Grinold and Kahn (1995) state that: It takes a modest amount of skill to win (the investment game) as long as that skill is deployed frequently and across a large number of stocks. They argue for frequent trading, large stock universes, and adding factors to models of forecast return. Clarke et al (2002) include a transfer coefficient in the formula to argue that removing constraints adds investment value, a result often used to rationalize many hedge fund strategies. We note that the formula treats asset management as a casino game that ignores estimation error and the role of inequality constraints necessary for properly defining portfolio optimality in practice. We use a simulation framework to confirm that principles commonly associated with the fundamental law are invalid and often self-defeating. Such principles have been taught in academic and professional journals for many years and likely adversely impact many hundreds of billions of dollars or more in contemporary practice. 2

3 The Grinold (1989) Fundamental Law of Active Management, is one of the most widely referenced publications in contemporary investment theory and practice. The Grinold insample (mathematical) formula is based on inequality unconstrained mean-variance (MV) efficient frontier optimization translated to the residual or benchmark relative return framework. Grinold asserts that the value added of an optimized MV investment strategy is proportional to the in-sample information ratio (IR) (alpha over residual risk). He further decomposes the IR into (approximately) the product of two simple attributes of an investment strategy square root of breadth (BR) and skill (IC). 3 The IC represents the manager s information coefficient or correlation of forecast and ex post return. Breadth represents the number of independent bets or factors associated with the strategy. Based on the formula Grinold and Kahn (1995, 1999) (GK) state that: It takes a modest amount of skill to win (the investment game) as long as that skill is deployed frequently and across a large number of stocks. 4 Their recommendations include increasing trading frequency, size of the optimization universe, and factors to models for forecasting return. There are three main assumptions that underlie their result: 1) accurate measure of IC; 2) independent sources of information, i. e. an information-rich universe that can always be mined for new independent sources of knowledge about investable securities; 3) IC the same for each component, i. e. maintainable over increases in breadth. GK use a roulette game framework to provide intuition for their results. Their principles are often used to rationalize many optimized portfolio investment strategies in current practice. Clarke, de Silva and Thorley (2002, 2006) (CST) generalize the Grinold formula by introducing the transfer coefficient (TC). The TC is a scaling factor that measures how information in individual securities is transferred into managed portfolios given Grinold formula assumptions. In this in-sample framework, TC measures the presumed reduction in investment value from imposing optimization constraints. This widely influential article has been used to promote many variations of long-short and hedge fund equity investment strategies. 5 A significant literature exists on applying the Grinold law and variations for rationalizing various active equity management strategies, particularly those associated with long-short and hedge fund portfolios. Extensions include: Buckle (2004), Qian and Hua (2004), Zhou (2008), Gorman et al (2010), Ding (2010), Huiz and Derwall (2011). Industry tutorials and perspectives include Kahn (1997), Kroll et al (2005), Utermann (2013), Darnell and Ferguson (2014). Teachings include the Chartered Financial Analyst (CFA) Institute Level 2, the Chartered Alternative Investment Analyst (CAIA) Level 1 and many conferences and graduate level courses in finance. Texts discussing the formula and applications 3 Note that the Grinold optimization framework which is analytically derived is not to be confused with Markowitz (1952, 1959) which assumes linear (inequality and equality) constrained portfolios and requires quadratic programming techniques to compute the MV efficient frontier. In particular, the Markowitz efficient frontier is generally a concave curve even in a residual return framework while in Grinold (see e.g., GK 1995, p. 94) it is a straight line emanating from a zero residual risk and return benchmark portfolio. 4 GK (1995, Ch. 6, p. 130), also GK (1999, Ch. 6, p. 162). 5 One example is Kroll et al (2005). Michaud (1993) was the first to note possible limitations of the longshort active equity optimization framework. 3

4 include Focardi and Fabozzi (2004), Jacobs and Levy (2008), Diderich (2009), Anson et al (2012), Schulmerich et al (2015). The essential wisdom of the Grinold formula adding an independent investment significant positive source of information adds investment value is uncontroversial. However, investment intuition supported by rigorous simulation studies demonstrate that the Grinold based GK and CST principles are invalid in practice and often defeat the effective use of investment information, even if the three demanding assumptions above are satisfied. The errors are due to ignoring estimation error in risk-return estimates and inequality constraints required for properly defining out-of-sample portfolio optimality. 6 Markowitz (1952, 1959) MV optimization, other portfolio construction procedures, and much financial theory are similarly afflicted. 7 The GK and CST principles have been taught for many years and likely adversely impact many hundreds of billions of dollars or more in contemporary asset management. The outline of the paper is as follows. Section 1 presents the Grinold formula, the GK and CST prescriptions for active management and a critique of their casino management rationale. Section 2 discusses the four fallacies associated with GK and CST prescriptions in investment intuitive terms. Section 3 presents a framework for our simulation studies addressing the Roll (1992) critique of benchmark optimization used in Grinold. Section 4 presents the Monte Carlo simulation studies that confirm and refine our conclusion that the principles commonly associated with the fundamental law are invalid and often selfdefeating. Section 5 provides resolutions for practical active optimization under estimation uncertainty. Section 6 provides a summary and conclusions. 1.0 Grinold s Fundamental Law of Active Management Grinold (1989) demonstrates that the in-sample value added of a MV inequality unconstrained optimized residual return investment strategy relative to an index or benchmark is proportional to the information ratio (IR) (alpha over residual risk). In Grinold s Law of Active Management the IR of a MV optimized investment strategy is shown to be (approximately) the product of the square root of the breadth (BR) and the assumed information correlation (IC). 8 Mathematically, IR IC * BR where IR = information ratio = (alpha) / (residual or active risk) IC = information correlation (ex ante, ex post return correlation) BR = breadth or number of independent sources of information. 6 The GK ( nd ed.) discussion of uncertainty in IC estimation is independent of estimation error uncertainty in portfolio optimality, the subject of this paper. Esch (2015) further discusses IC estimation issues. 7 For further discussion see Michaud (1989, 1998), Michaud and Michaud (2008a, 2008b) and Section 5.2 below. 8 The derivation is given in GK, Ch. 6, and Technical Appendix. 4

5 The essential wisdom of the formula, that successful asset management depends on both the information level of the forecasts and the breadth associated with the estimates, is not in doubt. What is in doubt are the principles associated with the formula that the value of an optimized investment strategy necessarily increases with increasing numbers of assets in the optimization universe, number of factors in a multiple valuation framework and increased trading frequency in practical applications. Clarke et al (2002) define the transfer coefficient (TC) as the cross-sectional correlation of risk-adjusted active weights with risk-adjusted forecasted residual returns for the N securities in the optimization universe. With additional assumptions they show that the TC can be incorporated into the Grinold formula and acts as a multiplicative scaling (a number between 0 and 1) of the IC. As constraints are added to the optimization, the TC is shown to diminish from its theoretical optimal value of one. From this point of view constraints limit the value of the information in the strategy and rationalize various long-short and unconstrained hedge fund strategies. There are two fundamental reasons for limitations of principles derived from the Grinold law for practical asset management: 1) the formula ignores the impact of estimation error in investment information on out-of-sample investment performance; 2) the formula assumes an unconstrained MV optimization framework and ignores the necessity of including many economically meaningful inequality constraints required for defining portfolio optimality in practice. We show that GK and CST prescriptions associated with the formula are not reliable and generally not recommendable for practice. 1.1 The Casino Game Rationale GK provide a revealing rationalization of the implications of their formula with reference to casino roulette games. In a casino the return distribution and hence the IC of plays of the roulette wheel is known, statistically significant positive, and independent. In this case the Grinold formula under the assumptions gives the (nearly) correct economic value of the play of the casino game. In contrast, the IC of the play of an investment game has estimation error, is by definition unknown, may be insignificant or even negatively related to return, and may not be independent the IC may change if the frequency of investing or the size of the universe is changed. Increasing the number of plays of an investment game if the return distribution or IC is unreliably positive may often be undesirable. While the GK and CST frameworks assume no constraints on the number of plays of the roulette game, there are practical limits. It is not possible to expand the number of roulette wheels infinitely. There are limits to the ability of croupiers to speed up the game and too frequent plays may reduce the take for each play. While adding more roulette tables to the casino may be theoretically beneficial, there are costs including limits to floor space, adding more croupiers, more advertising and other expenses. Also, there are limits to sustainable gaming interest in any community. More plays of the game in practice, may often be infeasible or even undesirable. Similar constraint limitations also exist in asset management and will be discussed further below. However, our simulation study shows that even in the absence of these types of real-world limitations, the presence of estimation 5

6 error causes diminishing performance gains, and a cumulative underperformance relative to the predictions of the fundamental law. GK principles apply to casino games where estimation error and important practical issues are ignored. But investing is not a casino game and asset managers do not know with certainty the risk and return distribution ex ante in practice. 9 Note that casino return certainty is also assumed in many other portfolio construction procedures in investment practice and much financial theory. 10 Their results follow from a theoretical framework that ignores the transcendent importance of estimation error and economically valid inequality constraints for properly defining portfolio optimality in practice. The following sections more formally explore the implications of estimation error and inequality constraints on the GK and CST proposals for asset management. 2.0 Discussion of GK and CST Prescriptions The four principles that are associated with GK and CST are: 1) increasing size of the optimization universe; 2) invest often or frequent trading; 3) add factors to forecast model; 4) remove constraints. In this section we discuss the limitations of each prescription from an intuitive point of view. 2.1 Large Optimization Universe Fallacy GK argue that investment value increases as the size of the optimization universe conditional that the IC is roughly equal for all securities in a given optimization universe. How realistic is this assumption? For a small universe of securities the assumption of uniform average IC may be tenable. Small universes may be fairly homogeneous in character. However, for a large and expanding optimization universe, it seems evidently untenable to assume uniform average IC across all subsets. Any manager will naturally use the securities with the best information first. While theoretically, adding more assets may add marginally to breadth, all other things the same, it is also likely to result in less predictable securities and reducing the overall average IC level of the universe. A lower level of average IC is undesirable according to the formula and may cancel any gains made by increasing breadth by increasing size. The issue can be framed in a more common practical setting. Consider an analyst suddenly asked to cover twice as many stocks. Given limitations of time and resources, it is highly unlikely that the analyst s average IC is the same for the expanded set of stocks. Issues of resources and time rationalize why analysts tend to specialize in areas of the market or managers in investment strategies that limit the number of securities that they cover. In practice many traditional managers limit the number of securities they include in their 9 The use of insider information is illegal under U.S. security laws. 10 A game framework has long been associated with the history of probability and applications. In this case there is assumed a known or underlying stable probability distribution associated with inference. More recently the notion of probability that includes uncertainty or estimation error has been found important in many applications in business and social sciences such as finance. For an up-to-date discussion see Weisberg (2014). 6

7 active portfolio to not much more than twenty or fifty. Except for relatively small asset universes, the average IC and overall level of IR may often be a decreasing function of the number of stocks in the optimization universe, all other things the same. Grinold and Kahn seem to be aware of these limitations, for example as suggested by their statement The fundamental law says that more breadth is better, provided the skill can be maintained. Nevertheless, this important caveat is omitted from their final summary and often ignored by practitioners who may not have accurate knowledge of their true IC, especially when coverage increases to larger universes of assets and/or factors. 2.2 Multiple Factor Model Fallacy Large stock universe optimizations may include the S&P500, Russell 1000 or even a global stock index as benchmarks. In this case individual analysis of each stock is generally infeasible and analysts typically rely on factor valuation frameworks for forecasting alpha. For example, stock rankings or valuations may be based in part on an earnings yield factor. 11 As GK note, if earnings yield is the only factor for ranking stocks, there is only one independent source of information and the breadth equals one. In the Grinold formula, BR is identified with the number of uncorrelated investment significant positive factors used to forecast alpha. The formula shows that the IR increases as the square root of the number of independent positive significant factors in the multiple valuation forecast model. However, in practice, asset valuation factors are often highly correlated and may often be statistically insignificant providing dubious out-of-sample forecast value. 12 Finding factors that are reasonably uncorrelated and positive investment significant relative to ex post return is no simple task. Factors are often chosen from a small number of categories considered to be relatively uncorrelated and positively related to return such as value, momentum, quality, dividends, and discounted cash flow. 13 In experience, breadth of multiple valuation models is typically very limited and unlikely to be very much greater than five independent of the size of the optimization universe. 14,15 As in adding stocks to an optimization universe, adding factors at some point is likely to include increasingly unreliable factors that are likely to reduce, not increase, the average IC of an investment strategy. Michaud (1990) provides a simple illustration of adding factors to a multiple valuation model. While adding investment significant factors related to return can be additive to IC, it can also be detrimental in practice. There is no free lunch. Adding factors can as easily 11 Some standard methods for converting rankings to a ratio scale to input to a portfolio optimizer include Farrell (1983) and references. Michaud (1998, Ch. 12) notes some common scaling errors. 12 There is a limit to the number of independent investment significant factors even in many commercial risk models, often far less than ten. 13 Standard methods such as principal component analysis for finding orthogonal risk factors are seldom also reliably related to return. 14 See e.g., Michaud (1999). 15 While principal component or factor analysis procedures for identifying orthogonal factors in a data set may be used, most studies find no more than five to ten investment significant identifiable factors that are also useful for investment practice. 7

8 reduce as well as enhance forecast value, and the number of factors that can be added while maintaining a desirable total IC is severely limited in practice. 2.3 Invest Often Fallacy GK recommend increasing trading period frequency or plays of the investment game to increase the IR of a MV optimized portfolio. The Grinold formula assumes trading decision period independence and constant IC level. However, almost all investment strategies have natural limits on trading frequency. 16 For example, an asset manager trading on book or earnings to price will have significant limitations increasing trading frequency smaller than a month or quarter. Reducing the trading period below some limit will generally reduce effectiveness while increasing trading costs. Fundamentally, trading frequency is limited by constraints on the investment process relative to investment style. 17 Deep value managers may often be reluctant to trade much more than once a year while growth stock managers may want to trade multiple times in a given year. Increased trading, to be effective, requires increasing the independence of the trading decision while maintaining the same level of skill. This will generally require increased resources, if feasible, all other things the same. The normal trading decision period should be sufficiently frequent, but not more so, in order to extract relatively independent reliable information for a given investment strategy and market conditions. It is worth noting that the notion of normal trading period for an investment strategy does not imply strict calendar trading. Portfolio drift and market volatility relative to new optimal may require trading earlier or later than an investment strategy normal period. In addition a manager may need to consider trading whenever new information is available or client objectives have changed. Portfolio monitoring relative to a normal trading period including estimation error is further discussed in Michaud et al (2012). 2.4 Remove Constraints Fallacy Markowitz s ( ) MV optimization can accommodate linear equality and inequality constraints. In actual investment practice, MV optimized portfolios typically include many linear constraints. This is because MV optimized portfolios are often investment unintuitive and impractical. Constraints are often imposed to manage instability, ambiguity, poor diversification characteristics, and limit poor out-of-sample performance. 18 However, constraints added solely for marketing or cosmetic purposes may result in little, if any, investment value and may obstruct the deployment of useful information in risk-return estimates. In general, inequality constraints are necessary for defining portfolio optimality in practice. Inequality constraints reflect the financial fact that even the largest financial institutions 16 Special cases may include proprietary trading desk strategies where the information level is maintained at a reasonable level and trading costs are nearly non-existent. Other cases, such as high frequency and algorithmic trading are arguably not investment strategies but very low level IC trading pattern recognition relative to highly sophisticated automated liquidity exchange intermediation. 17 Trading costs and market volatility are additional considerations. 18 Jobson and Korkie (1980, 1981), Michaud (1989). 8

9 have economic shorting and leveraging limitations. Recently, Markowitz (2005) demonstrates the importance of practical linear inequality constraints in defining portfolio optimality for theoretical finance and the validity of many tools of practical investment management. Long-only constraints limit liability risk, a largely unmeasured factor in most portfolio risk models and often an institutional requirement. Regulatory considerations may often mandate the use of no-shorting inequality constraints. Performance benchmarks may often mandate index related sets of constraints for controlling and monitoring investment objectives. In an important early study, Frost and Savarino (1988) demonstrate that sign or nonnegative inequality constraints may limit the impact of estimation error and consequently improve out-of-sample investment performance, contradicting CST. This is because economically valid constraints act like Bayesian priors focused on portfolio structure rather than the return estimation by enforcing rules representing legitimate information not contained in the optimization. Such restriction can mitigate estimation error in risk-return estimates implicitly by forcing the solutions towards more likely optimal portfolios. 3.0 Residual and Total Return MV Optimization The Grinold MV active management framework reflects much investment practice. An active manager is typically hired to explicitly beat some benchmark such as the S&P 500 or Russell 1000 index while limiting tracking error or residual risk. The mathematical consequence of using a residual rather than total return framework is simply a revision of the MV optimization budget constraint to sum to zero instead of one relative to index weights, and a consequent reformulation of the variance component of the utility objective. Interestingly, contemporary commercial equity risk models are often defined for either total or residual return optimization. The notion is that the optimal MV residual return portfolio for a specified index tracking error can also be estimated as a total return MV optimization calibrated to the desired tracking error. However, any practical benefits associated with the residual return MV optimization framework may often be associated with serious investment limitations. 3.1 The Roll Critique Roll (1992) provides a serious critique of the Grinold active return MV optimization framework. Roll shows that if the index is not total return MV efficient all the portfolios on the index relative efficient frontier are dominated in total return MV space. This means that there are always portfolios with less risk or more estimated return or both than any portfolio on the residual return efficient frontier. The presumed convenience of optimizing a portfolio relative to a given benchmark can lead to very poor investments. On the other hand, as Roll notes, if the index is MV efficient, the total and residual return efficient frontiers coincide and the residual return optimized portfolios are also total return MV efficient. In this case portfolios on the MV total return efficient frontier are also residual return MV efficient relative to some level of tracking error and maximization of IR is equivalent to max Sharpe ratio (MSR) optimization in total return space. From the point of view of rational markets, it is hard to justify the IR optimization framework if the index is not, in some investment meaningful sense, at least approximately 9

10 MV efficient. 19 We note that a framework where the Grinold assumptions are also valid for total return MV optimization is a best case for understanding the practical investment limitations of the GK and CST prescriptions. It is also important to avoid the Roll critique as an explanation for poor performance in our simulation experiment, which is designed to rigorously demonstrate the limitations of GK and CST principles in the context of estimation error. 3.2 Merton (1987) and Benchmark MV Efficiency In an important paper for investment practice, Merton (1987) proposes an information cost structure model of MV market equilibrium. In his study he presents relatively simple conditions under which common benchmarks in active management practice may be considered essentially total return MV efficient. Merton s incomplete information framework posits constraints and information levels where investors act as if they do not know many firms in large capital markets. 20 In this case, the cost of information limits the market portfolio that can be efficiently considered for investment. For example, a small cap stock manager may claim specialized expertise for managing a benchmark of small cap stocks relative to a larger universe of securities but little if any for large cap. Institutional investors often consider it optimal to hire managers with specialized expertise in different segments of the market, hoping that the total will exhibit a globally enhanced level of return for given risk level. In the Merton model, expected return reflects a discount factor for the subset of information available stocks. As Merton notes, there are many possible frameworks for justifying the notion of market equilibrium in incomplete information. These may include prudentinvesting laws, regulatory constraints, and short-sale proscriptions. Merton s framework rationalizes a variety of contexts that are consistent with actual sophisticated asset management. In the incomplete information case and in variations, the benchmark can be assumed essentially total return MV efficient. Alternatively, the contrapositive of the generalized Merton framework implies the existence of managers willfully managing money inefficiently and sophisticated investors and institutions willingly investing in such strategies, a contradiction of rational markets. As Roll notes, the notion of an index that is not, in some fundamentally meaningful sense, MV efficient raises important investment issues independent of those in this report. Our working assumption is that the benchmark can be assumed MV efficient relative to some set of constraints and assumptions including information costs. In this case the IR characteristics of the unconstrained MV optimal portfolio in a residual return framework can be equivalently analyzed with respect to the properties of maximum Sharpe ratio 19 One rationale noted by Roll is that estimation error is so extensive that the benchmark may not be statistically indistinguishable from MV efficiency. 20 Note that a benchmark consistent with the Merton incomplete information framework requires economic considerations and is inconsistent with actuarial based liability driven investing (LDI) popular with many actuarial and some pension consulting firms. See Michaud (1998, Ch. 10) and associated references for defining a liability benchmark based on economic principles. 10

11 optimal portfolios in total return MV space. We will often refer to maximizing IR and MSR interchangeably. 4.0 GK and CST Simulation Proofs While section 2 provides a number of challenges to many of the notions of GK and CST for practice, the narrative is largely based on investment intuition and practice rather than rigorous demonstration. In this section we address the limitations of the GK and CDT for practice within a rigorous simulation framework Jobson and Korkie Simulation Studies The Grinold MV framework assumes estimation error free unconstrained MV optimization. Jobson and Korkie (1981) (JK) provide the classic study of the effect of estimation error on the out-of-sample investment value of inequality unconstrained MV optimized portfolios. By means of a simulation study designed much like the one in this paper, they show that the additional performance gain from an unconstrained MSR optimization is more than cancelled out by the loss incurred by a realistic level of estimation error, i. e. that equal weighting substantially outperforms unconstrained Sharpe ratio maximization under a realistic amount of estimation uncertainty. Their study is performed with total-return optimization rather than benchmark-relative active-weight optimization, but their result can be extended to active weight optimization since the optimal frontiers are identical if the benchmark is efficient, and if not, the performance of the active-weight optimization can only be worse since the active-weight frontier is mathematically dominated everywhere by the total-return optimal one. 22 In contrast to JK study s use of estimation periods as a proxy for the degree of estimation error and thus the information level of the analysis in their experiment, GK use average IC and not estimation periods to represent information level in practice. For example, an equity portfolio manager may claim an average 0.10 IC to reflect their anticipated correlation between forecasts and ex post returns for a given investment strategy. However, the two concepts are closely related; i.e., increasing estimation periods increases the IC of the simulated forecasting process. 23 It is important to note that the average IC associated with a given number of estimation periods also depends on the risk-return distribution of the case-specific optimization universe. While estimation periods may be a more reliable engine to drive estimation error in a Monte Carlo simulation process, we will use the Grinold framework IC to define ex ante information level in our simulations Simulating Breadth while Maintaining Information Levels 21 Note that simulation proofs used in many recent studies are superior to any back tests of investment effectiveness. A back test is always time period dependent and unreliable out-of-sample. 22 Michaud (1998, Ch. 4) replicate the JK simulation studies based on a data set of six diversified country equity and two bond indices and found qualitatively similar results considering the different character of the historical risk-return distribution. 23 The 60 estimation periods in the JK study represents roughly an IC of Simulations were designed to attain a particular level of average IC by combining the target mean with some independently sampled noise. More information is available in Esch (2015).. 11

12 One of the fundamental GK precepts is the notion that simply adding securities as a way of adding breadth (BR) leads to improved MV optimized out-of-sample investment performance all other things the same. In the following we generalize the JK simulation framework to illustrate the impact of estimation error on out-of-sample investment value relative to optimization universe size, while maintaining a constant IC across all universe sizes. Although the case has been made that there are practical limits in the real world for increasing breadth while maintaining IC, we do not wish any failure in performance as breadth increases in our experiment to be attributable to a loss in IC. Although the number of assets is not identical to breadth as specified by GK and CST, the particular construction of the simulated covariance matrix that we are using guarantees that we are adding breadth as we continue to add assets to the case, since each asset is given some idiosyncratic variance in the model, and the covariance is guaranteed to have full rank. 25 Basing an estimation process on data from a greater number of assets in this simulation framework provides new independent information since each asset has a residual variance that is partly explained by the increased cardinality of the estimation. It is never true that we are using the best assets that explain the most of the total variance of all the assets first, as would likely be the case in a real investment situation. We are still adding breadth up to the last increment in portfolio size, and the results cannot be explained as breadth leveling off as a function of portfolio cardinality. 4.3 Simulation Methodology We calculate a truth for the purposes of simulation based on monthly data taken from the Russell 1000 index. 26 Our simulation provides good coverage of the return distribution from a recent history ( ) of this index, while our methodology guarantees a limitless supply of simulated breadth at a constant IC. 27 An important factor that can greatly reduce the average IR of an optimized portfolio is illconditioning of the covariance matrix. When the covariance matrix is calculated using the sample covariance of historical data, this performance-killing effect creeps in as the number of assets approaches the number of time periods in the estimation process. In practice, the covariance matrix for an equity optimization is likely to be obtained as the 25 A number of earlier versions of the Grinold law misidentified the N in breadth as the number of stocks. 26 We include all listed U. S. stocks in the CRSP database that had two years of continuous monthly returns from January 2012 to We excluded returns greater than 50% or less than -50%. We found 5307 stocks that met our criteria. 27 Choosing only securities with a fixed minimum available history creates survivorship bias and paints an overly positive portrait of expected return. In order to compromise between this selection bias and a realistic return distribution including returns from the low end of the spectrum, we have limited the historical data requirement to two years. This selection criterion still errs on the side of optimism, since real-world baskets of selected stocks are likely to produce returns biased negatively relative to the predictions of the experiment. Although using only two years of history definitely introduces estimation error, in aggregate the set of estimates, with estimation error, should provide good coverage of the true return distribution of real stock returns of investable stocks. We also performed simulation experiments with other datasets with different history requirements, and reached exactly the same conclusions Although using only two years of history definitely introduces estimation error, in aggregate the set of estimates, with estimation error, should provide good coverage of the true return distribution of real stock returns of investable stocks. These supplemental experiments are not shown here due to space limitations. 12

13 output of a factor model complete with an idiosyncratic variance term for each asset. By construction these estimates for the covariance matrix will always be full rank and reasonably well-conditioned, and performance as measured by IR will not suffer because of ill-conditioning. In our experiment we do not wish to test the impact of near-singularity of the covariance matrix, so we simulate the variance parameters (not the estimates) of the entire sampling pool of assets in such a way that well-conditioning is guaranteed for portfolio sizes up to 500 in our examples. This is almost certainly optimistic with respect to practice, so our findings on the out-of-sample performance of the fundamental law s predictions represent a best-case scenario, and real world applications are likely to fare worse. We use the direct estimates from the real two year histories to represent truth in the simulation experiment. From this true return distribution we simulate estimates which would correspond to the inputs in a practitioner s optimization. These estimates are designed to be consistent with their targets while including estimation error, all maintaining both a particular expected IC for the mean estimates 28 and a well-conditioned covariance estimate. 29 Portfolios are then created from the simulated mean and variance inputs via three methods: unconstrained maximum Sharpe ratio, maximum Sharpe ratio with positivity constraints, and equal weighting. Of course numerous other methods are possible, but not presented here due to space limitations. Information ratios are then calculated for each method using the population values. These are not the in-sample information ratios that an investor would calculate using his or her own estimates; they are the true population information ratios which are calculable only within the experiment using the simulation parameters. 28 Details of simulating with a particular IC are given in Esch (2015). The nominal ICs shown in this experiment are likely inflated from their counterparts in the real world, since ICs are typically calculated as the correlations between estimates and realized returns, rather than true return expectations. As shown in Esch (2015) this has the effect of inflating the IC by the ratio of the total standard deviation of the realized returns divided by the standard deviation of the selected expected return due to the portfolio sampling process. 29 Procedurally, we use the Ledoit (2003, 2004a, 2004b) covariance estimator on a short simulated history for the sampled subset within each simulation cluster, which creates a stable and full-rank estimate even when the dimensionality of the matrix exceeds the sample size. We use a small sample size of only ten observations here to create some error about the true covariance matrix. We feel that it is necessary to introduce some estimation error since the model assumption of a stationary covariance matrix is likely to be false, and in spite of their popularity and marketing claims, real-world factor models come with estimation error. In our experiments we found that larger sample sizes created estimates that were for practical purposes too close to their population values. After the model covariance is calculated as the Ledoit estimate of the dataset, repeated subsamples are drawn that are tightly clustered around these model covariances, by sampling from a Wishart distribution with degrees of freedom safely greater than the largest sample size in the experiment, in order that the matrices used in optimization will never suffer from ill-conditioning problems. This two-step simulated estimation process may seem unnecessarily complicated, but it successfully avoids the performance-killing ill-conditioning typical of matrices drawn from the thin information available for maintaining reasonably current estimates, and provides a good simulation of the estimation error implied by the paucity of relevant data to the current time period. Thus the step that provides the estimation error is the Ledoit step, taken with only ten time periods, and multiplicity is provided in the Wishart step, which is also done each time with a different set of assets, so the tight clustering of estimates provided by this method will not matter since each estimate is for a different asset mix. 13

14 Generally the in-sample estimates are far too optimistic, and indeed, although they are not shown on these graphs, their ranges dominate the others on the graph. For reference we also calculated the ranges of theoretical true maximum Sharpe ratios using the population parameters. Of course in practice these portfolios would be unattainable since they represent flawless estimation when only flawed information is obtainable in practice. In the simulation studies that follow we differentiate two cases that reflect investment practice: asset allocation and equity portfolio optimization strategies. Asset allocation strategies typically include five to thirty securities and rarely more than fifty. On the other hand equity portfolio optimization strategies may include hundreds or even thousands of assets in the optimization universe. In both asset allocation and equity portfolio optimization we consider IC values of 0.10 and While active equity asset managers may often claim to have an IC level of approximately 0.10 a more optimistic IC of 0.50 may be useful to bracket our results illustrating GK principles. 4.4 Russell 1000 MV Optimization Simulation Results Figures 1 and 2 each consist of two panels of simulation results corresponding to IC levels of 0.10 and Figures 1A and 1B display simulation results for universe sizes up to 50 stocks representing the asset allocation case. Figures 2A and 2B display simulation results for universe sizes up to 500 stocks and represent the equity portfolio optimization case. Four sets of ranges are displayed in each panel, each showing quantile ranges from 1,000 simulations of resampled data from the selected simulation universe. The dotted theoretical max series presents the averages and ranges of Sharpe ratios for in-sample inequality unconstrained MV optimized MSR portfolios. For this case the exact simulation parameters with no estimation error are used. Of course the Sharpe ratios in this result series are unattainable in practice since they use unavailable inputs. However, the other three graphed series show ranges of Sharpe ratios resulting from estimates based on available data, simulated with realistic and perhaps optimistic error. The unconstrained series displays the out-of-sample averages and ranges of Sharpe ratios of the simulated unconstrained MSR portfolios. The equal weight series displays the average Sharpe ratios of equal weighted portfolios. The constrained series reflects the average Sharpe ratios of out-of-sample simulated long-only MSR portfolios. Intervals are also shown in all cases, showing the central 90% of the simulated information ratios. In other words, the crossed lines mark the 5% and 95% quantiles of the simulated portfolio Sharpe ratios. The intervals as shown on the page are jittered horizontally so as not to overlap and to maintain readability of the chart. The simulations demonstrate the interaction of constraints, optimization methods, sample size, and information coefficients. The theoretical max series assumes no estimation error in the optimization process. In this case the results are plausibly consistent with the GK view that adding assets increases the investment value of MV optimized portfolios. The unattainability of this level of performance in practice is clearly demonstrated by the inferior performance of the feasible methods. 14

15 Note that our simulations assume that the average level of IC is constant independent of universe size, ignoring any realistic limitations on manager information. Consequently, a larger universe corresponds to a larger level of investment information, all other things the same. As a result, the slowly rising level of unconstrained average maximum Sharpe ratios as universe size increases is a necessary artifact of the simulation framework. In practice, adding assets is unlikely to add investment value beyond some optimal size universe consistent with the investor s level of information all other things the same. Indeed, beyond some optimal point, the unconstrained curve is likely to curve downward as the size of the optimization universe increases in applications. Our experiment is designed with deliberate optimism to distill the impact of estimation error on the fundamental law s predicted performance. The results of our experiments for the asset allocation cases demonstrate a definite failure of the GK and CST specifications of the fundamental law of management. In Figure 1A, the unconstrained portfolios dramatically underperform both sign constrained and equal weighting. While adding assets increases the Sharpe ratios of unconstrained portfolios outof-sample, the gain is minimal and, we will argue below, unrealistic. How positivity constraints help the optimization process depends on the quality of information and universe size but the results generally contradict the CST view that eliminating constraints adds investment value. 30 In all cases in Figure 1, positivity constraints narrow the confidence intervals. The naïve analyst may think a priori that performance will increase because of increased IR forecasts calculated with estimates used in the optimization, but such in-sample calculation amounts to assuming perfect information and estimation ability, which is clearly unrealistic for investors of any skill level. Our results vividly demonstrate the hazards of ignoring estimation error when optimizing. Our deliberate optimism in setting up the simulation has several important implications. The unconstrained cases would exhibit poorer performance with regard to IR in practice. Since almost all of the assets in the simulation universe are likely to have some investment value, the investor is not harmed by putting portfolio weight on the wrong assets. In the real world, in which the investable universe is not limited to stocks which will have any particular track records, constraints limit the harm caused by misinformation. This effect was clearly demonstrated and measured in Jobson and Korkie (1981). In a truly chaotic world with a lot of estimation error and bias, the equal weighted portfolio, which uses no information to distinguish among assets, can be hard to beat. Figure 2 presents similar simulation experiments to Figure 1 for expanded optimization universes of up to 500 securities. One clear difference in the large universe case is the overall inferiority of equal weighting particularly given the presence of significant levels of information. A second important difference is that the benefit of positivity constraints depends crucially on the level of presumed forecast information. For a typical level of IC = 0.10, sign constrained large universe optimization provides similar performance relative to unconstrained for much of the size spectrum. In the likely unattainable level of IC = 0.50 associated with large stock universe equity portfolio optimizations as in Figure 2B, unconstrained dominates. These results should not be surprising; nor do they represent any 30 We note that the results reaffirm the conclusions in Frost and Savarino (1988). 15

16 Sharpe Ratio Sharpe Ratio serious contradiction to our basic thesis that adding securities adds little if any investment value, all other things the same. 5.0 Prescriptions and Caveats Merton (1987) posits that the appropriate optimization universe should be defined only for securities with reliable information. Intuitively, managers should optimize only on what they know. Investing in large stock universes that include many low-information securities is likely to be suboptimal. But the Merton rule is an important limitation in a number of practical applications. In addition, estimation error uncertainty remains a key consideration for effective asset management. Figure 1A Average Max Sharpe Ratios with IC Theoretical Max Unconstrained Constrained Equal Weight Number of Assets in Portfolio Figure 1B Average Max Sharpe Ratios with IC Theoretical Max Unconstrained Constrained Equal Weight Number of Assets in Portfolio Figure 1: Maximum Sharpe Ratio ranges for three different portfolio construction methods and two different information coefficients for the asset allocation case, compared with corresponding ranges of MSRs of the unattainable perfect information frontiers. This experiment was run on many simulated resamplings of up to fifty U. S. stocks which had at least 2 years of contiguous monthly price data ending in December

17 Sharpe Ratio Sharpe Ratio 5.1 The Composite Asset Asset managers are often mandated to outperform an index while holding tracking error within a specified range. Defining the optimization universe solely for investment significant alpha securities may expose the optimized portfolio to unacceptable tracking error risk in the context of large stock universe benchmarks. Michaud and Michaud (2005) provide a reconciliation of these competing objectives. They recommend adding an index weighted composite asset to represent the non-investment significant alpha securities to the set of investment significant alpha securities as part of the optimization universe. Adding the composite asset does not violate Merton s theoretical prescription while satisfying the need for controlling tracking error risk in applications. Michaud and Michaud find that an optimized portfolio that includes consideration of estimation error with a composite asset for non-investment significant assets often exhibits very desirable optimization and portfolio risk characteristics. Figure 2A Average Max Sharpe Ratios with IC Theoretical Max Unconstrained Constrained Equal Weight Number of Assets in Portfolio Figure 2B Average Max Sharpe Ratios with IC Theoretical Max Unconstrained Constrained Equal Weight Number of Assets in Portfolio 17

The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement

The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement Richard Michaud, Robert Michaud, David Esch New Frontier Advisors Boston, MA 02110 Presented to: INSIGHTS 2016 fi360 National Conference April 6-8, 2016 San Diego,

More information

The Fundamental Law of Active Management Is No Law of Anything 1

The Fundamental Law of Active Management Is No Law of Anything 1 The Fundamental Law of Active Management Is No Law of Anything 1 By Richard O. Michaud, David N. Esch, and Robert O. Michaud 2 Draft: April 2017 2017 New Frontier Advisors, LLC. All rights reserved. Please

More information

An Introduction to Resampled Efficiency

An Introduction to Resampled Efficiency by Richard O. Michaud New Frontier Advisors Newsletter 3 rd quarter, 2002 Abstract Resampled Efficiency provides the solution to using uncertain information in portfolio optimization. 2 The proper purpose

More information

Deconstructing Black-Litterman*

Deconstructing Black-Litterman* Deconstructing Black-Litterman* Richard Michaud, David Esch, Robert Michaud New Frontier Advisors Boston, MA 02110 Presented to: fi360 Conference Sheraton Chicago Hotel & Towers April 25-27, 2012, Chicago,

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: An Investment Process for Stock Selection Fall 2011/2012 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements December, 20 th, 17h-20h:

More information

The Resampled Efficient Frontier

The Resampled Efficient Frontier 6 The Resampled Efficient Frontier This chapter introduces Resampled Efficient Frontier (REF) optimization, a generalization of linear constrained Markowitz MV portfolio optimization that includes uncertainty

More information

Approximating the Confidence Intervals for Sharpe Style Weights

Approximating the Confidence Intervals for Sharpe Style Weights Approximating the Confidence Intervals for Sharpe Style Weights Angelo Lobosco and Dan DiBartolomeo Style analysis is a form of constrained regression that uses a weighted combination of market indexes

More information

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Putnam Institute JUne 2011 Optimal Asset Allocation in : A Downside Perspective W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Once an individual has retired, asset allocation becomes a critical

More information

Dynamic Smart Beta Investing Relative Risk Control and Tactical Bets, Making the Most of Smart Betas

Dynamic Smart Beta Investing Relative Risk Control and Tactical Bets, Making the Most of Smart Betas Dynamic Smart Beta Investing Relative Risk Control and Tactical Bets, Making the Most of Smart Betas Koris International June 2014 Emilien Audeguil Research & Development ORIAS n 13000579 (www.orias.fr).

More information

Portfolio Construction Research by

Portfolio Construction Research by Portfolio Construction Research by Real World Case Studies in Portfolio Construction Using Robust Optimization By Anthony Renshaw, PhD Director, Applied Research July 2008 Copyright, Axioma, Inc. 2008

More information

Morningstar vs. Michaud Optimization Richard O. Michaud and David N. Esch September 2012

Morningstar vs. Michaud Optimization Richard O. Michaud and David N. Esch September 2012 Morningstar vs. Michaud Optimization Richard O. Michaud and David N. Esch September 2012 Classical linear constrained Markowitz (1952, 1959) mean-variance (MV) optimization has been the standard for defining

More information

Active Portfolio Management. A Quantitative Approach for Providing Superior Returns and Controlling Risk. Richard C. Grinold Ronald N.

Active Portfolio Management. A Quantitative Approach for Providing Superior Returns and Controlling Risk. Richard C. Grinold Ronald N. Active Portfolio Management A Quantitative Approach for Providing Superior Returns and Controlling Risk Richard C. Grinold Ronald N. Kahn Introduction The art of investing is evolving into the science

More information

JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING

JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING Our investment philosophy is built upon over 30 years of groundbreaking equity research. Many of the concepts derived from that research have now become

More information

NATIONWIDE ASSET ALLOCATION INVESTMENT PROCESS

NATIONWIDE ASSET ALLOCATION INVESTMENT PROCESS Nationwide Funds A Nationwide White Paper NATIONWIDE ASSET ALLOCATION INVESTMENT PROCESS May 2017 INTRODUCTION In the market decline of 2008, the S&P 500 Index lost more than 37%, numerous equity strategies

More information

Minimizing Timing Luck with Portfolio Tranching The Difference Between Hired and Fired

Minimizing Timing Luck with Portfolio Tranching The Difference Between Hired and Fired Minimizing Timing Luck with Portfolio Tranching The Difference Between Hired and Fired February 2015 Newfound Research LLC 425 Boylston Street 3 rd Floor Boston, MA 02116 www.thinknewfound.com info@thinknewfound.com

More information

Risks and Returns of Relative Total Shareholder Return Plans Andy Restaino Technical Compensation Advisors Inc.

Risks and Returns of Relative Total Shareholder Return Plans Andy Restaino Technical Compensation Advisors Inc. Risks and Returns of Relative Total Shareholder Return Plans Andy Restaino Technical Compensation Advisors Inc. INTRODUCTION When determining or evaluating the efficacy of a company s executive compensation

More information

Comment on Target Date Fund Rules to SEC/ DOL

Comment on Target Date Fund Rules to SEC/ DOL Comment on Target Date Fund Rules to SEC/ DOL submitted this comment to the SEC and DOL in response to File No. S7-12-10. June 4, 2014 The False Promise of Target Date Funds as QDIA Investments The Department

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

The Fallacy of Large Numbers

The Fallacy of Large Numbers The Fallacy of Large umbers Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis First Draft: March 0, 2003 This Draft: ovember 6, 2003 ABSTRACT Traditional mean-variance calculations tell us that the

More information

Does Relaxing the Long-Only Constraint Increase the Downside Risk of Portfolio Alphas? PETER XU

Does Relaxing the Long-Only Constraint Increase the Downside Risk of Portfolio Alphas? PETER XU Does Relaxing the Long-Only Constraint Increase the Downside Risk of Portfolio Alphas? PETER XU Does Relaxing the Long-Only Constraint Increase the Downside Risk of Portfolio Alphas? PETER XU PETER XU

More information

THEORY & PRACTICE FOR FUND MANAGERS. SPRING 2011 Volume 20 Number 1 RISK. special section PARITY. The Voices of Influence iijournals.

THEORY & PRACTICE FOR FUND MANAGERS. SPRING 2011 Volume 20 Number 1 RISK. special section PARITY. The Voices of Influence iijournals. T H E J O U R N A L O F THEORY & PRACTICE FOR FUND MANAGERS SPRING 0 Volume 0 Number RISK special section PARITY The Voices of Influence iijournals.com Risk Parity and Diversification EDWARD QIAN EDWARD

More information

GLOBAL EQUITY MANDATES

GLOBAL EQUITY MANDATES MEKETA INVESTMENT GROUP GLOBAL EQUITY MANDATES ABSTRACT As the line between domestic and international equities continues to blur, a case can be made to implement public equity allocations through global

More information

STRATEGY OVERVIEW. Long/Short Equity. Related Funds: 361 Domestic Long/Short Equity Fund (ADMZX) 361 Global Long/Short Equity Fund (AGAZX)

STRATEGY OVERVIEW. Long/Short Equity. Related Funds: 361 Domestic Long/Short Equity Fund (ADMZX) 361 Global Long/Short Equity Fund (AGAZX) STRATEGY OVERVIEW Long/Short Equity Related Funds: 361 Domestic Long/Short Equity Fund (ADMZX) 361 Global Long/Short Equity Fund (AGAZX) Strategy Thesis The thesis driving 361 s Long/Short Equity strategies

More information

The Fallacy of Large Numbers and A Defense of Diversified Active Managers

The Fallacy of Large Numbers and A Defense of Diversified Active Managers The Fallacy of Large umbers and A Defense of Diversified Active Managers Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis First Draft: March 0, 2003 This Draft: March 27, 2003 ABSTRACT Traditional

More information

International Finance. Estimation Error. Campbell R. Harvey Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc.

International Finance. Estimation Error. Campbell R. Harvey Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc. International Finance Estimation Error Campbell R. Harvey Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc February 17, 2017 Motivation The Markowitz Mean Variance Efficiency is the

More information

Active Management and Portfolio Constraints

Active Management and Portfolio Constraints Feature Article-Portfolio Constraints and Information Ratio Active Management and Portfolio Constraints orihiro Sodeyama, Senior Quants Analyst Indexing and Quantitative Investment Department The Sumitomo

More information

Parameter Estimation Techniques, Optimization Frequency, and Equity Portfolio Return Enhancement*

Parameter Estimation Techniques, Optimization Frequency, and Equity Portfolio Return Enhancement* Parameter Estimation Techniques, Optimization Frequency, and Equity Portfolio Return Enhancement* By Glen A. Larsen, Jr. Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Indianapolis, IN 46202, USA, Glarsen@iupui.edu

More information

Investment Insight. Are Risk Parity Managers Risk Parity (Continued) Summary Results of the Style Analysis

Investment Insight. Are Risk Parity Managers Risk Parity (Continued) Summary Results of the Style Analysis Investment Insight Are Risk Parity Managers Risk Parity (Continued) Edward Qian, PhD, CFA PanAgora Asset Management October 2013 In the November 2012 Investment Insight 1, I presented a style analysis

More information

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance analysis Prof. Massimo Guidolin Portfolio Management Second Term 2018 Outline and objectives Mean-variance and efficient frontiers: logical meaning o Guidolin-Pedio,

More information

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM Yan Zeng Version 1.0.2, last revised on 2012-05-30. Abstract A summary of mean variance analysis in portfolio management and capital asset pricing model. 1. Mean-Variance

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

The Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios

The Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios The Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios Apostolos Kourtis First version: June 6 2014 This version: January 23 2016 Abstract Investors often adopt mean-variance efficient portfolios for achieving

More information

in-depth Invesco Actively Managed Low Volatility Strategies The Case for

in-depth Invesco Actively Managed Low Volatility Strategies The Case for Invesco in-depth The Case for Actively Managed Low Volatility Strategies We believe that active LVPs offer the best opportunity to achieve a higher risk-adjusted return over the long term. Donna C. Wilson

More information

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada Operating Cash Flows: Sales $682,500 $771,750 $868,219 $972,405 $957,211 less expenses $477,750 $540,225 $607,753 $680,684 $670,048 Difference $204,750 $231,525 $260,466 $291,722 $287,163 After-tax (1

More information

Converting Scores into Alphas

Converting Scores into Alphas www.mscibarra.com Converting Scores into Alphas A Barra Aegis Case Study May 2010 Ilan Gleiser Dan McKenna 2010. All rights reserved. 1 of 13 Abstract The goal of this product insight is to illustrate

More information

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region*

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region* Posted SSRN 08/31/01 Last Revised 10/15/01 Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region* Bruce I. Jacobs and Kenneth N. Levy * Previously entitled Leverage Aversion and Portfolio Optimality:

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: From factor models to asset pricing Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Solution to exercise 1 of problem

More information

Models - Optimizer Report

Models - Optimizer Report Models - Optimizer Report Prepared on: 5/7/2012 Prepared For: Prepared By: Related parties: Alex Anderson 453 S. Fourth Ave Suite 200 Pittsburgh, PA 15222 Mark Deniro M.D.C Advisors 110 Main St. Sewickley,

More information

Fiduciary Insights LEVERAGING PORTFOLIOS EFFICIENTLY

Fiduciary Insights LEVERAGING PORTFOLIOS EFFICIENTLY LEVERAGING PORTFOLIOS EFFICIENTLY WHETHER TO USE LEVERAGE AND HOW BEST TO USE IT TO IMPROVE THE EFFICIENCY AND RISK-ADJUSTED RETURNS OF PORTFOLIOS ARE AMONG THE MOST RELEVANT AND LEAST UNDERSTOOD QUESTIONS

More information

Traditional Optimization is Not Optimal for Leverage-Averse Investors

Traditional Optimization is Not Optimal for Leverage-Averse Investors Posted SSRN 10/1/2013 Traditional Optimization is Not Optimal for Leverage-Averse Investors Bruce I. Jacobs and Kenneth N. Levy forthcoming The Journal of Portfolio Management, Winter 2014 Bruce I. Jacobs

More information

Expected Return Methodologies in Morningstar Direct Asset Allocation

Expected Return Methodologies in Morningstar Direct Asset Allocation Expected Return Methodologies in Morningstar Direct Asset Allocation I. Introduction to expected return II. The short version III. Detailed methodologies 1. Building Blocks methodology i. Methodology ii.

More information

Factor investing: building balanced factor portfolios

Factor investing: building balanced factor portfolios Investment Insights Factor investing: building balanced factor portfolios Edward Leung, Ph.D. Quantitative Research Analyst, Invesco Quantitative Strategies Andrew Waisburd, Ph.D. Managing Director, Invesco

More information

The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk, Reduction and Impact

The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk, Reduction and Impact The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk Reduction and Impact Jonathan Harris ET Index Research Quarter 1 017 This report focuses on three key questions for responsible investors:

More information

The misleading nature of correlations

The misleading nature of correlations The misleading nature of correlations In this note we explain certain subtle features of calculating correlations between time-series. Correlation is a measure of linear co-movement, to be contrasted with

More information

Highest possible excess return at lowest possible risk May 2004

Highest possible excess return at lowest possible risk May 2004 Highest possible excess return at lowest possible risk May 2004 Norges Bank s main objective in its management of the Petroleum Fund is to achieve an excess return compared with the benchmark portfolio

More information

REVERSE ASSET ALLOCATION:

REVERSE ASSET ALLOCATION: REVERSE ASSET ALLOCATION: Alternatives at the core second QUARTER 2007 By P. Brett Hammond INTRODUCTION Institutional investors have shown an increasing interest in alternative asset classes including

More information

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Table of Contents Lecture 1... 7 1. State the objective of modern portfolio theory... 7 2. Define the return of an asset... 7 3. How is expected return defined?...

More information

THE IMPORTANCE OF ASSET ALLOCATION vs. SECURITY SELECTION: A PRIMER. Highlights:

THE IMPORTANCE OF ASSET ALLOCATION vs. SECURITY SELECTION: A PRIMER. Highlights: THE IMPORTANCE OF ASSET ALLOCATION vs. SECURITY SELECTION: A PRIMER Highlights: Investment results depend mostly on the market you choose, not the selection of securities within that market. For mutual

More information

Quantitative Measure. February Axioma Research Team

Quantitative Measure. February Axioma Research Team February 2018 How When It Comes to Momentum, Evaluate Don t Cramp My Style a Risk Model Quantitative Measure Risk model providers often commonly report the average value of the asset returns model. Some

More information

Smart Beta and the Evolution of Factor-Based Investing

Smart Beta and the Evolution of Factor-Based Investing Smart Beta and the Evolution of Factor-Based Investing September 2016 Donald J. Hohman Managing Director, Product Management Hitesh C. Patel, Ph.D Managing Director Structured Equity Douglas J. Roman,

More information

Improving Returns-Based Style Analysis

Improving Returns-Based Style Analysis Improving Returns-Based Style Analysis Autumn, 2007 Daniel Mostovoy Northfield Information Services Daniel@northinfo.com Main Points For Today Over the past 15 years, Returns-Based Style Analysis become

More information

OMEGA. A New Tool for Financial Analysis

OMEGA. A New Tool for Financial Analysis OMEGA A New Tool for Financial Analysis 2 1 0-1 -2-1 0 1 2 3 4 Fund C Sharpe Optimal allocation Fund C and Fund D Fund C is a better bet than the Sharpe optimal combination of Fund C and Fund D for more

More information

Axioma Research Paper No January, Multi-Portfolio Optimization and Fairness in Allocation of Trades

Axioma Research Paper No January, Multi-Portfolio Optimization and Fairness in Allocation of Trades Axioma Research Paper No. 013 January, 2009 Multi-Portfolio Optimization and Fairness in Allocation of Trades When trades from separately managed accounts are pooled for execution, the realized market-impact

More information

Optimization 101. Dan dibartolomeo Webinar (from Boston) October 22, 2013

Optimization 101. Dan dibartolomeo Webinar (from Boston) October 22, 2013 Optimization 101 Dan dibartolomeo Webinar (from Boston) October 22, 2013 Outline of Today s Presentation The Mean-Variance Objective Function Optimization Methods, Strengths and Weaknesses Estimation Error

More information

ACTIVE PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION WHEN RISK AND ALPHA FACTORS ARE MISALIGNED

ACTIVE PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION WHEN RISK AND ALPHA FACTORS ARE MISALIGNED 24 ACTIVE PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION WHEN RISK AND ALPHA FACTORS ARE MISALIGNED Ralph Karels and Michael Sun MSCI Consultants CHAPTER OUTLINE 24.1 Introduction 399 24.2 Framework for Active Portfolio Construction

More information

GN47: Stochastic Modelling of Economic Risks in Life Insurance

GN47: Stochastic Modelling of Economic Risks in Life Insurance GN47: Stochastic Modelling of Economic Risks in Life Insurance Classification Recommended Practice MEMBERS ARE REMINDED THAT THEY MUST ALWAYS COMPLY WITH THE PROFESSIONAL CONDUCT STANDARDS (PCS) AND THAT

More information

The Optimization Process: An example of portfolio optimization

The Optimization Process: An example of portfolio optimization ISyE 6669: Deterministic Optimization The Optimization Process: An example of portfolio optimization Shabbir Ahmed Fall 2002 1 Introduction Optimization can be roughly defined as a quantitative approach

More information

Estimation Error and Portfolio Optimization: A Resampling Solution*

Estimation Error and Portfolio Optimization: A Resampling Solution* : A Resampling Solution* Richard Michaud and Robert Michaud 1 Publication forthcoming in the Journal of Investment Management Not to be quoted or reproduced without the authors permission Comments welcomed

More information

Interpreting the Information Ratio

Interpreting the Information Ratio Interpreting the Information Ratio Cameron Clement, CFA 11/10/09 The Information Ratio is a widely used and powerful tool for evaluating manager skill. In this paper, we attempt to foster a better understanding

More information

CFA Level III - LOS Changes

CFA Level III - LOS Changes CFA Level III - LOS Changes 2016-2017 Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Topic LOS Level III - 2016 (332 LOS) LOS Level III - 2017 (337 LOS) Compared 1.1.a 1.1.b 1.2.a 1.2.b 2.3.a

More information

THE CASE AGAINST MID CAP STOCK FUNDS

THE CASE AGAINST MID CAP STOCK FUNDS THE CASE AGAINST MID CAP STOCK FUNDS WHITE PAPER JULY 2010 Scott Cameron, CFA PRINCIPAL INTRODUCTION As investment consultants, one of our critical responsibilities is helping clients construct their investment

More information

Catastrophe Reinsurance Pricing

Catastrophe Reinsurance Pricing Catastrophe Reinsurance Pricing Science, Art or Both? By Joseph Qiu, Ming Li, Qin Wang and Bo Wang Insurers using catastrophe reinsurance, a critical financial management tool with complex pricing, can

More information

Risk Parity for the Long Run Building Portfolios Designed to Perform Across Economic Environments. Lee Partridge, CFA Roberto Croce, Ph.D.

Risk Parity for the Long Run Building Portfolios Designed to Perform Across Economic Environments. Lee Partridge, CFA Roberto Croce, Ph.D. Risk Parity for the Long Run Building Portfolios Designed to Perform Across Economic Environments Lee Partridge, CFA Roberto Croce, Ph.D. This information is being provided to you by Salient Capital Advisors,

More information

SHOULD YOU CARE ABOUT VALUATIONS IN LOW VOLATILITY STRATEGIES?

SHOULD YOU CARE ABOUT VALUATIONS IN LOW VOLATILITY STRATEGIES? SHOULD YOU CARE ABOUT VALUATIONS IN LOW VOLATILITY STRATEGIES? July 2017 UNCORRELATED ANSWERS TM Executive Summary Increasing popularity of low-volatility strategies has led to fear that low-volatility

More information

An analysis of the relative performance of Japanese and foreign money management

An analysis of the relative performance of Japanese and foreign money management An analysis of the relative performance of Japanese and foreign money management Stephen J. Brown, NYU Stern School of Business William N. Goetzmann, Yale School of Management Takato Hiraki, International

More information

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve Capacity Utilization As a Real-Time Predictor of Manufacturing Output Evan F. Koenig Research Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve indices

More information

Dividend Growth as a Defensive Equity Strategy August 24, 2012

Dividend Growth as a Defensive Equity Strategy August 24, 2012 Dividend Growth as a Defensive Equity Strategy August 24, 2012 Introduction: The Case for Defensive Equity Strategies Most institutional investment committees meet three to four times per year to review

More information

Performance of Active Extension Strategies: Evidence from the Australian Equities Market

Performance of Active Extension Strategies: Evidence from the Australian Equities Market Australasian Accounting, Business and Finance Journal Volume 6 Issue 3 Article 2 Performance of Active Extension Strategies: Evidence from the Australian Equities Market Reuben Segara University of Sydney,

More information

MAKING OPTIMISATION TECHNIQUES ROBUST WITH AGNOSTIC RISK PARITY

MAKING OPTIMISATION TECHNIQUES ROBUST WITH AGNOSTIC RISK PARITY Technical Note May 2017 MAKING OPTIMISATION TECHNIQUES ROBUST WITH AGNOSTIC RISK PARITY Introduction The alternative investment industry is becoming ever more accessible to those wishing to diversify away

More information

Fiduciary Insights. IMPLEMENTING LIABILITY- DRIVEN INVESTING: Not a Day at the Beach

Fiduciary Insights. IMPLEMENTING LIABILITY- DRIVEN INVESTING: Not a Day at the Beach IMPLEMENTING LIABILITY- DRIVEN INVESTING: Not a Day at the Beach THE THEORETICAL PROMISE OF LDI MUST BE MATCHED BY EXCELLENCE IN IMPLEMENTATION. Best practices in investment policy, active management,

More information

FACTOR MISALIGNMENT AND PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION. Jose Menchero

FACTOR MISALIGNMENT AND PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION. Jose Menchero JOIM Journal Of Investment Management, Vol. 14, No. 2, (2016), pp. 71 85 JOIM 2016 www.joim.com FCTOR MISLIGNMENT ND PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION Jose Menchero In recent years, there has been heightened interest

More information

Short Term Alpha as a Predictor of Future Mutual Fund Performance

Short Term Alpha as a Predictor of Future Mutual Fund Performance Short Term Alpha as a Predictor of Future Mutual Fund Performance Submitted for Review by the National Association of Active Investment Managers - Wagner Award 2012 - by Michael K. Hartmann, MSAcc, CPA

More information

+ = Smart Beta 2.0 Bringing clarity to equity smart beta. Drawbacks of Market Cap Indices. A Lesson from History

+ = Smart Beta 2.0 Bringing clarity to equity smart beta. Drawbacks of Market Cap Indices. A Lesson from History Benoit Autier Head of Product Management benoit.autier@etfsecurities.com Mike McGlone Head of Research (US) mike.mcglone@etfsecurities.com Alexander Channing Director of Quantitative Investment Strategies

More information

Reporter. Part I of this article published last month set forth several observations and MFA

Reporter. Part I of this article published last month set forth several observations and MFA Reporter MFA August 2001 Inside This Issue MFA in Washington: Legislative Action Heats Up...3 By Patrick J. McCarty, MFA General Counsel Overview of Commodity Funds in Japan in 2000 vs. 1999...5 By Mike

More information

U.S. Dynamic Equity Fund Money Manager and Russell Investments Overview April 2017

U.S. Dynamic Equity Fund Money Manager and Russell Investments Overview April 2017 Money Manager and Russell Investments Overview April 2017 RUSSELL INVESTMENTS APPROACH Russell Investments uses a multi-asset approach to investing, combining asset allocation, manager selection and dynamic

More information

FTSE RUSSELL PAPER. Factor Exposure Indices Index Construction Methodology

FTSE RUSSELL PAPER. Factor Exposure Indices Index Construction Methodology FTSE RUSSELL PAPER Factor Exposure Indices Contents Introduction 3 1. Factor Design and Construction 5 2. Single Factor Index Methodology 6 3. Combining Factors 12 4. Constraints 13 5. Factor Index Example

More information

Sharper Fund Management

Sharper Fund Management Sharper Fund Management Patrick Burns 17th November 2003 Abstract The current practice of fund management can be altered to improve the lot of both the investor and the fund manager. Tracking error constraints

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

CO-INVESTMENTS. Overview. Introduction. Sample

CO-INVESTMENTS. Overview. Introduction. Sample CO-INVESTMENTS by Dr. William T. Charlton Managing Director and Head of Global Research & Analytic, Pavilion Alternatives Group Overview Using an extensive Pavilion Alternatives Group database of investment

More information

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Ziemowit Bednarek, Pratish Patel and Cyrus Ramezani December 8, 2014 ABSTRACT Both building blocks of the Sharpe ratio the expected return and the expected volatility

More information

A Framework for Understanding Defensive Equity Investing

A Framework for Understanding Defensive Equity Investing A Framework for Understanding Defensive Equity Investing Nick Alonso, CFA and Mark Barnes, Ph.D. December 2017 At a basketball game, you always hear the home crowd chanting 'DEFENSE! DEFENSE!' when the

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

International Finance. Investment Styles. Campbell R. Harvey. Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc.

International Finance. Investment Styles. Campbell R. Harvey. Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc. International Finance Investment Styles Campbell R. Harvey Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc February 12, 2017 2 1. Passive Follow the advice of the CAPM Most influential

More information

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods Prepared by Kevin Pei for The Fund @ Sprott Abstract: In this document, I will model and back test our portfolio with various proposed models. It goes without

More information

Mean-Variance Model for Portfolio Selection

Mean-Variance Model for Portfolio Selection Mean-Variance Model for Portfolio Selection FRANK J. FABOZZI, PhD, CFA, CPA Professor of Finance, EDHEC Business School HARRY M. MARKOWITZ, PhD Consultant PETTER N. KOLM, PhD Director of the Mathematics

More information

Stochastic Analysis Of Long Term Multiple-Decrement Contracts

Stochastic Analysis Of Long Term Multiple-Decrement Contracts Stochastic Analysis Of Long Term Multiple-Decrement Contracts Matthew Clark, FSA, MAAA and Chad Runchey, FSA, MAAA Ernst & Young LLP January 2008 Table of Contents Executive Summary...3 Introduction...6

More information

Are you about to handcuff your information ratio? Received: 14th March, 2006

Are you about to handcuff your information ratio? Received: 14th March, 2006 Are you about to handcuff your information ratio? Received: 14th March, 2006 Renato Staub is a senior asset allocation and risk management analyst for UBS Global Asset management. He joined UBS in 1996

More information

Developing Time Horizons for Use in Portfolio Analysis

Developing Time Horizons for Use in Portfolio Analysis Vol. 44, No. 3 March 2007 Developing Time Horizons for Use in Portfolio Analysis by Kevin C. Kaufhold 2007 International Foundation of Employee Benefit Plans WEB EXCLUSIVES This article provides a time-referenced

More information

Back to the Future Why Portfolio Construction with Risk Budgeting is Back in Vogue

Back to the Future Why Portfolio Construction with Risk Budgeting is Back in Vogue Back to the Future Why Portfolio Construction with Risk Budgeting is Back in Vogue SOLUTIONS Innovative and practical approaches to meeting investors needs Much like Avatar director James Cameron s comeback

More information

It is well known that equity returns are

It is well known that equity returns are DING LIU is an SVP and senior quantitative analyst at AllianceBernstein in New York, NY. ding.liu@bernstein.com Pure Quintile Portfolios DING LIU It is well known that equity returns are driven to a large

More information

PORTFOLIO INSIGHTS DESIGNING A SMART ALTERNATIVE APPROACH FOR INVESTING IN AUSTRALIAN SMALL COMPANIES. July 2018

PORTFOLIO INSIGHTS DESIGNING A SMART ALTERNATIVE APPROACH FOR INVESTING IN AUSTRALIAN SMALL COMPANIES. July 2018 Financial adviser/ wholesale client use only. Not for distribution to retail clients. Until recently, investors seeking to gain a single exposure to a diversified portfolio of Australian small companies

More information

Does Naive Not Mean Optimal? The Case for the 1/N Strategy in Brazilian Equities

Does Naive Not Mean Optimal? The Case for the 1/N Strategy in Brazilian Equities Does Naive Not Mean Optimal? GV INVEST 05 The Case for the 1/N Strategy in Brazilian Equities December, 2016 Vinicius Esposito i The development of optimal approaches to portfolio construction has rendered

More information

Risk Parity Portfolios:

Risk Parity Portfolios: SEPTEMBER 2005 Risk Parity Portfolios: Efficient Portfolios Through True Diversification Edward Qian, Ph.D., CFA Chief Investment Officer and Head of Research, Macro Strategies PanAgora Asset Management

More information

Smart Beta and the Evolution of Factor-Based Investing

Smart Beta and the Evolution of Factor-Based Investing Smart Beta and the Evolution of Factor-Based Investing September 2017 Donald J. Hohman Managing Director, Product Management Hitesh C. Patel, Ph.D Managing Director Structured Equity Douglas J. Roman,

More information

ECONOMIA DEGLI INTERMEDIARI FINANZIARI AVANZATA MODULO ASSET MANAGEMENT LECTURE 6

ECONOMIA DEGLI INTERMEDIARI FINANZIARI AVANZATA MODULO ASSET MANAGEMENT LECTURE 6 ECONOMIA DEGLI INTERMEDIARI FINANZIARI AVANZATA MODULO ASSET MANAGEMENT LECTURE 6 MVO IN TWO STAGES Calculate the forecasts Calculate forecasts for returns, standard deviations and correlations for the

More information

Brazil Risk and Alpha Factor Handbook

Brazil Risk and Alpha Factor Handbook Brazil Risk and Alpha Factor Handbook In this report we discuss some of the basic theory and statistical techniques involved in a quantitative approach to alpha generation and risk management. Focusing

More information

Motif Capital Horizon Models: A robust asset allocation framework

Motif Capital Horizon Models: A robust asset allocation framework Motif Capital Horizon Models: A robust asset allocation framework Executive Summary By some estimates, over 93% of the variation in a portfolio s returns can be attributed to the allocation to broad asset

More information

MEAN-VARIANCE OPTIMIZATION AND PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION: A SHORT TERM TRADING STRATEGY

MEAN-VARIANCE OPTIMIZATION AND PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION: A SHORT TERM TRADING STRATEGY MEAN-VARIANCE OPTIMIZATION AND PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION: A SHORT TERM TRADING STRATEGY by Michael Leggatt BBA, Simon Fraser University, 2002 and Pavel Havlena BA (Economics), Simon Fraser University, 2001

More information

The Predictive Power of Portfolio Characteristics

The Predictive Power of Portfolio Characteristics Working Draft December 2, 2014 The Predictive Power of Portfolio Characteristics Applying the Fundamental Law of Active Management to Portfolio Characteristics in Order to Rank Prospective Information

More information