Dissecting Conglomerates

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Dissecting Conglomerates"

Transcription

1 Dissecting Conglomerates November 18, 2017 ABSTRACT We develop a new method to estimate Tobin s qs of conglomerate divisions without relying on standalone firms. Divisional qs differ considerably from qs of standalone firms and, consistent with theories of corporate diversification, are less volatile and less sensitive to macroeconomic shocks. In contrast to prior evidence based on standalone qs, divisional investment is highly sensitive to divisional qs. This sensitivity disappears after a division is spun-off into a standalone firm. Moreover, divisional qs predict both acquisition announcement returns and the volume of diversifying acquisitions. Overall, our estimates provide new opportunities to study conglomeration and internal capital allocation. JEL Classification: G32, G34. Keywords: boundaries of the firm, segment valuation, conglomerate investment, internal capital markets, quantile regressions.

2 Most large US firms operate in multiple divisions. Such conglomerates account for the lion s share of financing, investment, and value of US companies. Consequently, a vast literature studies conglomerates, focusing on conglomerate investment allocation and the value of conglomeration. It is notoriously challenging to investigate these empirically, however, because direct estimates of divisional valuations and investment opportunities are not available. In this paper, we address this challenge by developing a new method to estimate divisional valuation multiples, and use our estimates to study conglomerate investment and diversifying acquisitions. To understand our method, consider the traditional approach to studying conglomerates, pioneered by Lang and Stulz (1994) and Berger and Ofek (1995), which synthetically replicates the overall conglomerate by a portfolio of standalone firms. Specifically, this approach imputes v, the vector of valuations of diversified firms, as ˆv = W q sa, where W is a matrix of firms industry exposures of fundamentals (e.g., sales), and q sa is a vector of industry multiples derived from standalone firms. By using q sa, this approach assumes that industry multiples of standalone firms accurately proxy for those of conglomerate divisions. Thus, it does not account for systematic differences between conglomerates and standalone firms that may arise due to the endogeneity of firms organizational structure. Whited (2001) shows that estimates of Tobin s q of standalone firms are inappropriate for the study of investment by conglomerate divisions. We overcome this limitation by forming portfolios of conglomerates to mimic standalone firms. Specifically, we use data on v and W to directly estimate a vector of conglomerate-implied industry valuation multiples. As a simple example, consider two conglomerates that operate in the same two industries. Assume that the first conglomerate has unit exposure of fundamentals to each industry, and the second conglomerate has exposures of two and one to these industries. It is immediately clear that a portfolio long the second conglomerate and short the first conglomerate has industry exposures of one and zero. Thus, the value of this portfolio equals the conglomerate-implied valuation of divisions operating in the first industry, and provides a proxy of Tobin s q for 1

3 these divisions. In this example, the solution to the problem is unique and can be obtained by inverting the matrix containing the proportions of conglomerate exposures to each industry. For practical applications, the number of conglomerates exceeds the number of industries, and this matrix is not invertible. We show in Monte-Carlo simulations that median regressions of conglomerate valuation multiples on the matrix of exposure weights provide reliable estimates of the multiples of conglomerate divisions. Overall, this approach generates model-free estimates of conglomerate divisions qs that vary across industries and over time, and unlike traditional measures, are obtained without using industry multiples of standalone firms. The estimates therefore allow us to investigate the systematic differences between conglomerate divisions and standalone firms that operate in similar industries, and to shed new light on theories of corporate diversification and the efficiency of conglomerate investment. In our first set of analyses, we investigate the properties of divisional qs and compare them to traditional measures derived from standalone firms. We find large differences between these multiples. In the cross-section of industries, the average ratio of divisional and standalone qs varies considerably, ranging from -55% to 17%. Relative to standalone firms, divisional qs are lowest in the energy, high-tech, and healthcare industries, whereas divisions in the consumer nondurables and telecommunication industries have higher qs than their standalone counterparts. In the time series, the qs of conglomerate divisions are less volatile and less sensitive to macroeconomic shocks than those of standalone firms. The standard deviation of divisional qs is on average 15% lower than that of standalone qs. The sensitivity of divisional qs to different macroeconomic shocks, such as stock market-wide movements and productivity shocks, is a staggering 48% lower. These results suggest that conglomerate divisions are more insulated from external economic forces than standalone firms operating in the same industry, consistent with theories of corporate diversification (e.g., Lewellen, 1971, Matsusaka and Nanda, 2002). 2

4 Overall, these findings have broad implications for prior research on conglomerates, as they reveal systematic differences between qs of conglomerate divisions and qs of standalone firms. Consequently, analyses that rely on qs of standalone firms, such as the study of internal capital allocation, may mis-characterize intra-conglomerate processes and their efficacy. Moreover, conclusions from industry-specific analyses need not extrapolate to other industries, where the relation between divisional and standalone qs can differ considerably. 1 Having established that divisional qs differ considerably from traditional measures of q that rely on standalone firms, in the second set of analyses we employ these measures to study conglomerate investment. These tests are motivated by existing theory, which offers diverging views on the efficacy of capital allocation inside conglomerates. On the one hand, internal capital markets in conglomerates may allow raising more external finance (Lewellen, 1971, Hadlock, Ryngaert, and Thomas, 2001) and allocating capital more efficiently (Alchian, 1969, Weston, 1970, Stein, 1997, Matsusaka and Nanda, 2002). On the other hand, conglomerates may suffer from agency problems and, in particular, from the rent-seeking behavior of divisional managers. Consequently, the ceo may distort the conglomerate s internal capital allocation toward weaker divisions to retain divisional managers (Scharfstein and Stein, 2000) and to control their rentseeking behavior (Rajan, Servaes, and Zingales, 2000). Our empirical approach follows the analyses in Shin and Stulz (1998) and Ozbas and Scharfstein (2010). These studies use the neoclassical relation between investment and Tobin s q to investigate the efficacy of conglomerates internal capital allocation. Using estimates of qs derived from standalone firms, they find that investment of conglomerate divisions is less sensitive to investment opportunities than that of standalone firms. Our findings confirm that conglomerate investment is indeed less sensitive to qs estimated from standalone firms. Specifically, conglomerate divisions elasticity of in- 1 Examples of studies that focus on a single industry include Lamont (1997), who analyzes investment decisions of diversified oil companies following the oil price shock of 1986; Khanna and Tice (2001), who investigate the responses of diversified firms to Wal-Mart s entry into their market; Campello (2002), who studies the reactions of financial conglomerates to monetary policy; and Guedj and Scharfstein (2004), who analyze the development strategies and performance of biopharmaceutical firms. 3

5 vestment to standalone q is insignificant at 0.6%. This estimate is significantly lower than the elasticity of standalone firms (5.5%). However, conglomerate investment is highly sensitive to divisional qs: the elasticity of conglomerate divisions investment to divisional q is significantly positive at 2.6%, whereas the estimate for standalone firms is insignificant at -1.3%. These findings are less consistent with the hypothesis that conglomerates invest inefficiently, and suggest that our method generates clean measures of investment opportunities of conglomerate divisions. To shed light on the operation of internal capital markets, we also investigate the sensitivity of divisional investments to divisional cash flows. When we use qs estimated from standalone firms, our results confirm those of Shin and Stulz (1998). First, a division s investment is more sensitive to its own cash flow than to the other divisions cash flows. Second, the sensitivity of a division s investment to other divisions cash flows is not lower when it has better investment opportunities. These findings were traditionally interpreted as evidence against efficient internal capital markets. However, when we introduce the new measures of divisional qs into the analysis, we find strikingly different results. A division s investment becomes more sensitive to other divisions cash flows than its own cash flow. Further, the sensitivity to other divisions cash flows is lower when investment opportunities are higher. This evidence suggests that capital markets inside conglomerates facilitate the reallocation of resources across divisions towards divisions with high marginal products. A possible concern is that the sensitivity of investment to divisional qs is correlated with potentially unobservable firm-level characteristics. To address this concern, we estimate the elasticity of investment to standalone and divisional qs around the spinoff of conglomerate divisions. This analysis holds constant the firm and traces its investment policy through the organizational changes that it undergoes, thereby minimizing the confounding effects of potentially unobservable differences across firms. The results suggest that prior to the spinoff, divisional investment is highly sensitive to divisional q and insensitive to standalone q. Following the spinoff, however, invest- 4

6 ment becomes insensitive to divisional q and highly sensitive to standalone q. These results suggest that while the investment opportunities of conglomerates and standalone firms are different, investment efficiency at conglomerates and standalone firms is not. In our final set of analyses, we use divisional qs to study mergers and acquisitions (m&a) activity and the origins of conglomerate value. First, we investigate acquisition announcement returns. We find that the difference between divisional qs and standalone qs, which captures the implied value gains due to the change in the organizational structure, is a strong predictor of acquisition announcement returns. These results hold for target, acquirer, and combined announcement returns, and are economically important. For example, in the full sample of m&a announcements, which includes both focused and diversifying acquisitions, an increase of one standard deviation in the difference between standalone and divisional qs corresponds to an increase of 1.15% in the combined announcement returns. The economic magnitude increases by more than 50% when we restrict the sample to acquisitions that diversify across two of the 10 Fama-French industries. This last result indicates that divisional qs are strong indicators of the value of combining diversified divisions into a conglomerate. Second, we investigate the volume of m&a activity. Our findings indicate that for the full sample of m&a announcements, both divisional and standalone qs predict the volume of activity. In contrast, only divisional qs predict the volume of diversifying acquisitions. This finding provides further evidence that divisional qs capture the value of diversifying. It also suggests that, on average, firms make optimal diversifying acquisitions that exploit high valuations of corporate diversification. A possible concern with these findings is that they seem hard to reconcile with the diversification discount documented by Lang and Stulz (1994), Berger and Ofek (1995), and the literature that followed. However, studies such as Campa and Kedia (2002), Graham, Lemmon, and Wolf (2002), and Villalonga (2004b) show that after accounting for firms endogenous decision to diversify, conglomerates no longer appear discounted. Our findings support this view by providing direct evidence on the value 5

7 and volume of diversifying acquisitions. Consistent with these findings, Matsusaka (2001) develops a dynamic search model in which diversification is an optimal search process by which firms seek to acquire businesses that are good matches for their capabilities. In his model, diversified firms are discounted because they choose to diversify when their value decreases and not because they make bad diversification decisions. To test these predictions, we compare the divisional qs of conglomerates core and peripheral divisions. We find that the qs of core divisions are deeply discounted compared to the qs of peripheral divisions. These results suggest that lower conglomerate qs do not arise solely from diversifying into low-q peripheral divisions. Instead, discounted firms are those that choose to diversify. Overall, our paper contributes to the literature on corporate diversification and internal capital markets. It makes a step towards a better understanding of conglomerate investment and the efficacy of diversification decisions by providing clean disaggregated estimates of division-level valuation multiples. I. The New Method Our method inverts the traditional approach of Lang and Stulz (1994) and Berger and Ofek (1995). Rather than building up synthetic conglomerates from individual pieces (standalone firms), we break down actual conglomerates into their components. We group these components across conglomerates into classes that share observable characteristics, such as industry affiliation. We then use quantile regressions to obtain median conglomerate-implied estimates for the valuation multiples, or qs, of each class. Comparing these qs with those of standalone firms in each class allows us to analyze the systematic differences between conglomerates and standalone firms at the granular level of a single class. A. Overview of the Estimation Method Let W denote the matrix of I conglomerates by K classes that contains the fundamentals (e.g., sales) of a cross-section of conglomerates. For example, in the analysis of 6

8 Berger and Ofek (1995), K represents the number of 4-digit sic industries in which the I conglomerates operate. If divisions in all classes function independently, the value of the conglomerate, v, should equal the weighted sum of the valuation ratios of the classes represented by the K 1 vector q c : v = W q c. (1) In the special case where W contains the replacement costs of capital, q c corresponds to Tobin s q associated with each class. Because replacement costs are not observable, the corporate diversification literature relies on asset or sales multiples to proxy for Tobin s q (Lang and Stulz, 1994). The traditional approach of Lang and Stulz (1994) and Berger and Ofek (1995) imputes the value of conglomerates using industry-level qs estimated from standalone firms. In particular, they estimate the qs of each division as the median q of standalone firms operating in the same industry, ˆq c = q sa. A standard result in this literature is that the imputed values of conglomerates, ˆv = W q sa, on average exceed their market capitalization, suggesting that diversified firms are valued at a discount. Our method also builds on Equation (1), but we aim to estimate q c using only conglomerate-level information. In particular, we scale Equation (1) by the total fundamentals of each conglomerate to obtain ṽ = W q c, (2) where ṽ(i) = v(i)/ k W (i, k) and W (i, k) = W (i, k)/ k W (i, k) are valuation multiples and class weights of the conglomerates. Ostensibly, estimating ˆq c from Equation (2) could be achieved via an ordinary least squares (ols) regression of conglomerate multiples on class weights. However, the ols approach is problematic since valuation ratios are positively skewed. The prior literature addresses the skewness in valuation ratios by taking their natural logarithms, an approach not suitable for our purposes since logs are not additive. To resolve the problem of skewed valuation ratios, we base our analysis on medians rather than means, 7

9 and use quantile regressions. Specifically, we run median regressions of conglomerate multiples ṽ on class weights W cross-sectionally to back out the median class valuation ratios ˆq c. B. Quantile Regressions Before describing our analysis in detail, we provide a short review of quantile regressions. Our goal is to fit the median of the target variable y i conditional on the explanatory variables X i. When estimating Equation (2), y i corresponds to the valuation ratio of conglomerate i, ṽ(i), and X i is the ith row of the weight matrix W. The median, or 50th percentile, of y i is defined from its inverse probability distribution function P 50 (y i ) = inf {y : P rob (y i < y) 0.50}. (3) We can express the median as the solution to an optimization problem P 50 (y i ) = arg inf u E y i u, (4) which is particularly convenient for handling conditioning information sets such as the explanatory variables. 2 We follow the seminal quantile regression specification of Koenker and Bassett (1978), and assume that the median of y i conditional on X i is a linear function of the explanatory variables. This implies P 50 ( y i Xi ) = arg inf u E ( y i u Xi ) = γ0 + γ 1 X i. (5) The assumed linear relation is reminiscent of standard ols specifications. However, median regressions model the conditional median of y i, rather than its mean, as a linear function of X i. C. Monte Carlo Simulations We use Monte Carlo simulations to show that the qs of division classes can be robustly estimated using median regressions rather than ols regressions if conglomerate valuation ratios are positively skewed (e.g., Berger and Ofek, 1995). Specifically, we simulate 2 Equation (4) is a special case of the general quantile regression representation, where the quantile loss function for quantile τ is given by ρ τ (x) = x ( τ I (x<0) ) and the optimization problem is P τ (y i) = arg inf u E [ρ τ (y i u)]. 8

10 fundamentals (i.e., sales) across K = 5 classes for I = 500 conglomerates. Half of the conglomerates operate in two classes, a third in three classes, and a sixth in four classes, approximately in line with the empirical distribution of industries. 3 Fundamentals W are drawn from a lognormal distribution that is based on a Gaussian distribution with unit mean and a standard deviation of The valuation ratios of conglomerates, ṽ, are calculated as in Equation (2), where the class valuations are given by q c = [ ]. These class valuation approximately reflect standalone qs of the 10 Fama-French industries, which range from 0.50 to Conglomerates are then exposed to multiplicative valuation shocks that have a median of one and are drawn from either a Gaussian distribution that is truncated at zero or a lognormal distribution. These shocks reflect the significant empirical variation in excess values documented, for example, by Lamont and Polk (2001) who report cross-sectional standard deviations of excess values between 0.36 and shocks. Correspondingly, we consider 0.3 and 0.6 as standard deviations for our Table I shows averages and standard deviations of the differences between estimated and actual class valuations, ˆq c q c, across 100,000 simulations. In the last column, it also reports excess value measures computed as in Berger and Ofek (1995). Panels A and B correspond to multiplicative shocks with standard deviations of 0.3 and 0.6, respectively. When conglomerate valuation ratios are normally distributed, and therefore nonskewed, both median regressions and OLS regressions yield unbiased estimates of class valuations. Specifically, ˆq c q c = 0 across all columns for both median and OLS regressions. The cross-simulation averages of the median excess value are zero, but those of its mean are negative (-0.05 in Panel A and in Panel B). This is because 3 In our sample of XXX conglomerate-years, XXX operate in two industries, XXX operate in three industries, and XXX operate in four industries. 4 The standard deviation of 0.8 implies that, on average, conglomerates are well diversified and not dominated by a single division. The average Herfindahl index across conglomerates is about 0.5. It ranges from 0.35 for four-division firms to 0.6 for two-division firms, closely matching the empirical moments we obtain in untabulated analysis. 9

11 the use of the logarithm in the excess value calculation directly aims to eliminate the effects of positive skewness. With a normally distributed shock, that is, without positive skewness, Jensen s inequality implies a downward-biased measure of excess value. Several observations about the cross-simulation standard deviations, shown in parentheses, are noteworthy. First, they are increasing across the five classes. This is simply an artifact of having increasing valuation ratios across the classes, and a multiplicative valuation shock. Second, as expected with normally distributed residuals, ols is more efficient than median regressions. Lastly, the standard deviations of class valuations are significantly higher than those of excess values. This is not surprising given that the same data are used to obtain one estimate of excess value but five estimates of class valuation multiples. The finer granularity comes at a cost of reduced efficiency. The ols-based inferences change dramatically when valuation ratios are positively skewed. With lognormal shocks, ols yields strongly upward-biased estimates of class valuations. In Panel A these estimates range from 0.02 to 0.11, representing about 4% of the true valuation multiple. The drawbacks of ols regressions become even more pronounced in Panel B, where we assume a higher cross-sectional variation of 0.6 in excess values. In this case, the bias reaches 20%. Since valuation ratios are known to be positively skewed, our simulation evidence strongly suggests that ols should not be used to obtain class valuation multiples. In contrast, estimates from median regressions are unbiased and, like excess values, remain robust to different distributional assumptions. Overall, the simulations show that valuation ratios of classes can be estimated well using quantile regressions on the median, the approach we follow throughout the paper. II. Data and Empirical Approach A. Data We obtain firm-level accounting variables and sic industry classifications from Compustat, and division-level variables from the Compustat Segment files. Our sample period 10

12 starts in 1978, when Compustat segment data become available, and ends in Following the literature, we exclude firms with at least one division in the financial sector, (sic codes ), in agriculture (sic codes below 1000), and in government, other non-economic activities, or unclassified services (sic codes 8600, 8800, 8900, and 9000). Since we are interested in studying division investment opportunities, we exclude firms whose sales or assets at the level of business segments are unavailable on Compustat. We also exclude divisions with zero sales, such as corporate accounts. Following the literature, we further require total sales from the Compustat annual files to be greater than $20 million and within one percent of the sum of division sales. We follow Custodio s (2014) suggestion and focus our analysis on sales-based multiples. While earlier literature also considers assets-based multiples, Custodio (2014) offers a caveat by noting that the accumulation of goodwill in merger and acquisition accounting biases the book value of assets of conglomerates upwards, and that conglomerates have more flexibility in allocating assets across divisions. Consequently, we base our analysis on sales multiples. We define a conglomerate as a firm that operates in at least two distinct industries. The literature has frequently classified industries by 4-digit sic codes. A shortcoming of this definition is that the number of conglomerate divisions that operate in each industry in a given year is small, with a median number of divisions per industry-year of just two. Therefore, our subsequent empirical analyses rely on the 10 Fama-French industries, which are sufficiently coarse to ensure that a meaningful number of divisions operate in each industry in a given year, and thus that the matrix of industry weights for conglomerates, W, is well populated and has full column rank. 5 A benefit of this coarser classification is that our analysis is less exposed to the criticism of Villalonga (2004a), who highlights problems in the 4-digit sic assignment by Compustat. While a substantial number of divisions may be misclassified into wrong 4-digit sic codes, they likely remain in the same 10 Fama-French industry. 5 The industries are defined in Appendix A. We also consider the Fama-French five, seventeen, and thirty industries. A finer classification leads to missing observations for some industry-years but produces qualitatively similar results. 11

13 Table XXX reports summary statistics for the sample. Overall, the sample includes 2,512 conglomerates (12,521 firm-year observations) and 6,279 divisions (28,701 division-year observations). In this sample, an average (median) conglomerate has annual sales of $3.98 ($0.71) billion CPI-adjusted 2004 dollars, owns book assets valued at $4.20 ($0.70) billion, has a Tobin s q of 1.11 (0.93) based on asset multiples and of 1.39 (0.94) based on sales multiples, operates in 2.29 (2) business segments, and has annual capital expenditures of 9.13 (4.31) percent of sales. An average (median) division has annual sales of $1.77 ($0.23) billion and owns book assets valued at $1.88 ($0.24) billion. Requiring that conglomerates operate in two distinct industries based on the 10 Fama-French industry classification reduces the number of conglomerates by about a third relative to the 4-digit sic-based definition. However, the characteristics of this smaller sample are consistent with those reported in the literature (e.g., Custodio, 2014). Moreover, the average excess values are also similar across the two samples (-13.3% vs %). B. Empirical Approach In this section, we describe the empirical approach to estimating divisional qs. Every year, we perform cross-sectional quantile regressions, without intercept, of conglomerate qs onto their sales exposure to the 10 Fama-French industries. The resulting coefficients are estimates of the median q of conglomerate divisions in each industry for the year. The number of divisions in each industry range from 27 (Telecommunications) to 176 (Manufacturing) on average, which ensures that each regression coefficient is well identified. Our approach generates direct estimates of conglomerate divisions qs that do not rely on the industry qs of standalone firms. It therefore eliminates measurement errors that may arise due to the systematic differences between conglomerates and standalone firms. In fact, by generating independent conglomerate qs, it allows us to characterize the differences between the qs of conglomerate divisions and those of standalone firms. 12

14 While our method eliminates biases due to differences in valuations between conglomerates and standalone firms, a remaining identifying assumption is that conglomerate divisions in each of the K classes have common valuation ratios. We test this assumption directly in Figure 1 by comparing the excess values implied by our new method to those from the traditional approach of Berger and Ofek (1995). If our identifying assumption holds, and if our class-by-class estimates of q are indeed better estimates of divisional qs, then they should more accurately approximate the overall value of the conglomerate, resulting in more accurate estimates of conglomerate excess values. Figure 1 investigates whether this is the case by illustrating the distribution of standard deviations of two excess value estimates. For each firm and year, we follow Berger and Ofek (1995) and define excess value as the log-difference between the conglomerates true and imputed values. Imputed values are calculated as sales-weighted sum of either the median qs of standalone firms in the respective 4-digit sic industries, or the new divisional qs obtained from quantile regressions using the 10 Fama-French industries. We then compute the time-series standard deviations of both excess value measures for each firm with at least five consecutive observations, and plot the kernel density of these standard deviations. The evidence in Figure 1 clearly shows that our method results in excess value estimates with a lower standard deviation than the estimates produced by the traditional approach of Berger and Ofek (1995). This evidence suggests that the new estimates of intra-conglomerate qs are less noisy than the standard industry-median qs of standalone firms. This evidence is particularly convincing because the traditional Berger and Ofek (1995) estimates are based on a finer industry classification, and should arguably yield superior excess value estimates. We therefore conclude that our identifying assumption approximately holds, and that our approach provides cleaner estimates of divisional qs compared to the traditional approach based on qs of standalone firms. Next, we investigate the systematic differences between divisional qs and stan- 13

15 dalone qs, and use the new measures of divisional qs to investigate the efficacy of conglomerate investment and diversifying acquisitions. III. The Properties of Divisional q s A. Cross-Industry Analysis We begin our analysis by presenting evidence on the average valuation multiples, or qs, of divisions relative to standalone firms across industries. Our focus on industry-level valuation estimates is motivated by the standard definition of a diversified firm in corporate finance: a firm that operates in more than one industry. As suggested in Coase (1937) and Maksimovic and Phillips (2007), corporate diversification matters only if the conglomerate s industry composition affects its transaction costs and hence its optimal boundaries. Thus, for corporate diversification to be of interest, it must be that the industry composition of conglomerates is related to firm value. Table II shows the estimated average valuation multiples of conglomerate divisions, standalone firms, and the resulting relative division qs (rdqs) across the 10 Fama- French industries. Similar to Berger and Ofek (1995), we define the rdq of an industry as the log of the ratio of valuation multiples of conglomerate divisions and standalone firms. As such, rdqs can be used to examine the differences between conglomerate qs and standalone qs across industries. To establish the statistical properties of the time-series average of rdqs, we rely on bootstrapping. In particular, each year we resample residuals of the quantile regression 1,000 times and re-estimate the regression. We then compute average rdqs for each bootstrapped sample. The standard errors of rdqs are calculated using the standard deviation of the bootstrapped estimates. To account for a possible asymmetric distribution of the test statistic, we also report bootstrapped p-values for the test that rdqs are less than or equal to zero. There are two main takeaways from Table II. First, the valuation multiples of conglomerate divisions are significantly different from the valuation multiples of standalone 14

16 firms. The correlation between the valuation of divisions and standalone firms ranges from 0.37 in the health sector to 0.94 in the manufacturing sector. Furthermore, rdqs are statistically significantly different from zero in all sectors except manufacturing. These estimates suggest that industry multiples of standalone firms are noisy proxies for division multiples and can introduce large measurement errors. Second, Table II shows that the valuation multiples of divisions relative to standalone firms vary considerably across industries. Seven industries have a significantly negative rdq, with the largest discounts in the energy (-55%), high-tech (-35%), and healthcare (-28%) industries. In contrast, conglomerate divisions in two industries show substantial premia. Divisions in the nondurable goods sector are valued at a 16% premium and divisions in the telecommunications sector are valued at a 17% premium. Table II also reveals considerable within-industry variation in rdqs over time. The standard deviation in rdqs within industries ranges from 11% in the manufacturing and energy sectors to 38% in the healthcare sector. This variation is also illustrated in Figure 2, which shows the time-series of rdqs for each industry. Overall, these findings suggest that the aggregate estimates of conglomerate value provided by Berger and Ofek (1995) and the numerous studies that follow do not reflect the considerable within-conglomerate variation in valuation. In particular, our disaggregated estimates indicate that the value of conglomeration varies systematically across industries. Our findings have broad implications for prior research on corporate diversification. First, existing theories of the value of diversification cannot explain our findings. Neither the cross-subsidization of weak divisions (e.g., Rajan, Servaes, and Zingales (2000), Scharfstein and Stein (2000)), the endogenous decision to diversify via acquisitions (e.g., Graham, Lemmon, and Wolf (2002), Campa and Kedia (2002), Villalonga (2004b)), or strategic accounting to appear as artificially low performers (Villalonga, 2004a) readily accommodate systematic heterogeneity in conglomerate valuations across industries. Second, the variation in rdqs across industries also suggests that one needs to exer- 15

17 cise caution in extrapolating results based on industry-specific analyses. For example, a number of studies have used the Longitudinal Research Database to investigate the value of internal capital markets (e.g., Maksimovic and Phillips, 2002) and the productivity of conglomerate divisions (e.g., Schoar, 2002). However, this database tracks only manufacturing plants, a limitation that the authors of these studies acknowledge. While our estimates confirm that there is no significant discount in the manufacturing sector, they at the same time uncover deep discounts in the energy and high-tech sectors and large premiums in the non-durable and telecommunication sectors. One caveat with this analysis is that the value of operating an industry inside the conglomerate can be affected by its other divisions. For example, Hoberg and Phillips (2015) show that conglomerates tend to operate in economically related industries. Thus, a conglomerate s choice of industries is not random, and endogenous matching can create additional value through synergies. To assess this possibility, we study within-conglomerate cross-industry pairs. Each column in Panel A of Table III corresponds to all conglomerates operating a division in the given industry, and each row reports the proportion of conglomerates that also have divisions in the industry indicated by the row. The sum of each column exceeds one because conglomerates can operate in more than two industries. Consistent with nonrandom industry matching, we find that industry-pairs are not equally distributed inside conglomerates. This can be seen from the nonuniform distribution within each row. For example, 51% of conglomerates with a division in utilities also operate one in energy, whereas only 4% of conglomerates with a division in nondurables do. Importantly, however, we find an insignificant relation between divisions qs and their pairing with other industries inside the conglomerate. Panel B of Table III shows average rdqs that are obtained by omitting from the sample all conglomerates that operate in the industry indicated in the row label. For example, when the sample is limited to conglomerates that have a division in the nondurables industry but not in the durables industry, the nondurables divisions have estimated qs that are 16% larger than 16

18 those of standalone firms. Across all industries, the exclusion of industry pairs does not have a sizeable effect on the average rdq. These exclusions generate a small variation in rdqs within each industry (average standard deviation = 3.8%). Furthermore, the rdqs estimated after excluding industry pairs are statistically different from the fullsample rdqs at the 5% level only in 6 out of 90 cases (6.7%). Overall, this evidence suggests that the cross-industry variation in rdqs continues to hold after accounting for the endogenous within-conglomerate industry matching. Taken together, the results in this section suggest that conglomerate-implied valuations vary systematically across industries and are substantially different from the commonly used industry valuations based on standalone firms. In the next subsection, we compare the time-series properties of divisional and standalone qs. B. Time-Series Analysis Theories of corporate diversification (e.g., Lewellen, 1971, Matsusaka and Nanda, 2002) suggest that conglomerate divisions are more insulated from external economic forces than standalone firms. Consequently, the valuation multiples, or qs, of conglomerate divisions should be less volatile and less affected by macroeconomic shocks than those of standalone firms. Table II shows the time-series standard deviations of our estimates of divisional and standalone qs. While divisional qs are more volatile in half of the industries, on average across all industries the their standard deviation is 15% lower than that of standalone qs. This difference is economically large and statistically significant in a joint test (p = 0.00). [XXX It would be nice to add more details on how we estimate the difference between the standard deviations with/without adjusting for estimation noise XXX] Importantly, the 15% difference in standard deviations between divisional and standalone qs is understated due to estimation noise. In general, the volatility of an estimated series is inflated by the average volatility of the noise in the estimation. While this affects both divisional and standalone qs, medians are generally estimated with 17

19 less noise than the quantile regression coefficients. When we manually adjust the timeseries volatility estimates by subtracting the average cross-sectional estimation noise from bootstrapped samples, the standard deviation of divisional qs is 20% lower than that of standalone qs. In Table IV, we test the exposure of both divisional and standalone qs to macroeconomic shocks. For each industry, we regress the annual changes in q on contemporaneous changes in macroeconomic conditions, and report the average slope coefficients across the ten Fama-French industries. We consider nine proxies for macroeconomic conditions: market return, industry return, changes in market dividend yield, changes in the VIX index, changes in the default spread, changes in the industrial production, total factor productivity shocks, and the expansion indicator. These data are collectively gathered from XXX. The sensitivity of standalone qs to macroeconomic conditions is higher than that of divisional qs in all cases. For example, a positive shock to industrial production is associated with increases in both standalone and divisional qs. However, the increase in standalone qs is much higher (6.55) than that in divisional qs (3.80), and the difference of 2.75 is statistically significant. On average, across all these macroeconomic shocks, the sensitivity of divisional qs is a staggering 48% lower. Overall, the evidence in this section suggests that divisional qs are significantly different from standalone qs both cross-sectionally and in the time series. In the next section, we investigate the implications of these findings for conglomerate investment and internal capital allocation. IV. Conglomerate Investment Neoclassical theory suggests that, absent financial frictions, investment should depend only on investment opportunities measured by marginal Tobin s qs. Obtaining good estimates of these marginal Tobin s qs has been focus of extensive research, which acknowledges that it is particularly challenging for conglomerate divisions since their valu- 18

20 ation multiples are not observable. In this Section, we use our estimates of divisional qs to revisit the evidence on the investment-q sensitivity of conglomerate divisions. More concretely, Shin and Stulz (1998) and Ozbas and Scharfstein (2010) use the neoclassical relation between investment and q to study the efficacy of conglomerates internal capital allocation. Both paper proxy for a division s q by the median q of standalone firms in its industry. Ozbas and Scharfstein (2010) compare the sensitivity of investment to Tobin s q in conglomerate divisions and standalone firms. They find that investment is less sensitive to q in conglomerate divisions than in standalone firms. These results are broadly interpreted as evidence that conglomerates overinvest when opportunities are low and underinvest when they are high. Rather than comparing investments of conglomerates and standalone firms, Shin and Stulz (1998) focus solely on divisional investments, estimating their sensitivity to industry Tobin s q and divisional cash flows. They argue that if internal capital markets are working efficiently, (1) divisional investment will depend mostly on the cash flow of the firm as a whole and not on divisional cash flow, and (2) the sensitivity of investment to cash flow will be lower in divisions with a high q. In contrast, they find that divisional investment is more sensitive to its own cash flow than the cash flow of the firm as a whole, and that the sensitivity of a division s investment to cash flow does not depend on the quality of its investment opportunities. They interpret their evidence as consistent with inefficient internal capital markets and socialism divisions are treated alike irrespective of their investment opportunities. One concern with these studies is their use of standalone firms to proxy for the qs of conglomerate divisions. Whited (2001) and Maksimovic and Phillips (2002) demonstrate that estimates of investment opportunities derived from qs of standalone firms are inappropriate for the study of investment by conglomerate divisions. In particular, they show that these estimates suffer from measurement errors that arise due to potentially unobservable differences between conglomerate divisions and standalone firms. In contrast, the estimates of divisional qs generated by our method do not rely 19

21 on standalone firms. We therefore use these qs to investigate the differences in the q- sensitivity of investment between conglomerates and standalone firms (Ozbas and Scharfstein, 2010), and the sensitivity of conglomerates internal capital allocations to divisional qs and cash flows (Shin and Stulz, 1998). Columns (1)-(4) of Table V compare the sensitivity of investment to q in conglomerate divisions and standalone firms. As in Ozbas and Scharfstein (2010), the dependent variable is capital expenditures over sales, the regressions include year and industry fixed effects, and the standard errors are clustered by industry-year. In columns (1) and (3), the key explanatory variables are the industry median q of standalone firms (Standalone q), and its interaction with SA, an indicator variable equal to one for standalone firms and zero for conglomerate divisions. Hence, the coefficient on Standalone q represents conglomerate divisions sensitivity of investment to q estimated from standalone firms, and the interaction term captures the incremental sensitivity of standalone firms. In column (3), we also include the ratio of cash flows to sales, CF S. Following Ozbas and Scharfstein (2010), we normalize cash flows by sales instead of assets because conglomerates may have more discretion in allocating assets across divisions. The results in columns (1) and (3) are similar to those obtained by Ozbas and Scharfstein (2010). Conglomerate divisions exhibit lower q-sensitivity of investment than do standalone firms, as evidenced by a statistically significant positive coefficient on the interaction term Standalone q SA. Based on column (3), standalone firms sensitivity of investment to Standalone q is 2.8% higher than that of conglomerate divisions. In columns (2) and (4), we augment the regressions with Divisional q, the divisionlevel estimates of Tobin s q generated by our method. Our results are striking. We find that investment of standalone firms depends on Standalone q, but is insensitive to Divisional q. In contrast, investment of conglomerate divisions is highly sensitive to Divisional q, but is unrelated to Standalone q. For example, based on column 20

22 (4), the sensitivity of a standalone firm s investment to Standalone q is large and significant at 1.5% + 4.8% = 6.3%, while its exposure to Divisional q is negligible (2.9% 3.4% = 0.5%). In contrast, divisional investment is not significantly related to Standalone q, but highly sensitive to our estimate of the divisional q (2.9%, t-stat = 3.31). These results indicate that conglomerate investment is more sensitive to investment opportunities measured using conglomerate firms than to industry multiples estimated from standalone firms. This finding is more consistent with Whited s (2001) critique that investment opportunities are measured with error and less consistent with the hypothesis that conglomerates invest inefficiently. In columns (5) and (6) of Table V, we investigate the sensitivity of division investment to cash flows using the sample of conglomerate divisions as in Shin and Stulz (1998). This analysis allows for a division s investment to depend on its own investment opportunities and cash flows, as well as those of other divisions (indicated by j ). The investment-cash flow sensitivity can further depend on the division s investment opportunities (Standalone q CF S j and Divisional q CF S j ). When we use industry multiples (Standalone q) to proxy for a division s investment opportunities in column (5), our results are similar to those of Shin and Stulz (1998). First, a division s investment is more sensitive to its own cash flow than to the other divisions cash flows. Second, the sensitivity of a division s investment to other divisions cash flows is not lower when it has better investment opportunities. As noted above, these findings are traditionally interpreted as evidence against efficient internal capital markets. However, when we augment the specification with our division-level multiples Divisional q in column (6), we find different results. A division s investment is more sensitive to other divisions cash flows than its own cash flow (coefficients of vs ). Further, the sensitivity to other divisions cash flows is lower when investment opportunities are higher. This can be seen from the negative coefficient (0.333) on 21

23 the interaction term Divisional q CF S j. This evidence is broadly consistent with efficient internal capital allocation. Overall, we obtain strikingly different results about a division s q-sensitivity of investment when we use our division level q, Divisional q, rather than the industry median q of standalone firms, Standalone q. These results suggest that prior findings should be interpreted with caution because they may arise due to measurement error in Tobin s q rather than inefficient allocation of capital inside conglomerates. Moreover, these findings suggest that our method generates clean measures of qs inside conglomerates. While our regressions control for firm-level characteristics (XXX? do they), the sensitivity of investment to divisional qs could be correlated with potentially unobservable firm-level characteristics. Under this view, the estimates arise due to firm-level attributes that are unrelated to its organizational form. To address this concern, we estimate the elasticity of investment to standalone and divisional qs around the spinoff of conglomerate divisions. This analysis provides clean estimates that minimize confounding effects as it traces the investment policy of the same firm over time as the firm undergoes a change in its organizational structure. Our analysis focuses on spun-off conglomerate divisions that start operating as public standalone firms. We collect these data by augmenting the spinoff data provided by John McConnell with a sample of spinoffs from sdc. 6 We then collect capital expenditures and sales data for six years around the event. We estimate the investment-q sensitivity regressions after introducing a post-spinoff indicator (P OST ) that allows sensitivities to change at the time of the spinoff. Table VI summarizes the results. In the first two columns, we do not impose any further data restrictions, and analyze 1,561 firm-year observations that correspond to 478 spinoffs. They show that if Divisional q is omitted, investment in the spinoff 6 McConnell s sample contains crsp permnos, which facilitates matching to Compustat. The sdc sample is matched to Compustat based on company name and manually verified. Compustat provides the needed information prior to the spinoff for some firms, and we manually collect missing data from 10-k filings from edgar when available. We thank John McConnell for making the data available on 22

Dissecting Conglomerates

Dissecting Conglomerates Dissecting Conglomerates Oliver Boguth, Ran Duchin, and Mikhail Simutin September 1, 2017 ABSTRACT We develop a new method to study internal capital allocation in conglomerates by calculating direct estimates

More information

Dissecting Conglomerates

Dissecting Conglomerates Dissecting Conglomerates Oliver Boguth, Ran Duchin, and Mikhail Simutin April 6, 2016 ABSTRACT We develop a method to calculate valuation multiples of conglomerate divisions that does not rely on standalone

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

How increased diversification affects the efficiency of internal capital market?

How increased diversification affects the efficiency of internal capital market? How increased diversification affects the efficiency of internal capital market? ABSTRACT Rong Guo Columbus State University This paper investigates the effect of increased diversification on the internal

More information

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 6 Number 2 2012 AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University

More information

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time,

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, 1. Introduction Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, many diversified firms have become more focused by divesting assets. 2 Some firms become more

More information

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage Jin-Chuan Duan * and Yun Li (First draft: April 12, 2006) (This version: May 16, 2006) Abstract This paper identifies a key cause for the documented diversification

More information

Excess Value and Restructurings by Diversified Firms

Excess Value and Restructurings by Diversified Firms Excess Value and Restructurings by Diversified Firms Gayané Hovakimian Fordham University Schools of Business 1790 Broadway, 13 th floor New York, NY10019 Tel.: (212)-636-7021 E-mail: hovakimian@fordham.edu

More information

Corporate Diversification and Overinvestment: Evidence from Asset Write-Offs*

Corporate Diversification and Overinvestment: Evidence from Asset Write-Offs* Corporate Diversification and Overinvestment: Evidence from Asset Write-Offs* Gil Sadka and Yuan Zhang November 10, 2008 Preliminary and incomplete Please do not circulate Abstract This paper documents

More information

The Bright Side of Corporate Diversification:

The Bright Side of Corporate Diversification: The Bright Side of Corporate Diversification: Evidence from Policy Uncertainty Brian Clark Lally School of Management, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute Troy, NY 12180 clarkb2@rpi.edu Bill B. Francis Lally

More information

Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings

Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings Zhenxu Tong University of Exeter* Paper Number: 08/03 First Draft: June 2007 This Draft: February 2008 Abstract This paper studies how firm

More information

Divestitures and Divisional Investment Policies

Divestitures and Divisional Investment Policies Divestitures and Divisional Investment Policies Amy Dittmar Kelly School of Business Indiana University Bloomington, IN 47405 Phone: (812) 855-2698 Fax: (812) 855-5875 Email: adittmar@indiana.edu Anil

More information

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations Online Appendix of Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality By ANDREAS FAGERENG, LUIGI GUISO, DAVIDE MALACRINO AND LUIGI PISTAFERRI This appendix complements the evidence

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Appendices A A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Given the structure of venture capital financing just described, the potential mechanisms by which shocks might propagate across companies in

More information

DOES INFORMATION ASYMMETRY EXPLAIN THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT? Abstract

DOES INFORMATION ASYMMETRY EXPLAIN THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT? Abstract The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXVII, No. 2 Pages 235 249 Summer 2004 DOES INFORMATION ASYMMETRY EXPLAIN THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT? Ronald W. Best and Charles W. Hodges State University of West

More information

Do All Diversified Firms Hold Less Cash? The International Evidence 1. Christina Atanasova. and. Ming Li. September, 2015

Do All Diversified Firms Hold Less Cash? The International Evidence 1. Christina Atanasova. and. Ming Li. September, 2015 Do All Diversified Firms Hold Less Cash? The International Evidence 1 by Christina Atanasova and Ming Li September, 2015 Abstract: We examine the relationship between corporate diversification and cash

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

Conglomerates on the rise again? The worldwide impact of the financial crisis on the diversification discount

Conglomerates on the rise again? The worldwide impact of the financial crisis on the diversification discount Conglomerates on the rise again? The worldwide impact of the 2008-2009 financial crisis on the diversification discount Christin Rudolph l and Bernhard Schwetzler HHL Leipzig Graduate School of Management,

More information

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1 Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1 Andreas Fagereng (Statistics Norway) Luigi Guiso (EIEF) Davide Malacrino (Stanford University) Luigi Pistaferri (Stanford University

More information

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea Hangyong Lee Korea development Institute December 2005 Abstract This paper investigates the empirical relationship

More information

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract In this paper we study the market reaction to capital expenditure announcements in the backdrop

More information

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty Christopher F Baum Department of Economics, Boston College and DIW Berlin Mustafa Caglayan Department of Economics, University of Sheffield Oleksandr

More information

Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited. Hendrik Bessembinder. W.P. Carey School of Business. Arizona State University.

Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited. Hendrik Bessembinder. W.P. Carey School of Business. Arizona State University. Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited Hendrik Bessembinder W.P. Carey School of Business Arizona State University Feng Zhang David Eccles School of Business University of Utah May 2017

More information

Hedge Fund Activism and Internal Capital Markets

Hedge Fund Activism and Internal Capital Markets Hedge Fund Activism and Internal Capital Markets Sehoon Kim Warrington College of Business University of Florida October, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the impact of hedge fund activism on target companies

More information

The benefits and costs of group affiliation: Evidence from East Asia

The benefits and costs of group affiliation: Evidence from East Asia Emerging Markets Review 7 (2006) 1 26 www.elsevier.com/locate/emr The benefits and costs of group affiliation: Evidence from East Asia Stijn Claessens a, *, Joseph P.H. Fan b, Larry H.P. Lang b a World

More information

The Dynamics of Diversification Discount SEOUNGPIL AHN*

The Dynamics of Diversification Discount SEOUNGPIL AHN* The Dynamics of Diversification Discount SEOUNGPIL AHN* NUS Business School National University of Singapore Singapore 117592 Tel: (65) 6516-4555 e-mail: bizsa@nus.edu.sg Current version: June 2007 Preliminary

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

Debt Boundaries Matter: Evidence From The Subsidiary Debt

Debt Boundaries Matter: Evidence From The Subsidiary Debt Debt Boundaries Matter: Evidence From The Subsidiary Debt January 15, 2018 Abstract I exploit the introduction of an accounting reform in the US to investigate whether the presence of subsidiary debt affects

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

ARTICLE IN PRESS. JID:YJFIN AID:499 /FLA [m1g; v 1.36; Prn:26/05/2008; 15:02] P.1 (1-17) J. Finan. Intermediation ( )

ARTICLE IN PRESS. JID:YJFIN AID:499 /FLA [m1g; v 1.36; Prn:26/05/2008; 15:02] P.1 (1-17) J. Finan. Intermediation ( ) JID:YJFIN AID:499 /FLA [m1g; v 1.36; Prn:26/05/2008; 15:02] P.1 (1-17) J. Finan. Intermediation ( ) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect J. Finan. Intermediation www.elsevier.com/locate/fi Executive

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

Investment Policies and Excess Returns in Corporate Spinoffs: Evidence from the U.S. Market. Abstract

Investment Policies and Excess Returns in Corporate Spinoffs: Evidence from the U.S. Market. Abstract Investment Policies and Excess Returns in Corporate Spinoffs: Evidence from the U.S. Market BARBARA ROVETTA* This Draft: January 15, 2005 Abstract Stemming from the most recent contributions of financial

More information

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXVI, NO. 1 MARCH 1991 Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers HENRI SERVAES* ABSTRACT This paper analyzes the relation between takeover gains and the q ratios of targets and

More information

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva* The Role of Credit Ratings in the Dynamic Tradeoff Model Viktoriya Staneva* This study examines what costs and benefits of debt are most important to the determination of the optimal capital structure.

More information

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998) 219 239 Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Anup Agrawal*, Charles R. Knoeber College of Management, North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC

More information

Corporate Diversification and the Cost of Capital

Corporate Diversification and the Cost of Capital Corporate Diversification and the Cost of Capital April 2011 Abstract We examine whether organizational form matters for a firm s cost of capital. Contrary to conventional view, we argue that coinsurance

More information

A Synthesis of Accrual Quality and Abnormal Accrual Models: An Empirical Implementation

A Synthesis of Accrual Quality and Abnormal Accrual Models: An Empirical Implementation A Synthesis of Accrual Quality and Abnormal Accrual Models: An Empirical Implementation Jinhan Pae a* a Korea University Abstract Dechow and Dichev s (2002) accrual quality model suggests that the Jones

More information

The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in

The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in Summary 1 The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in state funding assistance between municipalities in South NJ compared to similar municipalities in Central and North

More information

Working Paper Series in Finance THE MARKET VALUE OF DIVERSIFIED FIRMS IN AUSTRALIA. Grant Fleming Australian National University

Working Paper Series in Finance THE MARKET VALUE OF DIVERSIFIED FIRMS IN AUSTRALIA. Grant Fleming Australian National University Working Paper Series in Finance 01-04 THE MARKET VALUE OF DIVERSIFIED FIRMS IN AUSTRALIA Grant Fleming Australian National University Barry Oliver Australian National University Steven Skourakis Deloitte

More information

Online Appendix for. Explaining Corporate Capital Structure: Product Markets, Leases, and Asset Similarity. Joshua D.

Online Appendix for. Explaining Corporate Capital Structure: Product Markets, Leases, and Asset Similarity. Joshua D. Online Appendix for Explaining Corporate Capital Structure: Product Markets, Leases, and Asset Similarity Section 1: Data A. Overview of Capital IQ Joshua D. Rauh Amir Sufi Capital IQ (CIQ) is a Standard

More information

The diversification puzzle revisited: The real options perspective

The diversification puzzle revisited: The real options perspective The diversification puzzle revisited: The real options perspective PABLO DE ANDRÉS-ALONSO AND GABRIEL DE LA FUENTE-HERRERO Department of Financial Economics University of Valladolid Avda. Valle Esgueva

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings

The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings Soohyung Kim University of Wisconsin La Crosse Hoontaek Seo Niagara University Daniel L. Tompkins Niagara University This

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. Stulz Working Paper 9523 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9523 NATIONAL

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: March 2013 First draft: October 2010 Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu. I am grateful

More information

RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN NONINTEREST INCOME AND BANK VALUATION: EVIDENCE FORM THE U.S. BANK HOLDING COMPANIES

RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN NONINTEREST INCOME AND BANK VALUATION: EVIDENCE FORM THE U.S. BANK HOLDING COMPANIES RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN NONINTEREST INCOME AND BANK VALUATION: EVIDENCE FORM THE U.S. BANK HOLDING COMPANIES by Mingqi Li B.Comm., Saint Mary s University, 2015 and Tiananqi Feng B.Econ., Jinan University,

More information

Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance. Panel Data, Fixed Effects, and Standard Errors

Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance. Panel Data, Fixed Effects, and Standard Errors Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance Panel Data, Fixed Effects, and Standard Errors The use of panel datasets Source: Bowen, Fresard, and Taillard (2014) 4/20/2015 2 The use of panel datasets Source:

More information

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LVI, NO. 6 DEC. 2001 Dividend Changes and Future Profitability DORON NISSIM and AMIR ZIV* ABSTRACT We investigate the relation between dividend changes and future profitability,

More information

Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? 1. Additional robustness checks

Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? 1. Additional robustness checks Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? This internet appendix provides robustness tests and supplemental analyses to the main results presented in Does Banking Competition Affect

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS, DIVERSIFICATION, AND THE FIRM S LIFECYCLE. Asli M. Arikan René M. Stulz

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS, DIVERSIFICATION, AND THE FIRM S LIFECYCLE. Asli M. Arikan René M. Stulz NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS, DIVERSIFICATION, AND THE FIRM S LIFECYCLE Asli M. Arikan René M. Stulz Working Paper 17463 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17463 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

How do business groups evolve? Evidence from new project announcements.

How do business groups evolve? Evidence from new project announcements. How do business groups evolve? Evidence from new project announcements. Meghana Ayyagari, Radhakrishnan Gopalan, and Vijay Yerramilli June, 2009 Abstract Using a unique data set of investment projects

More information

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck

More information

Investment and Financing Constraints

Investment and Financing Constraints Investment and Financing Constraints Nathalie Moyen University of Colorado at Boulder Stefan Platikanov Suffolk University We investigate whether the sensitivity of corporate investment to internal cash

More information

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4 Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4.1 Introduction Modelling and predicting financial market volatility has played an important role for market participants as it enables

More information

Do diversified or focused firms make better acquisitions?

Do diversified or focused firms make better acquisitions? Do diversified or focused firms make better acquisitions? on the 2015 American Finance Association (AFA) Meeting Program Mehmet Cihan Tulane University Sheri Tice Tulane University December 2014 ABSTRACT

More information

Why Does Global Diversification Still Make Sense? A Cross-Firm Analysis of the Risk and Value of Diversified Firms

Why Does Global Diversification Still Make Sense? A Cross-Firm Analysis of the Risk and Value of Diversified Firms Why Does Global Diversification Still Make Sense? A Cross-Firm Analysis of the Risk and Value of Diversified Firms Diego Escobari escobarida@utpa.edu The University of Texas Pan American Mohammad J. Nejad*

More information

Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis

Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis Armen Hovakimian Baruch College and Gayane Hovakimian * Fordham University May 12, 2005 ABSTRACT Using firm level estimates of investment-cash flow

More information

Do diversified firms allocate capital inefficiently? Evidence from equity carve-outs. Sudi Sudarsanam, Siyang Tian & Valeriya Vitkova

Do diversified firms allocate capital inefficiently? Evidence from equity carve-outs. Sudi Sudarsanam, Siyang Tian & Valeriya Vitkova Do diversified firms allocate capital inefficiently? Evidence from equity carve-outs Sudi Sudarsanam, Siyang Tian & Valeriya Vitkova Mergers & Acquisitions Research Centre (MARC) Cass Business School City

More information

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes *

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes * Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes * E. Han Kim and Paige Ouimet This appendix contains 10 tables reporting estimation results mentioned in the paper but not

More information

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios RESEARCH Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios March 2016 Wei Dai, PhD Research The predictability of expected stock returns is an old topic and an important one. While investors may increase expected returns

More information

50+ Years of Diversification Announcements

50+ Years of Diversification Announcements The Financial Review 45 (2010) 231 262 50+ Years of Diversification Announcements Mehmet E. Akbulut California State University, Fullerton John G. Matsusaka University of Southern California Abstract This

More information

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection of Stock Returns Cameron Truong Monash University, Melbourne, Australia February 2015 Abstract We document a significant positive relation

More information

An Empirical Investigation of the Lease-Debt Relation in the Restaurant and Retail Industry

An Empirical Investigation of the Lease-Debt Relation in the Restaurant and Retail Industry University of Massachusetts Amherst ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst International CHRIE Conference-Refereed Track 2011 ICHRIE Conference Jul 28th, 4:45 PM - 4:45 PM An Empirical Investigation of the Lease-Debt

More information

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance.

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Guillermo Acuña, Jean P. Sepulveda, and Marcos Vergara December 2014 Working Paper 03 Ownership Concentration

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

Internal Capital Markets in Financial Conglomerates: Evidence from Small Bank Responses to Monetary Policy

Internal Capital Markets in Financial Conglomerates: Evidence from Small Bank Responses to Monetary Policy Internal Capital Markets in Financial Conglomerates: Evidence from Small Bank Responses to Monetary Policy Murillo Campello* (This Draft: May 15, 2000) Abstract This paper examines the functioning of internal

More information

Investment, Alternative Measures of Fundamentals, and Revenue Indicators

Investment, Alternative Measures of Fundamentals, and Revenue Indicators Investment, Alternative Measures of Fundamentals, and Revenue Indicators Nihal Bayraktar, February 03, 2008 Abstract The paper investigates the empirical significance of revenue management in determining

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? *

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Thomas Moeller Neeley School of Business Texas Christian University Abstract In a large sample of public-public acquisitions, target

More information

1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 ),509$/8(5,6.$1'*52: ,7,(6. +\XQ+DQ6KLQ 5HQp06WXO] :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ

1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 ),509$/8(5,6.$1'*52: ,7,(6. +\XQ+DQ6KLQ 5HQp06WXO] :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ 1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 ),509$/8(5,6.$1'*52:7+23325781,7,(6 +\XQ+DQ6KLQ 5HQp06WXO] :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ 1$7,21$/%85($82)(&2120,&5(6($5&+ 0DVVDFKXVHWWV$YHQXH &DPEULGJH0$ -XO\ :HDUHJUDWHIXOIRUXVHIXOFRPPHQWVIURP*HQH)DPD$QGUHZ.DURO\LDQGSDUWLFLSDQWVDWVHPLQDUVDW

More information

CEO Inside Debt and Internal Capital Market Efficiency

CEO Inside Debt and Internal Capital Market Efficiency CEO Inside Debt and Internal Capital Market Efficiency Abstract Agency theory argues that managerial equity-based incentives are more effective when firm solvency is likely while debt-based incentives

More information

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang*

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang* Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds Kevin C.H. Chiang* School of Management University of Alaska Fairbanks Fairbanks, AK 99775 Kirill Kozhevnikov

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

THE IMPACT OF FINANCIAL CRISIS ON THE ECONOMIC VALUES OF FINANCIAL CONGLOMERATES

THE IMPACT OF FINANCIAL CRISIS ON THE ECONOMIC VALUES OF FINANCIAL CONGLOMERATES THE IMPACT OF FINANCIAL CRISIS ON THE ECONOMIC VALUES OF FINANCIAL CONGLOMERATES Hyung Min Lee The Leonard N. Stern School of Business Glucksman Institute for Research in Securities Markets Faculty Advisor:

More information

Approximating the Confidence Intervals for Sharpe Style Weights

Approximating the Confidence Intervals for Sharpe Style Weights Approximating the Confidence Intervals for Sharpe Style Weights Angelo Lobosco and Dan DiBartolomeo Style analysis is a form of constrained regression that uses a weighted combination of market indexes

More information

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership Robert C. Hanson Department of Finance and CIS College of Business Eastern Michigan University Ypsilanti, MI 48197 Moon H.

More information

Are CEOs Charged for Stock-Based Pay? An Instrumental Variable Analysis

Are CEOs Charged for Stock-Based Pay? An Instrumental Variable Analysis Are CEOs Charged for Stock-Based Pay? An Instrumental Variable Analysis Nina Baranchuk School of Management University of Texas - Dallas P.O. BOX 830688 SM31 Richardson, TX 75083-0688 E-mail: nina.baranchuk@utdallas.edu

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

Unrelated Acquisitions

Unrelated Acquisitions Unrelated Acquisitions Rajesh K. Aggarwal Carlson School of Management University of Minnesota 321 19 th Avenue South Room 3-122 Minneapolis, MN 55455 612-625-5679 rajesh@umn.edu Mufaddal Baxamusa Opus

More information

Internal Capital Market Efficiency of Belgian Holding Companies

Internal Capital Market Efficiency of Belgian Holding Companies Internal Capital Market Efficiency of Belgian Holding Companies Axel Gautier & Malika Hamadi December 14, 2004 Abstract In this paper, we raise the following two questions: (1) do Belgian holding companies

More information

Diversification, Refocusing, and Firm Value

Diversification, Refocusing, and Firm Value Diversification, Refocusing, and Firm Value by Gönül Çolak Henry B. Tippie College of Business University of Iowa Iowa City, Iowa 52242-1000 (319) 335-0980 gonul-colak@uiowa.edu This draft: January, 2003

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Internal Capital Allocation and Firm Performance

Internal Capital Allocation and Firm Performance Internal Capital Allocation and Firm Performance Ilan Guedj, Jennifer Huang, and Johan Sulaeman June 2009 Abstract Do conglomerate firms have the ability to allocate resources efficiently across business

More information

University of Southern California Law School

University of Southern California Law School University of Southern California Law School Law and Economics Working Paper Series Year 2008 Paper 73 50+ Years of Diversification Announcements Mehmet E. Akbulut John G. Matsusaka California State University,

More information

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University Colin Mayer Saïd Business School University of Oxford Oren Sussman

More information

Intra-Group Business Transactions with Foreign Subsidiaries and Firm Value: Evidence from Foreign Direct Investments of Korean Firms

Intra-Group Business Transactions with Foreign Subsidiaries and Firm Value: Evidence from Foreign Direct Investments of Korean Firms Intra-Group Business Transactions with Foreign Subsidiaries and Firm Value: Evidence from Foreign Direct Investments of Korean Firms Sung C. Bae a *, Taek Ho Kwon b September 2014 * Corresponding author

More information

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

CFA Level II - LOS Changes CFA Level II - LOS Changes 2018-2019 Topic LOS Level II - 2018 (465 LOS) LOS Level II - 2019 (471 LOS) Compared Ethics 1.1.a describe the six components of the Code of Ethics and the seven Standards of

More information

Hedge Fund Activism and Internal Capital Markets

Hedge Fund Activism and Internal Capital Markets Hedge Fund Activism and Internal Capital Markets Sehoon Kim Warrington College of Business University of Florida March, 2018 Abstract Hedge fund activism improves the internal capital allocation efficiency

More information

Dismantling internal capital markets via spinoff: effects on capital allocation efficiency and firm valuation

Dismantling internal capital markets via spinoff: effects on capital allocation efficiency and firm valuation Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (2005) 253 275 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Dismantling internal capital markets via spinoff: effects on capital allocation efficiency and firm valuation Chris R. McNeil

More information

Internet Appendix for: Does Going Public Affect Innovation?

Internet Appendix for: Does Going Public Affect Innovation? Internet Appendix for: Does Going Public Affect Innovation? July 3, 2014 I Variable Definitions Innovation Measures 1. Citations - Number of citations a patent receives in its grant year and the following

More information

EXPLAINING THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT. José Manuel Campa* Simi Kedia** RESEARCH PAPER No 424 October, 2000

EXPLAINING THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT. José Manuel Campa* Simi Kedia** RESEARCH PAPER No 424 October, 2000 IESE UNIVERSIDAD DE NAVARRA CIIF CENTRO INTERNACIONAL DE INVESTIGACION FINANCIERA EXPLAINING THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT José Manuel Campa* Simi Kedia** RESEARCH PAPER No 424 October, 2000 * Professor

More information

Corporate Acquisitions, Diversification, and the Firm s Lifecycle. Asli M. Arikan Ohio State University. and. René M. Stulz* Ohio State University

Corporate Acquisitions, Diversification, and the Firm s Lifecycle. Asli M. Arikan Ohio State University. and. René M. Stulz* Ohio State University ACCOUNTING WORKSHOP Corporate Acquisitions, Diversification, and the Firm s Lifecycle By Asli M. Arikan Ohio State University and René M. Stulz* Ohio State University Thursday, May 3 rd, 2012 1:20 2:50

More information

Online Appendix A: Verification of Employer Responses

Online Appendix A: Verification of Employer Responses Online Appendix for: Do Employer Pension Contributions Reflect Employee Preferences? Evidence from a Retirement Savings Reform in Denmark, by Itzik Fadlon, Jessica Laird, and Torben Heien Nielsen Online

More information

A RIDGE REGRESSION ESTIMATION APPROACH WHEN MULTICOLLINEARITY IS PRESENT

A RIDGE REGRESSION ESTIMATION APPROACH WHEN MULTICOLLINEARITY IS PRESENT Fundamental Journal of Applied Sciences Vol. 1, Issue 1, 016, Pages 19-3 This paper is available online at http://www.frdint.com/ Published online February 18, 016 A RIDGE REGRESSION ESTIMATION APPROACH

More information

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n.

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. 5/2014 April 2014 ISSN: 2239-2734 This Working Paper is published under

More information