Corporate Diversification and the Cost of Capital

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Corporate Diversification and the Cost of Capital"

Transcription

1 Corporate Diversification and the Cost of Capital April 2011 Abstract We examine whether organizational form matters for a firm s cost of capital. Contrary to conventional view, we argue that coinsurance among a firm s business units can reduce systematic risk through the avoidance of countercyclical deadweight costs. We find that diversified firms have on average a lower cost of capital than comparable portfolios of standalone firms. In addition, diversified firms with less correlated segment cash flows have a lower cost of capital, consistent with a coinsurance effect. Holding cash flows constant, our estimates imply an average value gain of approximately 5% when moving from the highest to the lowest cash flow correlation quintile.

2 1. Introduction The conventional view among practitioners and researchers is that organizational form does not matter for a firm s cost of capital because, while the imperfect correlation of business unit cash flows may help reduce idiosyncratic risk, this should have no effect on systematic risk. Long a part of mainstream thought, the conventional view is widely disseminated through standard finance textbooks and classroom teaching. The notion that corporate diversification cannot affect systematic risk is usually covered explicitly in the mergers and acquisitions chapter 1 or implicitly through the standalone principle in the capital budgeting chapter. In this paper, we present evidence that is contrary to the conventional view. We find that diversified firms have a lower cost of capital than comparable portfolios of standalone firms. We also find that the reduction in cost of capital is strongly related to the correlation of business unit cash flows, consistent with a coinsurance effect. We argue that organizational form can affect a firm s cost of capital, and in particular, coinsurance the imperfect correlation of cash flows among a firm s business units can reduce systematic risk through the avoidance of countercyclical deadweight costs. Using deadweight costs of financial distress as an illustrative example, if coinsurance reduces default risk (Lewellen (1971)) and enables a diversified firm to avoid countercyclical deadweight costs of financial distress (Elton, Gruber, Agrawal, and Mann (2001), and Almeida and Philippon (2007)) that its business units would have otherwise incurred as standalone firms, then coinsurance should lead to a reduction in the diversified firm s systematic risk and hence its cost of capital. Costly financial distress is of course just one example of deadweight costs faced by firms. Other examples include adverse selection and transaction costs of external finance and resulting 1 Systematic variability cannot be eliminated by diversification, so mergers will not eliminate this risk at all. (Ross, Westerfield, and Jaffe, p. 823) 1

3 investment distortions, forgone business opportunities due to defections by important stakeholders such as suppliers, customers, or employees, and so on. Many of these costs tend to arise following low cash flow realizations making them countercyclical since low cash flow realizations are more likely during bad economic times. Amplification mechanisms such as the credit channel or asset fire sales can also add to the countercyclical nature of these costs. Our general argument is that coinsurance should enable a diversified firm to transfer resources from cash-rich units to cash-poor units in some states of nature and thereby avoid some of the countercyclical deadweight costs that standalone firms cannot avoid on their own. As a result, cash flows of diversified firms should contain less systematic risk than those of comparable portfolios of standalone firms. In addition, the reduction in systematic risk should depend on the extent of coinsurance among diversified firms business units. We test these predictions using a sample of single- and multi-segment firms spanning the period 1988 to Our main cost of capital proxy is the weighted average of cost of equity and cost of debt. We use ex ante measures of expected returns for both components of financing: implied cost of equity constructed from analyst forecasts to proxy for expected equity returns and yields from the Barclays Capital Aggregate Bond Index to proxy for expected debt returns. We estimate implied cost of equity based on the approach of Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan (2001), which has been recently employed in several asset pricing contexts (Lee, Ng, and Swaminathan (2009) and Pastor, Sinha, and Swaminathan (2008)). Our empirical analyses are based on an excess cost of capital measure that benchmarks the cost of capital of a diversified firm against that of a comparable portfolio of standalone firms. We find that diversified firms on average have a significantly lower cost of capital than comparable portfolios of standalone firms, rejecting the conventional view that organizational 2

4 form does not matter for a firm s cost of capital. We consider cash flow and investment correlations among a firm s segments as an inverse measure of coinsurance. Consistent with a coinsurance effect, we find a significant positive relation between excess cost of capital and cross-segment correlations. In addition, we examine the role that financial slack also plays in helping firms avoid deadweight costs. We find that coinsurance effects are stronger for firms with less financial slack (higher net leverage and lower cash holdings). These findings are robust to controlling for potential analyst biases and using alternative measures of (i) implied cost of equity (Claus and Thomas (2001) and Easton (2004)), (ii) cost of equity not reliant on analyst forecasts, (iii) cost of debt inferred from publicly-traded bonds or private loans, and (iv) coinsurance. They are also robust to controlling for selection effects in a Heckman two-stage analysis and using changes in coinsurance over which managers arguably have no control (Lamont and Polk (2002)). Our findings are also economically significant. Our estimates imply an average percentage reduction of approximately 3% in cost of capital and an average value gain of approximately 5% when moving from the highest to the lowest cash flow correlation quintile. The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides a discussion of the setting and related research. Section 3 outlines the valuation approach that we use in estimating the implied cost of equity along with the construction of excess cost of capital and coinsurance measures. Section 4 describes our sample. Section 5 presents our findings. Section 6 concludes. 3

5 2. The Setting 2.1. Systematic Risk and Cost of Capital in a Model of Coinsurance Our hypotheses about organizational form and cost of capital are based on a model of coinsurance in the spirit of Lewellen (1971). This section summarizes the model s basics and outlines the assumptions under which the imperfect correlation of business unit cash flows lowers a diversified firm s cost of capital relative to a comparable portfolio of standalone firms. 2 To illustrate our main ideas, suppose that firms incur certain deadweight losses when their projects experience low cash flow outcomes. Examples of deadweight losses include forgone business opportunities due to defections by important stakeholders such as suppliers, customers, or employees, financial distress or external finance costs, and so on. A large body of research in finance shows that the expected value of such deadweight losses is higher during worse economic times, possibly due to the higher incidence of low cash flow outcomes, or due to amplification mechanisms such as the credit channel or asset fire sales. As a result, firms face deadweight losses that are partly countercyclical and firms cash flows contain more systematic risk than they otherwise would in a frictionless world. That is, countercyclical deadweight losses add to the systematic risk of firms. In such a setting, it is straightforward to show that a diversified firm s systematic risk would be lower than that of a comparable portfolio of standalone firms. The imperfect correlation of business unit cash flows allows resources to be transferred from cash-rich units to cash-poor units in some states of nature to avoid some of the countercyclical deadweight losses that standalone firms cannot avoid on their own. More generally, a diversified firm with less correlated business unit cash flows and hence greater coinsurance potential would have less 2 In a previous version of the paper, we used the model to derive additional testable predictions, which we later state in this section. The formal analysis can now be found in an Internet Appendix. 4

6 systematic risk. Only in the case of perfectly correlated business unit cash flows would a diversified firm s systematic risk approach that of a comparable portfolio of standalone firms. For these results to hold, two further assumptions are needed. First, it must be costly for standalone firms to enter into state-contingent financing contracts with each other to replicate the extent of deadweight loss avoidance achieved by diversified firms. Second, it must be costly for firms to hold first-best amounts of financial slack to avoid all future deadweight losses. Both assumptions strike us as accurate descriptions of the real world. Verifiability and enforcement frictions likely render state-contingent financing contracts expensive or infeasible. In addition, tax and agency costs likely discourage firms from holding first-best amounts of financial slack. In the Internet Appendix, we consider two extensions of the basic model. First, we allow for the possibility of agency costs of diversification and the possibility of inefficient internal capital markets to address a model prediction that some might see as counterfactual the basic model without any cost of diversification predicts a diversification premium. We show that these costs do not change the qualitative implications of the model about countercyclical coinsurance. So, it is possible to observe both a diversification discount and a coinsurance effect at the same time. Second, we extend the model to include debt alongside equity and show that the coinsurance results apply to both debt and equity financing. To summarize, the model setting outlined above has the following testable predictions. First, diversified firms should have a lower cost of capital than comparable portfolios of standalone firms. Second, the reduction in cost of capital should be related to expected coinsurance opportunities. Diversified firms with less correlated business unit cash flows and thus greater coinsurance potential should have a lower cost of capital. Third, financial slack, which firms can use to avoid deadweight losses, should reduce the importance of coinsurance 5

7 and its effect on cost of capital. Consequently, coinsurance effects should be smaller for diversified firms with greater financial slack Related Literature The notion of coinsurance among a firm s business units goes at least as far back as Lewellen (1971). The ensuing stream of research studies coinsurance in the context of conglomerate mergers (Higgins and Schall (1975) and Scott (1977)) and examines whether such mergers lead to wealth transfers from shareholders to bondholders (Kim and McConnell (1977)). Importantly, this literature does not recognize the possibility that coinsurance can affect a firm s systematic risk. For example, standard textbooks emphasize the irrelevance of corporate diversification and coinsurance when explaining the standalone principle of capital budgeting by either implicitly following or explicitly citing Schall s (1972) analysis. To our knowledge, our study is the first to establish a link between coinsurance and cost of capital. Our study also complements the literature on corporate diversification and firm value (Lang and Stulz (1994), Berger and Ofek (1995), Campa and Kedia (2002), Graham, Lemmon, and Wolf (2002), Mansi and Reeb (2002), and Villalonga (2004)) by exploring an important dimension that thus far has received little attention, namely, cost of capital. The discussion in this literature revolves mostly around future cash flow differences between conglomerates and standalone firms, and confounding selection effects. An exception is Lamont and Polk (2001), who raise the possibility that valuation differences may arise due to differences in expected returns. They find a significant and negative relation between excess values and future returns 3 It is worth noting that a model of contagion would generate the opposite predictions. For instance, if the liquidity concerns of cash-poor units spread to other units of the firm and cause deadweight losses that standalone firms would not incur on their own, then diversified firms would incur greater deadweight losses than comparable portfolios of standalone firms. 6

8 for diversified firms, suggesting that valuation differences are explained in part by differences in expected returns. While their study introduces the important role of expected returns in understanding the valuation of diversified firms, their main focus is to explain the cross-sectional variation in excess value, and not how diversification affects a firm s cost of capital. Our work deepens the foundations of this literature by exploring whether the cross-sectional variation in cost of capital is due to coinsurance. Our work is also related to an extensive literature on the deadweight costs of external finance, and the ability of different organizational forms to avoid them. Livdan, Sapriza, and Zhang (2009) show that more financially constrained firms are riskier and earn higher expected stock returns than less financially constrained firms. Dimitrov and Tice (2006) show that during recessions both sales and inventory growth rates drop more for bank-dependent standalone firms than they do for rival segments of bank-dependent diversified firms. Yan, Yang, and Jiao (2010) show that standalone firms experience investment declines relative to diversified firms during periods of depressed conditions in external capital markets. Related work by Yan (2006) also shows that diversified firms have higher valuations when external capital is more costly. Hovakimian (2011) shows that more financially constrained diversified firms allocate capital more efficiently during recessions. Using the financial crisis as a natural experiment, Kuppuswamy and Villalonga (2010) show that the value of diversified firms increased relative to standalone firms due to financing and investment advantages. Studying deadweight costs of asset fire sales, Pulvino (1998) finds that financially constrained airlines receive lower prices than their unconstrained rivals when selling used narrow-body aircraft. Consistent with deadweight costs of asset fire sales being countercyclical, Ortiz-Molina and Phillips (2009) find that firms with more liquid real assets have a lower cost of capital. Finally, Duchin (2010) studies the 7

9 relation between coinsurance and firms cash retention policies. Our paper combines with Duchin s to form a nascent literature examining the implications of coinsurance for corporate finance in general. 3. Empirical Design The coinsurance hypothesis outlined in Section 2.1 relates a diversified firm s cost of capital to the extent of coinsurance among its business units. In this section, we discuss our main proxies for these constructs Cost of Capital Prior research in finance has generally used ex post realized returns to proxy for expected returns and cost of capital (Fama and French (1997), Lamont and Polk (2001)). However, realized returns are noisy proxies for expected returns due to contamination by information shocks, which can lead to biased inferences in finite samples (Elton (1999)). To address this concern, recent literature in accounting and finance has developed an ex ante approach to measuring expected returns by estimating the implied cost of equity (Claus and Thomas (2001), Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan (2001), Easton (2004)). The implied cost of equity is the internal rate of return that equates the current stock price to the present value of all expected future cash flows to equity. Namely, the value of the firm at time t can be expressed as P t Et[ FCFEt i], i (1 r ) i 1 e where P t is the market value of equity at time t, FCFE t+i is free cash flow to equity at time t+i, and r e is the implied cost of equity. 8

10 In our main analysis, we follow the approach of Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan (2001) (hereafter, GLS) to estimate the implied cost of equity. The GLS measure has been successfully employed in several asset-pricing contexts (Lee, Ng, and Swaminathan (2009), Pastor, Sinha, and Swaminathan (2008), Chava and Purnanandam (2010)). Following GLS and much of the implied cost of equity literature, we use I/B/E/S consensus analyst forecasts to proxy for future earnings (see the Appendix for details). We then follow an approach similar to Lamont and Polk (2001) to estimate total cost of capital (COC). Lamont and Polk define total cost of capital as the weighted average of a firm s realized equity return and the return on an aggregate bond index. To avoid the pitfalls of using ex post realized returns, we use ex ante measures to proxy for expected equity and debt returns. More specifically, the COC for firm i in year t is computed as follows: COC i,t = D i,t-1 Y BC t + (1 - D i,t-1 ) COEC i,t, where Y t BC is the aggregate bond yield from the Barclays Capital Aggregate Bond Index (formerly, the Lehman Brothers Aggregate Bond Index), COEC i,t is the implied cost of equity (GLS), and D i,t-1 is the firm s book value of debt divided by total value (book value of debt plus market value of common equity). 4 To compare a diversified firm s cost of capital to the cost of capital that its business units would have as standalone firms, we compute excess COC as the natural logarithm of the ratio of the firm s COC to its imputed COC. The imputed COC of the firm is a value-weighted average of the imputed COC of its segments: 4 Book value of debt is long-term debt (Compustat Item #9) plus short-term debt (Compustat Item #34); market value of equity is fiscal year-end stock price (Compustat Item #199) multiplied by shares outstanding (Compustat Item #25). 9

11 icoc i n n k 1 k 1 imv ik imv ik icoc ik, where n is the number of the firm s segments, icoc ik is the imputed COC of segment k, which is equal to the median COC of single-segment firms in the segment s industry, and imv ik is the imputed market value of segment k, calculated as in Berger and Ofek (1995). The procedure for estimating segments imputed market values is described in detail in Berger and Ofek (1995). In short, the procedure consists of: (1) estimating the median ratio of enterprise value to sales for all single-segment firms in the industry to which the segment belongs, and (2) multiplying the segment s sales by the median industry ratio. Industry definitions are based on the narrowest SIC grouping that includes at least five single-segment firms with at least $20 million in sales and has a non-missing COC estimate Coinsurance Measuring the level of coinsurance among a diversified firm s business units is empirically challenging because the joint distribution of future business-unit cash flows is not observable. Moreover, using the distribution of historical business-unit cash flows is problematic because firm composition changes over time. Accordingly, we construct coinsurance proxies using correlations of industry-level cash flows based on single-segment firms. While our main proxy is based on business unit membership in 2-digit SIC industries, we also consider several other proxies using different industry definitions (see Section 5.3 for details). To ensure that estimated pairwise industry correlations are not contaminated with systematic risk, we perform the computation in two stages. First, for each industry in a given year, we compute idiosyncratic industry cash flows for the prior ten years as residuals from a 10

12 regression of average industry cash flow on average market-wide cash flow. Next, for each year in our sample, we estimate pairwise industry correlations using prior ten-year idiosyncratic industry cash flows. As coinsurance of investment opportunities can also help firms avoid deadweight costs of external finance (Matsusaka and Nanda (2002)), we similarly estimate pairwise industry correlations using prior ten-year idiosyncratic industry investments. 5 These estimated correlations serve as inputs to our coinsurance measures described below. As an inverse measure of coinsurance, we compute a sales-weighted portfolio correlation measure ρ it(n) for firm i in year t with n business segments as n n p 1 q 1 w w Corr ( j, k), ip( j) iq( k ) [ t 10, t 1] where w ip(j) is the sales share of segment p of firm i operating in industry j (similarly for business segment q of firm i operating in industry k), and Corr (, ) [ t 10, t 1] j k is the estimated correlation of idiosyncratic industry cash flows or investments between industries j and k over the ten-year period before year t. We obtain similar results using an alternative coinsurance measure, which also includes the standard deviation of industry cash flow and investment (Duchin (2010)). Note that a single-segment firm s sales-weighted cash flow or investment correlation measure equals one by definition. This is also true for a multi-segment firm whose segments operate in the same industry. 4. Sample and Data 4.1. Sample Selection 5 As is standard practice, we measure cash flow as operating income before depreciation (Compustat Item #13) scaled by total assets (Compustat Item #6) and investment as capital expenditures (Compustat Item #128) scaled by total assets (Compustat Item #6). 11

13 We obtain our sample from the intersection of the Compustat and I/B/E/S databases for the period 1988 to We construct cost of capital measures by combining firm-level accounting information from the Compustat annual files with analyst forecasts from I/B/E/S. The excess cost of capital measures and the coinsurance measures require availability of segment disclosures from the Compustat segment-level files. Additionally, we impose the following sample restrictions. First, we follow Berger and Ofek (1995) and require that (1) all firm-years have at least $20 million in sales to avoid distorted valuation multiples; (2) the sum of segment sales be within 1% of the total sales of the firm to ensure the integrity of segment data; (3) all of the firm s segments for a given year have at least five firms in the same 2-digit SIC industry with non-missing firm value to sales ratios and GLS COC estimates; and (4) all firms with at least one segment in the financial industry (SIC codes between 6000 and 6999) be excluded from the sample. Second, we require the following data to estimate the GLS COC measure: (1) one- and two-year-ahead earnings forecasts; (2) either a three-year-ahead earnings forecast or the long-term growth earnings forecast and a positive two-year-ahead earnings forecast; and (3) positive book value of equity. The initial sample with available GLS excess cost of capital estimates consists of 38,371 firmyear observations, of which 26,451 (11,920) are single-segment (multi-segment) firms. With additional data requirements for the control variables (discussed in the next section), the final sample consists of 29,080 firm-year observations, of which 19,996 (9,084) observations pertain to single-segment (multi-segment) firms. Some of the sensitivity analyses impose further data restrictions, as discussed in the corresponding sections of the paper. 6 The start of our sample period is driven by our use of pairwise industry correlation estimates based on prior tenyear single-segment data, which start in

14 4.2. Control Variables To ensure that our results on the relation between coinsurance and cost of capital are distinct from the well-documented return patterns (Fama and French (1992) and Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)), we control for size, book-to-market, and momentum as proxied by the log of market capitalization, the book-to-market ratio, and lagged buy-and-hold returns over the past 12 months, respectively. Including a measure of momentum also controls for sluggishness in analyst forecasts. Recent revisions in the stock market s earnings expectations, although immediately reflected in stock prices, may not be incorporated in analyst forecasts on a timely basis, which could induce a negative correlation between past returns and implied COE estimates. 7 Recent research by Hughes, Liu, and Liu (2009) shows that when discount rates are stochastic, implied COE estimates can deviate from expected returns and these deviations can be related to the volatility of, as well as the sample correlation among, expected returns and cash flows, expected growth in cash flows, and leverage. They argue that the resulting measurement error in implied COE estimates may therefore be correlated with variables that are traditionally not associated with systematic risk exposure, explaining the significant correlation between implied COE and leverage, expected earnings growth, and forecast dispersion documented in prior research (Gode and Mohanram (2003)). Therefore, we include these variables as additional controls to avoid spurious results. The timeline of variable measurement is depicted in Figure 1 and the definitions of control variables are summarized below (numbered items refer to the Compustat annual database): 7 It is possible that we are overcontrolling by including size and the book-to-market ratio in our regressions. First, book-to-market may be associated with coinsurance-related forward-looking betas in a conditional asset-pricing model (Petkova and Zhang (2005)). Second, size may serve as an alternative proxy for coinsurance. Larger firms are likely to have a greater number of unrelated projects and thus experience greater coinsurance benefits. 13

15 Log(market capitalization) = Natural logarithm of fiscal year-end stock price times shares outstanding from Compustat (#199*#25); Leverage = Book value of debt divided by the sum of book value of debt and market value of equity from Compustat (#9+#34)/(#9+#34+#199*#25); Book-to-market = Ratio of book value of equity to market value of equity from Compustat (#60/(#199*#25)); Log(forecast dispersion) = Natural logarithm of the standard deviation in analysts one-year-ahead earnings forecasts from I/B/E/S; Long-term growth forecast = Consensus (median) long-term growth forecast from I/B/E/S; Lagged 12-month return = Buy-and-hold stock return from the beginning of June (t-1) until the end of May (t) from CRSP. 5. Empirical Results 5.1. Summary Statistics: Excess Cost of Capital In Table 1, we present summary statistics for excess COC for multi- and single-segment firms separately. For the multi-segment subsample, both mean and median excess COC are negative and significant ( and ). For the single-segment subsample, the median value of excess COC is zero by construction because the imputed values are calculated using the COC of the median single-segment firm in each industry. The mean excess COC is negative ( ) and significant, indicating that the distribution of excess COC is negatively skewed. The difference in means between the multi- and single-segment subsamples is negative (-0.010) and different from zero at better than the 1% level of statistical significance, rejecting the conventional view that organizational form does not matter for a firm s cost of capital. Recall that our excess cost of capital measure is defined as the natural logarithm of the ratio of the firm s COC to its imputed COC based on comparable single-segment firms. Hence, 14

16 when we discuss percentage differences in excess cost of capital, we imply logarithmic percentage differences throughout the paper. Using the estimate above as an example a logarithmic percentage difference of -1% (-0.010) between multi- and single-segment firms the cost of capital of a multi-segment firm would be roughly 9.9% if the cost of capital of a singlesegment firm were 10%. The modest difference between the cost of capital of multi- and single-segment firms is likely due to the pooling of all multi-segment firms, many of which operate within a single industry and enjoy little cross-segment coinsurance. In the next section, we test for differences in cost of capital between multi-segment firms with lower and higher levels of coinsurance Analysis of Excess Cost of Capital and Coinsurance Nonparametric Results In Table 2, we sort our sample of multi-segment firms into quintiles based on crosssegment cash flow and investment correlations (defined in Section 3.2) and report the average excess COC for each quintile in the left and right panels, respectively. Because the results are similar across the two sorts, we focus our discussion on the first sort based on cross-segment cash flow correlations. We also present the results for single-segment firms. Note that singlesegment firms can be viewed as limit observations with respect to the degree of coinsurance for these firms, cash flow and investment correlations equal one by definition. Consistent with the coinsurance hypothesis, we observe a monotonic increase in excess COC from the lowest correlation quintile (Q1) with the most coinsurance to the highest correlation quintile (Q5) with the least coinsurance. The mean difference between Q1 and Q5 is a statistically significant Similarly, the mean difference between the cost of capital of 15

17 multi-segment firms in the lowest correlation quintile (Q1) and single-segment firms is , consistent with a significant coinsurance effect. These results reject the conventional view in favor of the coinsurance hypothesis diversified firms that consist of businesses with less correlated cash flows have a lower cost of capital Main Regression Results Next, we investigate whether the nonparametric evidence in Table 2 is robust to controlling for the set of firm characteristics discussed in Section 4.2. The results of this analysis are presented in Table 3, with robust standard errors (heteroskedasticity consistent and double clustered by firm and year (Petersen (2009)) reported in brackets below corresponding coefficients. In the first set of regressions, Models 1 and 2, we regress excess COC on cross-segment cash flow and investment correlations, respectively, and control for all variables except for the number of segments and the natural logarithm of market capitalization. We exclude these two measures because they likely capture some degree of coinsurance. Larger firms or firms with more segments are more likely to have business units with imperfectly correlated cash flows. Therefore, including them in the regressions could overcontrol for the coinsurance effect. In the second set of regressions, Models 3 and 4, we use the number of segments and the natural logarithm of market capitalization, respectively, as alternative measures of coinsurance. In the last set of specifications, Models 5 and 6, we include all control variables, including the number of segments and the natural logarithm of market capitalization, to disentangle other possible size effects from the coinsurance effect that is captured by cash flow and investment correlations. We therefore view this last set of specifications as the most demanding test of the coinsurance hypothesis. 16

18 Because the results for cash flow and investment correlations are similar in all specifications, we focus our discussion on cash flow correlations. Consistent with the nonparametric results, the coefficient estimate on cross-segment cash flow correlations in Model 1 is positive (0.056) and different from zero at the 1% level of statistical significance. In Models 3 and 4, we find negative and significant coefficients on the number of segments and the natural logarithm of market capitalization. As noted earlier, while these results are consistent with the coinsurance hypothesis, it is difficult to attribute them solely to the coinsurance effect as firm size and the number of segments may also proxy for other factors. Finally in Model 5, the coefficient estimate on cross-segment cash flow correlations is positive (0.053) and different from zero at the 1% level of statistical significance. The coefficient estimate is also similar to that in Model 1, suggesting that cross-segment correlations provide a source of variation in coinsurance that is relatively independent from that provided by firm size and number of segments. Overall, our results strongly reject the conventional view in favor of the coinsurance hypothesis. Firms with lower cross-segment cash flow correlations and hence greater coinsurance potential have a lower cost of capital Financial Slack As discussed in Section 2.1, financial slack can serve as an alternative mechanism for firms to limit or avoid deadweight costs. Thus, one would expect financial slack to reduce the benefit of coinsurance and its effect on cost of capital. We test this prediction in Table 4 using two measures of financial slack, net leverage (an inverse measure of slack) and cash holdings. The main coefficient of interest is the interaction term between cross-segment correlations and financial slack. Models 1 and 2 report the results for net leverage quintile rank, which ranges from 1 for firms in the lowest net leverage quintile (most financial slack) to 17

19 5 for firms in the highest net leverage quintile (least financial slack) in a given year. Models 3 and 4 report the results for cash quintile rank, which ranges from 1 for firms in the lowest cash quintile (least financial slack) to 5 for firms in the highest cash quintile (most financial slack) in a given year. The coefficient estimates on the interaction between cross-segment correlations and net leverage quintile rank are positive (0.024 in both Models 1 and 2) and significant at the 1% level. In addition, the coefficient estimates suggest that the coinsurance effect is approximately zero for firms in the lowest net leverage quintile ( and in Models 1 and 2, respectively), but rather substantial for firms in the highest net leverage quintile (0.091 and in Models 1 and 2, respectively). In Models 3 and 4, the coefficient estimates on the interaction between cross-segment correlations and cash quintile rank are negative ( in both Models 3 and 4) and significant at the 1% level, consistent with a weaker coinsurance effect for firms with higher cash holdings. These results suggest that the coinsurance effect is weaker for firms with more financial slack (lower net leverage or higher cash holdings), consistent with the prediction that coinsurance benefits are smaller for these firms Controlling for Selection Effects Our estimates of the coinsurance effect might be biased due to selection effects arising from firms decisions to diversify, an issue that has been addressed extensively in the diversification discount literature. However, it is unclear how a strong monotonic relation between our continuous coinsurance measures and excess cost of capital would be driven by a dichotomous selection mechanism that pushes some business units to conglomerate. In addition, one might think a priori that high-risk business units, which have the most to gain from coinsurance, are more likely to diversify than low-risk business units, in which case the selection bias would work against us finding a coinsurance effect. 18

20 Nevertheless, we acknowledge that selection is an important concern and we address this issue in two ways. First, we estimate Heckman two-stage regressions to correct for potential selection biases. Second, we follow an approach that is similar in spirit to that of Lamont and Polk (2002) and examine the relation between exogenous changes in coinsurance and changes in excess COC. As we describe below, the results from both analyses suggest that our estimates of the coinsurance effect in Table 3 are unlikely to be contaminated by selection effects or firms decisions to diversify. Heckman s Two-Stage Analysis To control for potential selection biases using Heckman s two-stage procedure, we first estimate a first-stage probit model for firms decisions to diversify. The dependent variable in the probit model is equal to 1 for a multi-segment firm and 0 for a single-segment firm. We estimate two different first-stage models. The first model ( No Instrument ) includes all of the control variables in our main regression model. The second model ( With Instruments ) further includes two instruments used in Campa and Kedia (2002), namely, PNDIV (the fraction of all firms in the industry which are conglomerates) and PSDIV (the fraction of sales accounted for by conglomerates). The second-stage regressions control for the inverse Mills ratio estimated from these two first-stage models. The results of the second-stage regressions are reported in Panel A of Table 5. The first two columns present the results using the inverse Mills ratio from the No Instrument first-stage probit model whereas the last two columns present the results using the inverse Mills ratio from the With Instruments first-stage probit model. In all models, the estimated coefficients on cross-segment correlations are positive and different from zero at the 1% level of statistical significance. Importantly, the magnitudes of the coefficients are similar to those reported in 19

21 Table 3. Further consistent with the absence of significant selection effects, the estimated coefficients on the Mills ratio are small and only marginally significant in the first two columns. Exogenous Changes in Coinsurance and Changes in Excess COC We also follow an approach that is similar to that of Lamont and Polk (2002) to address the issue of selection effects. Specifically, we decompose changes in cross-segment correlations into two components: an exogenous component that reflects changes in pairwise industry correlations that are arguably outside the control of managers, and an endogenous component that reflects changes in firm segment structure that managers can control. Specifically: ( s, c ) ( s, c ) t t t t 1 t 1 ( st, ct) ( st 1, ct) ( st 1, ct) ( st 1, ct 1) endogenous change in exogenous change in where s t and c t represent the firm s segment structure and estimates of pairwise industry correlations in year t, respectively. Next, we regress changes in excess COC on exogenous and endogenous changes in crosssegment correlations as well as changes in the control variables from Table 3. The results are reported in Panel B of Table 5. Models 1 and 3 are analogous to the main regression models in Table 3 (Models 5 and 6), but in a first-differenced form, which effectively controls for firm fixed effects. Models 2 and 4 decompose total changes in cross-segment correlations into exogenous and endogenous changes. Similar to the main regression results in Table 3, the coefficient estimates on crosssegment correlations in Models 1 and 3 are both positive and significant. More importantly, in Models 2 and 4, the coefficient estimates on exogenous changes in cross-segment correlations are also positive and significant, and they are similar in magnitude to those in Table 3. 20

22 It is worth noting that while our main focus is on exogenous changes in cross-segment correlations, endogenous changes are also of interest as a firm s cost of capital should change in response to changes in its organizational structure. Consistent with this prediction, the coefficient estimates on endogenous changes in cross-segment correlations are also positive, although significant only for cross-segment cash flow correlations in Model Economic Significance To evaluate the economic significance of our findings, we estimate the effect of coinsurance-related reduction in cost of capital on firm value. In the simple Gordon growth model, under a zero dividend growth assumption, a 1% decrease in cost of capital from 10% to 9.9% approximately translates into a 1% increase in firm value. However, the relation between cost of capital and firm value is in general nonlinear and depends on other inputs in the valuation formula expected earnings and earnings growth. Our analysis compares actual firm values to as-if firm values calculated using imputed cost of capital (i.e., the cost of capital on a comparable portfolio of single-segment firms) while holding cash flows constant in the GLS valuation model (described in the Appendix). The excess value attributable to differences in cost of capital is calculated as the natural logarithm of the ratio of actual firm value to as-if firm value. Using this approach, we find an economically significant 5.5% (5.4%) average gain in total firm value when moving from the lowest to the highest coinsurance quintile based on crosssegment cash flow (investment) correlations. We note that these estimates might represent a lower bound for the coinsurance effect on firm value because our proxies are limited to segment data and do not capture coinsurance among different product lines or geographic areas. 21

23 5.3. Robustness Tests Excluding Single-segment Firms To investigate the possibility that our results may be spuriously driven by differences between single- and multi-segment firms, we perform our main analysis using multi-segment firms only. The results, reported in Table 6, are qualitatively and statistically similar to those reported in Models 5 and 6 of Table 3. In particular, the coefficient estimates on cross-segment cash flow and investment correlations are both positive and significant at the 1% level. Alternative Measures of Coinsurance Our main coinsurance proxy is constructed using segment membership in 2-digit SIC industries, and we estimate idiosyncratic industry cash flows and investments using a singlefactor market model. We now check whether our results are robust to using: 1) more refined industry definitions, 2) a multi-factor (as opposed to a single-factor market) model to estimate idiosyncratic industry cash flows and investment, and 3) firm-specific segment data (as opposed to industry-level data) to compute cross-segment cash flow and investment correlations. First, we repeat our main analysis using three alternative coinsurance measures based on the following industry definitions: Fama and French (1997) 48 industries ( FF industries ), 3- digit SIC codes ( 3-digit SIC industries ), and the narrowest SIC grouping that includes at least five single-segment firms with at least $20 million in sales over the last ten years ( Narrowest SIC industries ). The results are presented in Panel A of Table 7. The coefficient estimates on cross-segment cash flow and investment correlations are positive and significant in all regressions, with the exception of the 3-digit SIC industries regression where the coefficient estimate on cash flow correlations is positive but insignificant. The weak statistical significance appears to be driven by some 3-digit SIC industries having very few firms in some years, 22

24 resulting in relatively noisy industry cash flows. This problem is alleviated when we adopt the narrowest SIC industry approach, which imposes a minimum of five single-segment firms. Next, we investigate whether our results are robust to a multi-factor model that includes two additional Fama and French (1995) factors size and book-to-market for estimating idiosyncratic industry cash flow and investment series. The results based on this alternative coinsurance measure ( FF multi-factor earnings ), reported in the first two columns of Panel B of Table 7, are qualitatively and statistically similar to those reported in Table 3. Finally, we perform our main analysis using two alternative coinsurance measures based on firm-specific segment cash flow and investment data. In order to provide a reasonable period for estimating cross-segment correlations, the analysis is performed using a subset of firms whose segment structures remain unchanged for 5 or 7 years ( 5-year sample and 7-year sample, respectively). The results are reported in the last four columns of Panel B of Table 7. As expected, a significant drawback of this approach is a small sample size 13,191 (9,847) firm-year observations in the 5-year (7-year) sample compared to 29,080 firm-year observations in our main analysis. Despite the substantial drop in sample size, the estimated coefficients on cross-segment correlations remain positive and statistically significant, with magnitudes similar to those reported in Table 3. Analyst Forecast Errors A potential limitation of implied cost of equity measures is measurement errors arising from biases in analyst forecasts. We use two approaches to address this concern. First, we control for one- and two-year-ahead unexpected and expected forecast errors in our main regression models. In particular, we follow Ogneva, Subramanyam, and Raghunandan (2007) and estimate expected forecast errors using the prediction model in Liu and Su (2005). Our parsimonious 23

25 version of the model includes the following predictors that proxy for systematic biases in analyst forecasts: (1) past stock returns, (2) recent analyst earnings forecast revisions, and variables related to overreaction to past information, namely, (3) forward earnings-to-price ratios, (4) longterm growth forecasts, and (5) investments in property, plant, and equipment. Estimation of the predicted forecast error is performed separately for one- and two-year-ahead forecast errors. Unexpected forecast errors are computed as the difference between realized errors and their predicted component. Because one- and two-year-ahead expected errors are highly collinear, we use the average expected errors over the two years as the control measure. The results, reported in Panel A of Table 8, continue to show a positive and significant coefficient on cross-segment cash flow and investment correlations, suggesting that our main findings are unlikely driven by systematic differences in analyst forecast biases between single- and multi-segment firms. Second, Easton and Monahan (2006) find that the reliability of implied cost of equity estimates increases as analyst forecast accuracy improves. Accordingly, we partition our sample into terciles using absolute forecast errors in one-year-ahead earnings and estimate cost of capital regressions within each subsample. The results are reported in Panel B of Table 8. The coinsurance effect is weakest in the subsample with high absolute forecast errors. These results suggest that our findings are unlikely driven by measurement errors in the implied cost of equity estimates that are induced by biased forecasts. Rather, our results are weakened by them. Alternative Measures of Implied Cost of Equity We also repeat our main analysis using two alternative implied cost of equity measures, CT (Claus and Thomas (2001)) and PEG (Easton (2004)), which differ from the Gebhardt, Lee and Swaminathan (2001) measure (GLS) used in our main analysis in terms of the assumptions regarding terminal value computation and the form of the valuation model. (See the Appendix 24

26 for details on both measures estimation). The results based on these two alternative implied cost of equity measures are reported in Table 9. Consistent with our earlier findings, the coefficient estimates on cross-segment cash flow and investment correlations are positive and significant. Alternative Measures of Cost of Equity In this subsection, we perform our main analysis using three alternative proxies for cost of equity that do not rely on implied cost of equity estimations and hence analyst forecasts: 1) expected returns from the Fama-French three-factor model (hereafter, FF), 2) realized annual buy-and-hold returns, and 3) earnings yield. The first two measures have been widely used as proxies for expected returns in the literature. 8 The last measure, earnings yield (E/P), while admittedly a crude proxy for cost of equity, provides a simple robustness check; it is computed as the ratio of net income to beginning of the year market value of equity. 9 Because earnings yield also contains information about growth opportunities, we include a second measure, E/P growth-adjusted, that incorporates the effect of earnings growth; it is calculated as the sum of earnings yield and growth in net income over the previous year. Excess FF (E/P and E/P growth-adjusted) is the logarithm of the ratio of the firm s FF (E/P and E/P growth-adjusted) to its imputed FF (E/P and E/P growth-adjusted). Excess realized return is a simple difference between the firm s realized return and its imputed realized return. The derivation of the corresponding imputed values is similar to that of our main cost of equity measure (see Section 3.1 for details). 8 To calculate FF expected returns, we estimate factor loadings using 24 months of prior excess returns, multiply the loadings with corresponding historical risk premiums, and add the yield on the 10-year Treasury note. We exclude observations with negative FF cost of equity estimates from the analysis (about 8% of our sample) Realized returns are 12-month buy-and-hold returns starting in June of year t+1 (see Figure 1 for timing convention). 9 Earnings yield is calculated only for observations with positive net income. 25

27 We repeat our main analysis using these three alternative excess cost of equity proxies alongside excess GLS implied cost of equity as a benchmark. The results are reported in Table 10. In the FF and realized return regression models, we include the same set of control variables as in our main regressions, with the exception of forecast dispersion and long-term growth forecast because these two variables are meant to control for measurement error when implied cost of capital measures are used as the dependent variable. For the same reason, we also exclude forecast dispersion in the E/P and E/P growth-adjusted regressions, but include long-term growth forecast to control for expected earnings growth in the E/P model. With the exception of realized returns, all coefficient estimates on cross-segment cash flow and investment correlations are significantly positive, with magnitudes comparable to those in the benchmark specifications using excess GLS implied cost of equity. While these results show that our coinsurance findings are not robust to using realized returns, the other proxies that are less susceptible to cash flow shocks (in particular, FF expected returns) provide further support for our ex ante approach to measuring expected returns. As pointed out by Elton (1999), ex post realized returns can be noisy proxies for ex ante expected returns and may lead to biased coefficient estimates in finite samples due to contamination by cash flow shocks. Several recent papers (Campello, Chen, and Zhang (2008) and Chava and Purnanandam (2010)) show that these biases can be substantial, and our analysis bears out a similar conclusion. Excess Cost of Debt The model outlined in Section 2.1 predicts coinsurance effects for both equity and debt. The results for excess GLS implied cost of equity in Table 10 show that coinsurance benefits are recognized by equityholders. In this subsection, we examine whether they are also recognized by debtholders. 26

Corporate Diversification and the Cost of Capital

Corporate Diversification and the Cost of Capital THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXVIII, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2013 Corporate Diversification and the Cost of Capital REBECCA N. HANN, MARIA OGNEVA, and OGUZHAN OZBAS ABSTRACT We examine whether organizational form

More information

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage Jin-Chuan Duan * and Yun Li (First draft: April 12, 2006) (This version: May 16, 2006) Abstract This paper identifies a key cause for the documented diversification

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings

Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings Zhenxu Tong University of Exeter* Paper Number: 08/03 First Draft: June 2007 This Draft: February 2008 Abstract This paper studies how firm

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Properties of implied cost of capital using analysts forecasts

Properties of implied cost of capital using analysts forecasts Article Properties of implied cost of capital using analysts forecasts Australian Journal of Management 36(2) 125 149 The Author(s) 2011 Reprints and permission: sagepub. co.uk/journalspermissions.nav

More information

ECCE Research Note 06-01: CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND THE COST OF EQUITY CAPITAL: EVIDENCE FROM GMI S GOVERNANCE RATING

ECCE Research Note 06-01: CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND THE COST OF EQUITY CAPITAL: EVIDENCE FROM GMI S GOVERNANCE RATING ECCE Research Note 06-01: CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND THE COST OF EQUITY CAPITAL: EVIDENCE FROM GMI S GOVERNANCE RATING by Jeroen Derwall and Patrick Verwijmeren Corporate Governance and the Cost of Equity

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect?

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? Yi Jiang Department of Finance, California State University, Fullerton SGMH 5160, Fullerton, CA 92831 (657)278-4363 yjiang@fullerton.edu Yiming Qian

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Do All Diversified Firms Hold Less Cash? The International Evidence 1. Christina Atanasova. and. Ming Li. September, 2015

Do All Diversified Firms Hold Less Cash? The International Evidence 1. Christina Atanasova. and. Ming Li. September, 2015 Do All Diversified Firms Hold Less Cash? The International Evidence 1 by Christina Atanasova and Ming Li September, 2015 Abstract: We examine the relationship between corporate diversification and cash

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: March 2013 First draft: October 2010 Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu. I am grateful

More information

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998) 219 239 Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Anup Agrawal*, Charles R. Knoeber College of Management, North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC

More information

The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings

The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings Soohyung Kim University of Wisconsin La Crosse Hoontaek Seo Niagara University Daniel L. Tompkins Niagara University This

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection of Stock Returns Cameron Truong Monash University, Melbourne, Australia February 2015 Abstract We document a significant positive relation

More information

What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium?

What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium? What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium? Hae mi Choi Loyola University Chicago This study investigates what drives the earnings announcement premium. Prior studies have offered various explanations

More information

Corporate Diversification and Overinvestment: Evidence from Asset Write-Offs*

Corporate Diversification and Overinvestment: Evidence from Asset Write-Offs* Corporate Diversification and Overinvestment: Evidence from Asset Write-Offs* Gil Sadka and Yuan Zhang November 10, 2008 Preliminary and incomplete Please do not circulate Abstract This paper documents

More information

Dissecting Conglomerates

Dissecting Conglomerates Dissecting Conglomerates November 18, 2017 ABSTRACT We develop a new method to estimate Tobin s qs of conglomerate divisions without relying on standalone firms. Divisional qs differ considerably from

More information

DOES INFORMATION ASYMMETRY EXPLAIN THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT? Abstract

DOES INFORMATION ASYMMETRY EXPLAIN THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT? Abstract The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXVII, No. 2 Pages 235 249 Summer 2004 DOES INFORMATION ASYMMETRY EXPLAIN THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT? Ronald W. Best and Charles W. Hodges State University of West

More information

Core CFO and Future Performance. Abstract

Core CFO and Future Performance. Abstract Core CFO and Future Performance Rodrigo S. Verdi Sloan School of Management Massachusetts Institute of Technology 50 Memorial Drive E52-403A Cambridge, MA 02142 rverdi@mit.edu Abstract This paper investigates

More information

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes *

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes * Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes * E. Han Kim and Paige Ouimet This appendix contains 10 tables reporting estimation results mentioned in the paper but not

More information

Excess Value and Restructurings by Diversified Firms

Excess Value and Restructurings by Diversified Firms Excess Value and Restructurings by Diversified Firms Gayané Hovakimian Fordham University Schools of Business 1790 Broadway, 13 th floor New York, NY10019 Tel.: (212)-636-7021 E-mail: hovakimian@fordham.edu

More information

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LVI, NO. 6 DEC. 2001 Dividend Changes and Future Profitability DORON NISSIM and AMIR ZIV* ABSTRACT We investigate the relation between dividend changes and future profitability,

More information

Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? 1. Additional robustness checks

Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? 1. Additional robustness checks Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? This internet appendix provides robustness tests and supplemental analyses to the main results presented in Does Banking Competition Affect

More information

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 6 Number 2 2012 AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University

More information

Conglomerates on the rise again? The worldwide impact of the financial crisis on the diversification discount

Conglomerates on the rise again? The worldwide impact of the financial crisis on the diversification discount Conglomerates on the rise again? The worldwide impact of the 2008-2009 financial crisis on the diversification discount Christin Rudolph l and Bernhard Schwetzler HHL Leipzig Graduate School of Management,

More information

Analysts and Anomalies ψ

Analysts and Anomalies ψ Analysts and Anomalies ψ Joseph Engelberg R. David McLean and Jeffrey Pontiff October 25, 2016 Abstract Forecasted returns based on analysts price targets are highest (lowest) among the stocks that anomalies

More information

The Impact of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX) on the Cost of Equity Capital of S&P Firms

The Impact of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX) on the Cost of Equity Capital of S&P Firms The Impact of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX) on the Cost of Equity Capital of S&P Firms Sheryl-Ann K. Stephen Butler University Pieter J. de Jong University of North Florida This study examines the impact

More information

A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968): Comparative Analysis of China and the US *

A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968): Comparative Analysis of China and the US * DOI 10.7603/s40570-014-0007-1 66 2014 年 6 月第 16 卷第 2 期 中国会计与财务研究 C h i n a A c c o u n t i n g a n d F i n a n c e R e v i e w Volume 16, Number 2 June 2014 A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968):

More information

Dissecting Conglomerates

Dissecting Conglomerates Dissecting Conglomerates Oliver Boguth, Ran Duchin, and Mikhail Simutin September 1, 2017 ABSTRACT We develop a new method to study internal capital allocation in conglomerates by calculating direct estimates

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Does Information Risk Really Matter? An Analysis of the Determinants and Economic Consequences of Financial Reporting Quality

Does Information Risk Really Matter? An Analysis of the Determinants and Economic Consequences of Financial Reporting Quality Does Information Risk Really Matter? An Analysis of the Determinants and Economic Consequences of Financial Reporting Quality Daniel A. Cohen a* a New York University Abstract Controlling for firm-specific

More information

A New Look at the Fama-French-Model: Evidence based on Expected Returns

A New Look at the Fama-French-Model: Evidence based on Expected Returns A New Look at the Fama-French-Model: Evidence based on Expected Returns Matthias Hanauer, Christoph Jäckel, Christoph Kaserer Working Paper, April 19, 2013 Abstract We test the Fama-French three-factor

More information

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models INTERNET APPENDIX 1. Logit and Linear Probability Models Table 1 Leverage and the Likelihood of a Union Strike (Logit Models) This table presents estimation results of logit models of union strikes during

More information

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly Online Appendix Section I provides details of the calculation of the variables used in the paper. Section II examines the robustness of the beta anomaly.

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

Why Does Global Diversification Still Make Sense? A Cross-Firm Analysis of the Risk and Value of Diversified Firms

Why Does Global Diversification Still Make Sense? A Cross-Firm Analysis of the Risk and Value of Diversified Firms Why Does Global Diversification Still Make Sense? A Cross-Firm Analysis of the Risk and Value of Diversified Firms Diego Escobari escobarida@utpa.edu The University of Texas Pan American Mohammad J. Nejad*

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

Positive Correlation between Systematic and Idiosyncratic Volatilities in Korean Stock Return *

Positive Correlation between Systematic and Idiosyncratic Volatilities in Korean Stock Return * Seoul Journal of Business Volume 24, Number 1 (June 2018) Positive Correlation between Systematic and Idiosyncratic Volatilities in Korean Stock Return * KYU-HO BAE **1) Seoul National University Seoul,

More information

Dissecting Conglomerates

Dissecting Conglomerates Dissecting Conglomerates Oliver Boguth, Ran Duchin, and Mikhail Simutin April 6, 2016 ABSTRACT We develop a method to calculate valuation multiples of conglomerate divisions that does not rely on standalone

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

The Bright Side of Corporate Diversification:

The Bright Side of Corporate Diversification: The Bright Side of Corporate Diversification: Evidence from Policy Uncertainty Brian Clark Lally School of Management, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute Troy, NY 12180 clarkb2@rpi.edu Bill B. Francis Lally

More information

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation Tao Wang Queens College and the Graduate Center of the City University of New York Abstract Stock return volatilities are related to firms' financial

More information

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less?

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Jia Chen, Kewei Hou, and René M. Stulz* January 2015 Abstract Using theories from the behavioral finance literature to predict that investors are attracted to

More information

The Hedging Benefits of Industrial and Global Diversification: Evidence from Economic Downturns

The Hedging Benefits of Industrial and Global Diversification: Evidence from Economic Downturns The Hedging Benefits of Industrial and Global Diversification: Evidence from Economic Downturns Yixin Liu University of New Hampshire Peter T. Paul College of Business and Economics 10 Garrison Avenue

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor In this online appendix, we provide a comparative static analysis of the theoretical model as well as further robustness checks on the trend factor.

More information

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time,

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, 1. Introduction Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, many diversified firms have become more focused by divesting assets. 2 Some firms become more

More information

Do Anomalies Exist Ex Ante?*

Do Anomalies Exist Ex Ante?* Review of Finance (2014) 18: pp. 843 875 doi:10.1093/rof/rft026 Advance Access publication: July 19, 2013 Do Anomalies Exist Ex Ante?* YUE TANG 1, JIN (GINGER) WU 2 and LU ZHANG 3 1 University of Florida;

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ASSET LIQUIDITY AND THE COST OF CAPITAL. Hernán Ortiz-Molina Gordon M. Phillips

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ASSET LIQUIDITY AND THE COST OF CAPITAL. Hernán Ortiz-Molina Gordon M. Phillips NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ASSET LIQUIDITY AND THE COST OF CAPITAL Hernán Ortiz-Molina Gordon M. Phillips Working Paper 15992 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15992 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050

More information

Can the Source of Cash Accumulation Alter the Agency Problem of Excess Cash Holdings? Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions ABSTRACT

Can the Source of Cash Accumulation Alter the Agency Problem of Excess Cash Holdings? Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions ABSTRACT Can the Source of Cash Accumulation Alter the Agency Problem of Excess Cash Holdings? Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions ABSTRACT This study argues that the source of cash accumulation can distinguish

More information

The Long-Run Equity Risk Premium

The Long-Run Equity Risk Premium The Long-Run Equity Risk Premium John R. Graham, Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, Durham, NC 27708, USA Campbell R. Harvey * Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, Durham, NC 27708, USA National

More information

Steve Monahan. Discussion of Using earnings forecasts to simultaneously estimate firm-specific cost of equity and long-term growth

Steve Monahan. Discussion of Using earnings forecasts to simultaneously estimate firm-specific cost of equity and long-term growth Steve Monahan Discussion of Using earnings forecasts to simultaneously estimate firm-specific cost of equity and long-term growth E 0 [r] and E 0 [g] are Important Businesses are institutional arrangements

More information

The Implied Cost of Capital: A New Approach

The Implied Cost of Capital: A New Approach The Implied Cost of Capital: A New Approach Kewei Hou, Mathijs A. van Dijk, and Yinglei Zhang * May 2010 Abstract We propose a new approach to estimate the implied cost of capital (ICC). Our approach is

More information

The Implied Equity Duration - Empirical Evidence for Explaining the Value Premium

The Implied Equity Duration - Empirical Evidence for Explaining the Value Premium The Implied Equity Duration - Empirical Evidence for Explaining the Value Premium This version: April 16, 2010 (preliminary) Abstract In this empirical paper, we demonstrate that the observed value premium

More information

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Yuhang Xing Rice University This version: July 25, 2006 1 I thank Andrew Ang, Geert Bekaert, John Donaldson, and Maria Vassalou

More information

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Anup Agrawal Culverhouse College of Business University of Alabama Tuscaloosa, AL 35487-0224 Jeffrey F. Jaffe Department

More information

ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT AND THE COST OF CAPITAL

ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT AND THE COST OF CAPITAL 2016 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol. 85, No. 1, 159 201 (2018). DOI: 10.1111/jori.12152 ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT AND THE COST OF CAPITAL Thomas R. Berry-St olzle Jianren Xu ABSTRACT Enterprise

More information

1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 ),509$/8(5,6.$1'*52: ,7,(6. +\XQ+DQ6KLQ 5HQp06WXO] :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ

1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 ),509$/8(5,6.$1'*52: ,7,(6. +\XQ+DQ6KLQ 5HQp06WXO] :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ 1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 ),509$/8(5,6.$1'*52:7+23325781,7,(6 +\XQ+DQ6KLQ 5HQp06WXO] :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ 1$7,21$/%85($82)(&2120,&5(6($5&+ 0DVVDFKXVHWWV$YHQXH &DPEULGJH0$ -XO\ :HDUHJUDWHIXOIRUXVHIXOFRPPHQWVIURP*HQH)DPD$QGUHZ.DURO\LDQGSDUWLFLSDQWVDWVHPLQDUVDW

More information

Do Managers Learn from Short Sellers?

Do Managers Learn from Short Sellers? Do Managers Learn from Short Sellers? Liang Xu * This version: September 2016 Abstract This paper investigates whether short selling activities affect corporate decisions through an information channel.

More information

Costly External Finance, Corporate Investment, and the Subprime Mortgage Credit Crisis

Costly External Finance, Corporate Investment, and the Subprime Mortgage Credit Crisis Costly External Finance, Corporate Investment, and the Subprime Mortgage Credit Crisis by Ran Duchin*, Oguzhan Ozbas**, and Berk A. Sensoy*** First draft: October 15, 2008 This draft: August 28, 2009 Forthcoming,

More information

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract In this paper we study the market reaction to capital expenditure announcements in the backdrop

More information

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009 Long Chen Washington University in St. Louis Fresh Momentum Engin Kose Washington University in St. Louis First version: October 2009 Ohad Kadan Washington University in St. Louis Abstract We demonstrate

More information

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Appendices A A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Given the structure of venture capital financing just described, the potential mechanisms by which shocks might propagate across companies in

More information

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva* The Role of Credit Ratings in the Dynamic Tradeoff Model Viktoriya Staneva* This study examines what costs and benefits of debt are most important to the determination of the optimal capital structure.

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks.

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks. Working Paper 2009-WP-04 May 2009 Performance of Debt Free Firms Tarek Zaher Abstract: This paper compares the performance of portfolios of debt free firms to comparable portfolios of leveraged firms.

More information

Price and Earnings Momentum: An Explanation Using Return Decomposition

Price and Earnings Momentum: An Explanation Using Return Decomposition Price and Earnings Momentum: An Explanation Using Return Decomposition Qinghao Mao Department of Finance Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Clear Water Bay, Kowloon, Hong Kong Email:mikemqh@ust.hk

More information

The Dynamics of Diversification Discount SEOUNGPIL AHN*

The Dynamics of Diversification Discount SEOUNGPIL AHN* The Dynamics of Diversification Discount SEOUNGPIL AHN* NUS Business School National University of Singapore Singapore 117592 Tel: (65) 6516-4555 e-mail: bizsa@nus.edu.sg Current version: June 2007 Preliminary

More information

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options Joshua D. Anderson jdanders@mit.edu (617) 253-7974 John E. Core* jcore@mit.edu (617) 715-4819 Abstract We measure

More information

Internet Appendix to Leverage Constraints and Asset Prices: Insights from Mutual Fund Risk Taking

Internet Appendix to Leverage Constraints and Asset Prices: Insights from Mutual Fund Risk Taking Internet Appendix to Leverage Constraints and Asset Prices: Insights from Mutual Fund Risk Taking In this Internet Appendix, we provide further discussion and additional empirical results to evaluate robustness

More information

Corporate Liquidity. Amy Dittmar Indiana University. Jan Mahrt-Smith London Business School. Henri Servaes London Business School and CEPR

Corporate Liquidity. Amy Dittmar Indiana University. Jan Mahrt-Smith London Business School. Henri Servaes London Business School and CEPR Corporate Liquidity Amy Dittmar Indiana University Jan Mahrt-Smith London Business School Henri Servaes London Business School and CEPR This Draft: May 2002 We are grateful to João Cocco, David Goldreich,

More information

This version: October 2006

This version: October 2006 Do Controlling Shareholders Expropriation Incentives Derive a Link between Corporate Governance and Firm Value? Evidence from the Aftermath of Korean Financial Crisis Kee-Hong Bae a, Jae-Seung Baek b,

More information

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance.

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. RESEARCH STATEMENT Heather Tookes, May 2013 OVERVIEW My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. Much of my work focuses on understanding the ways in which capital market

More information

When do banks listen to their analysts? Evidence from mergers and acquisitions

When do banks listen to their analysts? Evidence from mergers and acquisitions When do banks listen to their analysts? Evidence from mergers and acquisitions David Haushalter Penn State University E-mail: gdh12@psu.edu Phone: (814) 865-7969 Michelle Lowry Penn State University E-mail:

More information

Debt Maturity and the Cost of Bank Loans

Debt Maturity and the Cost of Bank Loans Debt Maturity and the Cost of Bank Loans Chih-Wei Wang a, Wan-Chien Chiu b*, and Tao-Hsien Dolly King c June 2016 Abstract We examine the extent to which a firm s debt maturity structure affects borrowing

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners

Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners A Model: Who Gains and Who Loses When Divergence-of-Opinion is Resolved? In the baseline model, the pessimist s gain or loss is equal to her shorting demand times

More information

Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns

Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns Wei Huang, Qianqiu Liu, S.Ghon Rhee and Liang Zhang Shidler College of Business University of Hawaii at Manoa 2404 Maile Way Honolulu, Hawaii,

More information

Disclosure Quality and the Excess Value of Diversification

Disclosure Quality and the Excess Value of Diversification Disclosure Quality and the Excess Value of Diversification Daniel A. Bens daniel.bens@gsb.uchicago.edu and Steven J. Monahan steven.monahan@gsb.uchicago.edu University of Chicago Graduate School of Business

More information

How Does Corporate Governance Affect the Implied Cost of Equity Capital? Evidence from REITs

How Does Corporate Governance Affect the Implied Cost of Equity Capital? Evidence from REITs How Does Corporate Governance Affect the Implied Cost of Equity Capital? Evidence from REITs Tom Thibodeau Leeds School of Business Ying Xiao* Mount Saint Mary College University of Colorado, Boulder,

More information

RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FIRM S PE RATIO AND EARNINGS GROWTH RATE

RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FIRM S PE RATIO AND EARNINGS GROWTH RATE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FIRM S PE RATIO AND EARNINGS GROWTH RATE Yuanlong He, Department of Accounting, Economics, Finance, and Management Information Systems, The School of Business Administration and Economics,

More information

Valuation of tax expense

Valuation of tax expense Valuation of tax expense Jacob Thomas Yale University School of Management (203) 432-5977 jake.thomas@yale.edu Frank Zhang Yale University School of Management (203) 432-7938 frank.zhang@yale.edu August

More information

Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix

Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix Yelena Larkin, Mark T. Leary, and Roni Michaely April 2016 Table I.A-I In table I.A-I we perform a simple non-parametric analysis

More information

Cost of Capital and Liquidity of Foreign Private Issuers Exempted From Filing with the SEC: Information Risk Effect or Earnings Quality Effect?

Cost of Capital and Liquidity of Foreign Private Issuers Exempted From Filing with the SEC: Information Risk Effect or Earnings Quality Effect? Cost of Capital and Liquidity of Foreign Private Issuers Exempted From Filing with the SEC: Information Risk Effect or Earnings Quality Effect? Giorgio Gotti University of Texas at El Paso ggotti@utep.edu

More information

Analyst Long-term Growth Forecasts, Accounting Fundamentals, and Stock Returns

Analyst Long-term Growth Forecasts, Accounting Fundamentals, and Stock Returns Analyst Long-term Growth Forecasts, Accounting Fundamentals, and Stock Returns Working Paper Draft Date: 8/05/2016 Abstract: We decompose consensus analyst long-term growth forecasts into a hard growth

More information

Style Timing with Insiders

Style Timing with Insiders Volume 66 Number 4 2010 CFA Institute Style Timing with Insiders Heather S. Knewtson, Richard W. Sias, and David A. Whidbee Aggregate demand by insiders predicts time-series variation in the value premium.

More information

Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns

Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns Thanos Verousis a and Nikolaos Voukelatos b a Newcastle University Business School, Newcastle University b Kent Business School, University of Kent Abstract

More information

Asubstantial portion of the academic

Asubstantial portion of the academic The Decline of Informed Trading in the Equity and Options Markets Charles Cao, David Gempesaw, and Timothy Simin Charles Cao is the Smeal Chair Professor of Finance in the Smeal College of Business at

More information

Internal Capital Allocation and Firm Performance

Internal Capital Allocation and Firm Performance Internal Capital Allocation and Firm Performance Ilan Guedj, Jennifer Huang, and Johan Sulaeman June 2009 Abstract Do conglomerate firms have the ability to allocate resources efficiently across business

More information

Local Culture and Dividends

Local Culture and Dividends Local Culture and Dividends Erdem Ucar I empirically investigate whether geographical variations in local culture, as proxied by local religion, affect dividend demand and corporate dividend policy for

More information

Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty?

Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty? Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty? Alexander Barinov Terry College of Business University of Georgia E-mail: abarinov@terry.uga.edu http://abarinov.myweb.uga.edu/ This version: July 2009 Abstract The

More information

University of California Berkeley

University of California Berkeley University of California Berkeley A Comment on The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns : The Statistical Significance of FVIX is Driven by a Single Outlier Robert M. Anderson Stephen W. Bianchi

More information

Shareholder-Level Capitalization of Dividend Taxes: Additional Evidence from Earnings Announcement Period Returns

Shareholder-Level Capitalization of Dividend Taxes: Additional Evidence from Earnings Announcement Period Returns Shareholder-Level Capitalization of Dividend Taxes: Additional Evidence from Earnings Announcement Period Returns John D. Schatzberg * University of New Mexico Craig G. White University of New Mexico Robert

More information

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? *

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Thomas Moeller Neeley School of Business Texas Christian University Abstract In a large sample of public-public acquisitions, target

More information

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Abstract Several previous studies show that consensus analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts are excessively influenced by past firm

More information

Management Earnings Forecasts and Value of Analyst Forecast Revisions

Management Earnings Forecasts and Value of Analyst Forecast Revisions Management Earnings Forecasts and Value of Analyst Forecast Revisions YONGTAE KIM* Leavey School of Business Santa Clara University Santa Clara, CA 95053, USA y1kim@scu.edu MINSUP SONG Sogang Business

More information