The WACC Fallacy: The Real Effects of Using a Unique Discount Rate 1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The WACC Fallacy: The Real Effects of Using a Unique Discount Rate 1"

Transcription

1 The WACC Fallacy: The Real Effects of Using a Unique Discount Rate 1 Philipp Krüger Geneva Finance Research Institute - Université de Genève Augustin Landier Toulouse School of Economics David Thesmar HEC Paris and CEPR December 2010 Preliminary Version Abstract We document investment distortions induced by the use of a single discount rate within firms. According to textbook capital budgeting, firms should value any project using a discount rate determined by the risk characteristics of the project. If they use a unique company-wide discount rate, such as the weighted average cost of capital (WACC), they overinvest (resp. underinvest) in divisions with a market beta higher (resp. lower) than the firm s core industry beta. We directly test this consequence of the WACC fallacy and establish a robust and significant positive relationship between division-level investment and the spread between the division s market beta and the firm s core industry beta. This bias is stronger when the CEO is older and for high growth divisions. It is weaker for larger divisions. We also provide evidence that bidder abnormal returns are higher in diversifying mergers and acquisitions in which the bidder s beta exceeds that of the target. 1 Corresponding Author: Philipp Krüger. philipp.krueger@unige.ch, Telephone: +41 (0) Augustin Landier, augustin.landier@tse-fr.eu, Telephone: +33 (0) David Thesmar, thesmar@hec.fr, Telephone: +33 (0) We thank Boris Vallée for excellent research assistance.

2 Ever since the seminal contribution of Modigliani and Miller (1958), a key result of corporate finance theory is that a project s cash-flows should be discounted at a rate that reflects the project s risk characteristics. Discounting cash flows at the firm s weighted average cost of capital (WACC) is therefore inappropriate if the project differs in terms of its riskiness from the rest of the firm s assets. In stark contrast, however, survey evidence suggests that performing capital-budgeting using a unique firm-level WACC is quite common. Graham and Harvey (2001) show that a large majority of firms report using a firm-wide discount rate to value a project independently of its risk characteristics. Similarly, Bierman (1993) surveys the top 100 firms of the Fortune 500 and finds that 93% of the responding firms use their firm-wide WACC to value projects and only 35% also rely on division-level discount rates. The potential distortions that firms might face if they discount projects at their firm-wide WACC are prominently underlined in standard MBA-level corporate finance text-books. Grinblatt and Titman (2002) note that the WACC of a firm is the relevant discount rate for [...] one of its projects only when the project has exactly the same risk profile as the entire firm.. Similarly, Brealey et al. (2005) explain that the weighted average formula works only for projects that are carbon copies of the rest of the firm. Such a gap between the normative formulation of the WACC method (the discount rate should be project-specific) and its implementation by practitioners (firms tend to use their firm-wide WACC for all projects) should lead to specific distortions in the investment policy of firms. This paper is an attempt to document and measure these distortions. We use business segment data to investigate whether diversified firms 1

3 rely on a firm wide WACC. In doing so, we examine whether companies are inclined to overinvest in their high-beta divisions and underinvest in their low-beta divisions. A company using a single firm-wide WACC would tend to overestimate the net present value (NPV) of a project whenever the project is riskier than the average project of the company. If companies apply the NPV principle to allocate capital across different divisions 2, they must have a tendency to overestimate the NPV of projects that are less risky than the firm average and vice versa. This, in turn, should lead to overinvestment (rep. underinvestment) in divisions that have a beta above (resp. below) the firm s average weighted beta. In line with this prediction, we show that investment in non-core divisions is robustly positively related to the difference between the cost of capital of the division and that of the most important division in the conglomerate (the core-division). We interpret these findings as evidence that firms do in fact discount investment projects from non-core divisions by relying on the core division s cost of capital. In a second step, using M&A data, we provide market-based evidence of the economic inefficiencies induced by the fallacy of evaluating projects using a unique company wide hurdle rate. We study a sample of diversifying mergers and acquisitions in order to examine whether and how differences in bidder and target asset betas affect abnormal bidder returns. We show that abnormal announcement returns of such diversifying transactions are significantly higher if the target company s asset beta falls short of that of the 2 Survey evidence of CEOs and CFOs presented in Graham et al. (2010) suggests that the NPV ranking is the predominant principle governing capital budgeting decisions. 2

4 acquirer. In other words, abnormal announcement returns are significantly higher whenever the acquirer is likely to be undervaluing the target. This finding is robust to the inclusion of a number of different control variables. Our paper is related to several streams of research in corporate finance. First, it contributes to the literature concerned with the theory and practice of capital budgeting and mergers and acquisitions. Graham and Harvey (2001) provides survey evidence regarding firms capital budgeting, capital structure and cost of capital choices. Most relevant to our study, they show that firms tend to use a firm wide risk premium instead of a project specific one when evaluating new investment projects. Relying entirely on observed firm level investment behavior, our study is the first to test the direct consequences of the finding in Graham and Harvey (2001) that few firms use project specific costs of capital. More precisely, we provide evidence that the use of a single firm wide discount rate (the WACC fallacy ) does in fact have statistically and economically significant effects on capital allocation and merger decisions. Since we make the assumption that managers do rely on the NPV criterion, the present paper is also related to Graham et al. (2010). This more recent contribution takes a forensic view on capital allocation and delegation of decision making in firms and provides strong survey evidence showing that the net present value rule is still the dominant way for allocating capital across different divisions. Secondly, our paper contributes to the growing behavioral corporate finance literature. Baker et al. (2007) propose a taxonomy organizing this literature around two sets of contributions: irrational investors vs. irrational managers. The more developed irrational investors stream assumes 3

5 that arbitrage is imperfect and that rational managers, in their corporate finance decisions, exploit market mispricing. Our paper is more related to the less developed irrational managers literature. This approach assumes that, while markets are arbitrage free, managerial behavior can be influenced by psychological biases. So far, this stream of research has mostly focused on how psychological traits such as optimism and overconfidence can have distorting effects on managerial expectations about the future and investment decisions (see Malmendier and Tate (2005, 2008) or Landier and Thesmar (2009)). By contrast, far less attention has been paid to whether and how bounded rationality and resulting rule of thumbs type of behaviour can shape corporate decisions. To the best of our knowledge, the present paper is the first to consider how a simplifying heuristic (using a single company wide discount rate) can have real effects on important corporate policies such as corporate investment and mergers and acquisitions. The reason why firms use a single discount rate might result from lack of sophistication. It is actually not obvious at first sight why the firm-level cost of capital is not the relevant discount rate for all the projects of the firm. A company that benefits from a low cost of capital might feel that financing risky projects is an arbitrage opportunity. In fact, by changing the risk of the firm s cash-flows, these projects also modify the expected rate of return that the market expects from the firm (Modigliani-Miller). We find two pieces of evidence coherent with the view that the WACC fallacy is related to managerial bounded rationality: Firms managed by younger CEOs, who are more likely to have been exposed to modern capital budgeting, are less prone to overinvest in high beta divisions. Also, when a division becomes larger, the 4

6 overinvestment pattern becomes smaller, suggesting that firms cease to use a unique discount rate when the cost of doing so is higher. this evidence is in line with the view that full rationality is costly and that agents become more rational when the gains of doing so increase. A model of bounded rationality with such feature is e.g. Gabaix (2010), where agents try to avoid using too many parameters to avoid complexity costs in optimizing decisions. Finally, our paper is also related to the extensive literature on the functioning of internal capital markets (see for instance Lamont (1997); Shin and Stulz (1998)). Rajan et al. (2000); Scharfstein and Stein (2000) show that politicking within large organizations can lead to inefficient cross-subsidization between divisions: Divisions with lower investment opportunities obfuscate information about their real needs and manage to extract from management inefficiently large capital allocations at the expense of divisions with better opportunities (conglomerate socialism ). Rajan et al. (2000) show empirically that industry diversity within firms increases transfers toward divisions with below-average investment opportunities. Their proxy of investment opportunities is based on industry-level Tobin s q. Ozbas and Scharfstein (2010) show that unrelated segments of conglomerates invest less than standalone firms in high-q industries. A contribution of our paper is to show that division-level industry betas (and not simply divisions Tobin s q) are an important factor in understanding investment distortions within conglomerates. We relate this new type of capital misallocation to the use of a single discount rate, which we call the WACC fallacy. This bias might be related to the politicking argument, in that more complex, division-specific, discounting rules can potentially facilitate politicking, since divisions can advocate 5

7 through various arguments (strategic choice of industry categorization and beta evaluation techniques) that their discount rate should be lower: In other words, firms might use a unique discount rate precisely because they want to limit the scope for politicking by making rules simple and non-manipulable. The rest of the paper is organized as follows: The next section provides evidence on how division level investment in conglomerates is related to firm wide measures of the cost of capital. Section II presents the evidence on diversifying mergers and acquisitions. Finally, section III concludes. I Investment distortions within diversified firms. A. Does division level investment in non-core divisions depend on the assetbeta of the core-division? To obtain information on a firm s industrial diversification, we aggregate segment data from the Compustat Business Segment database between 1987 and 2007 by segment industries. Segment industries are defined by mapping the segment s primary four digit SIC code to its corresponding Fama and French (1997) industry category (FF48). For each year, we define a division as the bundle a firm s segments operating within the same FF48 industry. We define a conglomerate firm as a firm diversified across more than one FF48 industry, whereas standalone firms have their activities concentrated in a single industry. Table I shows descriptive statistics for all firm-level variables for both standalone and conglomerate firms. [Table I about here.] 6

8 Division sales are defined as the sum of sales of all segments composing the division. Whenever the sum of division sales exceeds or falls short of total firm sales (item12 from Compustat North America) by a margin of 5 % or more, we remove the firm-division-year observations from the sample. This is done in order to ensure consistency between the Compustat Segments and the Compustat North America databases and to reduce the potential noise induced by a firm s incorrect reporting of segment sales. For each conglomerate firm, we then identify the division with the highest level of sales and label it core-division. Conversely, divisions with sales lower than those of the core-division are refereed to as non-core divisions. Next, we construct a yearly industry-level measure of the cost of capital. We do so by regressing monthly returns of value-weighted portfolios comprised of companies belonging to the same FF48 industry on the CRSP Value Weighted Index for moving-windows of 60 months. We then unlever the estimated industry-level equity beta using the average leverage and average market value of equity observed in that industry. This procedure allows us to obtain a yearly industry-level asset beta β A i,t = E i,t E i,t + D i,t β E i,t (1), where E i,t is the mean market value of equity at fiscal year end and D i,t is mean industry book value of debt in the respective FF48 industry. At the firm level, the market value of equity is defined as (abs(item25)*item199) and the book value of debt is calculated as book assets (item6) minus common 7

9 equity (item60) and deferred taxes (item74). βi,t E is the estimated equity beta coeffcient from the moving-window regressions. In order to limit the impact of outliers, we set to mising all observations for which a firm level variable deviates from the median by more than five times the interquartile range. Note also that i indexes industries here. If diversified firms are discounting all projects at the core division s cost of capital, their willingness to invest in a non-core division belonging to industry i should depend positively on the difference between the non-core division s (βdiv,t A ) and the core division (βa DIV,t ) asset beta. If they use a weighted average cost of capital, this remains true as (βcore,t A ) is a proxy for the asset-weighted beta of the firm, (β A AV ERAGE,t ). Using (βa CORE,t ) as a determinant of the firm-wide discount rate avoids the multi-colinearity concern that arises when putting (βcore,t A ) and (βa AV ERAGE,t ) together in a regression. Thus, investment in non-core divisions should depend systematically on whether the asset risk of the respective non-core division is lower or higher than that of the core division. On the contrary, if headquarters use divisionspecific hurdle rates, the difference in industry betas should play no role in predicting investment at the division level. [Table II about here.] We calculate division-level investment as a division s capital expenditures scaled by total division assets at the previous fiscal year end. Mirroring the calculation of division sales, we obtain division assets and division capital expenditures by summing the respective variables over all firm segments be- 8

10 longing to the same FF48 industry in a given year. In table II we summarize descriptive statistics of all variables at the non-core division level. With the aim of testing whether investment of non-core divisions depends on the difference between the core and the non-core division s cost of capital, we regress investment of divisions which do not have the highest sales in the conglomerate (i.e. non-core divisions) on the difference in industrylevel asset betas between the non-core division and the core division, that is (βdiv,t A βa CORE,t ). We also control for the classical determinants of corporate investment, essentially industry-level Tobin s q computed for standalone firms, year fixed-effects and firm-level cash-flows. [Table III about here.] The results from pooled cross-sectional regressions clustered at the firm level are reported in Table III. Column (1) establishes the basic fact by showing that non-core division investment depends positively on the spread between the non-core and the core division s industry betas. The larger the spread, the higher the investment in the respective non-core division. This is precisely what would be expected if companies discount risky projects using too low discount rates. In the regression of column (1), the identified effect could be due to an omitted variable bias, since we choose a very parsimonious specification to present the basic fact. In order to address this issue, we add the main determinants of corporate investment, i.e. industry-level Tobin s q of the core and the non-core division calculated for standalone firms (Q CORE,t and Q DIV,t ), as well as Firm Cash Flow to the division investment equation in column (2). 9

11 Following Kaplan and Zingales (1997), we approximate Tobin s q at the firm level by the ratio of the market value of assets to its book value. Market value of assets is calculated as the book value of assets (item 6) plus the market value of common equity (item199*abs(item25)) at fiscal year end minus the book value of common equity (item60) and minus balance sheet deferred taxes (item74). Industry level Tobin s q is calculated as the average Tobin s q in a given FF48 industry-year. We choose industry Tobin s q in order to control for the quality of a division s investment opportunities because Tobin s q cannot be calculated at the division level due to the absence of a market price for a division s assets. Montgomery and Wernerfelt (1988) show, however, that industry-level Tobin s q does in fact explain a large fraction of the variation in firm level Tobin s q. Their evidence justifies industry-level Tobin s q as a reasonable proxy for the investment opportunities faced by a division. Firm Cash Flow is calculated as the sum of income before extraordinary items (item18) and depreciation and amortization (item14) scaled by total assets (item6). We choose to control for the investment opportunities of both the core and the non-core division in order to address the concern that asset betas are merely reflecting differences in valuation or investment opportunities between core and non-core divisions. After controlling for the main determinants of investment and potential differences in valuation, there is little economic justification for neither the spread in asset betas nor βcore,t A and β A DIV,t individually to have any explanatory power for non-core division investment. Yet, the coefficient estimate for the spread remains highly statistically significant. 10

12 Columns (3) and (4) add other potential determinants of division level investment, i.e. Division Size, Firm Size, Firm Age and a measure of Firm Focus to the specification. Firm Focus is defined as the core division s sales divided by total sales. It measures the extent to which the firm is concentrated within its core activity. Our results remain unchanged after the inclusion of these additional control variables. In unreported regressions, we also replace industry-level Tobin s q by a division level measure of investment opportunities, i.e. lagged sales growth. Again, our results remain robust in this alternative specification. In untabulated analysis, we also control for non-core division-industry fixed effects, which does not influence our results either. In column (5) we regress non-core division investment on the two elements of the spread. The results show a negative sign for the coefficient estimate for βcore,t A and a positive sign for βa DIV,t. This suggests that whenever the company has a low risk core activity (low βcore,t A ), and therefore a low hurdle rate, it is inclined to invest more strongly in non-core divisions with a higher asset risk. The fact that β A CORE,t is significant provides strong evidence that diversified companies look at divisions belonging to industries different from their core activity with the eyes of their core industry s characteristics. In terms of magnitude, the investment distortion we document is quite important. If βdiv,t A βa CORE,t = 0.5, meaning that the gap in discount rates between the division and the core-division is equal to half the market riskpremium (say 3.5%), the non-core division s investment rate would be (0.0155*0.5) percentage points higher. This is a relatively large effect taking into consideration that the median non-core division investment rate is about 11

13 4 % in our data (see table II). We also find (in unreported regressions) that the effect of the spread is stronger for highly levered companies: financial constraints seem to make companies more prone to block investment in low beta divisions. One interpretation is that financial constraints increase the hurdle rate up to a level where low beta divisions have very few projects that pass the bar. In another unreported set of regressions, we sort on the size of the company (measured by the log of assets or total enterprise value) and, consistent with evidence in Graham and Harvey (2001) that large firms are more likely to use the net present value rule in allocating capital, the impact of both β A CORE,t and the spread in asset betas turns out to be stronger for large firms. Thus, the bias we document cannot be seen as a small firm effect. Interestingly, we also find that non-core division investment in small firm is not related to the core division s beta. This is, at least to a certain extent, reconcilable with survey evidence in Graham et al. (2010), suggesting that small firms are much more likely to rely on managerial gut feeling in making capital allocation decisions. Hence, it might not be surprising, that an empirical analysis focusing on present value style allocation of capital is unable to dissect significant effects for small firms. [Figure 1 about here.] Next, we document that the effect is stronger in non-core divisions which are relatively less important with respect to the core division. To do so, we calculate the Relative Importance of a non-core division by scaling its sales by the sales of the core division. Values close to one indicate that the non-core division in question is almost as important as the core-division within the 12

14 conglomerate. By contrast, values close to zero indicate that the non-core division is negligible vis à vis the core division. Figure 1 shows a histogram of Relative Importance. We then sort non-core division investment by Relative Importance and group the observations into four quartiles. Low quartiles indicate low importance of the division with respect to the core division, whereas higher quartiles indicate that the respective non-core division is almost as important as the conglomerate s core division. [Table IV about here.] Table IV estimates specification 4 from table III for the four quartiles of relative importance. The regression results reveal that the biasing effect of using the core division s asset beta is strongest for relatively unimportant divisions (column (1) and (2)) and vanishes for those that are almost as important as the core-division (column (4)). The finding that the spread (i.e. βdiv,t A βa CORE,t ) does not play a role in explaining the investment of non-core divisions with high organizational importance (fourth quartile of Relative Importance) is particularly interesting, since it suggests that capital allocation in more important non-core divisions is determined by more traditional factors such as investment opportunities and cash flows. This idea is further substantiated by observing that a traditional determinant of investment, i.e. the non-core division s industry-level Tobin s q, becomes significant in explaining division investment for the fourth quartile, while it is not significant in explaining non-core division investment for the first and second quartiles. Taken together, this evidence suggests that the investment distortion induced 13

15 by boundedly rational managers relying on inappropriate discount rates is concentrated within divisions of low organizational importance. [Table V about here.] Table V splits the sample into four sub periods (i.e , , and ). The analysis by sub-period indicates that the investment distortion has been strongest between 1987 and 1996 (See columns (1) and (2)). Interestingly, the change in business segment reporting standards initiated by the FASB issuance of SFAS 131 in June 1997 does not seem to have an impact on our results, since our coefficients remain statistically significant also in sub-periods following the change in regulation. The magnitude of the effect we document has, however, declined recently (see column (4)). This evidence is consistent with an interpretation that capital allocation within conglomerate firms has become more elaborate over time. A potential explanation could be that financial knowledge of corporate decision makers in charge of making capital budgeting decisions has improved over time. Higher financial sophistication of managers due to MBA style education could thus have improved the quality of capital allocation decisions within conglomerate firms. B. Is the investment distortion related to observable characteristics of the executive suite? In order to give more flesh to our interpretation stressing financial education of managers, we estimate the baseline non-core division level investment regression from the previous tables on a subsample spanning from 1992 to

16 for which we observe the chief executive s (CEO) age. We expect the CEO s age to be a reasonable proxy for the age of the overall executive suite. We are able to obtain the CEO s age from the Compustat Excecucomp database for 5,868 division-firm-years. In a similar vein to the investment regressions conditioned on Relative Importance of non-core divisions, we sort on terciles of CEO Age, and estimate the specification for all three terciles. The average age of young CEOs is about 49 years (first tercile), for medium aged CEOs about 58 years and for the oldest about 69 years (third tercile). [Table VI about here] We choose to bunch observations by terciles here because of the smaller sample size. Interestingly, for relatively young CEOs (column (1)), the spread in asset betas is not significantly related to division-level investment. This finding suggests that firms in which younger CEOs and consequently younger executives (potentially holding MBA degrees) are in charge, might be less prone to the WACC fallacy. By contrast, the coefficient estimate for β A DIV,t βa CORE,t is the most statistically significant for the tercile of oldest CEOs (see column (3)). The idea that mature CEOs might not use the most adequate capital allocation tools is also eluded in Graham and Harvey (2001). The authors provide evidence that mature CEOs, in contrast to younger ones, are more likely to rely on payback methods in allocating capital. In a similar vein, our evidence is also somewhat in line with evidence in Bertrand and Schoar (2003) showing that capital expenditures in firms run by CEOs with MBA style education are on average less responsive to cash flows and more responsive to growth opportunities as embodied in Tobin s 15

17 q. Assuming that age is a reasonable proxy for MBA style education, this is precisely what we find: Firms with young CEOs are neither subject to the WACC fallacy, nor is investment strongly related to cash flow. In fact, non-core division investment turns out to be the most conform with textbook recommendations in that it is the most sensitive to investment opportunities (Q DIV,t ). By contrast, non-core divisions in companies run by old CEOs tend to be very cash flow sensitive and also negatively related to Tobin s q, suggesting that capital allocation decisions in these firms are taken differently to what would be recommended by corporate finance textbooks. [Table VII about here] In table VII we test whether these differences are statistically significant by coding two interaction terms between dummies indicating whether the CEO belongs to the second or third tercile of CEO Age. Even though the spread turns out to be significant when non-core division investment is sorted on CEO Age, the interaction terms between the binary variables for medium and high CEO age and the spread in asset betas are no longer significant. Baker et al. (2007) note that in order for irrational managers to have an impact on corporate policies, corporate governance should be somewhat limited. Analogous to the assumption of limits to arbitrage in the behavioral finance literature concerned with irrational investors, the assumption of imperfect corporate governance is required in order for irrational managers to have a lasting impact on corporate policies. In order to measure the likelihood of imperfect corporate governance, we code a binary variable indicating low CEO ownership. Low CEO ownership firms are those for which 16

18 the CEO owns less than 1% of the common equity. Low CEO ownership firms are more likely to suffer from moral hazard problems and thus to deviate from optimal investment rules. We test whether there are significant differences in terms of firms being WACC fallacious conditional on corporate governance by interacting the spread in asset betas with the High Ownership Dummy. Consistent with the argument in Baker et al. (2007), column (2) of table VII reveals that the WACC-Fallacy is less strongly pronounced in firms in which CEOs have high share ownership (t-stat -2.65). This is also in line with evidence in Ozbas and Scharfstein (2010) showing that inefficient investment in conglomerates decreases with management equity ownership. In column (3) we measure a firm s quality of corporate governance by relying on interaction terms based on terciles of the Gompers et al. (2003) (GIM) index. However, when approximating corporate governance by the GIM index, we do not reach the same conclusions. Both the spread and the interacted spread terms for medium (second tercile) and high (third tercile) of the GIM index are not significant. C. What is the relationship between misvaluation and sales growth? In this section we demonstrate that the extent of the investment distortion resulting from using a single discount rate depends strongly on the expected sales growth of the division the project belongs to. First, we use a simple example to illustrate the basic idea. Second, we study whether the documented investment distortion is in fact related to past sales growth. Assume, in the spirit of Gordon and Shapiro (1956), that an investment project in a non-core division pays a constantly growing perpetuity C. The 17

19 growth rate of the perpetuity is denoted by g, which is assumed to be lower than the cost of capital of both the core and the non-core division and best approximated by sales growth. For notational simplicity, we drop index t. If the firm uses the correct divisional cost of capital in order to value the project, the present value of the perpetuity is given by C r f + β A DIV (r m r f ) g (2) If, however, the firm s management is subject to the WACC fallacy, the value of the perpetuity would be fallaciously taken to be C r f + β A CORE (r m r f ) g (3) The extent of misvaluation, or the misevaluation factor is thus given by r f + β A CORE (r m r f ) g r f + β A DIV (r m r f ) g (4), which can be shown to be increasing in g whenever βdiv A > βa CORE. The latter condition holds for the mean of the population (see table II). Hence, we expect the investment distortion to be increasing in the non-core division s sales growth rate. 18

20 [Figure 2 about here] In figure 2, we calibrate the overvaluation factor. The plot of the overvaluation factor as a function of the sales growth rate suggests the relationship between the non-core division investment and the spread in betas is somewhat convex in sales growth. In order to test this prediction, we use a simple proxy for sales growth, i.e. lagged industry-level sales growth. We sort noncore division investment on lagged industry-level sales growth and estimate the relationship by terciles (low, medium and high growth). The results are reported in table VIII. [Table VIII about here] Non-core division level investment is most sensitive to the spread in asset betas for high growth divisions. In fact, the coefficient estimate for β A DIV,t βa CORE,t seems to be increasingly monotonic in the terciles of lagged industry sales growth. This evidence is consistent with the simple argument based on Gordon and Shapiro (1956) and the resulting calibration. In order to test whether the relationship is in fact convex in lagged industry growth, that is significantly more pronounced for divisions belonging to high growth sectors, we code an indicator variable for each tercile of lagged industry sales growth (Low, Medium and High Growth). In column (4) of table VII, we include the spread variable and two interaction terms between the indicator variables for medium and high growth divisions and the spread in asset betas. Medium and High Growth indicate whether the division belongs to the second, respectively third tercile in terms of lagged industry sales growth. The results show that while investment of medium growth non-core divisions 19

21 are not significantly more sensitive to the spread than low growth divisions (Medium Growth (βdiv,t A βa CORE,t ) is not significant), high growth divisions turn out to be significantly more sensitive to the spread than low growth divisions (t-stat 2.02 for High Growth (βdiv,t A βa CORE,t ). This evidence underlines the idea suggested by the calibration that the investment sensitivity is in fact convex in lagged sales growth. D. Robustness Checks. Table IX reports a host of robustness checks of our main finding. First, in column (1) we replace the beta of the core division with an average firm beta βav A ERAGE,t. This firm-wide average asset beta is calculated as a weighted average division asset beta, where the weights correspond to the ratio of division to total firm assets. Should firms discount future cash flows at an average firm-wide WACC, division investment should depend significantly on the average firm-wide WACC. As expected, the coefficient estimate for β A AV ERAGE,t is significantly negative. [Table IX about here.] In column (2) of the same table we run a horse race between the average firm beta and the beta of the core division by including both measures in the equation at the same time. In this specification, the average beta of the firm is no longer significant, suggesting that the average firm-wide beta is dominated by the core-division s beta. The documented investment distortion thus seems to be driven by the use of the core-division s discount rate rather than the use of an average firm-wide WACC. In column (3) we in- 20

22 clude the gap between the division-level s and the firm s overall Tobin s q. In column (4) we control for a measure of the diversity of a firm s investment opportunities, which is essentially the standard deviation of industry-level Tobin s qs normalized by firm wide q. As expected, the more diverse the firm s investment opportunities, the lower non-core division investment. Yet, the inclusion of the diversity control and the gap between the division and the firm s Tobin s q does not affect our conclusions. In column (5) of table IX we include the core division s investment rate as a control variable. This control variable also leaves the coefficient estimates for both βcore,t A and βdiv,t A unchanged. One concern might be that industry-level asset betas capture industry specific effects. In order to address this issue, we include division industryyear fixed-effects in column (6). In this regression, the identification is purely based on the comparison between divisions in the same industry, depending on whether they belong to low beta or high beta industries. The evidence on β A CORE,t in column (6) suggests that our results are driven by cross-sectional variation in β A CORE,t rather than by high WACC or low WACC industries being treated differently in conglomerates. Finally, we control for firm fixed effects (see column (7)). After controlling for firm fixed effects, we still find evidence of an investment bias towards more risky non-core divisions (significant coefficient for β A DIV,t ). By contrast, βa CORE,t is no longer significant. The non-significance of the coefficient βcore,t A is hardly surprising since little time-series variation in β A CORE,t makes identification in fixed-effects estimations difficult to achieve. 21

23 II Efficiency effects. A. Do low industry-level beta firms engage in inefficient diversifying asset acquisitions? In this section we examine whether the fallacy of looking at investment projects belonging to other industries through the eyes of a firm s core activity does in fact generate inefficiencies in terms of firm value. In doing so, we study bidder abnormal returns for a sample of diversifying mergers and acquisitions. We define diversifying mergers and acquisitions as transactions in which a bidder gains control of an asset which belongs to a FF48 industry different from its own core activity. The sample is constructed by downloading all completed transactions between 1988 and 2007 from the SDC Platinum Mergers and Acquisitions database in which both target and bidder are domestic companies. The bidder s and target s core activities are identified through the SDC variables Acquiror Primary SIC Code and Target Primary SIC Code, which are matched to their corresponding FF48 industry categories. We keep only completed mergers and acquisitions (control events), in which the bidder has gained control of at least 50 % of the common shares of the target. We include transactions that include both private and public targets. We drop all transaction announcements in which the value of the target represents less than 1 percent of the bidder s equity market value (calculated at the end of the fiscal year prior to the year of the acquisition announcement) and also drop all transactions with a disclosed deal value lower than 1 million US-$. Daily stock returns of the bidder are downloaded from CRSP for the eleven day event window surrounding the 22

24 announcement date of the deal. Finally, we obtain balance sheet data for all bidders from the Compustat North America database. In total, we identify 6,544 of these diversifying transactions between 1988 and 2007 for which the sample selection criteria are satisfied. Descriptive statistics of bidder, target and deal characteristics as well as the temporal distribution of our merger and cquisition sample are summarized in tables X and XI. [Tables X and XI about here.] In a first step, we split the sample conditional on whether the WACC of the bidder exceeds or falls short of that of the target. Assuming that bidders apply some sort of present value method in order to determine their private valuation of the target, we expect bidders from high beta industries to be more likely to undervalue targets from low beta industries. Conversely, low industry beta bidders should tend to overvalue targets from industries subject to a higher cost of capital. The fallacy of using inadequate discount rates is thus expected to have implications for bidder abnormal returns around the announcement of diversifying acquisitions as it is likely to directly affect the bidder s private valuation of the target and hence the offer price the bidder is proposing to pay for the target s assets. Whenever bidders use too high a discount rate, they are more likely to undervalue their targets and therefore more likely to propose an offer price for the target s assets below fair value. Shareholders of the bidder should thus perceive a bid from a high beta bidder for a low beta target as relatively better news, since it reduces the likelihood of overpaying for the target. Conversely, a low industry-level beta bidder should have a tendency to overvalue high beta assets. Hence, the bid 23

25 announcement from a low industry-level asset beta company for a high beta industry asset should be perceived as bad news by stock markets because the bidder is paying too much. This should lead to significantly lower abnormal returns than an otherwise equal bid from a high industry-level beta company. Taken together, we thus expect bidder abnormal returns around diversifying transactions to be significantly higher whenever the bidder s WACC is higher than that of the target. [Figure 3 about here] In figure 3, we plot the mean cumulative abnormal returns of bidders around the announcement of diversifying asset acquisitions conditional on whether the bidder s WACC is lower or higher than that of the target. Abnormal returns are calculated as market adjusted returns on the respective event day. We use the CRSP Value Weighted Index as the market benchmark. As hypothesized, the mean cumulative abnormal return between event days -5 and 1 is about 100bp lower for bids involving low beta bidders and high beta targets than for transactions involving high beta bidders and low beta targets. In order to formally test whether this difference is statistically significant, we regress both the abnormal return on the announcement day (AR(0)), as well as the seven day cumulative abnormal return surrounding the announcement (CAR(3,3)) on a dummy variable indicating whether the bidder s WACC exceeds that of the target. The results from regressions in which the abnormal return serves as the dependent variable are reported in table XII. Table XIII reports the regression results for the cumulative 24

26 abnormal return (CAR(-3,3)). [Table XII about here.] Column (1) of table XII establishes the main result by showing that bidder abnormal returns on the announcement day of transactions involving low beta bidders and high beta targets are significantly lower than transactions involving high industry-level beta bidders and low industry-level beta targets. The coefficient estimate for the dummy variable indicating whether the difference between the bidder s and the target s WACC is positive turns out to be significantly positive (t-stat of 2.95). In order to control for deals that are announced on the same day, standard errors are clustered by announcement dates. In unreported regressions we cluster standard errors by week, month and year, which does not affect our results. We also include year dummies to capture the potential impact of merger waves on announcement returns and control for the size of the transaction, which we calculate as the natural log of the deal value as disclosed by SDC. Note that the average market reactions that we document are positive. This might seem to conflict with Morck et al. (1990) who provide evidence of negative bidder returns to diversifying transactions for a sample of 329 diversifying transactions. We reconcile the conflicting evidence of positive abnormal bidder returns in our sample with the previous evidence on diversifying acquisitions by noting that a large part of the sampled transactions involves private targets. Most often, the literature shows that that bidder returns to acquisitions of private targets tend to be positive (see Betton et al. (2008) or Bradley and Sundaram (2006)). [Table XIII about here.] 25

27 Column (1) of XIII confirms the main result by showing that also the CAR(3,3) is significantly higher for high beta bidder and low beta target transactions. Even though the short run announcement returns might not capture the overall value implications of the transaction, such concerns are less of a concern for the difference in announcement returns, since the CAR from both categories is likely to be affected in the same way by these imperfections. In other words, the imperfections would be differenced away. In columns (2) to (7) of the tables XII and XIII, we control for bidder, target and deal characteristics that the literature has found to significantly influence bidder abnormal returns. As such, column (2) introduces a dummy variable which takes on the value of one whenever the industry-level Tobin s q of the bidder is higher than that of the target. Column (3) controls for whether the target is a private company. Column (4) introduces a dummy variable controlling for whether the transaction is a tender offer. In column (5), we also include a measure of the relative value of the target, which we calculate as the ratio of the deal value, as disclosed by SDC, to the bidder s equity market value at the end of the fiscal year preceding the year of the transaction. Columns (5) and (6) control for the payment method by introducing measures for whether the bidder pays for the target using cash or shares only. Column (7) controls for whether the acquirer is a conglomerate firm in the sense of having activities diversified across multiple FF48 industry categories. Finally column (8) controls for the attitude of the transaction and for whether there is a challenging bid. The coefficient estimate for the dummy variable capturing differences in the cost of capital between the target and the bidder remains highly statistically significant in all regressions, with t- 26

28 statistics ranging between 1.94 and 2.73 for the CAR(-3,3) and t-statistics going as high as 3.07 for AR(0). In unreported regressions, we remove all observations for which the CAR(-3,3) exceeds the median CAR(3,3) by 5 times the interquartile range. The coefficient estimate for (βbidder,t A βa T arget,t > 0) remains virtually unchanged in the regressions in which extreme cumulative abnormal returns are removed from the analysis, suggesting that our results are not driven by statistical outliers. B. Do low beta firms engage in larger diversifying asset acquisitions? As argued in the preceding section, relying on a wrong discount rate can affect a bidder s private valuation of a target. In this subsection we examine whether a firm s cost of capital affects the scale of firms diversifying mergers and acquisitions. We hypothesize that a bidder who is relying on too low a discount rate might engage in bigger diversifying acquisitions. We construct two yearly measures capturing the size of a bidder s diversifying transactions. The first measure (Avg. Size) relates the yearly average deal value of the targets to the bidder s equity market valuation calculated in the year preceding the transaction announcement. The second measure (Sum Size) relates the sum of all deal values in a given year to the bidder s equity market valuation. We expect the bidder s WACC to be negatively related to both of our scale measures. In other words, companies relying on low discount rates are expected, on average, to not only acquire larger assets, but also more firms. [Table XIV about here.] 27

29 In table XIV, we regress both measures on the asset beta and a number of control variables. In line with the argument that using low discount rates leads to higher private valuations of the target, both the scaled average size of the deal and the scaled total sum of deal values turn out to be significantly negatively related to the firm s industry-level asset beta. Since we include only firms that have embarked on mergers and acquisitions in our regressions, these results should be interpreted conditionally. Thus, conditional on being involved in a merger or acquisition, the size of the deal tends to be larger, the lower the firm s asset beta. This is precisely what would be expected when firms tend to overestimate the benefits from acquiring assets belonging to industries different from their core activity. III Conclusion Survey evidence suggests that many firms use a firm-wide discount rate to evaluate projects (Graham et al. (2001)). The prevalence of this WACC fallacy implies that firms tend to bias investment upwards for divisions that have a higher industry beta than the firm s core division. This paper provides a direct test of this prediction using segment-level accounting data. We find a robust positive relationship between division-level investment and the spread between its industry beta and the beta of the firm s core division. Using unrelated data on mergers and acquisitions, we also find that the acquiror s stock-price reaction to the announcement of an acquisition is lower when the target has a higher beta than the acquiror. The prevalence of the WACC fallacy among corporations seems consistent with managerial 28

30 bounded rationality. It is actually not so simple to explain to a non-finance executive why it is logically flawed for a firm to discount a risky project using its own cost of capital. We find evidence that younger CEOs (more likely to have been exposed to modern corporate finance textbooks) and divisions which are relatively important in size are less subject to the WACC fallacy. This is in line with the view that the complexity of using division-dependent discount rates might come at a cost that companies trade-off against its gains (the costs of investment distortions are higher if the division is big). The costs associated with using multiple discount rates might not be purely cognitive or computational: They might also be organizational, as the use of multiple discount rates might increase the scope for politicking and gaming of the capital budgeting process in a hierarchy, in the spirit of Rajan et al. (2000); Scharfstein and Stein (2000). 29

31 References Baker, M., Ruback, R., and Wurgler, J. (2007). Behavioral Corporate Finance. Handbook of corporate finance: Empirical corporate finance, 1: Berger, P. and Ofek, E. (1995). Diversification s effect on firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 37(1): Bertrand, M. and Schoar, A. (2003). Managing with Style: The Effect of Managers on Firm Policies. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4): Betton, S., Eckbo, B., and Thorburn, K. (2008). Corporate Takeovers. Handbook of Corporate Finance: Empirical Corporate Finance, 2(15): Bierman, J. H. (1993). Capital budgeting in 1992: a survey. Financial Management, 22(3):24. Bradley, M. and Sundaram, A. (2006). Acquisition and performance: A reassessment of the evidence. Working Paper, Fuqua School of Business, Duke University. Brealey, R., Myers, S., and Allen, F. (2005). Principles of Corporate Finance, McGraw-Hill, New York. McGraw-Hill, New-York, NY. Fama, E. and French, K. (1997). Industry costs of equity. Journal of Financial Economics, 43(2): Gabaix, X. (2010). A Sparsity-Based Model of Bounded Rationality. Working Paper, Stern School of Business, New York University. Gompers, P., Ishii, J., and Metrick, A. (2003). Corporate Governance and Equity Prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1): Gordon, M. and Shapiro, E. (1956). Capital Equipment Analysis: The Required Rate of Profit. Management Science, 3(1): Graham, J. and Harvey, C. (2001). The theory and practice of corporate finance: evidence from the field. Journal of Financial Economics, 60(2-3): Graham, J., Harvey, C., and Puri, M. (2010). Capital Allocation and Delegation of Decision-Making Authority within Firms. Working Paper, Fuqua School of Business, Duke University. 30

32 Grinblatt, M. and Titman, S. (2002). Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. McGraw-Hill, New-York, NY. Kaplan, S. and Zingales, L. (1997). Do Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities Provide Useful Measures of Financing Constraints? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1): Lamont, O. (1997). Cash Flow and Investment: Evidence from Internal Capital Markets. Journal of Finance, 52(1): Landier, A. and Thesmar, D. (2009). Financial Contracting with Optimistic Entrepreneurs. Review of Financial Studies, 22(1):117. Malmendier, U. and Tate, G. (2005). CEO Overconfidence and Corporate Investment. The Journal of Finance, 60(6): Malmendier, U. and Tate, G. (2008). Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the market s reaction. Journal of Financial Economics, 89(1): Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (1958). The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment. The American Economic Review, 48(3): Montgomery, C. and Wernerfelt, B. (1988). Diversification, Ricardian rents, and Tobin s q. The RAND Journal of Economics, 19(4): Morck, R., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1990). Do Managerial Objectives Drive Bad Acquisitions? Journal of Finance, 45(1): Ozbas, O. and Scharfstein, D. (2010). Evidence on the Dark Side of Internal Capital Markets. Review of Financial Studies, 23(2):581. Poterba, J. and Summers, L. (1995). A CEO survey of US companies time horizons and hurdle rates. Sloan Management Review, 37(1):43. Rajan, R., Servaes, H., and Zingales, L. (2000). The Cost of Diversity: The Diversification Discount and Inefficient Investment. The Journal of Finance, 55(1): Scharfstein, D. and Stein, J. (2000). The Dark Side of Internal Capital Markets: Divisional Rent-Seeking and Inefficient Investment. The Journal of Finance, 55(6): Shin, H. and Stulz, R. (1998). Are Internal Capital Markets Efficient? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(2):

33 A Appendix 32

34 Table I Firm-Level Descriptive Statistics This table reports means and standard deviations (in parentheses) of the employed firm-level variables. Variables based on data from Compustat and CRSP are observed for the period of 1987 to CEO related variables are observed from 1992 to 2007 only. Firm Cash Flow is the sum of income before extraordinary items (Compustat item18 ) and depreciation and amortization (item14 ) scaled by total assets (item6). Firm Size is the natural logarithm of the firm s total assets (data6). Firm Age is the logarithm of the current year plus one minus the year in which the firm first appeared in the Compustat North America database. Firm Investment is total firm wide capital expenditures (data128) scaled by total firm assets (item6). Leverage is long term debt (item9) scaled by total assets (item6). The Number of Divisions is obtained by grouping business segments by Fama and French (1997) industries and counting the number of different industries across which a firm is diversified in a given year. Sales are total firm sales (item12). Sales Growth is the firm s total sales growth between periods t 1 and t. Firm Focus is sales of the division with the highest level of sales (core division) divided by total firm wide sales. Q F IRM,t is the firm s Tobin s q, which is approximated by the firm s Market to Book ratio. Market value is of assets is calculated as the book value of assets (item 6) plus the market value of common equity at fiscal year end (item199*abs(item25)) minus the book value of common equity (item60) and balance sheet deferred taxes (item74). SD(Q DIV,t )/Q F IRM,t is the standard deviation of a firm s division-level Tobin s q s scaled by the firm wide Tobin s q. βav A ERAGE,t is the firm s asset weighted average asset beta, where the weights correspond to division-level assets. Division-level equity betas are obtained by regressing monthly FF48 portfolio returns on the CRSP Value Weighted Index for rolling windows of 60 months. Division-level asset betas are obtained by unlevering the yearly industry-level equity betas using the yearly industry average ratio of equity and total firm value. This ratio is calculated as the industry-year average ratio of market value of equity (abs(item25)*item199) to book value of debt (item6-item60-item74) and equity (abs(item25)*item199). All CEO related variables are obtained from Compustat Execucomp. CEO Ownership is equal to the first available of the Execucomp variable shrown excl opts pct and shrown excl opts/(10*abs(item25)). Standalone firms are firms with activities concentrated in a single FF48 industry, whereas Multi-Division firms are diversified across at least two different FF48 sectors. Standalone Firms Mean Median SD P25 P75 N Firm Cash Flow t Firm Size t Firm Age t Firm Investment t Leverage t Sales t Sales Growth t Q F IRM,t βav A ERAGE,t CEO Age CEO Share Ownership Conglomerate Firms Mean Median SD P25 P75 N Firm Cash Flow t Firm Size t Firm Age t Firm Investment t Leverage t Number of Divisions t Sales t Sales Growth t Firm Focus t Q F IRM,t SD(Q DIV,t )/Q F IRM,t βav A ERAGE,t CEO Age CEO Share Ownership

35 Table II Non-Core Division-Level Descriptive Statistics This table reports summary statistics of variables at the non-core division-level for the sample period of Non-core divisions are divisions that do not have the highest sales within the Conglomerate firm. Divisions are defined by grouping together segments operating in the same Fama and French (1997) industry category. All division-level variables are obtained by summing the respective data item from the Compustat Business Segment Database over all segments belonging to the same FF48 industry. Capx are division-level capital expenditures in period t + 1. Assets are division-level assets in period t. Division Size is the natural logarithm of division-level sales in period t. Q DIV,t is the industry-level Tobin s q of the division in period t. Q CORE,t is the industry-level Tobin s q of the firm s core division. Industry-level Tobin s q for both the core and the non-core divisions are calculated as the industry-year average Tobin s q for a sample of standalone firms from the same industry. We calculate Tobin s q as the ratio of the market value of assets (Book assets (item 6) plus the market value of common equity (item199*abs(item25)) at fiscal year end minus the book value of common equity (item60) and balance sheet deferred taxes (item74)) to the book value of assets (item6). βdiv,t A is the industry-level asset beta of the non-core division and βcore,t A is the industry level asset beta of the firm s core division. We construct the industry-level asset betas by regressing monthly returns of the FF48 industry portfolios on the CRSP Value Weighted market index for moving windows of 60 months. These industry-level equity betas are subsequently unlevered using the industry-year average ratio of market equity to total firm value. This ratio is calculated as the industry-year average ratio of market value of equity (abs(item25)*item199) to book value of debt (item6-item60-item74) and equity (abs(item25)*item199). Mean Median SD P25 P75 N Capx/Assets Divison Size t Q DIV,t Q CORE,t Q DIV,t Q CORE,t Q DIV,t Q F IRM,t βdiv,t E βcore,t E βdiv,t A βcore,t A βdiv,t A βa CORE,t Investment Core Division t Divison Sales Growth t Divison Industry-Level Sales Growth t Observations

36 Table III Non-Core Division-Level Investment Regressions Using business segment data from Compustat ( ), we construct industry-level divisions by aggregating segment data by Fama and French (1997) industries. A division is defined as the bundle of a firm s segments operating in the same FF48 industry. The regressions are run on divisions which do not have the highest sales in the conglomerate (non-core divisions). The dependent variable Capx/Assets is divisionlevel capital expenditures in period t + 1 scaled by division assets in period t. βcore A is the industry-level asset beta of the core-division (i.e. the division with the highest sales). βdiv A is the industry-level asset beta of the non-core division. Q DIV,t is the division s industry-level Tobin s q. Q CORE,t is the industry-level Tobin s q of the division with the highest sales in the conglomerate. Both are calculated for a sample of standalone firms from the same industry. Firm Cash Flow is the firm s cash flow scaled by total assets. Division Size is the logarithm of division sales and Firm Size is the log of total assets. Firm Age is the logarithm of the current year plus one minus the year in which the firm first appeared in the Compustat North America database. Firm Focus is the ratio of the firm s core division sales to total sales. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets βdiv,t A βa CORE,t (8.15) (6.85) (6.56) (6.41) β A CORE,t β A DIV,t (-4.20) (5.24) Q DIV,t (2.43) (2.28) (2.26) (1.92) Q CORE,t (-0.78) (-1.44) (-1.38) (-1.59) Firm Cash Flow t (12.05) (11.33) (10.98) (10.99) Divison Size t (2.64) (3.16) (3.08) Firm Size t (-1.01) (-1.26) (-1.14) Firm Age t (-1.54) (-1.51) (-1.52) Firm Focus t (1.62) (1.65) Observations R All regressions include year fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. Standard errors clustered at the firm level. p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p <

37 Figure 1. Distribution of the Relative Importance of Non-Core Divisions. Relative importance is calculated as non-core division-level sales scaled by the sales of the core division. Values close to one indicate that the non-core division is almost as important as the core division within the conglomerate, whereas values close to zero indicate that the non-core division is not important with respect to the core division. 36

38 Table IV Non-Core Division Level Investment Regressions by Relative Importance In this table, the non-core division level investment regression is conditioned on the division s organizational importance. Relative importance is calculated as non core-division sales scaled by the core division s sales. The dependent variable Capx/Assets (division-level capital expenditures in period t + 1 scaled by division assets in period t) is sorted by quartiles of Relative Importance. The first column shows the results for the first quartile of Relative Importance. Non-core divisions included in the first quartile play a subordinate role in the conglomerate. Column 4 shows the results for non-core divisions that have high organizational importance within the conglomerate firm, in the sense of having sales almost as high as the core division. βcore A is the industry-level asset beta of the core-division (i.e. the division with the highest sales). βdiv A is the industry-level asset beta of the non-core division. Q DIV,t is the division s industry-level Tobin s q. Q CORE,t is the industry-level Tobin s q of the division with the highest sales in the conglomerate firm. Both are calculated for a sample of standalone firms from the same industry. Firm Cash Flow is the firm s cash flow scaled by total assets. Division Size is the logarithm of division sales and Firm Size is the log of total assets. Firm Age is the logarithm of the current year plus one minus the year in which the firm first appeared in the Compustat North America database. Firm Focus is the ratio of the firm s core division sales to total sales. (Q1) (Q2) (Q3) (Q4) Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets βdiv,t A βa CORE,t (4.11) (3.90) (3.12) (0.86) Q DIV,t (1.02) (0.62) (1.97) (2.34) Q CORE,t (-0.21) (-0.20) (-1.39) (-0.92) Firm Cash Flow t (2.08) (4.87) (5.25) (4.52) Divison Size t (1.78) (1.68) (0.66) (-1.63) Firm Size t (-0.42) (-1.15) (-0.10) (2.12) Firm Age t (-0.73) (-0.46) (0.54) (-0.43) Firm Focus t (1.26) (0.03) (0.57) (1.28) Observations R All regressions include year fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. Standard errors clustered at the firm level. p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p <

39 Table V Non-Core Division Level Investment Regressions by Sub-Period In this table, the main investment specification is estimated for four distinct sub-periods of the sample period. Column (1) shows the relationship between non-core division investment and the asset betas for all firm-year observations between 1987 and Column (2) shows the results for the sub-period of 1992 to 1996, column (3) for and column (4) for The dependent variable Capx/Assets is division-level capital expenditures in period t + 1 scaled by division assets in period t. βcore A is the industry-level asset beta of the core-division (i.e. the division with the highest sales). βa DIV is the industry-level asset beta of the non-core division. Q DIV,t is the division s industry-level Tobin s q. Q CORE,t is the industry-level Tobin s q of the division with the highest sales in the conglomerate firm. Both are calculated for a sample of standalone firms from the same industry. Firm Cash Flow is the firm s cash flow scaled by total assets. Division Size is the logarithm of division sales and Firm Size is the log of total assets. Firm Age is the logarithm of the current year plus one minus the year in which the firm first appeared in the Compustat North America database. Firm Focus is the ratio of the firm s core division sales to total sales. (1) (2) (3) (4) Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets βdiv,t A βa CORE,t (4.50) (5.10) (3.41) (2.10) Q DIV,t (2.04) (-0.12) (0.83) (1.37) Q CORE,t (-1.96) (-0.88) (0.99) (-0.62) Firm Cash Flow t (9.84) (4.57) (5.26) (4.40) Divison Size t (0.98) (3.79) (0.32) (2.32) Firm Size t (0.15) (-3.24) (0.43) (-0.31) Firm Age t (0.05) (-1.47) (-0.16) (-2.75) Firm Focus t (2.06) (0.71) (-0.12) (1.02) Observations R All regressions include year fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. Standard errors clustered at the firm level. p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p <

40 Table VI Non-Core Division Level Investment Regressions by Terciles of CEO Age In this table, we condition the non-core division-level investment regressions on the age of the CEO. We are able to match 5,866 division-firm-year observations between with the Compustat Execucomp database. The non-core investment regressions are run by terciles of CEO Age. The first column shows the relationship for the tercile of the youngest CEOs (Average age: 49 years), the second column shows the relation for second tercile of CEO age ( 58 years) while the last column shows it for the tercile of oldest CEOs ( 66 years). The dependent variable Capx/Assets is division-level capital expenditures in period t + 1 scaled by division assets in period t. βcore A is the industry-level asset beta of the core-division (i.e. the division with the highest sales). βdiv A is the industry-level asset beta of the non-core division. Q DIV,t is the division s industry-level Tobin s q. Q CORE,t is the industry-level Tobin s q of the division with the highest sales in the conglomerate. Both are calculated for a sample of standalone firms from the same industry. Firm Cash Flow is the firm s cash flow scaled by total assets. Division Size is the logarithm of division sales and Firm Size is the log of total assets. Firm Age is the logarithm of the current year plus one minus the year in which the firm first appeared in the Compustat North America database. Firm Focus is the ratio of the firm s core division sales to total sales. (LOW) (MEDIUM) (HIGH) Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets β A DIV,t βa CORE,t (0.50) (1.79) (2.39) Q DIV,t (2.06) (0.31) (-2.57) Q CORE,t (-0.20) (-1.38) (-1.47) Firm Cash Flow t (1.87) (3.71) (3.55) Divison Size t (0.20) (0.10) (0.95) Firm Size t (-0.91) (-2.70) (-1.87) Firm Age t (0.38) (1.71) (-0.24) Firm Focus t (0.77) (-0.66) (0.54) Observations R All regressions include year fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. Standard errors clustered at the firm level. p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p <

41 Overvaluation Factor as a function of lagged industry sales growth Overvaluation Factor Overvaluation Factor as a function of g 0 1.0% 2.0% 3.0% 4.0% 5.0% 6.0% g Figure 2. Calibrated overvaluation factor as a function of lagged industry growth. This figure plots the overvaluation factor r f +β CORE A (rm r f ) g r f +β DIV A (rm r f ) g as a function of g (lagged industry-level growth rate). In the calibration, we chose the following values for the parameters: (rm rf ) = 4%, β DIV A = 1, β CORE A = 0.75 and r f = 2%. 40

42 Table VII Interaction Effects In this table, non-core division-level investment is regressed on all variables used in the baseline specification plus four sets of interaction terms. In Column (1), Medium and High CEO Age are binary variables indicating whether the age of the CEO falls in the second or third tercile. High CEO Ownership is a dummy variable indicating whether CEO equity ownership exceeds 1%. Medium and High GIM Index are indicator variables that take on the value of one whenever the company s Gompers et al. (2003) Index falls in the second, respectively third tercile. Medium and High Sales Growth indicate whether lagged industry level sales growth falls in the second, respectively, third tercile. (1) (2) (3) (4) Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets β A DIV,t βa CORE,t (1.22) (3.58) (1.48) (3.85) Medium CEO Age (β A DIV,t βa CORE,t ) (0.23) High CEO Age (β A DIV,t βa CORE,t ) (0.16) High CEO Ownership (β A DIV,t βa CORE,t ) (-2.65) Medium GIM Index (β A DIV,t βa CORE,t ) (0.62) High GIM Index (β A DIV,t βa CORE,t ) (1.30) Medium Sales Growth (β A DIV,t βa CORE,t ) (0.60) High Sales Growth (β A DIV,t βa CORE,t ) (2.02) Q DIV,t (0.39) (0.30) (-0.42) (2.19) Q CORE,t (-1.30) (-1.10) (-1.15) (-1.26) Firm Cash Flow t (4.28) (4.06) (6.66) (11.14) Divison Size t (0.86) (0.72) (0.76) (3.41) Firm Size t (-2.92) (-2.79) (-2.34) (-1.61) Firm Focus t (0.44) (0.16) (0.42) (1.37) Firm Age t (0.87) (0.54) (0.43) (-1.41) Observations R All regressions include year fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. Standard errors clustered at the firm level. p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p <

43 Table VIII Non-Core Division Level Investment Regressions By Lagged Industry-Level Sales Growth In this table, non-core division-level investment is sorted on lagged industry level sales growth. Lagged Industry Sales Growth is the average sales growth observed in the FF48 industry in a given year. The first column shows the non-core division level investment sensitivity for non-core divisions belonging to low growth sectors. Column (3) shows the investment sensitivity with respect to the spread in asset betas for divisions belonging to high growth sectors. (LOW) (MEDIUM) (HIGH) Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets β A DIV,t βa CORE,t (3.63) (3.76) (5.88) Q DIV,t (-0.34) (1.17) (2.61) Q CORE,t (-1.53) (-2.27) (0.56) Firm Cash Flow t (6.75) (7.39) (7.19) Divison Size t (0.87) (2.71) (3.50) Firm Size t (1.12) (-1.42) (-2.97) Firm Age t (-1.99) (-0.40) (-0.84) Firm Focus t (1.09) (2.80) (-0.20) Observations R All regressions include year fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. Standard errors clustered at the firm level. p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p <

44 Table IX Non-Core Division-Level Investment Regressions: Robustness Checks This table shows robustness checks on the main specification of non-core division-level investment regressions used in the previous tables. β CORE,t A industry-level asset beta of the core-division (i.e. the division with largest sales). β DIV,t A is the industry-level asset beta of the non-core division. βa AV ERAGE,t is a firm wide average beta and is calculated as the weighted average of division-level asset betas, where the weights correspond to the ratio of division-level to total firm assets. QDIV,t and QCORE,t are the industry level Tobin s q of the non-core and core divisions respectively. QDIV,t QFIRM,t is the gap between the industry-level Tobin s q of the division and the firm-wide Tobin s q. SD(QDIV,t)/QF IRM,t is the standard deviation of firm s division-level Tobin s q s in a given year scaled by the overall Tobin s q of the firm. This variable measures the diversity of a a conglomerate s investment opportunities. Investment Core Division is calculated as Capx of the core division in period t+1 scaled by the core division s assets in period t. All other variables are as previously defined. is the (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets Capx/Assets β CORE,t A (-3.49) (-4.07) (-4.59) (-4.45) (-2.26) (0.41) β AV A ERAGE,t (-2.64) (1.16) β DIV,t A (6.20) (4.64) (4.71) (4.84) (5.61) (4.25) QDIV,t QF IRM,t (-5.66) SD(QDIV,t)/QF IRM,t (-3.27) Investment Core Divisiont (6.67) (6.93) (6.91) (0.60) QDIV,t (1.84) (1.82) (3.68) (2.37) (2.13) (2.68) QCORE,t (-2.10) (-1.22) (-2.92) (-1.54) (-1.90) (-1.42) (-0.12) Firm Cash Flowt (12.28) (12.20) (9.96) (9.48) (10.49) (9.81) (7.46) Divison Sizet (2.69) (2.93) (3.70) (3.22) (3.12) Firm Sizet (-0.90) (-1.17) (-1.77) (-1.21) (-4.17) Firm Focust (-0.41) (-0.40) (0.93) (0.85) (1.14) (1.46) (3.52) Firm Aget (-0.80) (-0.73) (-1.72) (-1.65) (-1.22) (-1.04) (0.37) Observations R Year Fixed Effects YES YES YES YES YES NO YES Division Industry*Year Fixed Effects NO NO NO NO NO YES NO Firm Fixed Effects NO NO NO NO NO NO YES t statistics in parentheses p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p <

45 Table X Descriptive Statistics of Deal, Bidder and Target Characteristics This table shows descriptive statistics of deal, bidder and target characteristics of our sample of 6,544 diversifying transactions. A diversifying transaction is a completed merger or acquisition in which the bidder has successfully sought control of a target not belonging to its own FF48 industry. βbidder A and βa T ARGET denote the industry-level asset beta of the bidder and target respectively. Q BIDDER and Q T ARGET denote the industry-level Tobin s q ratios of the bidder and the target. (βbidder A βa T ARGET > 0) and (Q BIDDER Q T ARGET > 0) are two dummy variables indicating whether the differences in asset betas and Tobin s q s respectively are positive. Assets BIDDER is the log of the book value of the bidder s assets (item6) in the year prior to the announcement of the bid. E BIDDER is the fiscal year end equity market value of the bidder in the year prior to the bid announcement. V T ARGET is the value of the transaction as disclosed by SDC. arget private? is a dummy variable indicating whether the target is a private company and Tender Offer? indicates whether the bidder sought control through the process of a tender offer. All Cash? is a dummy variable that takes on the value one when the consideration was entirely paid in cash whereas All Equity? takes on the value of one whenever the target s shareholders are entirely compensated with shares. Multi-Division Acquirer? takes on the value of one when the bidder s business activities are diversified across at least two multiple FF48 industry categories. Hostile and Challenging Bid? are two dummy variables indicating whether the bid s nature is hostile and whether there has been a challenging bid. Mean Median SD P75 p75 βbidder A βt A ARGET βbidder A βa T ARGET (βbidder A βa T ARGET > 0) Q BIDDER Q T ARGET Q BIDDER Q T ARGET (Q BIDDER Q T ARGET > 0) E BIDDER V T ARGET V T ARGET /E BIDDER Target private? Tender Offer? All Cash? All Equity? Multi-Division Acquirer? Hostile Bid? Challenging Bid? Observations

46 Table XI Diversifying Transactions Sample by Calendar Year This table shows the temporal distribution of the sample of diversifying mergers and acquisitions. Yearly means and standard deviations of the nominal deal value (In Million US-$) are calculated by relying on the deal value as disclosed by SDC. Year # of Acquisitions Mean Value (Million US-$) SD Total

47 Figure 3. Bidder Cumulative Abnormal Returns (All Acquisitions). Mean cumulative abnormal returns of the bidder around the announcement of an asset acquisition conditional on whether the WACC of the bidder exceeds that of the target. Only diversifying acquisitions in which the acquiring firm s Fama and French (1997) industry differs from that of the target are considered. Abnormal returns are market adjusted and calculated as the difference between the acquiring firm s daily stock return and the CRSP Value Weighted Market Return on the respective event day. All transactions between 1988 and 2007 fulfilling the sample construction conditions are considered (N=6,544). 46

The WACC Fallacy: The Real Effects of Using a Unique Discount Rate

The WACC Fallacy: The Real Effects of Using a Unique Discount Rate 11-222 Research Group: Finance in Toulouse February, 2011 The WACC Fallacy: The Real Effects of Using a Unique Discount Rate PHILIPP KRUGER, AUGUSTIN LANDIER AND DAVID THESMAR The WACC Fallacy: The Real

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time,

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, 1. Introduction Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, many diversified firms have become more focused by divesting assets. 2 Some firms become more

More information

How increased diversification affects the efficiency of internal capital market?

How increased diversification affects the efficiency of internal capital market? How increased diversification affects the efficiency of internal capital market? ABSTRACT Rong Guo Columbus State University This paper investigates the effect of increased diversification on the internal

More information

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Manohar Singh The Pennsylvania State University- Abington Reporting a positive relationship between institutional ownership on one hand and capital expenditures

More information

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Mehmet E. Akbulut 1 Department of Finance College of Business and Economics California State University Fullerton Abstract This paper examines whether managers

More information

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Appendices A A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Given the structure of venture capital financing just described, the potential mechanisms by which shocks might propagate across companies in

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings

Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings Zhenxu Tong University of Exeter* Paper Number: 08/03 First Draft: June 2007 This Draft: February 2008 Abstract This paper studies how firm

More information

Managerial Optimism, Investment Efficiency, and Firm Valuation

Managerial Optimism, Investment Efficiency, and Firm Valuation 1 Managerial Optimism, Investment Efficiency, and Firm Valuation I-Ju Chen* Yuan Ze University, Taiwan Shin-Hung Lin Yuan Ze University, Taiwan This study investigates the relationship between managerial

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva* The Role of Credit Ratings in the Dynamic Tradeoff Model Viktoriya Staneva* This study examines what costs and benefits of debt are most important to the determination of the optimal capital structure.

More information

WACC Calculations in Practice: Incorrect Results due to Inconsistent Assumptions - Status Quo and Improvements

WACC Calculations in Practice: Incorrect Results due to Inconsistent Assumptions - Status Quo and Improvements WACC Calculations in Practice: Incorrect Results due to Inconsistent Assumptions - Status Quo and Improvements Matthias C. Grüninger 1 & Axel H. Kind 2 1 Lonza AG, Münchensteinerstrasse 38, CH-4002 Basel,

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

International Journal of Asian Social Science OVERINVESTMENT, UNDERINVESTMENT, EFFICIENT INVESTMENT DECREASE, AND EFFICIENT INVESTMENT INCREASE

International Journal of Asian Social Science OVERINVESTMENT, UNDERINVESTMENT, EFFICIENT INVESTMENT DECREASE, AND EFFICIENT INVESTMENT INCREASE International Journal of Asian Social Science ISSN(e): 2224-4441/ISSN(p): 2226-5139 journal homepage: http://www.aessweb.com/journals/5007 OVERINVESTMENT, UNDERINVESTMENT, EFFICIENT INVESTMENT DECREASE,

More information

The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings

The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings Soohyung Kim University of Wisconsin La Crosse Hoontaek Seo Niagara University Daniel L. Tompkins Niagara University This

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? *

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Thomas Moeller Neeley School of Business Texas Christian University Abstract In a large sample of public-public acquisitions, target

More information

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract In this paper we study the market reaction to capital expenditure announcements in the backdrop

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

Divestitures and Divisional Investment Policies

Divestitures and Divisional Investment Policies Divestitures and Divisional Investment Policies Amy Dittmar Kelly School of Business Indiana University Bloomington, IN 47405 Phone: (812) 855-2698 Fax: (812) 855-5875 Email: adittmar@indiana.edu Anil

More information

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less?

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Jia Chen, Kewei Hou, and René M. Stulz* January 2015 Abstract Using theories from the behavioral finance literature to predict that investors are attracted to

More information

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior By Jackson Mills Abstract The retention of deep in-the-money exercisable stock options by CEOs has generally been attributed to managers

More information

Local Culture and Dividends

Local Culture and Dividends Local Culture and Dividends Erdem Ucar I empirically investigate whether geographical variations in local culture, as proxied by local religion, affect dividend demand and corporate dividend policy for

More information

Irrational people and rational needs for optimal pension plans

Irrational people and rational needs for optimal pension plans Gordana Drobnjak CFA MBA Executive Director Republic of Srpska Pension reserve fund management company Irrational people and rational needs for optimal pension plans CEE Pension Funds Conference & Awards

More information

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada Operating Cash Flows: Sales $682,500 $771,750 $868,219 $972,405 $957,211 less expenses $477,750 $540,225 $607,753 $680,684 $670,048 Difference $204,750 $231,525 $260,466 $291,722 $287,163 After-tax (1

More information

Corporate Diversification and Overinvestment: Evidence from Asset Write-Offs*

Corporate Diversification and Overinvestment: Evidence from Asset Write-Offs* Corporate Diversification and Overinvestment: Evidence from Asset Write-Offs* Gil Sadka and Yuan Zhang November 10, 2008 Preliminary and incomplete Please do not circulate Abstract This paper documents

More information

Dynamic Capital Structure Choice

Dynamic Capital Structure Choice Dynamic Capital Structure Choice Xin Chang * Department of Finance Faculty of Economics and Commerce University of Melbourne Sudipto Dasgupta Department of Finance Hong Kong University of Science and Technology

More information

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University Colin Mayer Saïd Business School University of Oxford Oren Sussman

More information

A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968): Comparative Analysis of China and the US *

A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968): Comparative Analysis of China and the US * DOI 10.7603/s40570-014-0007-1 66 2014 年 6 月第 16 卷第 2 期 中国会计与财务研究 C h i n a A c c o u n t i n g a n d F i n a n c e R e v i e w Volume 16, Number 2 June 2014 A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968):

More information

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXVI, NO. 1 MARCH 1991 Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers HENRI SERVAES* ABSTRACT This paper analyzes the relation between takeover gains and the q ratios of targets and

More information

Optimism, Attribution and Corporate Investment Policy. Richard Walton

Optimism, Attribution and Corporate Investment Policy. Richard Walton Optimism, Attribution and Corporate Investment Policy by Richard Walton A Dissertation Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Doctor of Philosophy Approved April 2016 by the

More information

Figure 14.1 Per Share Earnings and Dividends of the S&P500 Index. III. Figure 14.2 Aggregate Dividends and Repurchases for All U.S.

Figure 14.1 Per Share Earnings and Dividends of the S&P500 Index. III. Figure 14.2 Aggregate Dividends and Repurchases for All U.S. I. The Basics of Payout Policy: A. The term payout policy refers to the decisions that a firm makes regarding whether to distribute cash to shareholders, how much cash to distribute, and the means by which

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. Stulz Working Paper 9523 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9523 NATIONAL

More information

Thriving on a Short Leash: Debt Maturity Structure and Acquirer Returns

Thriving on a Short Leash: Debt Maturity Structure and Acquirer Returns Thriving on a Short Leash: Debt Maturity Structure and Acquirer Returns Abstract This research empirically investigates the relation between debt maturity structure and acquirer returns. We find that short-term

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1]

Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1] The Determinants of Capital Structure in Stock Exchange Listed Non Financial Firms in Pakistan By Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1] and Attaullah Shah 2[2] 1[1] Professor & Dean Faculty of Business Administration

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

Does Debt Help Managers? Using Cash Holdings to Explain Acquisition Returns

Does Debt Help Managers? Using Cash Holdings to Explain Acquisition Returns University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2017 Does Debt Help Managers? Using Cash Holdings to Explain Acquisition Returns Michael Evans Michael.Evans-1@Colorado.EDU

More information

Corporate cash shortfalls and financing decisions

Corporate cash shortfalls and financing decisions Corporate cash shortfalls and financing decisions Rongbing Huang and Jay R. Ritter December 5, 2015 Abstract Immediate cash needs are the primary motive for debt issuances and a highly important motive

More information

Excess Value and Restructurings by Diversified Firms

Excess Value and Restructurings by Diversified Firms Excess Value and Restructurings by Diversified Firms Gayané Hovakimian Fordham University Schools of Business 1790 Broadway, 13 th floor New York, NY10019 Tel.: (212)-636-7021 E-mail: hovakimian@fordham.edu

More information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Critical Finance Review, 2016, 5: 165 175 Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Kent Daniel Sheridan Titman 1 Columbia Business School, Columbia University, New York,

More information

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck

More information

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios RESEARCH Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios March 2016 Wei Dai, PhD Research The predictability of expected stock returns is an old topic and an important one. While investors may increase expected returns

More information

The relationship between share repurchase announcement and share price behaviour

The relationship between share repurchase announcement and share price behaviour The relationship between share repurchase announcement and share price behaviour Name: P.G.J. van Erp Submission date: 18/12/2014 Supervisor: B. Melenberg Second reader: F. Castiglionesi Master Thesis

More information

Managerial Characteristics and Corporate Cash Policy

Managerial Characteristics and Corporate Cash Policy Managerial Characteristics and Corporate Cash Policy Keng-Yu Ho Department of Finance National Taiwan University Chia-Wei Yeh Department of Finance National Taiwan University December 3, 2014 Corresponding

More information

Note on Cost of Capital

Note on Cost of Capital DUKE UNIVERSITY, FUQUA SCHOOL OF BUSINESS ACCOUNTG 512F: FUNDAMENTALS OF FINANCIAL ANALYSIS Note on Cost of Capital For the course, you should concentrate on the CAPM and the weighted average cost of capital.

More information

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 140 ( 2014 ) PSYSOC Assessment of Corporate Behavioural Finance

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 140 ( 2014 ) PSYSOC Assessment of Corporate Behavioural Finance Available online at www.sciencedirect.com ScienceDirect Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 10 ( 201 ) 32 39 PSYSOC 201 Assessment of Corporate Behavioural Finance Daiva Jurevičienė*, Egidijus Bikas,

More information

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n.

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. 5/2014 April 2014 ISSN: 2239-2734 This Working Paper is published under

More information

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 6 Number 2 2012 AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University

More information

Research on the Relationship between CEO's Overconfidence and Corporate Investment Financing Behavior

Research on the Relationship between CEO's Overconfidence and Corporate Investment Financing Behavior Research on the Relationship between CEO's Overconfidence and Corporate Investment Financing Behavior Yan-liang Zhang*, Zi-wei Yang Shandong University of Finance and Economics. Jinan P.R.China E-mail:zhyanliang@sina.com

More information

Do All Diversified Firms Hold Less Cash? The International Evidence 1. Christina Atanasova. and. Ming Li. September, 2015

Do All Diversified Firms Hold Less Cash? The International Evidence 1. Christina Atanasova. and. Ming Li. September, 2015 Do All Diversified Firms Hold Less Cash? The International Evidence 1 by Christina Atanasova and Ming Li September, 2015 Abstract: We examine the relationship between corporate diversification and cash

More information

Factors in the returns on stock : inspiration from Fama and French asset pricing model

Factors in the returns on stock : inspiration from Fama and French asset pricing model Lingnan Journal of Banking, Finance and Economics Volume 5 2014/2015 Academic Year Issue Article 1 January 2015 Factors in the returns on stock : inspiration from Fama and French asset pricing model Yuanzhen

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: March 2013 First draft: October 2010 Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu. I am grateful

More information

The Impact of Institutional Investors on the Monday Seasonal*

The Impact of Institutional Investors on the Monday Seasonal* Su Han Chan Department of Finance, California State University-Fullerton Wai-Kin Leung Faculty of Business Administration, Chinese University of Hong Kong Ko Wang Department of Finance, California State

More information

Does Size Matter? The Impact of Managerial Incentives and

Does Size Matter? The Impact of Managerial Incentives and Does Size Matter? The Impact of Managerial Incentives and Firm Size on Acquisition Announcement Returns Master Thesis R.M. Jonkman Using 3,042 acquiring firm observations for the period 1993 2007, I find

More information

Concentration and Stock Returns: Australian Evidence

Concentration and Stock Returns: Australian Evidence 2010 International Conference on Economics, Business and Management IPEDR vol.2 (2011) (2011) IAC S IT Press, Manila, Philippines Concentration and Stock Returns: Australian Evidence Katja Ignatieva Faculty

More information

Can the Source of Cash Accumulation Alter the Agency Problem of Excess Cash Holdings? Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions ABSTRACT

Can the Source of Cash Accumulation Alter the Agency Problem of Excess Cash Holdings? Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions ABSTRACT Can the Source of Cash Accumulation Alter the Agency Problem of Excess Cash Holdings? Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions ABSTRACT This study argues that the source of cash accumulation can distinguish

More information

The benefits and costs of group affiliation: Evidence from East Asia

The benefits and costs of group affiliation: Evidence from East Asia Emerging Markets Review 7 (2006) 1 26 www.elsevier.com/locate/emr The benefits and costs of group affiliation: Evidence from East Asia Stijn Claessens a, *, Joseph P.H. Fan b, Larry H.P. Lang b a World

More information

Are Dividend Changes a Sign of Firm Maturity?

Are Dividend Changes a Sign of Firm Maturity? Are Dividend Changes a Sign of Firm Maturity? Gustavo Grullon * Rice University Roni Michaely Cornell University Bhaskaran Swaminathan Cornell University Forthcoming in The Journal of Business * We thank

More information

Citation for published version (APA): Oosterhof, C. M. (2006). Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging s.n.

Citation for published version (APA): Oosterhof, C. M. (2006). Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging s.n. University of Groningen Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging Oosterhof, Casper Martijn IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Are Mergers Driven by Overvaluation? Evidence from Managerial Insider Trading Around Merger Announcements

Are Mergers Driven by Overvaluation? Evidence from Managerial Insider Trading Around Merger Announcements Paper 1 of 2 USC FBE FINANCE SEMINAR presented by Mehmet Akbulut FRIDAY, September 16, 2005 10:00 am 11:30 am, Room: JKP-104 Are Mergers Driven by Overvaluation? Evidence from Managerial Insider Trading

More information

Corporate Investment and Institutional Investors. Author. Published. Journal Title. Copyright Statement. Downloaded from. Link to published version

Corporate Investment and Institutional Investors. Author. Published. Journal Title. Copyright Statement. Downloaded from. Link to published version Corporate Investment and Institutional Investors Author Chung, Richard Yiu-Ming Published 2013 Journal Title Corporate Ownership & Control Copyright Statement 2013 VirtusInterpress. The attached file is

More information

Do diversified or focused firms make better acquisitions?

Do diversified or focused firms make better acquisitions? Do diversified or focused firms make better acquisitions? on the 2015 American Finance Association (AFA) Meeting Program Mehmet Cihan Tulane University Sheri Tice Tulane University December 2014 ABSTRACT

More information

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision Modern Applied Science; Vol. 9, No. 4; 2015 ISSN 1913-1844 E-ISSN 1913-1852 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision Seok Weon Lee 1 1 Division

More information

Acquiring Intangible Assets

Acquiring Intangible Assets Acquiring Intangible Assets Intangible assets are important for corporations and their owners. The book value of intangible assets as a percentage of total assets for all COMPUSTAT firms grew from 6% in

More information

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage Jin-Chuan Duan * and Yun Li (First draft: April 12, 2006) (This version: May 16, 2006) Abstract This paper identifies a key cause for the documented diversification

More information

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect?

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? Yi Jiang Department of Finance, California State University, Fullerton SGMH 5160, Fullerton, CA 92831 (657)278-4363 yjiang@fullerton.edu Yiming Qian

More information

Dividend Policy Responses to Deregulation in the Electric Utility Industry

Dividend Policy Responses to Deregulation in the Electric Utility Industry Dividend Policy Responses to Deregulation in the Electric Utility Industry Julia D Souza 1, John Jacob 2 & Veronda F. Willis 3 1 Johnson Graduate School of Management, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY 14853,

More information

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Anup Agrawal Culverhouse College of Business University of Alabama Tuscaloosa, AL 35487-0224 Jeffrey F. Jaffe Department

More information

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LVI, NO. 6 DEC. 2001 Dividend Changes and Future Profitability DORON NISSIM and AMIR ZIV* ABSTRACT We investigate the relation between dividend changes and future profitability,

More information

Module 3: Factor Models

Module 3: Factor Models Module 3: Factor Models (BUSFIN 4221 - Investments) Andrei S. Gonçalves 1 1 Finance Department The Ohio State University Fall 2016 1 Module 1 - The Demand for Capital 2 Module 1 - The Supply of Capital

More information

Risk Cluster Framework How to analyse Companies by Operating Leverage 1

Risk Cluster Framework How to analyse Companies by Operating Leverage 1 Précis Risk Cluster Framework How to analyse Companies by Operating Leverage 1 The operating leverage is part of most management accounting textbooks. The considerations are limited to breakeven analysis.

More information

Web Appendix for: Medicare Part D: Are Insurers Gaming the Low Income Subsidy Design? Francesco Decarolis (Boston University)

Web Appendix for: Medicare Part D: Are Insurers Gaming the Low Income Subsidy Design? Francesco Decarolis (Boston University) Web Appendix for: Medicare Part D: Are Insurers Gaming the Low Income Subsidy Design? 1) Data Francesco Decarolis (Boston University) The dataset was assembled from data made publicly available by CMS

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

Economics of Behavioral Finance. Lecture 3

Economics of Behavioral Finance. Lecture 3 Economics of Behavioral Finance Lecture 3 Security Market Line CAPM predicts a linear relationship between a stock s Beta and its excess return. E[r i ] r f = β i E r m r f Practically, testing CAPM empirically

More information

CEO Centrality. NELLCO Legal Scholarship Repository NELLCO. Lucian Bebchuk Harvard Law School. Martijn Cremers. Urs Peyer

CEO Centrality. NELLCO Legal Scholarship Repository NELLCO. Lucian Bebchuk Harvard Law School. Martijn Cremers. Urs Peyer NELLCO NELLCO Legal Scholarship Repository Harvard Law School John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business Discussion Paper Series Harvard Law School 11-6-2007 CEO Centrality Lucian Bebchuk Harvard

More information

The Influence of CEO Experience and Education on Firm Policies

The Influence of CEO Experience and Education on Firm Policies The Influence of CEO Experience and Education on Firm Policies Helena Címerová Nova School of Business and Economics This version: November 2012 Abstract We study the influence of CEO experience and education

More information

Dissecting Conglomerates

Dissecting Conglomerates Dissecting Conglomerates November 18, 2017 ABSTRACT We develop a new method to estimate Tobin s qs of conglomerate divisions without relying on standalone firms. Divisional qs differ considerably from

More information

CAPM-Based Company (Mis)valuations

CAPM-Based Company (Mis)valuations CAPM-Based Company (Mis)valuations Olivier Dessaint, Jacques Olivier, Clemens A. Otto, and David Thesmar March 2018 Abstract There is a discrepancy between CAPM-implied and realized returns. As a result,

More information

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998) 219 239 Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Anup Agrawal*, Charles R. Knoeber College of Management, North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC

More information

DOES INFORMATION ASYMMETRY EXPLAIN THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT? Abstract

DOES INFORMATION ASYMMETRY EXPLAIN THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT? Abstract The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXVII, No. 2 Pages 235 249 Summer 2004 DOES INFORMATION ASYMMETRY EXPLAIN THE DIVERSIFICATION DISCOUNT? Ronald W. Best and Charles W. Hodges State University of West

More information

Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix

Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix Yelena Larkin, Mark T. Leary, and Roni Michaely April 2016 Table I.A-I In table I.A-I we perform a simple non-parametric analysis

More information

Risk Tolerance and Risk Exposure: Evidence from Panel Study. of Income Dynamics

Risk Tolerance and Risk Exposure: Evidence from Panel Study. of Income Dynamics Risk Tolerance and Risk Exposure: Evidence from Panel Study of Income Dynamics Economics 495 Project 3 (Revised) Professor Frank Stafford Yang Su 2012/3/9 For Honors Thesis Abstract In this paper, I examined

More information

Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis

Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis Armen Hovakimian Baruch College and Gayane Hovakimian * Fordham University May 12, 2005 ABSTRACT Using firm level estimates of investment-cash flow

More information

Discussion of Overinvestment of free cash flow

Discussion of Overinvestment of free cash flow Rev Acc Stud (2006) 11:191 202 DOI 10.1007/s11142-006-9002-3 Discussion of Overinvestment of free cash flow Daniel Bergstresser Published online: 20 May 2006 Ó Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2006

More information

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009 Long Chen Washington University in St. Louis Fresh Momentum Engin Kose Washington University in St. Louis First version: October 2009 Ohad Kadan Washington University in St. Louis Abstract We demonstrate

More information

The Role of Management Incentives in the Choice of Stock Repurchase Methods. Ata Torabi. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business

The Role of Management Incentives in the Choice of Stock Repurchase Methods. Ata Torabi. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business The Role of Management Incentives in the Choice of Stock Repurchase Methods Ata Torabi A Thesis In The John Molson School of Business Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree

More information

Debt/Equity Ratio and Asset Pricing Analysis

Debt/Equity Ratio and Asset Pricing Analysis Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies Summer 8-1-2017 Debt/Equity Ratio and Asset Pricing Analysis Nicholas Lyle Follow this and additional works

More information

Dividend Policy in Switzerland

Dividend Policy in Switzerland Dividend Policy in Switzerland Bogdan Stacescu October 30, 2004 Abstract The paper examines dividend policy for a sample of Swiss companies. Several factors that determine cross-sectional variations in

More information

Corporate disclosure, information uncertainty and investors behavior: A test of the overconfidence effect on market reaction to goodwill write-offs

Corporate disclosure, information uncertainty and investors behavior: A test of the overconfidence effect on market reaction to goodwill write-offs Corporate disclosure, information uncertainty and investors behavior: A test of the overconfidence effect on market reaction to goodwill write-offs VERONIQUE BESSIERE and PATRICK SENTIS CR2M University

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

Efficiency of Internal Capital Allocation and the Success of Acquisitions

Efficiency of Internal Capital Allocation and the Success of Acquisitions University of New Orleans ScholarWorks@UNO University of New Orleans Theses and Dissertations Dissertations and Theses 12-20-2009 Efficiency of Internal Capital Allocation and the Success of Acquisitions

More information

Firms Histories and Their Capital Structures *

Firms Histories and Their Capital Structures * Firms Histories and Their Capital Structures * Ayla Kayhan Department of Finance Red McCombs School of Business University of Texas at Austin akayhan@mail.utexas.edu and Sheridan Titman Department of Finance

More information

Debt Boundaries Matter: Evidence From The Subsidiary Debt

Debt Boundaries Matter: Evidence From The Subsidiary Debt Debt Boundaries Matter: Evidence From The Subsidiary Debt January 15, 2018 Abstract I exploit the introduction of an accounting reform in the US to investigate whether the presence of subsidiary debt affects

More information

INTERNAL CAPITAL MARKET AND CAPITAL MISALLOCATION: EVIDENCE FROM CORPORATE SPINOFFS. Dezie L. Warganegara, M.B.A

INTERNAL CAPITAL MARKET AND CAPITAL MISALLOCATION: EVIDENCE FROM CORPORATE SPINOFFS. Dezie L. Warganegara, M.B.A INTERNAL CAPITAL MARKET AND CAPITAL MISALLOCATION: EVIDENCE FROM CORPORATE SPINOFFS Dezie L. Warganegara, M.B.A Dissertation Prepared for the Degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY UNIVERSITY OF NORTH TEXAS August

More information

Internet Appendix: Costs and Benefits of Friendly Boards during Mergers and Acquisitions. Breno Schmidt Goizueta School of Business Emory University

Internet Appendix: Costs and Benefits of Friendly Boards during Mergers and Acquisitions. Breno Schmidt Goizueta School of Business Emory University Internet Appendix: Costs and Benefits of Friendly Boards during Mergers and Acquisitions Breno Schmidt Goizueta School of Business Emory University January, 2014 A Social Ties Data To facilitate the exposition,

More information

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM ) MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM Ersin Güner 559370 Master Finance Supervisor: dr. P.C. (Peter) de Goeij December 2013 Abstract Evidence from the US shows

More information