and Contract Enforcement 1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "and Contract Enforcement 1"

Transcription

1 Foreign Direct Investment and Contract Enforcement 1 Zhigang TAO School of Business The University of Hong Kong Susheng WANG Department of Economics Hong Kong University of Science and Technology July, 1998 Suggested running head: Foreign Direct Investment Correspondence to: Susheng WANG, Department of Economics, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Clear Water Bay, HONG KONG. Tel: (852) We would like to thank sincerely Editor John Bonin, three anonymous referees and Danyang Xie. Their invaluable comments and suggestions have contributed to substantial improvement of the paper. We would also like to acknowledge nancial support from the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong. 1

2 Abstract A long-standing deterrent to foreign direct investment in developing countries is weak enforcement of binding contracts. A local rm may learn business skills from a cooperating multinational rm and subsequently do business on its own based on the acquired skills. In a two-period doublemoral-hazard model, non-binding contracts are shown to be preferred by all parties, implying that contract enforcement is unnecessary. Our results shed light on the puzzling phenomenon that substantial FDI has been carried out under contractual arrangements in developing countries in which contract enforcement is problematic. They can also explain some interesting stylized facts of contractual joint ventures between multinationals and local rms in the early stage of an economic transition. Keywords: foreign direct investment, contract enforcement, contractual joint ventures, double moral hazard, learning by doing. Journal of Economic Literature Classi cation Numbers: D2, F2, L2. 2

3 1. Introduction In the past three decades, foreign direct investment (FDI) has increased substantially. In particular, during the eighties, FDI worldwide grew faster than GDP and trade by a factor of four and three respectively (Neven and Siotis, 1993). Not surprisingly, almost all outward FDI comes from developed countries. Developing countries are attracting an increasingly larger share of inward FDI. 2 Multinational corporations from developed countries are looking for markets as well as sources of low-cost production in developing countries through either ownership arrangements, e.g., wholly-owned subsidiaries and equity joint ventures (EJVs), or contractual arrangements, e.g., contractual joint ventures (CJVs). In recent years, FDI has played an important role in the economic transition of East Asian countries, East European countries and the former Soviet Union. A longstanding deterrent to FDI 3 in many developing countries is weak contract enforcement. 4 Companies in developing countries try to master trade secrets from their partners through cooperation and conduct business on their own based on the acquired knowledge. Indeed, some governments in developing countries have declared openly that the absorption of superior technologies is a key condition for the approval of a FDI project. Weak contract enforcement, especially regarding the penalty for violation of binding contracts, is thought to deter FDI in developing countries. Evidence reveals that, in developing countries even with poor contract enforcement, a substantial amount of FDI has been carried out under contractual arrangements. For example, when China began to attract FDI in 1979, the law for EJVs was enacted in anticipation that the form of EJV would be widely used by foreign investors. 5 Interestingly, the form of CJV was instead more widely used even though there was no law for CJVs until In fact, from 1980 to 1987, CJVs outnumbered EJVs, see Wang (1992). 2 Developed countries supplied 97 to 99% of the total FDI throughout the period (Hummels and Stern, 1994). On the other hand, developing countries have obtained an increasingly larger share, 21% in 1993 and 40% in 1994, of total inward FDI (Banks, 1995). 3 Other deterrents to FDI include restrictions on foreign ownership and requirements for local content, both of which are beyond the scope of this paper. 4 In this paper, short-term contracts and long-term non-binding contracts on veri able revenues are always enforced. What we mean by weak contract enforcement is that of long-term binding contracts (see (Grout, 1984) for contract enforcement problem of short-term contracts). For ease of exposition, contracts in this paper, both binding and non-binding, are meant to be long-term unless otherwise speci ed. 5 In an EJV, participating rms have equity shares. The venture s pro ts are split among the participating rms according to equity shares that are constant throughout the cooperation unless they are voluntarily exchanged. 6 The de ning feature of CJVs is the absence of equity shares so that the pro ts are split according to the revenue shares speci ed in the contracts. 3

4 Table 1: Contractual Joint Ventures a Company Duration Revenue Share b Technology Stone cutting 10 year 50/50 Equipment from West from 1986 Germany, some from Italy. Dried duck 5 years 55/45 Basically traditional processing from 1985 technology. Confectionery 6 years 50/50 for rst 3 years Packaging machinery, manufacturing from /45 for last 3 years imported from Japan. Footwear 10 years 50/50 Equipment from Japan. manufacturing from 1985 Restaurant unspeci ed 10/90 Hong Kong style from 1984 restaurant supervision. Kitchen equipment 8 years 0/100 for rst 3 years NA for restaurant from /60 for next 2 years manufacturing 50/50 for next 1 year 60/40 for last 2 years. Jewellery 10 years 56/44 Hong Kong designs. manufacturing from 1985 over and above repayment capital to HK side Camera 10 years 30/70 of net pro t NA manufacturing from 1985 a This table is adopted from Thoburn et al. (1990). b Chinese revenue share compared to foreign revenue share. Substantial FDI using contractual arrangements, despite weak contract enforcement, presents a puzzle to economists as well as to legal scholars. Hall (1992) highlights the puzzle in his discussion of economic transition in Asia and Eastern Europe. In an attempt to solve this puzzle, we investigate contractual arrangements for FDI in settings in which the enforcement of binding contracts is problematic. In particular, we consider a foreign rm that provides technology or know-how and a local rm that provides complementary inputs, both involved in a joint two-period project. The 4

5 success of the project in the rst period depends on unveri able e ort by each rm. Furthermore, we consider the possibility that, through cooperation in the rst period, the local rm may learn the necessary skills from the foreign rm, in which case the local rm may conduct business on its own in the second period. 7 If the good technology is provided by the foreign rm, the possibility of learning is determined by the local rm s e ort in the rst period, which is a characterization of learning by doing. The two rms can sign either a two-period binding contract under which the local rm is not allowed to do business on its own upon learning the technology or a twoperiod non-binding contract under which the local rm is allowed to leave the contract arrangement upon learning the technology. Note that the former requires contract enforcement whereas the latter does not. We show that the equilibrium non-binding contract is preferred by both partners to the equilibrium binding contract. Thus, contract enforcement is unnecessary. We also nd that, under the equilibrium nonbinding contract, the foreign rm s revenue share is decreasing or constant over the duration of the cooperation. Interestingly, this theoretical result is consistent with the puzzling empirical fact of decreasing foreign revenue share for CJVs in China, see Table 1 for examples. Learning is a key incentive device in our model of FDI because it depends on endogenously determined e ort in the rst period. Under the non-binding contract, the local rm works harder in the rst period in order to learn the technology and the foreign rm extracts a larger revenue share in the rst period to compensate for its potential second-period loss from learning. On balance, both rms are better o under the non-binding contract. A surprising implication of our results is that contract enforcement is not a prerequisite for FDI in developing countries, especially in the early stage of economic development. The nding sheds light on the puzzle that there has been substantial FDI in developing countries in which contract enforcement is problematic. It may also explain why FDI under CJVs was popular in China despite its weak contract enforcement, at least in the early stage of the country s economic reform. However, we stress that our conclusions depend crucially on some important stylized facts. We consider a scenario in which the foreign rm s know-how does not have any immediate application without some complementary inputs or skills from the local rm. This captures a characteristic feature of FDI in developing countries in which only the local rm has access to certain inputs and resources so that the foreign rm must cooperate with the local rm to obtain the resources. During the cooperation, 7 A survey of CJVs in China reveals that multinational rms generally provide technologies that are not too complex or sophisticated for Chinese rms to learn. See Table 1 for some examples. 5

6 however, it is di cult for the foreign rm to protect its know-how, e.g., management skills and style, market knowledge and experience, from being acquired by the local rm. Indeed, a substantial portion of FDI by foreign rms is for sources of lowcost production; the technologies and know-how involved are conventional and easy to learn, see Table 1 for some examples. Moreover, since the foreign rm s know-how is embedded or di cult to transfer, the local rm needs to work with the foreign rm for a certain time period in order to learn the technology. Such learning-by-doing implies a lag and creates an incentive for the foreign rm to cooperate with the local rm, which is in turn willing to give up a large share of revenue to the foreign rm in the initial period of their cooperation. Our model and its implications are most suitable for the early stage of economic development. In Section 2, FDI is modeled as a two-period moral-hazard problem with learning and various contractual arrangements are discussed. Sections 3 and 4 investigate equilibrium non-binding and binding contracts, respectively. Section 5 presents the main result. Section 6 highlights the special characteristics of the equilibrium contracts. Finally, the paper concludes with some general remarks. 2. The Model We model FDI as a way of pooling complementary inputs between rms from di erent countries. A foreign rm has technology or business know-how and a local rm has some complementary inputs in production and marketing. The two rms undertake jointly a project through a contractual arrangement. The project lasts for two periods. The success of the project in the rst period depends on unveri able e orts from both the foreign rm and the local rm: E 1 from the foreign rm and e 1 from the local rm. For simplicity, the success probability of the project is assumed to be p 1 = E 1 e 1, where E 1 is 0 or 1 and e 1 2 [0, 1]. 8 The foreign rm s e ort is interpreted as providing either good technology, E 1 = 1 with cost C 1 > 0, or bad technology, E 1 = 0 with zero cost. The local rm s e ort is interpreted as developing the foreign rm s technology or know-how into a product with cost c(e 1 ) = β 1+β e β 1+β 1, where β > 0. Since c 0 (e 1 ) = e 1/β 1 and e 1 2 [0, 1], 1/β represents the local rm s productivity. 9 Once successful, the project generates observable and veri able revenue R 1 > 0; otherwise it has zero revenue. 8 The simplifying assumption of discrete E 1 re ects the fact that the multinational rm provides technology or know-how rather than labor e ort. 9 This speci c form is chosen for the simplicity of derivations. Cost can be written as c(e) = Ae γ for a closed-form solution, where A and γ 0. 6

7 Through cooperation in the rst period, the local rm may learn the foreign rm s technology. The probability of doing so is given by φ = ke 1 E 1, where k 2 [0, 1]. 10 If the foreign rm provides good technology, the harder the local rm works in the rst period, the more likely it is to succeed in learning the technology. The probability of learning depends on an exogenous parameter k that may be interpreted as the speed of learning. As k increases from 0 to 1, learning becomes more likely. On the other hand, e 1 and E 1 are endogenously determined in equilibrium. Hence, learning has an endogenous component, i.e., learning by doing, that is based on the e orts expended by the local and foreign rms in the rst period. Our model focuses on the possibility that the local rm will learn the foreign rm s know-how through cooperation and do business on its own afterwards. This situation applies to the early stage of economic development, e.g., the early years of China s economic transition, when foreign rms technologies and know-how are conventional and easy to learn and local rms are given exclusive access to certain inputs and resources by their governments. If the local rm has learned the technology in the rst period, the success probability of the project in the second period, p 2, depends solely on the local rm s e ort in the second period e 2, i.e., p 2 = e 2, where e 2 2 [0, 1]. If the local rm does not learn the technology, the success probability depends again on the foreign rm s e ort, E 2, and the local rm s e ort, e 2, i.e., p 2 = e 2 E 2, where e 2 2 [0, 1] and E 2 = 0 or 1. In the second period, the foreign rm provides either good technology, E 2 = 1 with cost C 2 > 0, or bad technology, E 2 = 0 with zero cost. The local rm incurs cost c(e 2 ). Once successful, the project generates observable and veri able revenue R 2 > 0 in the second period; otherwise it has zero revenue. Without losing generality, 11 assume that the foreign rm designs the contract. In a standard principal-agent model, the principal does not provide any input; if the agent is risk-neutral, the optimal contract has the agent paying a lump-sum fee or franchise fee upfront and then getting all the revenue, see Hart and Holmström (1987). In our model, both the local and the foreign rms must provide costly e orts. In particular, the foreign rm can provide good technology at positive cost or bad technology at zero cost. If the quality of the foreign rm s technology can be veri ed by a third party such as a court, our problem would be subsumed in the standard principal-agent model and the optimal solution would be the franchise fee. The franchise fee constitutes the rst-best solution as the local rm has the maximum incentive to supply e ort while the foreign rm is induced to provide the good technology. 10 This learning structure can be generalized to the Cobb-Douglas form, see Remark 4 in Section See Remark 2 in Section 5 for the case in which the local rm designs the contract. 7

8 Our model is concerned with a situation in which the quality of the foreign rm s technology cannot be veri ed when the technology is delivered. This is characteristic of FDI in developing countries (Marin and Schnitzer, 1995). While the quality of the foreign rm s technology cannot be veri ed, it could be inferred by the local rm. However, the crucial point is that the local rm cannot verify its inference to a third party because the success of the joint project depends on both the quality of the foreign rm s technology and the local rm s e ort. It is impossible for a third party to determine whether a failure of the joint project is due to the foreign rm s bad technology or the local rm s low e ort. In the above situation, the franchise fee solution will not work. The foreign rm would accept the franchise fee and supply bad technology at zero cost, because the foreign rm knows that the local rm cannot prove to a third party that the technology is of low quality. Given the inferiority of the franchise fee solution, share contracts emerge as optimal contracts in our model. 12 Under such contracts, the foreign rm obtains payo s only when the project is successful; thus, it provides good technology if it has a signi cant share. We consider two possible share contracts. First, the foreign rm can write a nonbinding contract that allows the local rm to do business on its own upon learning the technology. Speci cally, if the project is successful in the rst period, the foreign and local rms get X 1 and R 1 X 1, respectively. In the second period, the local rm will work on its own if it has learned the technology; otherwise it will be in both rms interests to continue their cooperation. In the former case, the local rm gets the entire amount R 2 if the project is successful; in the latter case, the foreign rm and the local rm get X 2 and R 2 X 2, respectively, if the project is successful. Second, the foreign rm can write a binding contract that prevents the local rm from doing business on its own upon learning the technology. Speci cally, if the project is successful in the rst period, the foreign and local rms get X 1 and R 1 X 1, respectively. In the second period, regardless of whether or not the local rm has learned the technology, i.e., regardless of whether or not the foreign rm is needed to provide good technology, the foreign and the local rms get X 2 and R 2 X 2, respectively, if the project is successful. 12 We model foreign direct investment as a team moral hazard problem; we would like to thank an anonymous referee for bringing the existing literature to our attention. Holmström (1982) shows that the rst-best outcome can be achieved if contingent violation of the team s budget constraint is allowed and credibly implemented by an outsider who receives the di erence between the total surplus and payo s to the team members. The incentive schemes for achieving rst-best outcomes require the team members to post bonds. Such schemes may not be feasible for foreign direct investment in developing countries in which the local rms face initial capital constraints. The literature also establishes the solution to the team moral hazard problem if the game is repeated inde nitely. Our paper studies scenarios in which weak contract enforcement and poor protection of intellectual property rights make it practically impossible for the foreign and local rms to cooperate inde nitely. 8

9 The di erence between binding and non-binding contracts lies in the rms secondperiod payo s. Under the binding contracts, the foreign rm always gets X 2, even if the local rm has learned the technology in the rst period and the foreign rm s e ort is no longer needed in the second period. In contrast, under the non-binding contracts, the foreign rm gets X 2 only when the local rm has not learned the technology in the rst period and the foreign rm s e ort is still needed in the second period. Clearly, binding contracts require contract enforcement whereas non-binding contracts do not. 3. Non-Binding Contracts 3.1. E ort Choices To derive the equilibrium non-binding contract, we analyze rst the choice of e orts by the two rms for a given contract (X 1, R 1 X 1 ; X 2, R 2 X 2 ). In the second period, if the local rm has learned the technology, the success of the project depends only on the local rm s e ort. Under non-binding contracts, the local rm will choose to work on its own to capture all the revenue. The local rm chooses e 2 to maximize its second-period pro t: 13 π 2,F max e 2 0 e 2R 2 c(e 2 ), where c(e 2 ) = β 1+β 1+β e β 2. The rst-order condition is R 2 = c 0 (e 2 ) = e 1 β 2, which yields e 2,F = Rβ 2, π 2,F = β (e 2,F ) 1+β β. This solution will be shown to be the rst-best solution, so it is denoted by the subscript F. If the local rm has not learned the technology, it may be bene cial for both rms to continue the cooperation in the second period. Speci cally, given the foreign rm s e ort E 2, the local rm chooses an e ort to maximize its second-period pro t: ^π 2 max e 2 0 e 2E 2 (R 2 X 2 ) c(e 2 ), (3.1) 13 Throughout this paper, we use π i to denote the local rm s pro t in period i and i to denote the foreign rm s pro t in period i. 9

10 which yields 8 < [E 2 (R 2 X 2 )] β, if X 2 R 2, ^e 2 = : 0, otherwise, ^π 2 = 1 1+β 1 + β ^e β 2. On the other hand, given the local rm s e ort e 2, the foreign rm s expected pro t is 2 = E 2 (e 2 X 2 C 2 ). The foreign rm would provide good technology, ^E2 = 1, if and only if e 2 X 2 C 2 0, otherwise ^E 2 = 0. Thus, there are two possible Nash equilibria, depending on parameter values (R 2, β, C 2 ) and X 2. If X 2 R 2, and (3.2a) (R 2 X 2 ) β X 2 C 2 0, (3.2b) the Nash equilibrium is ^E 2 = 1, ^e 2 = (R 2 X 2 ) β (3.3) with ^ 2 = ^e 2 X 2 C 2, ^π 2 = 1 1+β 1 + β ^e β 2 ; otherwise the Nash equilibrium is ^E 2 = 0 and ^e 2 = 0, with ^ 2 = 0 and ^π 2 = 0. The local and foreign rms choose their e orts noncooperatively and simultaneously, and their e ort levels depend critically on the above conditions. When the conditions are satis ed, the foreign rm has the incentive to provide the good technology and the local rm puts in positive e ort. When the condition is not satis ed, the foreign rm does not provide the good technology and the local rm abandons the project, i.e., there is no cooperation in the second period. In the rst period, the foreign and local rms again choose their e orts simultaneously. Speci cally, given the foreign rm s e ort E 1, the local rm chooses e ort to maximize total pro t: ^π N max e 1 0 e 1E 1 (R 1 X 1 ) c(e 1 ) + δ ke 1 E 1 π 2,F + (1 ke 1E 1 )^π 2, (3.4) where ke 1 E 1 is the probability that the local rm has learned the technology in the rst period, and δ is the discount factor. Here, the subscript N is used to denote the non-binding contract. The solution of (3.4) is: 8 < E1 R1 X 1 + kδ(π 2,F ^e 1 = ^π 2) ª β, if X1 R 1 + kδ(π 2,F ^π 2), : 0, otherwise, 10

11 and ^π N = ^π 1 + δ^π 2, where ^π β 1 + β ^e β 1. On the other hand, given the local rm s e ort e 1, the foreign rm has expected total pro t N = E 1 (e 1 X 1 C 1 ) + δ(1 ke 1 E 1 )^ 2, where E 1 (e 1 X 1 C 1 ) is the foreign rm s expected pro t in the rst period and ^ 2 is the foreign rm s pro t in the second period if the local rm has not learned the technology (with probability 1 ke 1 E 1 ). The foreign rm will provide the good technology, i.e., choose ^E 1 = 1 as opposed to ^E 1 = 0, if and only if or e 1 X 1 C 1 + δ(1 ke 1 )^ 2 δ ^ 2, e 1 (X 1 δk ^ 2 ) C 1 0. Again, there are two possible Nash equilibria, depending on parameter values (R 1, R 2, β, C 1, C 2 ) and X 1. If X 1 R 1 + kδ(π 2,F ^π 2), and (3.5a) R1 X 1 + kδ(π 2,F ^π 2 ) β (X1 δk ^ 2 ) C 1 0, (3.5b) then the Nash equilibrium is ^E 1 = 1, ^e 1 = R 1 X 1 + kδ(π 2,F ^π 2) β, (3.6) with ^ N = ^e 1 X 1 C 1 + δ(1 k^e 1 )^ 2, ^π N = ^π 1 + δ^π 2 ; otherwise the Nash equilibrium is ^E 1 = 0 and ^e 1 = 0, with ^ N = δ ^ 2 and ^π N = δ^π 2. When conditions (3.5a) and (3.5b) do not hold, neither rm has the incentive to cooperate in the rst period. However, the two rms may still cooperate in the second period, as speci ed in (3.1) through (3.3). Thus, the rms total pro ts are not necessarily zero Contract Design We now analyze the design of the contract (X 1, R 1 X 1 ; X 2, R 2 X 2 ) to maximize the foreign rm s pro t. Under conditions (3.2a), (3.2b), (3.5a) and (3.5b), which imply Nash equilibrium e orts of (3.3) in the second period and Nash equilibrium e orts of (3.6) in the rst period, the foreign rm solves: N max X 1, X 2 2( 1, 1) ^e 1X 1 C 1 + δ(1 k^e 1 )^ 2 11

12 which yields: where X 1,N = 1 R1 + kδ(π 2,F 1 + β π 2 + β 2 ), X 2 = R β, µ β µ β e 1,N = β R1 + kδ(π 2,F 1 + β π 2 2 ) β, e βr2 2 =, 1 + β E 1 = 1, E 2 = 1, π N = π 1,N + δπ 2, N = 1,N + δ 2, π 1,N β (e 1,N ) 1+β β, π β (e 2 ) 1+β β, 1,N 1 β (e 1,N ) 1+β β C1, 2 1 β (e 2 ) 1+β β C2. Under the optimal choice of X 1 and X 2, constraints (3.2a) and (3.5a) are automatically satis ed. Constraints (3.5b) and (3.2b) are equivalent to 1,N 0 and 2 0, respectively, which de ne a feasible set of (R 1, R 2, β, C 1, C 2 ) for the equilibrium nonbinding contract. If either 1,N < 0 or 2 < 0, there will be no cooperation in either the rst period or the second period. These cases will be dealt with in Section 5.1. In summary, Lemma 1. Non-binding Contract If 1,N 0 and 2 0, there exists an equilibrium non-binding share contract (X 1,N, R 1 X 1,N ; X 2, R 2 X 2 ) with e orts e 1,N, e 2, E 1, E 2 and pro ts π N and N. The foreign rm s expected rst-period pro t is e 1,N X 1,N C 1 = 1,N + δke 1,N 2, and its expected discounted second-period pro t is δ 2 δke 1,N 2. As δke 1,N 2 is the foreign rm s expected second-period loss from learning, 1,N and 2 can be interpreted as the learning-free pro ts. Thus, under the equilibrium non-binding contract, the foreign rm extracts a larger revenue share in the rst period to compensate for its expected second-period loss from learning. Notice that, in the rst period, the local rm s payment to the foreign rm may exceed the total revenue (X 1,N > R 1) when the local rm learns fast (with a large k). Hence, the local rm may need liquidity to pay the foreign rm in the rst period. Compared with borrowing money to pay a franchise fee for a technology of uncertain quality, it should be easier if the revenue is realized in the rst period and more revenue is expected in the second period. 12

13 4. Binding Contracts 4.1. E ort Choices To derive the equilibrium binding contract, we analyze rst the choice of e orts by the two rms for a given contract (X 1, R 1 X 1 ; X 2, R 2 X 2 ). In the second period, if the local rm has learned the technology, the success of the project depends only on its own e ort. However, as the contract is binding, the local rm only receives a share of the revenue R 2 X 2. The local rm thus solves: ^π 0 2 = max e 2 0 e 2(R 2 X 2 ) c(e 2 ), which gives 8 < (R ^e 0 2 X 2 ) β, if X 2 R 2, 2 = : 0, otherwise, ^π 0 2 = β (^e0 2) 1+β β. As the foreign rm does not need to provide the technology, 14 its second-period pro t is ^ 0 2 = ^e0 2 X 2. If the local rm has not learned the technology, the success of the project depends on both rms e orts. The analysis is the same as Section 3.1, with the outcomes given by ^e 2, ^E2, ^π 2 and ^ In the rst period, given the foreign rm s e ort E 1, the local rm chooses an e ort to maximize its total pro t: which yields ^π B max e 1 0 e 1E 1 (R 1 X 1 ) c(e 1 ) + δ[ke 1 E 1^π (1 ke 1E 1 )^π 2 ], 8 < [E 1 (R 1 X 1 ) + δke 1 (^π 0 2 ^e 1 = ^π 2)] β, if X 1 R 1 + δk(^π 0 2 ^π 2), : 0, otherwise, and ^π B = ^π 1 + δ^π 2, where ^π β 1+β β ^e Under our speci cation of the local rm s payo, the local rm has no interest in requesting unnecessary e ort from the foreign rm. 15 Note that ^π 0 2 and ^π 2 have same mathematical formula. However, the former is always obtainable while the latter depends on the conditions (3.2a) and (3.2b). 13

14 Here, the subscript B is used to denote the binding contract. On the other hand, given the local rm s e ort e 1, the foreign rm has expected total pro t given by: i B = E 1 (e 1 X 1 C 1 ) + δ hke 1 E 1 ^ 02 + (1 ke 1 E 1 )^ 2, where E 1 (e 1 X 1 C 1 ) is the foreign rm s expected pro t in the rst period, ^ 0 2 = ^e 0 2X 2 is the foreign rm s pro t in the second period if the local rm has learned the technology (with probability ke 1 E 1 ), and ^ 2 = ^E 2 (^e 2 X 2 C 2 ) is the foreign rm s pro t in the second period if the local rm has not learned the technology (with probability 1 ke 1 E 1 ). The foreign rm will provide the good technology, i.e., choose ^E 1 = 1 as opposed to ^E 1 = 0, if and only if i e 1 X 1 C 1 + δ hke 1 ^ 02 + (1 ke 1 )^ 2 δ ^ 2, or e 1 [X 1 + δk(^ 0 2 ^ 2 )] C 1 0. Again, there are two possible Nash equilibria, depending on parameter values (R 1, R 2, β, C 1, C 2 ) and X 1 and X 2. If X 1 R 1 + δk(^π 0 2 ^π 2 ), and (4.1a) (R 1 X 1 ) β [X 1 + δk(^ 0 2 ^ 2 )] C 1 0, (4.1b) the Nash equilibrium is ^E 1 = 1, ^e 1 = (R 1 X 1 ) β, (4.2) with i ^ B = ^e 1 X 1 C 1 + δ hk^e 1 ^ 02 + (1 k^e 1 )^ 2, ^π B = ^π 1 + δ^π 2 ; otherwise the Nash equilibrium is ^E 1 = 0 and ^e 1 = 0, i.e., there is no cooperation in the rst period Contract Design We now analyze the design of the contract (X 1, R 1 X 1 ; X 2, R 2 X 2 ) to maximize the foreign rm s total pro t. Under conditions (3.2a), (3.2b), (4.1a) and (4.1b), which imply Nash equilibrium e orts of (3.3) in the second period and Nash equilibrium e orts of (4.2) in the rst period, the foreign rm solves: i B max ^e 1X 1 C 1 + δ hk^e 1 ^ 02 + (1 k^e 1 )^ 2 X 1, X 2 2( 1, 1) 14

15 which yields: X 1,B = R 1 kδβc 2, 1 + β X 2,B = X 2, µ β β e 1,B = (R 1 + kδc 2 ) β, 1 + β e 2,B = e 2, E 1 = 1, E 2 = 1, π B = π 1,B + δπ 2, B = 1,B + δ 2, where π 2, e 2, X 2 and 2 are de ned in Lemma 1, and π 1,B β (e 1,B) 1+β β, 1,B 1 β (e 1,B) 1+β β C 1. Under the optimal choice of X 1 and X 2, constraints (3.2a) and (4.1a) are automatically satis ed. Constraints (4.1b) and (3.2b) are equivalent to 1,B 0 and 2 0, respectively, which de ne a feasible set of (R 1, R 2, β, C 1, C 2 ) for the equilibrium binding contract. If either 1,B < 0 or 2 < 0, there will be no cooperation in either the rst period or the second period. These cases will be dealt with in Section 5.1. In summary, Lemma 2. Binding Contract If 1,B 0 and 2 0, there exists an equilibrium binding contract (X 1,B, R 1 X 1,B ; X 2, R 2 X 2) with e orts e 1,B, e 2, E 1, E 2 and pro ts π B and B. Here, the foreign rm s expected rst-period pro t is e 1,B X 1,B C 1 = 1,B δke 1,B C 2, and its expected second-period pro t is δ 2 + δke 1,B C 2. As δke 1,B C 2 is the foreign rm s expected second-period gain from learning, 1,B and 2 can be interpreted as the learning-free pro ts. That is, under the equilibrium binding contract, the foreign rm reduces its rst-period revenue share by the amount of its expected second-period gain from learning. 5. The Dominant Contract This section investigates the rms contractual preferences, given any combination of parameter values. To do that, we rst discuss the possibility of one-period contracts and the characteristics of the rst-best solution. 15

16 5.1. One-Period Contracts As shown in Lemmas 1 and 2, there exist equilibrium two-period binding and nonbinding contracts if 2 0, 1,N 0 and 1,B 0. However, under those conditions, it is also feasible for the rms to cooperate in one period but not in the other. We call such a contractual relation a one-period contract. Moreover, when the above conditions fail, one-period contracts prevail except in a special case where no contract exists. Lemma 3. One-Period Contracts (i) If 1st 0, there exists an equilibrium one-period contract (X 1,1st, R 1 X 1,1st) in the rst period with e orts e 1,1st and E 1,1st and pro ts π 1st and 1st, where X 1,1st = R β + kδ 1 + β π 2,F, e 1,1st = µ βr1 1 + β + kδβ 1 + β π 2,F E 1,1st = 1, π 1st = β (e 1,1st ) 1+β β, 1st = 1 β (e 1,1st ) 1+β β C 1, β, and π 2,F is de ned in Section 3.1. (ii) If 2 0, there exists an equilibrium one-period contract (X 2, R 2 X 2) in the second period with e orts e 2 and E 2 and pro ts π 2 and 2, where X 2, e 2, E 2, π 2 and 2 are de ned in Lemma 1. The derivations of these two contracts, together with the parameter conditions, are similar to those in Section 3 or 4. Note that, in our model, the local rm needs to work with the foreign rm for one period in order to learn the technology, which means that contract enforcement is unnecessary for implementing one-period contracts First-Best Solution The rst-best solution is considered here as the benchmark. The foreign rm is assumed to provide good technology when necessary and the local rm is assumed to 16

17 put forth rst-best e ort, thereby maximizing joint pro t. How the rms divide their total joint pro t is of no concern. Denote e 1,F (R 1 + δkc 2 ) β, e 1 (R 1 + δkπ 2,F )β, e 2,F = Rβ 2, and J 1,F β (e 1,F ) 1+β β C 1, J β (e 1) 1+β β C 1, J 2,F β (e 2,F ) 1+β β C 2. As will be shown, J 2,F is the joint pro t in the second period; and J 1,F pro t in the rst period if J 2,F 0, while J 1 is the joint is the joint pro t in the rst period if J 2,F < 0. Similarly, e 2,F is the local rm s second-period e ort; and e 1,F rm s rst-period e ort if J 2,F 0, while e 1 J 2,F < 0. is the local is the local rm s rst-period e ort if Lemma 4. First-Best Solution (a) If J 1,F 0 and J 2,F 0, the rst-best solution is a two-period cooperation with e orts e 1,F and e 2,F and total joint pro t J 1,F + δj 2,F. (b) If J 1,F < 0 and J 2,F 0, the rst-best solution is a one-period cooperation in the second period with e ort e 2,F and total joint pro t J 2,F. (c) If J 1 0 and J 2,F < 0, the rst-best solution is a one-period cooperation in the rst period with e ort e 1 and total joint pro t J 1. (d) If J 1 < 0 and J 2,F < 0, the rst-best solution is no cooperation. The second-period e orts of the share contracts are generally lower than in the rst-best solution because the local rm has to share revenue with the foreign rm. The exception is that, under the non-binding contract, the local rm can work on its own and apply the rst-best e ort if it learns the technology. The rst-period e orts of the share contracts are, however, not generally lower than in the rst-best solution. In expectation of a future pro t, the local rm has the incentive to learn the technology (under the non-binding contract) or it is given the incentive to work hard by the foreign rm (under the binding contract). In essence, e orts across periods under the share contracts are distorted by moral hazard. 17

18 5.3. Main Result Since e 1 and e 2 are part of the success probabilities, we need e 1 and e 2 to each be no greater than one. To guarantee this, we suggest two simple su cient, but not necessary, conditions in the following lemma. Lemma 5. If R 1 + C 2 1 and R 2 1, then e 1,N, e 1,B, e 1,1st, e 1, e 1,F, e 2,F, e 2 each no greater than one. are Let us now investigate the rms preferences over equilibrium binding, non-binding, and one-period contracts. We call a contract the dominant contract if it is preferred by both rms to all other contracts. Proposition 1. Dominant Contracts (1) If 1,N 0 and 2 0, the dominant contract is the non-binding contract in Lemma 1. (2) If 1,N < 0 but 2 0, the dominant contract is the one-period contract in the second period in Lemma 3. (3) If 1st 0 but 2 < 0, the dominant contract is the one-period contract in the rst period in Lemma 3. (4) If 1st < 0 and 2 < 0, there is no feasible contract. Proposition 1 establishes the rms preferences for all possible parameter values. That is, any combination (R 1, R 2, β, C 1, C 2 ) of parameter values will be in one of the four cases in Proposition 1. Proposition 1 shows that the dominant contract must be either the non-binding contract, case (1), or the one-period contracts, cases (2) and (3). Recall that neither non-binding contracts nor one-period contracts need contract enforcement. Therefore, Proposition 1 implies that contract enforcement is unnecessary for all parameter values. This may explain why FDI has not been deterred by weak or non-existent contract enforcement in some developing countries. It may also explain why a great deal of FDI, especially in the early stage of an economic transition, has been carried out under contractual forms in those countries. Example. By choosing three sets of parameter values corresponding to the rst three cases in Proposition 1, we calculate the dominant contracts: 18

19 Table 2. Dominant Contracts a Parameters R 1 = 0.7, R 2 = 0.9 b R 1 = 0.1, R 2 = 1 R 1 = 1, R 2 = 0.1 Non-Binding Contract One-Period Contract One-Period Contract e 1,N = 0.57 e 1,1st = 0.58 Dominant X 1,N = 0.67 X 1,1st = 0.68 Contract e 2 = 0.55 e 2 = 0.58 X 2 = 0.6 X 2 = 0.67 π N = 0.22 π 2 = 0.13 π 1st = 0.13 N = = st = 0.19 Conditions 1,N = 0.17, 2 = ,N = 0.11, 2 = st = 0.19, 2 = 0.29 a C 1 = 0.2, C 2 = 0.3, k = 0.7, δ = 0.9 and β = 0.5. b Under the same parameter values, the binding contract yields: e 1,B = 0.54, X 1,B = 0.40, e 2 = 0.55, X 2 = 0.6, π B = 0.21, B = Clearly, both rms get larger pro ts under the non-binding contract than under the binding contract. Remark 1. Simulations reveal that case (2) is likely to happen when R 2 /R 1 large, and case (3) is likely to happen when R 1 /R 2 is very is very large. The intermediate case is covered by case (1). The case with high relative costs C 1 /R 1 and C 2 /R 2 is covered by case (4). Remark 2. If the local rm is to write the contract, it will cooperate with the foreign rm only when it has not learned the technology and will o er the foreign rm revenue shares such that the expected revenue just covers the costs C 1 and C 2, under which it is in the foreign rm s own interest to provide good technology. The foreign rm will earn zero rent under both the equilibrium binding and non-binding contracts, whereas the local rm prefers the non-binding contract under the same conditions, 1,N 0 and 2 0, as in Proposition 1. Remark 3. We have also considered contingent contracts where the second-period revenue shares depend on the learning outcomes. Implementation of such contracts may involve less transaction costs than that of binding contracts. Even assuming same transaction costs for implementing all types of contracts, we nd that the equilibrium contingent contract is either the non-binding or one-period contract and it dominates the binding contract. Remark 4. A more general model has also been considered, in which p i = e α i Ea i, c(e i) = e γ i, φ = eβ 1 Eb 1, where α, β, γ, a, b > 0. All the results still hold under minor additional conditions. Hence, our conclusions are robust to di erent model speci cations. 19

20 6. Characteristics of CJVs To understand the dominance of the equilibrium non-binding contract, we now study its key characteristics in comparison with the equilibrium binding contract. Among others, we nd that the non-binding contract induces higher e ort incentive from the local rm than the binding contract does. Stylized facts of CJVs in China are presented along with the theoretical results and the implications for contract enforcement are discussed. We rst establish an equivalence result between binding and non-binding contracts when the possibility of learning is ruled out. Characteristic 1. No Learning Without learning, i.e., k = 0, the binding contract is identical to the non-binding contract, with X 1,N R 1 = X 1,B R 1 = X 2 R 2 = β ; e 1,N = e 1,B ; π N = π B, N = B. In this case, the local rm has to cooperate with the foreign rm in each period to carry out the project, and the foreign rm has to provide the technology in each period. Consequently, our two-period model degenerates into two consecutive, oneperiod models and the two rms are indi erent between the binding and non-binding contracts. Therefore, the presence of learning is crucial to contractual preferences in our model. The revenue shares in the presence of learning are characterized in the following. Characteristic 2. Patterns of Revenue Shares With Learning 1. The foreign rm s revenue shares in the second period are always the same under both the binding and non-binding contracts: X 2 R 2 = β. (6.1) 2. Across periods, under the non-binding contract, the foreign rm demands a larger revenue share in the rst period: X 1,N R 1 > X 2 R 2. (6.2) 20

21 3. However, under the binding contract, the foreign rm demands a smaller revenue share in the rst period: X 1,B R 1 < X 2 R 2. (6.3) In the second (or last) period, there are no future gains or losses from learning for either rm, no matter whether the cooperation is governed by the binding or the nonbinding contract. Thus, the second-period revenue shares need not be ne-tuned for the redistribution of pro ts so that they are the same for both contracts. However, in the rst period, there are potential future gains or losses from learning for both rms, depending on whether the cooperation is governed by the binding or the non-binding contract. While the foreign rm does not have direct control over its second-period gains or losses from learning, it can design contracts with optimal revenue shares for the redistribution of pro ts. Under the non-binding contract, the foreign rm may receive nothing in the second period. Thus, in the rst period, the foreign rm demands a larger revenue share. In particular, we can show that X 1,N = 1 1 β e β 1,N + kδ 2. This implies that, in the rst period, the foreign rm receives its expected second-period loss from learning, i.e., kδ 2, in addition to the learning-free share, i.e., 1 1 β e β 1,N In contrast, under the. binding contract, the foreign rm expects to gain from learning in the second period. Thus, in the rst period, the foreign rm accepts a smaller revenue share. In particular, we can show that X 1,B = 1 1 β e β 1,B kδc 2. This implies that, in the rst period, the foreign rm accepts less than the learning-free share. We would like to highlight that, under the non-binding contract, the revenue share for the foreign rm declines over the two periods of cooperation. 16 pattern does not depend on the cost ratio C 1 /C 2, revenue ratio R 1 /R 2 Notice that such a and the discount factor δ. 17 Interestingly, this theoretical result is consistent with the experience with CJVs in China (see Table 1). What is the underlying factor that determines the rms preferences over the two possible contracts? By comparing N with B and π N with π B, we have: 16 In the current model, learning has only two possible outcomes: learn or not learn. More realistically, learning is a continuous process that could be approximated by a sequence of small steps, e.g., learn 0% or 10% in the rst year, learn 10% or 20% in the second year, learn 20% or 30% in the third year, and so on. Our basic result holds for the more general case. 17 One might think the decreasing revenue share for the foreign rm is a direct consequence of its decreasing costs, and dismiss the result as trivial. Our analysis indicates that more fundamental reasons are responsible for the phenomenon. Indeed, even increasing costs will still imply decreasing revenue shares. 21

22 Characteristic 3. Contractual Preference Suppose k > 0. In the rst period, the local rm always chooses more e ort under the non-binding contract than under the binding contract, i.e., e 1,N > e 1,B. Characteristic 3 highlights the importance of learning as an incentive device. In our model of endogenous learning-by-doing, under the non-binding contract, the prospect of doing business on its own and capturing all future revenue gives the local rm an extra incentive to work hard in the rst period. On the other hand, the foreign rm can extract its expected second-period loss from learning in the rst period as illustrated by Characteristic 2. Because of the increased incentive for the local rm to provide e ort, both rms are better o under the non-binding contract. This rms contractual preference could also be understood in terms of a positive externality. Under the non-binding contract, the prospect of learning and implementing the foreign rm s technology motivates the local rm to work hard during the initial cooperative phase and increase total pro t, in general, and the foreign rm s pro t, in particular. In other words, a positive externality results from the non-binding contract in that the local rm s hard work to learn the technology also has the side e ect of increasing pro ts. However, such a positive externality does not arise under the equilibrium binding contract. The presence of an externality casts serious doubt on the popular policy view attributing a negative incentive for incoming FDI to an unsettled legal environment. An interesting feature of our results is that the preference for the non-binding contract is independent of the revenue ratio R 1 /R 2. This distinguishes our paper from the work of Anton and Yao (1994), who study how an innovator sells his (readily pro table) innovation in the absence of property rights. When dealing with a buyer, the innovator can always threaten to sell the innovation to another buyer and thus create a competitor in the output market. This threat is shown to guarantee some return from the innovation to the innovator when certain conditions concerning revenue are satis ed. In contrast, our results hold even if the foreign rm could contract with another local rm in the second period as represented by a smaller R 2 /R 1. Finally, it is interesting to probe the robustness of the rms contractual preference when it is easier for the local rm to learn the foreign rm s technology as represented by a larger k. Faster learning depends on the nature of the foreign rm s technology or know-how. Local rms may nd it easier to catch up in certain industries. Moreover, k could be a ected by the degree of contract enforcement. Interestingly, the following result shows that, with faster learning, the rms preference for the non-binding contract is strengthened further and the revenue share for the foreign rm declines faster across periods. 22

23 Characteristic 4. Contract Preference Under Faster Learning The pro t differences π N π B and N B di erences X 1,N R 1 X 2 R 2 and X 2 R 2 X 1,B R 1. increase as k increases as do the revenue share Intuitively, with a higher k, the local rm has even more incentive to work hard and learn the technology under the non-binding contract. The foreign rm, on the other hand, can demand an even greater revenue share in the rst period to compensate for its larger expected second-period loss from learning. Thus, both rms will prefer the non-binding contract because the induced positive externality is greater with faster learning. k. The last issue of interest is whether the rms will prefer faster learning, i.e., a larger Characteristic 5. Payo s Under Faster Learning non-binding contract, π N and N, increase as k increases. Both rms pro ts under the Our characterization of k addresses an important issue: the protection of intellectual property rights (IPRs). The impact of IPR protection on FDI has not been examined theoretically until recently. 18 While poor protection of IPRs in developing countries is thought to deter inward FDI, empirical evidence has been inconclusive. In fact, countries in Latin America and East Asia that o er only limited protection of IPRs were the most active places for FDI in the 1980s. 19 In our model, the incentive to learn may be a ected adversely by the protection of IPRs. Characteristic 5 suggests that even the foreign rm prefers less protection of IPRs. Notice that this conclusion relies heavily on a key feature in our model, i.e., a time lag for learning the technology. In our model, the acquisition of foreign technology requires cooperation and sharing of pro ts with the foreign rm in the rst period. The time lag is enough for the foreign rm to compensate for its potential loss of IPRs. Therefore, on balance, the foreign rm prefers compensation by larger initial revenue shares, which have less adverse effect on the local rm s incentive to work, than compensation from future revenues by legal protection. 18 See, for examples, Chin and Grossman (1990) and Diwan and Rodrik (1991), who show that developed and developing countries have di erent preferences concerning IPR protection. 19 The economic environment in a developing country, including cost conditions, market size, quality of work force, infrastructure and macroeconomic conditions, is found to be an important factor determining inward FDI, whereas regulations on FDI are not found to be important factors (United Nations Publication, 1993). 23

24 7. Concluding Remarks Our model addresses a realistic and timely issue of FDI: by cooperating with a foreign rm, a local rm can master new technology and then do business on its own. The non-binding contract is shown to be preferred by both the foreign and the local rm, which implies that neither enforcement of binding contracts nor protection of IPRs is a prerequisite for FDI. Thus, our model can explain the puzzle that signi cant FDI has been carried out under contractual forms in developing countries in which protection of IPRs is weak and contract enforcement is problematic. It also con rms some stylized facts about CJVs including their widespread use in the early stage of an economic transition as is the case in contemporary China. It is interesting to point out that there is little variation among the Visegrad countries (i.e., Poland, Hungary, the Czech Republic and Slovakia) in contract enforcement but much variation in FDI (Peitsch, 1995). Di erences in FDI ow may be due to political and economic stability as well as market size. Those factors can be, to some extent, re ected in the relative sizes of R 1 and R 2 in our model; the prediction of our model for various R 1 /R 2 seems consistent with the above facts. However, the policy implications of our theoretical results for the Visegrad countries depend on careful empirical study of FDI in those countries. Finally, we expect that our model is suitable only for the early stage of an economic transition during which foreign rms know-how and technologies are easy to learn on the one hand, and local rms are given exclusive access to certain inputs and resources by their governments on the other hand. At that stage, learning by doing is an important factor, perhaps the dominant factor, a ecting local rm s incentives. 20 As an economy develops, more sophisticated know-how and technology will be involved, and many other factors will become important. Strict contract enforcement may thus be necessary for the later stage of an economic transition. References [1] Anton, James J., and Yao, Dennis A., Expropriation and Inventions: Appropriable Rents in the Absence of Property Rights. American Economic Review 84, 1: , March For example, the Chinese government recently chose General Motors over Ford in a large joint venture project, simply because General Motors agreed to transfer more technology and thus provide more chances for the local company to learn the technology. 24

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking (preliminary draft) Ying Syuan Li National Taiwan University Yiting Li National Taiwan University April 2009 Abstract We consider an economy where people have the needs

More information

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics ISSN 974-40 (on line edition) ISSN 594-7645 (print edition) WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY

More information

Sequential Decision-making and Asymmetric Equilibria: An Application to Takeovers

Sequential Decision-making and Asymmetric Equilibria: An Application to Takeovers Sequential Decision-making and Asymmetric Equilibria: An Application to Takeovers David Gill Daniel Sgroi 1 Nu eld College, Churchill College University of Oxford & Department of Applied Economics, University

More information

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Economic Theory 14, 247±253 (1999) Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Christopher M. Snyder Department of Economics, George Washington University, 2201 G Street

More information

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model Guido Ascari University of Pavia Nicola Branzoli University of Pavia October 27, 2006 Abstract This note shows that full price indexation

More information

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation Edgar A. Ghossoub The University of Texas at San Antonio Abstract Most studies that use an overlapping generations setting assume complete depreciation

More information

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017 For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market June 017 This appendix contains the proofs and additional analyses that we mention in paper but that

More information

Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers

Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers Vasileios Zikos University of Surrey Dusanee Kesavayuth y University of Chicago-UTCC Research Center

More information

A Multitask Model without Any Externalities

A Multitask Model without Any Externalities A Multitask Model without Any Externalities Kazuya Kamiya and Meg Sato Crawford School Research aper No 6 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1899382 A Multitask Model without Any Externalities

More information

Dynamic games with incomplete information

Dynamic games with incomplete information Dynamic games with incomplete information Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium (PBE) We have now covered static and dynamic games of complete information and static games of incomplete information. The next step

More information

Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management

Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management Douglas W. Blackburn Fordham University Andrey D. Ukhov Indiana University 17 October 2007 Abstract Research on executive compensation has been unable

More information

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Henrik Horn (Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm) Giovanni Maggi (Princeton University) Robert W. Staiger (Stanford University and

More information

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1 Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose,

More information

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam Dirk Bergemann Department of Economics Yale University Microeconomic Theory (50b) Comprehensive Exam. (5) Consider a moral hazard model where a worker chooses an e ort level e [0; ]; and as a result, either

More information

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters Khaled Bennour 2006 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7233/ MPRA Paper No. 7233, posted. September

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus Summer 2009 examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2008/2009 syllabus Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours. This paper contains nine questions in three sections. Answer question one

More information

SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS

SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS Question : Answers should recognize that this result does not hold when there are search frictions in the labour market. The proof should follow a simple matching

More information

Simple e ciency-wage model

Simple e ciency-wage model 18 Unemployment Why do we have involuntary unemployment? Why are wages higher than in the competitive market clearing level? Why is it so hard do adjust (nominal) wages down? Three answers: E ciency wages:

More information

Security Design Under Routine Auditing

Security Design Under Routine Auditing Security Design Under Routine Auditing Liang Dai May 3, 2016 Abstract Investors usually hire independent rms routinely to audit companies in which they invest. The e ort involved in auditing is set upfront

More information

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not Chapter 11 Information Exercise 11.1 A rm sells a single good to a group of customers. Each customer either buys zero or exactly one unit of the good; the good cannot be divided or resold. However, it

More information

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. 1 Oligopoly The key feature of the oligopoly (and to some extent, the monopolistically competitive market) market structure is that one rm

More information

How Do Exporters Respond to Antidumping Investigations?

How Do Exporters Respond to Antidumping Investigations? How Do Exporters Respond to Antidumping Investigations? Yi Lu a, Zhigang Tao b and Yan Zhang b a National University of Singapore, b University of Hong Kong March 2013 Lu, Tao, Zhang (NUS, HKU) How Do

More information

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Sta Report November 2009 Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies Harris Schlesinger Department of Finance, University of Alabama, USA Center of Finance & Econometrics, University of Konstanz, Germany E-mail: hschlesi@cba.ua.edu

More information

Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers

Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers Elif Incekara y Department of Economics, Pennsylvania State University June 006 Abstract In this paper, we show that the consumer might be unresponsive

More information

1 Unemployment Insurance

1 Unemployment Insurance 1 Unemployment Insurance 1.1 Introduction Unemployment Insurance (UI) is a federal program that is adminstered by the states in which taxes are used to pay for bene ts to workers laid o by rms. UI started

More information

Quality, Upgrades, and Equilibrium in a Dynamic Monopoly Model

Quality, Upgrades, and Equilibrium in a Dynamic Monopoly Model Quality, Upgrades, and Equilibrium in a Dynamic Monopoly Model James Anton and Gary Biglaiser Duke and UNC November 5, 2010 1 / 37 Introduction What do we know about dynamic durable goods monopoly? Most

More information

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Some Notes on Timing in Games Some Notes on Timing in Games John Morgan University of California, Berkeley The Main Result If given the chance, it is better to move rst than to move at the same time as others; that is IGOUGO > WEGO

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY Summer 2011 Examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours + 10 minutes reading time. This paper contains seven questions in three

More information

Problem Set # Public Economics

Problem Set # Public Economics Problem Set #3 14.41 Public Economics DUE: October 29, 2010 1 Social Security DIscuss the validity of the following claims about Social Security. Determine whether each claim is True or False and present

More information

Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities

Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities Alberto Galasso September 2, 2007 Abstract Building on Genicot and Ray (2006) we develop a model of non-cooperative bargaining that combines

More information

Econ 277A: Economic Development I. Final Exam (06 May 2012)

Econ 277A: Economic Development I. Final Exam (06 May 2012) Econ 277A: Economic Development I Semester II, 2011-12 Tridip Ray ISI, Delhi Final Exam (06 May 2012) There are 2 questions; you have to answer both of them. You have 3 hours to write this exam. 1. [30

More information

Income-Based Price Subsidies, Parallel Imports and Markets Access to New Drugs for the Poor

Income-Based Price Subsidies, Parallel Imports and Markets Access to New Drugs for the Poor Income-Based Price Subsidies, Parallel Imports and Markets Access to New Drugs for the Poor Rajat Acharyya y and María D. C. García-Alonso z December 2008 Abstract In health markets, government policies

More information

Reference Dependence Lecture 3

Reference Dependence Lecture 3 Reference Dependence Lecture 3 Mark Dean Princeton University - Behavioral Economics The Story So Far De ned reference dependent behavior and given examples Change in risk attitudes Endowment e ect Status

More information

N-Player Preemption Games

N-Player Preemption Games N-Player Preemption Games Rossella Argenziano Essex Philipp Schmidt-Dengler LSE October 2007 Argenziano, Schmidt-Dengler (Essex, LSE) N-Player Preemption Games Leicester October 2007 1 / 42 Timing Games

More information

Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version

Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version Andreea Cosnita and Jean-Philippe Tropeano y Abstract We develop a theoretical model to compare the current ex post

More information

Optimal Organization of Financial Intermediaries

Optimal Organization of Financial Intermediaries Optimal Organization of Financial Intermediaries Spiros Bougheas Tianxi Wang CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 5452 CATEGORY 7: MONETARY POLICY AND INTERNATIONAL FINANCE JULY 2015 An electronic version of the paper

More information

Size and Focus of a Venture Capitalist s Portfolio

Size and Focus of a Venture Capitalist s Portfolio Size and Focus of a enture Capitalist s Portfolio Paolo Fulghieri University of North Carolina paolo_fulghieriunc.edu Merih Sevilir University of North Carolina merih_sevilirunc.edu October 30, 006 We

More information

Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments

Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments 1 Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments David C. Mills, Jr. 1 Federal Reserve Board Washington, DC E-mail: david.c.mills@frb.gov Version: May 004 I explore

More information

For Online Publication Only. ONLINE APPENDIX for. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

For Online Publication Only. ONLINE APPENDIX for. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market For Online Publication Only ONLINE APPENDIX for Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market By: Thierry Foucault (HEC, Paris) and Laurent Frésard (University of Maryland) January 2016 This appendix

More information

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth Florian Misch a, Norman Gemmell a;b and Richard Kneller a a University of Nottingham; b The Treasury, New Zealand March

More information

Strategic Pre-Commitment

Strategic Pre-Commitment Strategic Pre-Commitment Felix Munoz-Garcia EconS 424 - Strategy and Game Theory Washington State University Strategic Commitment Limiting our own future options does not seem like a good idea. However,

More information

The Economics of State Capacity. Weak States and Strong States. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th 2008.

The Economics of State Capacity. Weak States and Strong States. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th 2008. The Economics of State Capacity Weak States and Strong States Ely Lectures Johns Hopkins University April 14th-18th 2008 Tim Besley LSE Lecture 2: Yesterday, I laid out a framework for thinking about the

More information

Monetary Economics. Chapter 5: Properties of Money. Prof. Aleksander Berentsen. University of Basel

Monetary Economics. Chapter 5: Properties of Money. Prof. Aleksander Berentsen. University of Basel Monetary Economics Chapter 5: Properties of Money Prof. Aleksander Berentsen University of Basel Ed Nosal and Guillaume Rocheteau Money, Payments, and Liquidity - Chapter 5 1 / 40 Structure of this chapter

More information

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University WORKING PAPER NO. 11-4 OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University Daniel R. Sanches Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia December 2010 Optimal

More information

Exclusive Contracts, Innovation, and Welfare

Exclusive Contracts, Innovation, and Welfare Exclusive Contracts, Innovation, and Welfare by Yongmin Chen* and David E. M. Sappington** Abstract We extend Aghion and Bolton (1987) s classic model to analyze the equilibrium incidence and impact of

More information

Optimal Progressivity

Optimal Progressivity Optimal Progressivity To this point, we have assumed that all individuals are the same. To consider the distributional impact of the tax system, we will have to alter that assumption. We have seen that

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Online Appendix for Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Giacomo Rodano Bank of Italy Nicolas Serrano-Velarde Bocconi University December 23, 2014 Emanuele Tarantino University of Mannheim 1 1 Reorganization,

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice 1. MWG - Decisive Subgroups Recall proposition 21.C.1: (Arrow s Impossibility Theorem) Suppose that the number of alternatives is at least

More information

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation Pai-Ling Yin First Draft: October 2002 This Draft: June 2005 Abstract This paper proposes tests to empirically examine whether auction prices aggregate information

More information

The Economics of State Capacity. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th Tim Besley LSE

The Economics of State Capacity. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th Tim Besley LSE The Economics of State Capacity Ely Lectures Johns Hopkins University April 14th-18th 2008 Tim Besley LSE The Big Questions Economists who study public policy and markets begin by assuming that governments

More information

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin 4.454 - Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin Juan Pablo Xandri Antuna 4/22/20 Setup Continuum of consumers, mass of individuals each endowed with one unit of currency. t = 0; ; 2

More information

The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role. of Fiscal Policy Revisited

The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role. of Fiscal Policy Revisited The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role of Fiscal Policy Revisited Santanu Chatterjee y Department of Economics University of Georgia Sugata Ghosh z Department of Economics and Finance

More information

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and investment is central to understanding the business

More information

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation Ed Nosal December 2008 Abstract An increase in in ation will cause people to hold less real balances and may cause them to speed up their spending.

More information

Income Distribution and Growth under A Synthesis Model of Endogenous and Neoclassical Growth

Income Distribution and Growth under A Synthesis Model of Endogenous and Neoclassical Growth KIM Se-Jik This paper develops a growth model which can explain the change in the balanced growth path from a sustained growth to a zero growth path as a regime shift from endogenous growth to Neoclassical

More information

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Christopher Phelan Working Paper 676 December 2009 Phelan: University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve

More information

One Sided Access in Two-Sided Markets

One Sided Access in Two-Sided Markets One Sided Access in Two-Sided Markets Marianne Verdier y August 26, 2013 Abstract In this paper, I analyze the incentives of a monopolistic platform to open its infrastructure to an entrant on the buyer

More information

Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives

Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives THE WORLD BANK WORKSHOP Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives Session IV Presentation Sectoral Infrastructure Investment in an Unbalanced Growing Economy: The Case of India Chetan

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Liability and Reputation in Credence Goods Markets

Liability and Reputation in Credence Goods Markets Liability and Reputation in Credence Goods Markets Yuk-fai Fong 1 Ting Liu 2 Jan. 2018 Abstract This paper studies the impact of liability on a credence-good seller s incentives to maintain a good reputation.

More information

Internal Financing, Managerial Compensation and Multiple Tasks

Internal Financing, Managerial Compensation and Multiple Tasks Internal Financing, Managerial Compensation and Multiple Tasks Working Paper 08-03 SANDRO BRUSCO, FAUSTO PANUNZI April 4, 08 Internal Financing, Managerial Compensation and Multiple Tasks Sandro Brusco

More information

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS 5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS We studied how individual consumers and rms behave in Part I of the book. In Part II of the book, we studied how individual economic agents make decisions when there are strategic

More information

Optimal Unemployment Bene ts Policy and the Firm Productivity Distribution

Optimal Unemployment Bene ts Policy and the Firm Productivity Distribution Optimal Unemployment Bene ts Policy and the Firm Productivity Distribution Tomer Blumkin and Leif Danziger, y Ben-Gurion University Eran Yashiv, z Tel Aviv University January 10, 2014 Abstract This paper

More information

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from: Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ On the Implementation of Markov-Perfect Monetary Policy Michael Dotsey y and Andreas Hornstein

More information

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default 0.287/MSOM.070.099ec Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default Robert Swinney Serguei Netessine The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, 904

More information

Endogenous Protection: Lobbying

Endogenous Protection: Lobbying Endogenous Protection: Lobbying Matilde Bombardini UBC January 20, 2011 Bombardini (UBC) Endogenous Protection January 20, 2011 1 / 24 Protection for sale Grossman and Helpman (1994) Protection for Sale

More information

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry Lin, Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 7(2), December 2014, 17-31 17 Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically

More information

Emissions Trading in Forward and Spot Markets of Electricity

Emissions Trading in Forward and Spot Markets of Electricity Emissions Trading in Forward and Spot Markets of Electricity Makoto Tanaka May, 2009 Abstract In recent years there has been growing discussion regarding market designs of emissions allowances trading.

More information

Strategic information acquisition and the. mitigation of global warming

Strategic information acquisition and the. mitigation of global warming Strategic information acquisition and the mitigation of global warming Florian Morath WZB and Free University of Berlin October 15, 2009 Correspondence address: Social Science Research Center Berlin (WZB),

More information

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 26/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case

More information

Ownership Concentration, Monitoring and Optimal Board Structure

Ownership Concentration, Monitoring and Optimal Board Structure Ownership Concentration, Monitoring and Optimal Board Structure Clara Graziano and Annalisa Luporini y This version: September 30, 2005 z Abstract The paper analyzes the optimal structure of the board

More information

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result Arantza Gorostiaga Rubio-Ramírez Juan F. Universidad del País Vasco Duke University and Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Abstract

More information

the Gain on Home A Note Bias and Tel: +27 Working April 2016

the Gain on Home A Note Bias and Tel: +27 Working April 2016 University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series A Note on Home Bias and the Gain from Non-Preferential Taxation Kaushal Kishore University of Pretoria Working Paper: 206-32 April 206

More information

Monetary credibility problems. 1. In ation and discretionary monetary policy. 2. Reputational solution to credibility problems

Monetary credibility problems. 1. In ation and discretionary monetary policy. 2. Reputational solution to credibility problems Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 2/4 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Monetary credibility problems 1. In ation and discretionary monetary policy 2. Reputational solution

More information

Liquidity, moral hazard and bank runs

Liquidity, moral hazard and bank runs Liquidity, moral hazard and bank runs S.Chatterji and S.Ghosal, Centro de Investigacion Economica, ITAM, and University of Warwick September 3, 2007 Abstract In a model of banking with moral hazard, e

More information

Institutional Quality and International Trade

Institutional Quality and International Trade Institutional Quality and International Trade Levchenko: Review of Economic Studies (2007) PhD: International Trade & Institutions Alireza Naghavi () Institutional Quality and International Trade PhD:

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

Career Concern, Raiders and Disclosure Policy

Career Concern, Raiders and Disclosure Policy Career Concern, Raiders and Disclosure Policy Wonsuk, Chung Indiana University - Bloomington 16th April 2009 Abstract Agents has to worry about not only his incentives but also his future career. Employer

More information

The New Growth Theories - Week 6

The New Growth Theories - Week 6 The New Growth Theories - Week 6 ECON1910 - Poverty and distribution in developing countries Readings: Ray chapter 4 8. February 2011 (Readings: Ray chapter 4) The New Growth Theories - Week 6 8. February

More information

Signaling Concerns and IMF Contingent Credit Lines

Signaling Concerns and IMF Contingent Credit Lines Signaling Concerns and IMF Contingent Credit ines Nicolas Arregui July 15, 2010 JOB MARKET PAPER Abstract Emerging market economies are exposed to signi cant macroeconomic risk. International reserves

More information

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D by Eytan Sheshinski* (Contribution to the Baumol Conference Book) March 2005 * Department of Economics, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, ISRAEL.

More information

A New Regulatory Tool

A New Regulatory Tool A New Regulatory Tool William C. Bunting Ph.D. Candidate, Yale University Law and Economics Fellow, NYU School of Law January 8, 2007 Fill in later. Abstract 1 Introduction Shavell (1984) provides a seminal

More information

Black Markets and Pre-Reform Crises in Former Socialist Economies

Black Markets and Pre-Reform Crises in Former Socialist Economies Black Markets and Pre-Reform Crises in Former Socialist Economies Michael Alexeev Lyaziza Sabyr y June 2000 Abstract Boycko (1992) and others showed that wage increases in a socialist economy result in

More information

Introduction to Economics I: Consumer Theory

Introduction to Economics I: Consumer Theory Introduction to Economics I: Consumer Theory Leslie Reinhorn Durham University Business School October 2014 What is Economics? Typical De nitions: "Economics is the social science that deals with the production,

More information

Problem Set 2 Answers

Problem Set 2 Answers Problem Set 2 Answers BPH8- February, 27. Note that the unique Nash Equilibrium of the simultaneous Bertrand duopoly model with a continuous price space has each rm playing a wealy dominated strategy.

More information

What should regulators do about merger policy?

What should regulators do about merger policy? Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 623±627 What should regulators do about merger policy? Anil K Kashyap * Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, IL 60637,

More information

E cient Minimum Wages

E cient Minimum Wages preliminary, please do not quote. E cient Minimum Wages Sang-Moon Hahm October 4, 204 Abstract Should the government raise minimum wages? Further, should the government consider imposing maximum wages?

More information

II. Competitive Trade Using Money

II. Competitive Trade Using Money II. Competitive Trade Using Money Neil Wallace June 9, 2008 1 Introduction Here we introduce our rst serious model of money. We now assume that there is no record keeping. As discussed earler, the role

More information

Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI

Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI Presented by: Romita Mukherjee February 20, 2008 Basic Principles of International Taxation of Capital Income Residence Principle (1) Place of Residency

More information

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly EconS 50 - Micro Theory I Recitation #9 - Monopoly Exercise A monopolist faces a market demand curve given by: Q = 70 p. (a) If the monopolist can produce at constant average and marginal costs of AC =

More information

D S E Dipartimento Scienze Economiche

D S E Dipartimento Scienze Economiche D S E Dipartimento Scienze Economiche Working Paper Department of Economics Ca Foscari University of Venice Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi Illiquidity and Under-Valutation of Firms ISSN: 1827/336X No. 36/WP/2008

More information

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model Zhiwei Xu (xuzhiwei@sjtu.edu.cn) Solow model (Solow, 1959) is the starting point of the most dynamic macroeconomic theories. It introduces dynamics and transitions into

More information

The taxation of foreign profits: a unified view WP 15/04. February Working paper series Michael P Devereux University of Oxford

The taxation of foreign profits: a unified view WP 15/04. February Working paper series Michael P Devereux University of Oxford The taxation of foreign profits: a unified view February 2015 WP 15/04 Michael P Devereux University of Oxford Clemens Fuest Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW) Ben Lockwood University of Warwick

More information

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions. Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions. Ilan Kremer and Andrzej Skrzypacz March 21, 2002 1 Introduction In many papers considering the sale of many objects in a sequence of auctions the seller

More information

Monopolistic Competition, Managerial Compensation, and the. Distribution of Firms in General Equilibrium

Monopolistic Competition, Managerial Compensation, and the. Distribution of Firms in General Equilibrium Monopolistic Competition, Managerial Compensation, and the Distribution of Firms in General Equilibrium Jose M. Plehn-Dujowich Fox School of Business Temple University jplehntemple.edu Ajay Subramanian

More information

Acquisition and Disclosure of Information as a Hold-up Problem

Acquisition and Disclosure of Information as a Hold-up Problem Acquisition and Disclosure of Information as a Hold-up Problem Urs Schweizer, y University of Bonn October 10, 2013 Abstract The acquisition of information prior to sale gives rise to a hold-up situation

More information

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen Online Appendix Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen Appendix A: Analysis of Initial Claims in Medicare Part D In this appendix we

More information

Tari s, Taxes and Foreign Direct Investment

Tari s, Taxes and Foreign Direct Investment Tari s, Taxes and Foreign Direct Investment Koo Woong Park 1 BK1 PostDoc School of Economics Seoul National University E-mail: kwpark@snu.ac.kr Version: 4 November 00 [ABSTRACT] We study tax (and tari

More information