Optimal capital allocation principles

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Optimal capital allocation principles"

Transcription

1 MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Optimal capital allocation principles Jan Dhaene and Andreas Tsanakas and Valdez Emiliano and Vanduffel Steven University of Connecticut 23. January 2009 Online at MPRA Paper No , posted 22. February :00 UTC

2 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles Jan Dhaene Andreas Tsanakas Emiliano A. Valdez Steven Vanduffel January 23, 2009 Abstract This paper develops a unifying framework for allocating the aggregate capital of a financial firm to its business units. The approach relies on an optimisation argument, requiring that the weighted sum of measures for the deviations of the business unit s losses from their respective allocated capitals be minimised. This enables the association of alternative allocation rules to specific decision criteria and thus provides the risk manager with flexibility to meet specific target objectives. The underlying general framework reproduces many capital allocation methods that have appeared in the literature and allows for several possible extensions. An application to an insurance market with policyholder protection is additionally provided as an illustration. Keywords: Capital allocation; risk measure; comonotonicity; Euler allocation; default option; Lloyd s of London. 1 Introduction The level of the capital held by a bank or an insurance company is a key issue for its stakeholders. The regulator, primarily sharing the interests of depositors and policyholders, establishes rules to determine the required capital to be held by the company. The level of this capital is determined such that the company will be able to meet its financial obligations with a high probability as they fall due, even in adverse situations. Rating agencies rely on the level of available capital to assess the financial strength of a company. Shareholders and investors alike are concerned with the risk of their capital investment and the return that it will generate. The determination of a sufficient amount of capital to hold is only part of a larger risk management and solvency policy. The practice of Enterprise Risk Management (ERM) enhances identifying, measuring, pricing, and controlling risks. An important component of an ERM framework is the exercise of capital allocation, a term referring to the subdivision of the aggregate capital held by the firm across its various constituents, e.g. business lines, types of exposure, territories or even individual products in a portfolio of insurance policies. Most financial firms write several lines of business and may want their total capital allocated across these lines for a number of reasons. First, there is a need to redistribute the total (frictional or opportunity) cost associated with holding capital across various business lines so that this cost is equitably transferred back to the depositors or policyholders in the form of charges. An early draft of this paper was presented at the 9th International Congress on Insurance: Mathematics and Economics (IME2005) in Laval, Quebec, Canada. Corresponding author: jan.dhaene@econ.kuleuven.be (phone: ) Faculty of Business and Economics, Katholieke Universiteit, Leuven, Belgium. Cass Business School, City University, London, United Kingdom. Department of Mathematics, University of Connecticut, Storrs, Connecticut, USA. Department of Economics and Political Science, Vrije Universiteit Brussel (VUB), Brussel, Belgium. 1

3 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 2 Secondly, the allocation of expenses across lines of business is a necessary activity for financial reporting purposes. Lastly, capital allocation provides for a useful device of assessing and comparing the performance of the different lines of business by determining the return on allocated capital for each line. Comparing these returns allows one to distinguish the most profitable business lines and hence may assist in remunerating the business line managers or in making decisions concerning business expansions, reductions or even eliminations. There is countless number of ways to allocate the aggregate capital of a company to its different business units. Mutual dependencies that may exist between the performances of the various business units make capital allocation a non-trivial exercise. Accordingly, there is an extensive amount of literature on this subject with a wide number of proposed capital allocation algorithms. Cummins (2000) provides an overview of several methods suggested for capital allocation in the insurance industry and relates capital allocation to management decision making tools such as RAROC (risk-adjusted return on capital) and EVA (economic value added). Myers and Read Jr. (2001) consider capital allocation principles based on the marginal contribution of each business unit to the company s default option. LeMaire (1984) and Denault (2001) discuss capital allocations based on game theory considerations, where a risk measure is used as a cost functional. In the case of coherent risk measures (see Artzner et al. (1999)), such capital allocations reduce to subdivisions according to marginal costs. In closely related works, marginal ( Euler ) capital allocations are proposed within a portfolio optimisation context by Tasche (2004) and an axiomatic allocation system is proposed by Kalkbrener (2005). A commentary on the various approaches to allocating capital has appeared in Venter (2004). A recent work by Kim and Hardy (2008) proposed a method based on a solvency exchange option and which explicitly accounts for the notion of limited liability. Panjer (2001) considers the particular case of multivariate normally distributed risks and provides an explicit expression of marginal cost based allocations, when the risk measure used is Tail Value-at-Risk (TVaR). Landsman and Valdez (2003) extends these explicit capital allocation formulas to the case where risks belong to the class of multivariate elliptical distributions, for which the class of multivariate normal is a special case. Dhaene et al. (2008) derive the results of Landsman and Valdez (2003) in a rather more straightforward manner and apply these to sums that involve normal as well as lognormal risks. In Valdez and Chernih (2003), expressions for covariance-based allocations are derived for multivariate elliptical risks. Tsanakas (2004) studies allocations where the relevant risk measure belongs to the class of distortion risk measures, while Tsanakas (2008) extends these allocation principles to the more general class of convex risk measures including the exponential risk measures. Furman and Zitikis (2008b) introduce the class of weighted risk capital allocations which stems from the weighted premium calculation principle. The multitude of allocation methods proposed in the literature is bewildering. Allocation methods are sometimes proposed in an ad-hoc fashion lacking usually with much economic justification and are thereby viewed as arbitrary. This motivated some authors to doubt the legitimate purpose of the exercise itself of allocating capital e.g. Gründl and Schmeiser (2007). Certain allocation methods may be best suited in order to address specific issues, but it is always unclear what these issues are. Indeed, Gründl and Schmeiser (2007) point out this importance because accordingly, certain allocation techniques can dangerously lead to wrong financial decisions. This paper attempts to resolve several of these issues by constructing a unifying framework designed to address specific decision criteria in a comprehensive yet still highly stylised setting. We consider capital allocation as the outcome of a particular optimisation problem, in which the weighted sum of measures for the deviations of the business unit s losses from their respective allocated capitals is minimised. This idea has also been presented in Section 4.1 of Dhaene et al. (2003) in the context of stop-loss premiums. In this paper, we generalise the optimisation

4 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 3 approach of Dhaene et al. (2003) by considering more general deviation measures. We show that alternative specifications of the objective function, by applying different deviation measures, different weights on the possible outcomes of the random deviations and different exposure weights on the business units, reproduces several of the allocation techniques in the literature within the general framework we propose in this paper. Note that related results, in the context of premium allocation, have been presented in Zaks et al. (2006). A generalisation of the optimisation approach of Dhaene et al. (2003) in a different direction than the one we propose in this paper, may also be found in Laeven and Goovaerts (2004). A quadratic deviation criterion gives rise to allocations that generally have the form of expectations. Allocations based on well-known risk measures such as the Conditional Tail Expectation (CTE) as well as allocations taking into account the insurer s default option are derived in this setting. An absolute deviation criterion will give rise to quantile-based allocations. In both cases, the allocations may or may not reflect the dependence structure of the portfolio, via dependence between the individual and the aggregate risks. Furthermore, the general optimal allocation framework proposed in this paper is also applied to the case of an insurance market with policyholder protection, found, for example, in Lloyd s of London. In that context, novel interpretations arise for allocation methods used in the past and present at Lloyd s. The structure of this paper is as follows. In Section 2, risk measures and the capital allocation problem are discussed and an overview of some popular allocation methods is given. In Section 3, which forms the main contribution of the paper, a unifying optimal capital allocation approach is presented. From this general approach, a multitude of special cases is derived. In Section 4, we discuss the case of an insurance market with policyholder protection. Finally, brief conclusions are given in Section 5. 2 Capital allocation 2.1 Risk Measures A risk measure is a mapping ρ from a set Γ of real-valued random variables defined on a probability space (Ω, F, P) to the real line R: ρ : Γ R : X Γ ρ [X]. (1) The random variable X refers to the loss associated with conducting a business. Risk measures have traditionally been used for determining insurance premia (Goovaerts et al. (1984)). More recently, however, they have been applied in a risk management context, with ρ [X] representing the amount of capital to be set aside in order to make the loss X an acceptable risk; see Artzner et al. (1999). Some well known properties that risk measures may or may not satisfy are law invariance, monotonicity, positive homogeneity, translation invariance (or equivariance) and subadditivity. They are formally defined as: Law invariance: For any X 1, X 2 Γ with P[X 1 x] = P[X 2 x] for all x R, ρ[x 1 ] = ρ[x 2 ]. Monotonicity: For any X 1, X 2 Γ, X 1 X 2 implies ρ [X 1 ] ρ [X 2 ]. Positive homogeneity: For any X Γ and a > 0, ρ [ax] = aρ [X]. Translation invariance: For any X Γ and b R, ρ [X + b] = ρ [X] + b. Subadditivity: For any X 1, X 2 Γ, ρ [X 1 + X 2 ] ρ [X 1 ] + ρ [X 2 ].

5 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 4 Artzner et al. (1999) call any risk measure that satisfies the last four properties a coherent risk measure. Föllmer and Schied (2002) and Dhaene et al. (2008) provide weaker sets of properties and discuss the desirability or otherwise of the properties of coherent risk measures. 2.2 The allocation problem Consider a portfolio of n individual losses X 1, X 2,..., X n materialising at a fixed future date T. Assume that (X 1, X 2,..., X n ) is a random vector on the probability space (Ω, F, P). Throughout the paper, we will always assume that any loss has a finite mean. The distribution function P [ x] of will be denoted by F Xi (x). The aggregate loss is defined by the sum S =, (2) i=1 where this aggregate loss S can be interpreted as: the total loss of a corporate, e.g. an insurance company, with the individual losses corresponding to the losses of the respective business units; the loss from an insurance portfolio, with the individual losses being those arising from the different policies; the loss suffered by a financial conglomerate, while the different individual losses correspond to the losses suffered by its subsidiaries; or the total loss across an insurance/financial market, with the individual losses being the ones from the different companies in this market. It is the first of these interpretations we will use throughout this article, with the exception of Section 4. Hence S is the aggregate loss faced by an insurance company and the loss of business unit i. We assume that the company has already determined the aggregate level of capital and denote this total risk capital by K. The company now wishes to allocate this exogenously given total risk capital K across its various business units, that is, to determine non-negative real numbers K 1,..., K n satisfying the full allocation requirement: K i = K. (3) i=1 This allocation is in some sense a notional exercise; it does not mean that capital is physically shifted across the various units, as the company s assets and liabilities continue to be pooled. The allocation exercise could be made in order to rank the business units according to levels of profitability. This task is performed by determining at time T, the respective returns on the respective allocated capital [(K i ) /K i ] 1, i = 1,..., n. Given that a capital allocation can be carried out in a countless number of ways, additional criteria must be set up in order to determine the most suitable. A reasonable start is to require the allocated capital amounts K i to be close to their corresponding losses in some appropriately defined sense. This underlies the approach proposed in the present paper. Prior to introducing the idea of closeness between individual loss and allocated capital, we revisit some well-known capital allocation methods.

6 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles Some known allocation formulas For a given probability level p (0, 1), we denote the Value-at-Risk (VaR) or quantile of the loss random variable X by F 1 X (p). As usual, it is defined by F 1 X (p) = inf {x R F X(x) p}, p [0, 1]. (4) with inf{ } = + by convention. Below we will also need so-called α mixed inverse distribution functions, see Dhaene et al. (2002). Therefore, we first define the inverse distribution function F 1+ X (p) of the random variable X by F 1+ X (p) = sup {x R F X(x) p}, p [0, 1], (5) with sup{ } =. The α mixed inverse distribution function F 1(α) X of s then defined as follows: (p) = αf 1 1+ (p) + (1 α)f (p), p (0, 1) α [0, 1]. (6) F 1(α) X X From this definition, one immediately finds that for any random variable X and for all x with 0 < F X (x) < 1, there exists an α x [0, 1] such thatf 1(αx) X (F X (x)) = x The haircut allocation principle A straightforward allocation method consists of allocating the capital K i = γf 1 (p), i = 1,..., n, to business unit i, where the factor γ is chosen such that the full allocation requirement (3) is satisfied. This gives rise to the haircut allocation principle: K i = X K n F 1 X j (p) F 1 (p), i = 1,..., n. (7) For an exogenously given value for K, this principle leads to an allocation that is not influenced by the dependence structure between the losses of the different business units. In this sense, one can say that the allocation method is independent of the portfolio context within which the individual losses are embedded. It is a common industry practice, driven by banking and insurance regulations to measure stand-alone losses by a VaR, for a given probability level p. Therefore, let us assume that K = (p). In addition, we assume that in case business unit i was a stand-alone unit, then its loss F 1 S would be measured by F 1 (p). It is well-known that the quantile risk measure is not always subadditive. Consequently, using the p-quantile as stand-alone risk measure will not necessarily imply that the subportfolios will benefit from a pooling effect. This means that it may happen that the allocated capitals K i exceed the respective stand-alone capitals F 1 (p) The quantile allocation principle The haircut allocation rule (7) allocates to each business unit i a proportion γ of its p-quantile, with γ chosen such that the full allocation condition is fulfilled. This means that a constant proportional reduction (or increase) is applied on each of the quantiles F 1 (p). Instead of applying a proportional cut on the monetary amounts F 1 (p), one could adopt the probability level p equally among all business units and determine an α mixed inverse with α [0, 1], such that the full allocation requirement is again satisfied. This approach gives rise to the quantile allocation principle with allocated capital amounts K i given by K i = F 1(α) (βp), with α and β such that K i = K. (8) i=1

7 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 6 Similar to the haircut allocation principle, for a given aggregate capital K, the allocated capitals K i are not influenced by the dependence structure between the different losses, i = 1,..., n. The quantile allocation rule is in compliance with the principle of using equal quantiles to measure the risk associated with the different business units. If it is considered consistent to measure each stand-alone loss by the corresponding quantile F 1 (p), then it makes sense to measure each pooled loss by F 1(α) (βp) where α and β are chosen such that the full allocation requirement is satisfied. This means that all losses continue to be evaluated at the same probability level β p and the benefits from pooling are in some sense subdivided neutrally across the different business units. The haircut allocation principle (7) will in general not lead to a quantile-based allocation with the same probability level for all business units. Companies and regulators when debating that all risks should be evaluated using the same p-quantile measure may prefer the quantile allocation principle rather than the haircut principle. The appropriate levels of α and β are to be determined as the solutions to K = i=1 F 1(α) (βp), (9) In order to solve this problem, we need to introduce the concept of a comonotonic sum S c defined by S c = F 1 (U), (10) where U is a uniform random variable on (0, 1). It then holds that which leads us to Furthermore, we have that i=1 K = F 1(α) S c (βp), (11) βp = F S c(k). (12) K = F 1(α) S c (F S c(k)). (13) Further additional details can be found in Dhaene et al. (2002). The quantile allocation rule in (8) can then be re-expressed as K i = F 1(α) (F S c (K)), i = 1,..., n, (14) with α determined from (13). In the special case that all distribution functions F Xi are strictly increasing and continuous, this rule reduces to K i = F 1 (F S c (K)), i = 1,..., n. (15) This allocation principle was proposed in Dhaene et al. (2003), where it was derived as the solution of an appropriate optimisation problem; See also Section 3.3. Notice that for strictly increasing and continuous distribution functions F Xi, the quantile allocation principle can be considered as a special case of the haircut allocation principle (7) by choosing p = F S c (K) The covariance allocation principle The covariance allocation principle proposed by e.g. Overbeck (2000) is given by K i = K Var [S] Cov [, S], i = 1,..., n, (16)

8 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 7 where Cov[, S] is the covariance between the individual loss and the aggregate loss S and Var[S] is the variance of the aggregate loss S. Because clearly the sum of these individual covariances is equal to the variance of the aggregate loss, the full allocation requirement is automatically satisfied in this case. The covariance allocation rule, unlike the haircut and the quantile allocation principles, explicitly takes into account the dependence structure of the random losses (X 1, X 2,..., X n ). Business units with a loss that is more correlated with the aggregate portfolio loss S are penalised by requiring them to hold a larger amount of capital than those which are less correlated The CTE allocation principle For a given probability level p (0, 1), the Conditional Tail Expectation (CTE) of the aggregate loss S is defined as CTE p [S] = E [ S S > F 1 S (p)]. (17) At a fixed level p, it gives the average of the top (1 p)% losses. In general, the CTE as a risk measure does not necessarily satisfy the subadditivity property. However, it is known to be a coherent risk measure in case we restrict to random variables with continuous distribution function. See Acerbi and Tasche (2002) and Remark in Dhaene et al. (2006). The CTE allocation principle, for some fixed probability level p (0, 1), has the form K i = K CTE p [S] E [ S > F 1 S (p)], i = 1,..., n (18) In the particular case that K = CTE p [S], formula (18) reduces to the allocation suggested by Overbeck (2000) and Denault (2001). The CTE allocation rule explicitly takes into account the dependence structure of the random losses (X 1, X 2,..., X n ). Imterpreting the event S > F 1 S (p) as the aggregate portfolio loss S is large, we see from (18) that business units with larger conditional expected loss, given that the aggregate loss S is large, will be penalised with a larger amount of capital required than those with lesser conditional expected loss Proportional allocations The capital allocation methods we have discussed so far are special cases of a more general class. Each member of this class is obtained by first choosing a risk measure ρ and then attributing the capital K i = αρ [ ] to each business unit i, i = 1,..., n. The factor α is chosen such that the full allocation requirement (3) is satisfied. This gives rise to the proportional allocation principle: K i = K n ρ[x j] ρ[], i = 1,..., n. (19) Clearly, all allocation principles discussed in the previous subsections follow from (19) by choosing the appropriate risk measure ρ: Haircut allocation: ρ[ ] = F 1 (p), (20) Quantile allocation: ρ[ ] = F 1 (F S c (K)) with α from (13), (21) Covariance allocation: ρ[ ] = Cov [, S], and (22) CTE allocation: ρ[ ] = E [ S > F 1 S (p)]. (23) Note that if ρ is law invariant, the proportional allocation derived from ρ is not influenced by the dependence structure between the losses of the different business units.

9 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 8 Let us assume that stand-alone losses are measured by a risk measure ρ. This means that K = ρ[s] and also that the risk of business unit i, considered as a stand-alone unit, is measured by ρ[ ]. From (19) one finds that in case of a proportional allocation, each business unit benefits from a pooling effect in the sense that K i ρ[ ] if and only if K = ρ[s] ρ[x j ]. (24) This condition is fulfilled for subadditive risk measures ρ. As we have observed before, the haircut allocation method, which chooses a VaR as a stand-alone risk measure, may lead to a positive or a negative pooling effect. On the other hand, choosing Tail Value-at-Risk (TVaR) as stand-alone risk measure such as in the CTE allocation method, will lead to K i ρ[ ] Location-scale families of distributions This section investigates the relationship that exists between the different allocation rules presented above, in case the losses belong to the same location-scale family of distributions. Herewith, we assume that there exists a random variable Z with a zero mean and constants a i > 0 and b i such that d = ai Z + b i, i = 1,..., n, (25) where d = stands for equality in distribution. We further assume that F Z is strictly increasing and continuous on R. Let us first consider the general proportional allocation principle (19) where ρ is assumed to be law invariant, translation invariant and positive homogeneous. In this case, all ρ[ ] can be expressed as ρ[ ] = F 1 (p), i = 1,..., n, (26) for some fixed probability level p (0, 1), see e.g. Dhaene et al. (2009). This means that under the stated conditions, the proportional allocation principle (19) reduces to the haircut allocation principle (7). Next we consider the CTE allocation principle (18) with K = CTE p [S] and where the vector of business losses (X 1, X 2,..., X n ) is multivariate elliptically distributed with E [ ] = 0, i = 1,..., n. The assumption that all have a zero mean may be relevant for practical situations where a provision equal to the expected value of the aggregate loss is set aside, and in addition capital is used as a buffer to protect against the uncertainty of the aggregate loss around its mean. In this case, each has to be interpreted as the loss of business unit i minus its expectation. From Landsman and Valdez (2003), we find that in this case the allocated capitals K i are given by K i = E [ S > F 1 S (p)] = CTE p[s] Var[S] Cov [, S], i = 1,..., n. (27) Hence, we can conclude that when (X 1, X 2,..., X n ) is multivariate elliptically distributed with zero means and in addition K = CTE p [S], the CTE allocation principle (18) coincides with the covariance allocation principle (16) Allocation and the default option A somewhat different class of approaches, based on the arguments of Myers and Read Jr. (2001), produces a capital allocation procedure by considering the value of the insurer s default option. Since the shareholders of the company have limited liability, in the event of default, i.e. when

10 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 9 S > K, they are not, in principle, obligated to pay the excess loss S K. Therefore, the protection that the collective of policyholders purchases is min(s, K), which can be written as S (S K) +. (28) The quantity (S K) + is called the policyholder deficit or alternatively the insurer s default option. Myers and Read Jr. (2001) assume that markets are complete and that a proportional increase in the exposure to a particular line of business produces a proportional increase in its allocated capital. They subsequently allocate the value of the default option via the marginal contributions of each line of business to that value. It can be shown that the Myers-Read allocation is given by the general formula (which does not appear in their paper in this form), E[(S K) + ] = E[(X j K j ) I(S > K)], (29) where I(A) is the indicator function of event A and expectations may be taken under a risk neutral measure. It is worth noting that (29) is not a capital allocation formula in itself, as the K 1..., K n are considered as given and only the default option value is allocated. Capital allocation methods that consider the value of the default options have been derived by e.g. Sherris (2006). 3 Optimal capital allocations 3.1 General setting The allocation of the exogenously given aggregate capital K to n parts K 1,..., K n, corresponding to the different subportfolios or business units, can be carried out in an infinite number of ways, some of which were illustrated in the previous section. At first glance, there seems to be a lack of a clear motivation for preferring to choose one method over another, although it appears obvious that different capital allocations must in some sense correspond to different questions that can be asked within the context of risk management. Hereafter we systematise capital allocation methods by viewing them as solutions to a particular decision problem. For that we need to formulate a decision criterion, such as: Capital should be allocated such that for each business unit the allocated capital and the loss are sufficiently close to each other. In order to cast this statement in a more formal setting, consider the aggregate portfolio loss S = X X n with aggregate capital K. Once the aggregate capital is allocated, the difference between aggregate loss and aggregate capital can be expressed as S K = (X j K j ), (30) where the quantity (X j K j ) expresses the loss minus the allocated capital for subportfolio j. Important to notice is that in this setting, the subportfolios are cross-subsidising each other, in the sense that the occurence of the event X k > K k does not necessarily lead to ruin ; such unfavorable performance of subportfolio k may be compensated by a favorable outcome for one or more values (X l K l ) of the other subportfolios. A different setting will be considered in section 4.

11 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 10 We propose to determine the appropriate allocation by the following optimisation problem: Optimal capital allocation problem: Given the aggregate capital K > 0, determine the allocated capitals K i, i = 1,..., n, from the following optimisation problem: min K 1,...,K n [ v j E ζ j D ( Xj K j v j )], such that K j = K, (31) where the v j are non-negative real numbers such that n v j = 1, the ζ j are non-negative random variables such that E[ζ j ] = 1 and D is a non-negative function. Before solving the general optimal capital allocation problem (31), we first elaborate on its various elements. ( ) Xj K D j v j : For simplicity, we first assume that v j = 1 and also that ζ j 1. The terms D (X j K j ) quantify the deviations of the outcomes of the losses X j from their allocated capital K j. Minimising the sum of the expectations of these quantities essentially reflects the requirement that the allocated capitals should be as close as possible to the losses they are allocated to. ζ j : The deviations of the losses X j from their respective allocated capital levels K j are measured by the terms E [ζ j D (X j K j )]. These expectations involve non-negative random variables ζ j with E[ζ j ] = 1 that are used as weight factors to the different possible outcomes of D (X j K j ). One possible choice for the ζ j could be ζ j = h(x j ) for some non-negative and nondecreasing function h. In this case, the heaviest weights are attached to deviations that correspond to states-of-the-world leading to the largest outcomes of X j. We will call allocations based on such a choice for the ζ j business unit driven allocations. Another choice is to let ζ j = h(s) for some non-negative and non-decreasing function h, such that the outcomes of the deviations are weighted with respect to the aggregate portfolio performance. In this case, heavier weights are attached to deviations that correspond to states-of-the-world leading to larger outcomes of S. Allocations based on such a choice for the random variables ζ j will be called aggregate portfolio driven allocations. A yet different approach is to let ζ j = ζ M for all j, where ζ M can be interpreted as the loss on a reference (or market) portfolio. In this case, the weighting is market driven and the corresponding allocation is said to be a market driven allocation. v j : The non-negative real number v j is a measure of exposure or business volume of the j- th unit, such as revenue, insurance premium, etc. These scalar quantities are chosen such that they sum to 1. Their inclusion in the expression D ( ) Xj K j v j normalises the deviations of loss from allocated capital across business units to make them relatively more comparable. [ ( At the )] same time, the v j s are used as weights attached to the different values Xj K of E ζ j D j v j in the minimisation problem (31), in order to reflect the relative importance of the different business units. In summary, we propose in (31) to fully allocate the aggregate capital K to the different business units such that the exposure-weighted sum of the expectations of the weighted and normalised deviations of the losses X j from their respective allocated capitals K j, is minimised.

12 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles The quadratic optimisation criterion General solution of the quadratic allocation problem In this subsection we discuss optimal allocation under a quadratic criterion, that is, by letting D(x) = x 2. (32) In this case, the optimal allocation problem (31) reduces to [ ] (X j K j ) 2 min E ζ j, such that K 1,...,K n v j K j = K. (33) The solution to this minimisation problem is given in the following theorem. Theorem 1 The optimal allocation problem (33) has the following unique solution: K i = E[ζ i ] + v i K E[ζ j X j ], i = 1,..., n. (34) Proof. Problem (33) can be solved via a Lagrange optimisation. However, we will give a simple geometric proof, based on an argument given in Zaks et al. (2006) who considered the minimisation problem (33) in the special case that all ζ j 1. Taking into account the relations [ E ζ j (X j K j ) 2] = (E [ζ j X j ] K j ) 2 + E [ ζ j Xj 2 ] (E [ζj X j ]) 2, j = 1,..., n, we have that the solution of the minimisation problem (33) is identical to the solution of the following minimisation problem: min K 1,...,K n (E [ζ j X j ] K j ) 2, such that v j K j = K. (35) Clearly, eliminating the term ( [ ] n E ζ j Xj 2 (E [ζ j X j ]) 2) does not change the optimal allocation. By introducing the notation x j = K j E [ζ j X j ] vj j = 1,..., n, (36) we can transform (35) into min x 1,...,x n x 2 j, such that vj x j = K E[ζ j X j ]. (37) Let us now interpret the set (x 1, x 2,..., x n ) R n vj x j = K E[ζ j X j ]

13 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 12 as a hyperplane in R n. The solution of (37) can then be interpreted as the point (x 1, x 2,..., x n ) on the hyperplane ( n vj x j = K ) n E[ζ jx j ] that is closest to the origin (0, 0,..., 0). Hence, x i = v i K E[ζ j X j ], i = 1,..., n. Translating this result in terms of the K i via (36) immediately leads to (34). The capital K i given by (34) equals the weighted expected loss of, in addition to a term proportional to the volume of the unit. This second term is a redistribution of the difference between the amount of aggregate capital K held and n E[ζ jx]. This redistribution is assigned using weights v i based on the volume or on some other measure of the riskiness of the corresponding business units. In the particular case that the volume weights are given by v i = E[ζ i ] n E[ζ jx j ], (38) it immediately follows that (34) reduces to K i = K n E[ζ jx j ] E[ζ i ], i = 1,..., n. (39) This allocation rule can be seen as a special case of the proportional allocation rule (19), by choosing ρ[ ] = E[ζ i ], i = 1,..., n. (40) Notice that (39) can be rearranged as K i E[ζ i ] E[ζ i ] = K n E[ζ jx j ] n E[ζ, i = 1,..., n. (41) jx j ] In the special case that the aggregate capital K is given by K = n E[ζ jx j ], the allocation rule (34) reduces to K i = E[ζ i ], i = 1,..., n. (42) This class of allocations is investigated in Furman and Zitikis (2008b) who call the members of this class weighted risk capital allocations Business unit driven allocations In this subsection we consider the case where the weighting random variables ζ i s in the quadratic allocation problem (33) are given by ζ i = h i ( ), (43) with h i being a non-negative and non-decreasing function such that E[h i ( )] = 1, for i = 1,..., n. Hence, for each business unit i, the states-of-the-world to which we want to assign the heaviest weights are those under which the business unit performs the worst. As earlier pointed out, we call allocations based on (43) business unit driven allocations. In this case, the allocation rule (34) can be rewritten as K i = E[ h i ( )] + v i K E[X j h i (X j )], i = 1,..., n. (44)

14 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 13 For an exogeneously given value of K, the allocations K i are not influenced by the mutual dependence structure between the losses of the different business units. In this sense, one can say that the allocation principle (44) is independent of the portfolio context within which the s are embedded, and hence, is indeed business unit driven. Such allocations might be a useful instrument for determining the performance bonuses of the business unit managers, in case one assumes that each manager should be rewarded for the performance of his own business unit, but not extra rewarded (or penalised) for the interrelationship that exists between the performance of his business unit and that of the other units of the company. The law invariant risk measure E[ h i ( )] assigns to any loss the expected value of the weighted outcomes of this loss, where higher weights correspond to larger outcomes of the loss, that is, to more adverse scenarios. Risk measures and premium principles of this general type have been proposed and investigated in Heilmann (1989), Tsanakas (2007) and Furman and Zitikis (2008a). A particular choice of the random variables h i ( ) considered in (44) is given by ( ) I > F 1 (p) h i ( ) = ( ), i = 1,..., n, (45) 1 F Xi F 1 (p) for some p (0, 1). In this case, we find that E[ h i ( )] transforms into E[ h i ( )] = CTE p [ ], i = 1,..., n. (46) More generally, consider the random variables h i ( ) defined by h i ( ) = g ( F Xi ( ) ), i = 1,..., n, (47) with g : [0, 1] [0, 1] an increasing and concave function with derivative g if it exists, and F X the decumulative function of X. We then find that E[ h i ( )] = E[ g ( F Xi ( ) ) ], i = 1,..., n, (48) and E[ h i ( )] is a concave distortion risk measure, also called spectral risk measure. See Wang (1996), Acerbi (2002), or Dhaene et al. (2006). Other examples of risk measures of the form E[ h i ( )] are the standard deviation principle, the Esscher principle and the exponential principle. These are summarised in Table 1. Defining the volumes v i by v i = E[ h i ( )] n E[X, i = 1,..., n, (49) jh j (X j )] we find that the allocation principle (44) reduces to K i = K n E[X jh j (X j )] E[h i ( )], i = 1,..., n, (50) which is a special case of the proportional allocation principles discussed in Section Aggregate portfolio driven allocations Let us now consider the case where ζ i = h(s), i = 1,..., n, (51)

15 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 14 Table 1: Business unit driven risk measures Risk measure h i ( ) E[ h i ( )] Standard deviation principle Bühlmann (1970) 1 + a E[ ] σ Xi, a 0 E[ ] + aσ Xi Conditional tail expectation Overbeck (2000) 1 ( ) 1 p I > F 1 (p), p (0, 1) CTE p [ ] Distortion risk measure Wang (1996), Acerbi (2002) Exponential principle Gerber (1974) Esscher principle Gerber (1981) g ( F Xi ( ) ), g : [0, 1] [0, 1], g > 0, g < e γa E[e γa ] dγ, a > 0 e a E[e a ], a > 0 E [ g ( F Xi ( ) )] 1 a ln E [ e ax ] i E[ e a ] E[e a ] with h being a non-negative and non-decreasing function such that E[h(S)] = 1. In this case, the states-of-the-world to which we assign the heaviest weights are those under which the aggregate portfolio performs worst. Therefore, we call such allocations aggregate portfolio driven allocations. The allocation rule (34) can now be rewritten as K i = E[ h(s)] + v i (K E[Sh(S)]), i = 1,..., n. (52) Hence, the capital K i allocated to unit i is determined using a weighted expectation of the loss, with higher weights attached to states-of-the-world that involve a large aggregate loss S. Notice that the allocation principle (52) can be reformulated as K i = E[ ] + Cov[, h(s)] + v i (K E[Sh(S)]), i = 1,..., n. (53) This means that the capital allocated to the i-th business unit is given by the sum of the expected loss E[ ], a loading which depends on the covariance between the individual and aggregate losses and h(s), plus a term proportional to the volume of the business unit. A strong positive correlation between and h(s), which reflects that could be a substantial driver of the aggregate loss S, produces a higher allocated capital K i. Allocation principles of the form (52) are closely related to the Euler allocations proposed in Tasche (2004). Using aggregate portfolio driven allocations might be appropriate when one wants to investigate each individual portfolio s contribution to the aggregate loss of the entire company. In other words, the company wishes to evaluate the subportfolio performances, e.g. the returns on the allocated capitals, in the presence of the other subportfolios. This can provide relevant information to the company within which it can further be used to evaluate either business expansions or reductions. Defining the volumes v i by v i = E[h(S)], i = 1,..., n, (54) E[Sh(S)] we find that the allocation principle (52) reduces to the proportional allocation rule K i = K E[Sh(S)] E[h(S)], i = 1,..., n. (55)

16 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 15 A particular choice of the random variable h(s) considered in (52) is given by h(s) = I ( S > F 1 S ( (p)) 1 F S F 1 i = 1,..., n, (56) S (p)), for some p (0, 1). In this case, we find that E[ h(s)] and E[Sh(S)] transform into and E[ h(s)] = E [ S > F 1 S (p)], i = 1,..., n (57) E[Sh(S)] = CTE p [S], (58) respectively. The CTE allocation principle (18) follows as a special case of the allocation principle (55) by choosing h(s) as in (56). Taking h(s) = S E[S], (59) we find and E[ h(s)] = Cov [, S], i = 1,..., n (60) E[Sh(S)] = Var[S], (61) which implies that the allocation principle (55) reduces to the covariance allocation principle (16) discussed in Section Other choices for the random variable h(s) and the related expressions for E[ h(s)] can be found in Table 2. They correspond to capital allocation principles that have been considered in Overbeck (2000), Tsanakas (2004), and Tsanakas (2008). Table 2: Aggregate portfolio driven allocations Reference h(s) E[ h(s)] Overbeck (2000) 1 + a S E[S], a 0 E[ ] + a Cov[, S] σ S σ S Overbeck (2000) 1 ( ( 1 F S F 1 S (p))i S > F 1 S (p)), p (0, 1) E[ S > F 1 S (p)] Tsanakas (2004) Tsanakas (2008) g (F S (S)), g : [0, 1] [0, 1], g > 0, g < e γas E[e γas ] dγ, a > 0 E [ g (F S (S)) ] 1 [X E e γas ] i 0 E[e γas ] dγ Wang (2007) e as E[e as ], a > 0 E[ e as ] E[e as ] Market driven allocations Let ζ M be a random variable such that market-consistent values of the aggregate portfolio loss S and the business unit losses are given by π[s] = E[ζ M S] (62)

17 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 16 and π[ ] = E[ζ M ], i = 1,..., n, (63) respectively. Further suppose that at the aggregate portfolio level, a provision π[s] is set aside to cover future liabilities S. Apart from the aggregate provision π[s], the aggregate portfolio has an available solvency capital equal to (K π[s]). The solvency ratio of the aggregate portolio is then given by K π[s]. (64) π[s] In order to determine an optimal capital allocation over the different business units, we let in (31) ζ i = ζ M, i = 1,..., n, thus allowing the market to determine which states-of-the-world are to be regarded adverse. This yields: K i = π[ ] + v i (K π[s]). (65) If we now use the market-consistent prices as volume measures, after substituting in (65), we find v i = π[], i = 1,..., n, (66) π[s] K i = Rearranging these expressions leads to K π[s] π[], i = 1,..., n. (67) K i π[ ] π[ ] = K π[s], i = 1,..., n. (68) π[s] The quantities π[ ] and (K i π[ ]) can be interpreted as the market-consistent provision and the solvency capital attached to business unit i, while K i π[ ] π[ ] is its corresponding solvency ratio. From (68), we can conclude that the optimisation criterion (33) with ζ i = ζ M, i = 1,..., n, and volume measures given by (66), leads to a capital allocation whereby the solvency ratio for each business unit is the same and equal to that of the aggregate portfolio. A similar allocation principle has been proposed by Sherris (2006) within the context of allocating the company s total equity to the different business units to determine an expected return on equity by line of business Allocation with respect to the default option An alternative choice for the weighting random variable ζ i is given by ζ i = h(s) = I(S > K), i = 1,..., n, (69) P[S > K] such that only those states-of-the-world that correspond to insolvency are considered when determining the expectations E[ h(s)]. The allocation rule (34) then becomes K i = E [ S > K] + v i (K E [S S > K]). (70) Notice the similarity between (69) and the choice of h(s) made in (56) which led to the CTE allocation rule. Expression (70) can be rearranged as follows: E[( K i ) I(S > K)] = v i E[(S K) + ], i = 1,..., n. (71)

18 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 17 Summing the left and right hand sides of this expression over i = 1,..., n, leads to expression (29). The quantity E[(S K) + ] represents the expected policyholder deficit or alternatively, the expected value of the default option that shareholders of an insurance company hold, given their limited liability. The allocation principle in (71) is such that the marginal contribution of each business unit to the expected value of the policyholder deficit is the same per unit of business volume, and hence is consistent with the arguments of Myers and Read Jr. (2001). 3.3 The absolute deviation optimisation criterion In this section we discuss the optimal allocation problem under an absolute deviation criterion, that is, by letting D(x) = x. (72) In this case the optimisation problem (31) reduces to min K 1,...,K n E [ζ j X j K j ], such that K j = K. (73) From the relation x = 2 (x) + x, (74) we immediately find that the optimal solution of (73) is identical to the solution of the following problem: E [ ] ζ j (X j K j ) +, such that K j = K. (75) min K 1,...,K n This means that the absolute deviation optimisation problem (73) only takes into account the outcomes of the business unit losses X j that lead to technical insolvency X j > K j in that unit. In order to solve the optimisation problem (75), we first consider the special case where all ζ j s are identical to 1. Theorem 2 Assuming that F 1+ S (0) < K < F 1 c S (1), the optimal allocation problem c min K 1,...,K n E [ ] (X j K j ) + such that K j = K (76) has the following solution: where S c is defined in (10) and α [0, 1] follows from K i = F 1(α) (F S c(k)), i = 1,..., n, (77) F 1(α) S c (F S c(k)) = K. (78) Proof. Let α be determined from (78). Then we immediately find from Dhaene et al. (2002) that E [ (S c ] [ ( ) ] K) + = E X j F 1(α) (F S c(k)) + E [ (X j K j ) + ], K ( F 1+ S c (0), F 1 S c (1) ),

19 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 18 holds for all (K 1, K 2,..., K n ) such that n K j = K. This proves the stated result. We can conclude that the quantile allocation principle (14) considered in Section is a solution of the minimisation problem (76). This optimisation problem and its solution were previously considered in Dhaene et al. (2003) in the particular case that the F Xi s are all strictly increasing. A proof of Theorem 2 using Lagrange techniques can be found in Laeven and Goovaerts (2004). The solution to the general optimisation problem (73) will be expressed in terms of functions defined as follows: (x) = E[ζ i I( x)] = E[ζ i x] F Xi (x), i = 1,..., n. (79) One can prove that each function defines a proper distribution function, which we will call the ζ i weighted distribution of ; See Rao (1997), Furman and Zitikis (2008a) and the references therein. The decumulative distribution function (x) = 1 (x) is given by (x) = E [ζ i I( > x)] = E[ζ i > x] F Xi (x), i = 1,..., n. (80) A sufficient condition for to be continuous is that F Xi be continuous. A sufficient condition for to be strictly increasing is that F Xi be strictly increasing and that P[ζ i > 0] = 1. For any p (0, 1) and any α [0, 1], we denote the α mixed inverse of ( at level p by ) 1(α) (p). In the following lemma, we prove that the deviation measure E [ ζ i ( K i ) + ] can be transformed to a stop-loss premium of with retention K i, where the expectation is taken with respect to the ζ i weighted distribution of. Lemma 3 Let U be a uniform random variable on the unit interval (0, 1). Then it holds that E [ [( ] ( ) ) ] ζ i ( K i ) + = E F (ζ 1 i) (U) Ki, i = 1,..., n. (81) Proof. From the tower property of the expectation operator, we find E [ ζ i ( K i ) + ] = E [ ζi E [ ( K i ) + ζ i ]]. Substituting E [ ] ( K i ) + ζ i by P[ > x ζ i ] dx and changing the order of the integrations, we find K i E [ ζ i ( K i ) + ] = = K i Taking into account the power property once more leads to K i + E [ζ i P[ > x ζ i ]] dx E [ζ i E[I( > x) ζ i ]] dx. E [ ] ζ i ( K i ) + = K i E [ζ i I( > x)] dx = K i (x) dx. ( The stated result follows then from observing that the distribution function of ( given by so that (x) dx is an expression for the stop-loss premium of K i with retention K i. ) 1 (U) is ) 1 (U)

20 Optimal Capital Allocation Principles 19 Now we are able to prove our main result concerning the absolute deviation optimisation problem. Theorem 4 Let S c be the comonotonic sum defined by S c = i=1 ( ) 1 (U), (82) where the random variable U is uniformly distributed on the unit interval (0, 1). In case F 1+ S c (0) < K < F 1 c (1), the optimal allocation problem (73) has the following solution: S ( ) K i = F (ζ 1(α) i) X (FS i ck), i = 1,..., n, (83) where α [0, 1] follows from F 1(α) S c (F S c (K)) = K. (84) Proof. From Lemma 3, we find that the optimisation problem (73) can be rewritten as min K 1,...,K n [( ( ) ) ] E F (ζ 1 j) X j (U) Kj, such that + The stated result follows then by applying Theorem 2. K j = K. From the theorem above, we can conclude that the mean absolute deviation optimality criterion (73) gives rise to a quantile-based allocation principle: Each allocated capital K i is given by the α mixed inverse of the ζ i weighted distribution function of at a fixed probability level, which is chosen such that the full allocation requirement is satisfied. From (83), we find that the optimal allocations K i satisfy the following conditions: In the case where and the distributions F (ζ j) X j (K i ) = F S c(k), i = 1,..., n. (85) P[ζ i > 0] = 1, i = 1,..., n, (86) are strictly increasing, then the optimal allocations in (83) reduce to K i = ( ) 1 (FS ck), i = 1,..., n. (87) We end this subsection with an example of an absolute deviation allocation principle. Consider the following choice for the weighting random variables: ζ i = I(S > K), i = 1,..., n. (88) P[S > K] This means that the optimisation procedure only considers those outcomes that lead to insolvency, i.e. the case where S > K, on the aggregate portfolio level. In this instance, the optimisation problem (75) reduces to min K 1,...,K n E [ (X j K j ) + S > K ], such that K j = K. (89)

Lecture 3 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

Lecture 3 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia. Principles and Lecture 3 of 4-part series Spring School on Risk, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia 2-4 April 2012 University of Connecticut, USA page 1 Outline 1 2 3 4

More information

Capital Allocation Principles

Capital Allocation Principles Capital Allocation Principles Maochao Xu Department of Mathematics Illinois State University mxu2@ilstu.edu Capital Dhaene, et al., 2011, Journal of Risk and Insurance The level of the capital held by

More information

An application of capital allocation principles to operational risk

An application of capital allocation principles to operational risk MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive An application of capital allocation principles to operational risk Jilber Urbina and Montserrat Guillén Department of Economics and CREIP, Universitat Rovira i Virgili,

More information

Capital allocation: a guided tour

Capital allocation: a guided tour Capital allocation: a guided tour Andreas Tsanakas Cass Business School, City University London K. U. Leuven, 21 November 2013 2 Motivation What does it mean to allocate capital? A notional exercise Is

More information

Lecture 1 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

Lecture 1 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia. Principles and Lecture 1 of 4-part series Spring School on Risk, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia 2-4 April 2012 s University of Connecticut, USA page 1 s Outline 1 2

More information

On an optimization problem related to static superreplicating

On an optimization problem related to static superreplicating On an optimization problem related to static superreplicating strategies Xinliang Chen, Griselda Deelstra, Jan Dhaene, Daniël Linders, Michèle Vanmaele AFI_1491 On an optimization problem related to static

More information

Lecture 4 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

Lecture 4 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia. Principles and Lecture 4 of 4-part series Spring School on Risk, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia 2-4 April 2012 University of Connecticut, USA page 1 Outline 1 2 3 4

More information

SOLVENCY AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION

SOLVENCY AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION SOLVENCY AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION HARRY PANJER University of Waterloo JIA JING Tianjin University of Economics and Finance Abstract This paper discusses a new criterion for allocation of required capital.

More information

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments T. Fischer Darmstadt University of Technology November 11, 2003 Abstract This brief paper explains how to obtain upper boundaries of shortfall

More information

Risk based capital allocation

Risk based capital allocation Proceedings of FIKUSZ 10 Symposium for Young Researchers, 2010, 17-26 The Author(s). Conference Proceedings compilation Obuda University Keleti Faculty of Business and Management 2010. Published by Óbuda

More information

Can a coherent risk measure be too subadditive?

Can a coherent risk measure be too subadditive? Can a coherent risk measure be too subadditive? J. Dhaene,,, R.J.A. Laeven,, S. Vanduffel, G. Darkiewicz, M.J. Goovaerts, Catholic University of Leuven, Dept. of Applied Economics, Naamsestraat 69, B-3000

More information

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management Risk Measures Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com Reference: Chapter 8

More information

Economic capital allocation derived from risk measures

Economic capital allocation derived from risk measures Economic capital allocation derived from risk measures M.J. Goovaerts R. Kaas J. Dhaene June 4, 2002 Abstract We examine properties of risk measures that can be considered to be in line with some best

More information

Optimal retention for a stop-loss reinsurance with incomplete information

Optimal retention for a stop-loss reinsurance with incomplete information Optimal retention for a stop-loss reinsurance with incomplete information Xiang Hu 1 Hailiang Yang 2 Lianzeng Zhang 3 1,3 Department of Risk Management and Insurance, Nankai University Weijin Road, Tianjin,

More information

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers Université de Lyon 1, ISFA April 23 2014 Tlemcen - CIMPA Research School Motivations Study of optimal risk transfer structures, Natural question in Reinsurance.

More information

Conditional Value-at-Risk: Theory and Applications

Conditional Value-at-Risk: Theory and Applications The School of Mathematics Conditional Value-at-Risk: Theory and Applications by Jakob Kisiala s1301096 Dissertation Presented for the Degree of MSc in Operational Research August 2015 Supervised by Dr

More information

Pareto-optimal reinsurance arrangements under general model settings

Pareto-optimal reinsurance arrangements under general model settings Pareto-optimal reinsurance arrangements under general model settings Jun Cai, Haiyan Liu, and Ruodu Wang Abstract In this paper, we study Pareto optimality of reinsurance arrangements under general model

More information

A generalized coherent risk measure: The firm s perspective

A generalized coherent risk measure: The firm s perspective Finance Research Letters 2 (2005) 23 29 www.elsevier.com/locate/frl A generalized coherent risk measure: The firm s perspective Robert A. Jarrow a,b,, Amiyatosh K. Purnanandam c a Johnson Graduate School

More information

A capital allocation based on a solvency exchange option

A capital allocation based on a solvency exchange option A capital allocation based on a solvency exchange option Joseph H.T. Kim and Mary R. Hardy University of Waterloo September 19, 2007 Abstract In this paper we propose a new capital allocation method based

More information

Capital requirements, risk measures and comonotonicity

Capital requirements, risk measures and comonotonicity Capital requirements, risk measures and comonotonicity Jan Dhaene 1 Steven Vanduffel 1 Qihe Tang 2 Marc Goovaerts 3 Rob Kaas 2 David Vyncke 1 Abstract. In this paper we examine and summarize properties

More information

2 Modeling Credit Risk

2 Modeling Credit Risk 2 Modeling Credit Risk In this chapter we present some simple approaches to measure credit risk. We start in Section 2.1 with a short overview of the standardized approach of the Basel framework for banking

More information

Value at Risk, Expected Shortfall, and Marginal Risk Contribution, in: Szego, G. (ed.): Risk Measures for the 21st Century, p , Wiley 2004.

Value at Risk, Expected Shortfall, and Marginal Risk Contribution, in: Szego, G. (ed.): Risk Measures for the 21st Century, p , Wiley 2004. Rau-Bredow, Hans: Value at Risk, Expected Shortfall, and Marginal Risk Contribution, in: Szego, G. (ed.): Risk Measures for the 21st Century, p. 61-68, Wiley 2004. Copyright geschützt 5 Value-at-Risk,

More information

Conditional Value-at-Risk, Spectral Risk Measures and (Non-)Diversification in Portfolio Selection Problems A Comparison with Mean-Variance Analysis

Conditional Value-at-Risk, Spectral Risk Measures and (Non-)Diversification in Portfolio Selection Problems A Comparison with Mean-Variance Analysis Conditional Value-at-Risk, Spectral Risk Measures and (Non-)Diversification in Portfolio Selection Problems A Comparison with Mean-Variance Analysis Mario Brandtner Friedrich Schiller University of Jena,

More information

Solvency, Capital Allocation and Fair Rate of Return in Insurance

Solvency, Capital Allocation and Fair Rate of Return in Insurance Solvency, Capital Allocation and Fair Rate of Return in Insurance Michael Sherris Actuarial Studies Faculty of Commerce and Economics UNSW, Sydney, AUSTRALIA Telephone: + 6 2 9385 2333 Fax: + 6 2 9385

More information

To split or not to split: Capital allocation with convex risk measures

To split or not to split: Capital allocation with convex risk measures To split or not to split: Capital allocation with convex risk measures Andreas Tsanakas October 31, 27 Abstract Convex risk measures were introduced by Deprez and Gerber (1985). Here the problem of allocating

More information

Multivariate TVaR-Based Risk Decomposition for Vector-Valued Portfolios

Multivariate TVaR-Based Risk Decomposition for Vector-Valued Portfolios risks Article Multivariate TVaR-Based Risk Decomposition for Vector-Valued Portfolios Mélina Mailhot, * and Mhamed Mesfioui Department of Mathematics and Statistics, Concordia University, 400 de Maisonneuve

More information

A note on the stop-loss preserving property of Wang s premium principle

A note on the stop-loss preserving property of Wang s premium principle A note on the stop-loss preserving property of Wang s premium principle Carmen Ribas Marc J. Goovaerts Jan Dhaene March 1, 1998 Abstract A desirable property for a premium principle is that it preserves

More information

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Carole Bernard (Grenoble Ecole de Management) Hannover, Current challenges in Actuarial Mathematics November 2015 Carole Bernard Risk Aggregation with Dependence

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

Allocation of Risk Capital Based on Iso-Entropic Coherent Risk Measure

Allocation of Risk Capital Based on Iso-Entropic Coherent Risk Measure Journal of Industrial Engineering and Management JIEM, 2015 8(2): 530-553 Online ISS: 2013-0953 Print ISS: 2013-8423 http://dx.doi.org/10.3926/jiem.1375 Allocation of Risk Capital Based on Iso-Entropic

More information

Optimizing Portfolios

Optimizing Portfolios Optimizing Portfolios An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2010 Introduction Investors may wish to adjust the allocation of financial resources including a mixture

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Aggregating Economic Capital

Aggregating Economic Capital Aggregating Economic Capital J. Dhaene 1 M. Goovaerts 1 M. Lundin 2. Vanduffel 1,2 1 Katholieke Universiteit Leuven & Universiteit van Amsterdam 2 Fortis Central Risk Management eptember 12, 2005 Abstract

More information

Optimal reinsurance strategies

Optimal reinsurance strategies Optimal reinsurance strategies Maria de Lourdes Centeno CEMAPRE and ISEG, Universidade de Lisboa July 2016 The author is partially supported by the project CEMAPRE MULTI/00491 financed by FCT/MEC through

More information

Risk measures: Yet another search of a holy grail

Risk measures: Yet another search of a holy grail Risk measures: Yet another search of a holy grail Dirk Tasche Financial Services Authority 1 dirk.tasche@gmx.net Mathematics of Financial Risk Management Isaac Newton Institute for Mathematical Sciences

More information

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management Ineffectiveness of VaR and ES constraints John Armstrong (KCL), Damiano Brigo (Imperial) Quant Summit March 2018 Are ES constraints effective against rogue

More information

Mathematics in Finance

Mathematics in Finance Mathematics in Finance Steven E. Shreve Department of Mathematical Sciences Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213 USA shreve@andrew.cmu.edu A Talk in the Series Probability in Science and Industry

More information

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Carole Bernard GEM and VUB Risk: Modelling, Optimization and Inference with Applications in Finance, Insurance and Superannuation Sydney December 7-8, 2017

More information

Risk Measure and Allocation Terminology

Risk Measure and Allocation Terminology Notation Ris Measure and Allocation Terminology Gary G. Venter and John A. Major February 2009 Y is a random variable representing some financial metric for a company (say, insured losses) with cumulative

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Measures of Contribution for Portfolio Risk

Measures of Contribution for Portfolio Risk X Workshop on Quantitative Finance Milan, January 29-30, 2009 Agenda Coherent Measures of Risk Spectral Measures of Risk Capital Allocation Euler Principle Application Risk Measurement Risk Attribution

More information

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing Richard M. H. Suen University of Leicester 29 March 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/86499/ MPRA Paper

More information

Capital Allocation in Insurance: Economic Capital and the Allocation of the Default Option Value

Capital Allocation in Insurance: Economic Capital and the Allocation of the Default Option Value Capital Allocation in Insurance: Economic Capital and the Allocation of the Default Option Value Michael Sherris Faculty of Commerce and Economics, University of New South Wales, Sydney, NSW, Australia,

More information

Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game

Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Tokyo, June 2015 Haijun Li Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game Tokyo, June 2015 1

More information

Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles

Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles Ka Chun Cheung Email: kccheung@math.ucalgary.ca Tel: +1-403-2108697 Fax: +1-403-2825150 Department of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Calgary,

More information

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index Advanced Topics in Machine Learning and Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index Lecturer: Yishay Mansour Scribe: Mariano Schain 7.1 Introduction In the Bayesian approach

More information

SOLVENCY, CAPITAL ALLOCATION, AND FAIR RATE OF RETURN IN INSURANCE

SOLVENCY, CAPITAL ALLOCATION, AND FAIR RATE OF RETURN IN INSURANCE C The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2006, Vol. 73, No. 1, 71-96 SOLVENCY, CAPITAL ALLOCATION, AND FAIR RATE OF RETURN IN INSURANCE Michael Sherris INTRODUCTION ABSTRACT In this article, we consider the

More information

EXCHANGEABILITY HYPOTHESIS AND INITIAL PREMIUM FEASIBILITY IN XL REINSURANCE WITH REINSTATEMENTS

EXCHANGEABILITY HYPOTHESIS AND INITIAL PREMIUM FEASIBILITY IN XL REINSURANCE WITH REINSTATEMENTS International Journal of Pure and Applied Mathematics Volume 72 No. 3 2011, 385-399 EXCHANGEABILITY HYPOTHESIS AND INITIAL PREMIUM FEASIBILITY IN XL REINSURANCE WITH REINSTATEMENTS Antonella Campana 1,

More information

An overview of comonotonicity and its applications in finance and insurance

An overview of comonotonicity and its applications in finance and insurance An overview of comonotonicity and its applications in finance and insurance Griselda Deelstra Jan Dhaene Michèle Vanmaele December 11, 2009 Abstract Over the last decade, it has been shown that the concept

More information

TMV-based Capital Allocation for Multivariate Risks

TMV-based Capital Allocation for Multivariate Risks TMV-based Capital Allocation for Multivariate Risks Maochao Xu Department of Mathematics Illinois State University, Normal, IL, USA mxu2@ilstu.edu December 7, 2015 Abstract This paper studies a novel capital

More information

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator ISSN: 2455-216X Impact Factor: RJIF 5.12 www.allnationaljournal.com Volume 4; Issue 3; September 2018; Page No. 25-30 Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

More information

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing THE UNIVERSITY OF SOUTHAMPTON Paul Klein Office: Murray Building, 3005 Email: p.klein@soton.ac.uk URL: http://paulklein.se Economics 3010 Topics in Macroeconomics 3 Autumn 2010 Lecture 8: Introduction

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

COHERENT VAR-TYPE MEASURES. 1. VaR cannot be used for calculating diversification

COHERENT VAR-TYPE MEASURES. 1. VaR cannot be used for calculating diversification COHERENT VAR-TYPE MEASURES GRAEME WEST 1. VaR cannot be used for calculating diversification If f is a risk measure, the diversification benefit of aggregating portfolio s A and B is defined to be (1)

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

Compositional methods applied to capital allocation problems

Compositional methods applied to capital allocation problems Compositional methods applied to capital allocation problems Jaume Belles-Sampera a, Montserrat Guillen a and Miguel Santolino a January 20, 2016 Abstract In this article we examine the relationship between

More information

Study Guide on Non-tail Risk Measures for CAS Exam 7 G. Stolyarov II 1

Study Guide on Non-tail Risk Measures for CAS Exam 7 G. Stolyarov II 1 Study Guide on Non-tail Risk Measures for CAS Exam 7 G. Stolyarov II 1 Study Guide on Non-tail Risk Measures for the Casualty Actuarial Society (CAS) Exam 7 (Based on Gary Venter's Paper, "Non-tail Measures

More information

Risk Measures, Stochastic Orders and Comonotonicity

Risk Measures, Stochastic Orders and Comonotonicity Risk Measures, Stochastic Orders and Comonotonicity Jan Dhaene Risk Measures, Stochastic Orders and Comonotonicity p. 1/50 Sums of r.v. s Many problems in risk theory involve sums of r.v. s: S = X 1 +

More information

Statistical Methods in Financial Risk Management

Statistical Methods in Financial Risk Management Statistical Methods in Financial Risk Management Lecture 1: Mapping Risks to Risk Factors Alexander J. McNeil Maxwell Institute of Mathematical Sciences Heriot-Watt University Edinburgh 2nd Workshop on

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Allocation of Risk Capital and Performance Measurement

Allocation of Risk Capital and Performance Measurement Allocation of Risk Capital and Performance Measurement Uwe Schmock Research Director of RiskLab Department of Mathematics ETH Zürich, Switzerland Joint work with Daniel Straumann, RiskLab http://www.math.ethz.ch/

More information

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Lecture 8: Asset pricing BURNABY SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY BRITISH COLUMBIA Paul Klein Office: WMC 3635 Phone: (778) 782-9391 Email: paul klein 2@sfu.ca URL: http://paulklein.ca/newsite/teaching/483.php Economics 483 Advanced Topics

More information

The mathematical definitions are given on screen.

The mathematical definitions are given on screen. Text Lecture 3.3 Coherent measures of risk and back- testing Dear all, welcome back. In this class we will discuss one of the main drawbacks of Value- at- Risk, that is to say the fact that the VaR, as

More information

References. H. Föllmer, A. Schied, Stochastic Finance (3rd Ed.) de Gruyter 2011 (chapters 4 and 11)

References. H. Föllmer, A. Schied, Stochastic Finance (3rd Ed.) de Gruyter 2011 (chapters 4 and 11) General references on risk measures P. Embrechts, R. Frey, A. McNeil, Quantitative Risk Management, (2nd Ed.) Princeton University Press, 2015 H. Föllmer, A. Schied, Stochastic Finance (3rd Ed.) de Gruyter

More information

Introduction Models for claim numbers and claim sizes

Introduction Models for claim numbers and claim sizes Table of Preface page xiii 1 Introduction 1 1.1 The aim of this book 1 1.2 Notation and prerequisites 2 1.2.1 Probability 2 1.2.2 Statistics 9 1.2.3 Simulation 9 1.2.4 The statistical software package

More information

Budget Setting Strategies for the Company s Divisions

Budget Setting Strategies for the Company s Divisions Budget Setting Strategies for the Company s Divisions Menachem Berg Ruud Brekelmans Anja De Waegenaere November 14, 1997 Abstract The paper deals with the issue of budget setting to the divisions of a

More information

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. 3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. Orientation. In the examples studied in Chapter 1, we worked with a single period model and Gaussian returns; in this Chapter, we shall drop these assumptions

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Davit Khantadze September 30, 017 Abstract We are interested in optimal signals for the sender when the decision maker (receiver) has to make two separate decisions.

More information

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel) All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel) First Name: Waterloo, April 2013. Last Name: UW ID #:

More information

Lecture 5 Theory of Finance 1

Lecture 5 Theory of Finance 1 Lecture 5 Theory of Finance 1 Simon Hubbert s.hubbert@bbk.ac.uk January 24, 2007 1 Introduction In the previous lecture we derived the famous Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) for expected asset returns,

More information

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management Basic Concepts and Techniques of Risk Management Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand Alfredo Garcia and Robert L. Smith Department of Industrial and Operations Engineering Universityof Michigan, Ann Arbor MI 48109 December

More information

Comparing approximations for risk measures of sums of non-independent lognormal random variables

Comparing approximations for risk measures of sums of non-independent lognormal random variables Comparing approximations for risk measures of sums of non-independent lognormal rom variables Steven Vuffel Tom Hoedemakers Jan Dhaene Abstract In this paper, we consider different approximations for computing

More information

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note Working Paper Series Department of Economics University of Verona Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note Louis Raymond Eeckhoudt, Elisa Pagani, Emanuela Rosazza Gianin WP

More information

Robustness, Model Uncertainty and Pricing

Robustness, Model Uncertainty and Pricing Robustness, Model Uncertainty and Pricing Antoon Pelsser 1 1 Maastricht University & Netspar Email: a.pelsser@maastrichtuniversity.nl 29 October 2010 Swissquote Conference Lausanne A. Pelsser (Maastricht

More information

Reducing risk by merging counter-monotonic risks

Reducing risk by merging counter-monotonic risks Reducing risk by merging counter-monotonic risks Ka Chun Cheung, Jan Dhaene, Ambrose Lo, Qihe Tang Abstract In this article, we show that some important implications concerning comonotonic couples and

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Table of Contents Lecture 1... 7 1. State the objective of modern portfolio theory... 7 2. Define the return of an asset... 7 3. How is expected return defined?...

More information

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET Vol 18 No 2 Journal of Systems Science and Complexity Apr 2005 CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET SUN Wangui (School of Economics & Management Northwest University Xi an 710069 China Email: wans6312@pubxaonlinecom)

More information

Robustness issues on regulatory risk measures

Robustness issues on regulatory risk measures Robustness issues on regulatory risk measures Ruodu Wang http://sas.uwaterloo.ca/~wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo Robust Techniques in Quantitative Finance Oxford

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation Further Variance Reduction Methods Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com Outline

More information

Pricing in the Multi-Line Insurer with Dependent Gamma Distributed Risks allowing for Frictional Costs of Capital

Pricing in the Multi-Line Insurer with Dependent Gamma Distributed Risks allowing for Frictional Costs of Capital Pricing in the Multi-Line Insurer with Dependent Gamma Distributed Risks allowing for Frictional Costs of Capital Zinoviy Landsman Department of Statistics, Actuarial Research Centre, University of Haifa

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier Weerachart Kilenthong RIPED, UTCC c Kilenthong 2017 Tee (Riped) Introduction 1 / 43 Two Fund Theorem The Two-Fund Theorem states that we can reach any

More information

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén PORTFOLIO THEORY Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Portfolio Theory Investments 1 / 60 Outline 1 Modern Portfolio Theory Introduction Mean-Variance

More information

This version: December 3, 2009

This version: December 3, 2009 Rethinking risk capital allocation in a RORAC framework Arne Buch a, Gregor Dorfleitner b,*, Maximilian Wimmer b a d-fine GmbH, Opernplatz 2, 60313 Frankfurt, Germany b Department of Finance, University

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require Chapter 8 Markowitz Portfolio Theory 8.7 Investor Utility Functions People are always asked the question: would more money make you happier? The answer is usually yes. The next question is how much more

More information

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

Log-Robust Portfolio Management Log-Robust Portfolio Management Dr. Aurélie Thiele Lehigh University Joint work with Elcin Cetinkaya and Ban Kawas Research partially supported by the National Science Foundation Grant CMMI-0757983 Dr.

More information

On Tail Conditional Variance and Tail Covariances

On Tail Conditional Variance and Tail Covariances On Tail Conditional Variance and Tail Covariances Emiliano A. Valdez, PhD, FSA, FIAA School of Actuarial Studies Faculty of Commerce & Economics The University of New South Wales Sydney, AUSTRALIA 05 First

More information

Solution of the problem of the identified minimum for the tri-variate normal

Solution of the problem of the identified minimum for the tri-variate normal Proc. Indian Acad. Sci. (Math. Sci.) Vol., No. 4, November 0, pp. 645 660. c Indian Academy of Sciences Solution of the problem of the identified minimum for the tri-variate normal A MUKHERJEA, and M ELNAGGAR

More information

Asymptotic methods in risk management. Advances in Financial Mathematics

Asymptotic methods in risk management. Advances in Financial Mathematics Asymptotic methods in risk management Peter Tankov Based on joint work with A. Gulisashvili Advances in Financial Mathematics Paris, January 7 10, 2014 Peter Tankov (Université Paris Diderot) Asymptotic

More information

Backtesting Expected Shortfall: the design and implementation of different backtests. Lisa Wimmerstedt

Backtesting Expected Shortfall: the design and implementation of different backtests. Lisa Wimmerstedt Backtesting Expected Shortfall: the design and implementation of different backtests Lisa Wimmerstedt Abstract In recent years, the question of whether Expected Shortfall is possible to backtest has been

More information

Risk Measurement: History, Trends and Challenges

Risk Measurement: History, Trends and Challenges Risk Measurement: History, Trends and Challenges Ruodu Wang (wang@uwaterloo.ca) Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo, Canada PKU-Math International Workshop on Financial

More information

Portfolio selection with multiple risk measures

Portfolio selection with multiple risk measures Portfolio selection with multiple risk measures Garud Iyengar Columbia University Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Joint work with Carlos Abad Outline Portfolio selection and risk measures

More information

Risk exchange with distorted probabilities

Risk exchange with distorted probabilities Risk exchange with distorted probabilities Topic 2: Risk finance and risk transfer Tsanakas Andreas 1 Centre for Quantitative Finance, Imperial College Exhibition Road, London SW7 2BX, UK tel: +44 20 7594

More information

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring 2006 Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle 1 Overview This lecture derives the consumption-based capital asset pricing

More information

Non replication of options

Non replication of options Non replication of options Christos Kountzakis, Ioannis A Polyrakis and Foivos Xanthos June 30, 2008 Abstract In this paper we study the scarcity of replication of options in the two period model of financial

More information