Wage-led growth in the EU15 Member States:

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Wage-led growth in the EU15 Member States:"

Transcription

1 Wage-led growth in the EU15 Member States: The effects of income distribution on growth, investment, trade balance, and inflation Őzlem Onaran University of Greenwich And Thomas Obst University of Greenwich Year: 2015 No: GPERC28

2 Abstract: This paper estimates a multi-country demand-led growth model for EU15 countries. A decrease in the share of wages in national income in isolation leads to lower growth in Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and the United Kingdom, whereas it stimulates growth in Austria, Belgium, Denmark and Ireland. However, a simultaneous decline in the wage share leads to an overall decline in EU15 GDP; hence EU15 as a whole is a wage-led economy. Furthermore, Austria and Ireland also experience negative effects on growth when they decrease their wage share along with their trading partners. The results indicate that a decline in the wage share has had significant negative effects on growth in the EU15 countries and supports the case of wage coordination. We present different wage-led recovery scenarios taking into account further effects of a change in the wage share on prices, nominal unit labour costs, investment, and net exports. Keywords: Wage Share, Growth, European Multiplier, Demand Regime JEL Codes: E12, E22, E25 Acknowledgements: This paper has received funding from the Foundation of European Progressive Studies, TASC, and Irish Congress of Trade Unions for the project titled "Wage- Led Growth in Europe? Demand Effects of Changes in Functional Income Distribution in Financialised Open Economies." The authors are grateful to Maria Nikolaidi, Engelbert Stockhammer, Mehmet Ugur and participants in the 7 th annual PhD conference of the Post Keynesian Study Group, University of Greenwich, May 2015 for helpful comments. The usual disclaimers apply. Corresponding author: : Özlem Onaran: Greenwich Political Economy Research Centre, University of Greenwich, Park Row, Greenwich, London, SE10 9LS, UK, o.onaran@gre.ac.uk, phone: Thomas Obst: University of Greenwich, Park Row, Greenwich, London, SE10 9LS, UK, t.obst@greenwich.ac.uk

3 1. Introduction Starting in the 1980s, there has been a substantial decline in the share of wages in national income in the majority of the European countries. In contrast to conventional wisdom, this development was associated with a poor growth performance in most European countries. Indeed, the outbreak of the Great Recession in 2007 and slow recovery in the aftermath shed light on the limitations of the conventional growth strategy of Europe that claims wage moderation, i.e. real wage growth below the rate of growth in labour productivity, would lead to a more productive and dynamic economic system with enhanced growth performance as is repeatedly advocated by the European Commission (EC, 2006). In contrast, Post-Keynesian models of distribution and growth demonstrate that the relationship between the wage share and growth is an empirical matter, which depends on the structural characteristics of the economy. The significant fall in the wage share has also been associated with increasing personal income inequality. Daudey and Garcia-Penalosa (2007) show that changes in the factor distribution of income are an important explanatory determinant of personal income inequality. Similarly, Atkinson (2009) argues that analysing changes in functional income distribution is crucial to understand trends of increasing dispersion in personal incomes. In the rest of the paper, we will focus on changes in functional income distribution, which allows us to aggregate the effects of increasing inequality on demand. This paper offers a theoretical and empirical analysis of the effect of a pro-capital redistribution of income on growth in the EU15 countries. The model estimated in this paper is similar to the spirit of the post-keynesian/post-kaleckian demand-led growth model developed by Bhaduri and Marglin (1990), and aims at analysing the effects of a change in the wage share on growth. A priori one would expect a falling wage share, i.e. a rising profit share, to have negative effects on consumption, since the marginal propensity to consume out of wage 3

4 income is higher than that out of profit income, but positive effects on investment and net exports. However, the question whether the negative effect of an increasing profit share on consumption overpowers the positive effects on investment and net exports essentially becomes an empirical one, depending on the relative size of the consumption differential, the sensitivity of investment to profit and the sensitivity of net exports to unit labour costs. If the total effect is negative, the demand regime is called wage-led; otherwise it is profit-led. The post-keynesian/post-kaleckian theoretical framework highlights the central role of demand in determining growth in economies operating below full employment and points out the dual role of wages as a cost item to the firm but also as a source of demand in the economy. The flexible framework provided by the Bhaduri and Marglin (1990) model, which allows for both wage-led and profit-led demand regimes, lets us illuminate whether it is possible to promote higher growth with a more equitable income distribution in the case of Europe. Furthermore, by developing a multi-country model, we analyse whether coordinated wage policies present a feasible alternative to the European strategy of wage restraint. The novelty of this paper is that it integrates cross-country effects of a simultaneous decline in the wage share on demand in Europe. Previous studies have only analysed a subset of European countries 1 (i.e. Onaran and Galanis, 2014; Storm and Naastepad, 2012; Hein and Vogel 2008; Bowles and Boyer, 1995) or taken the Euro area (twelve West European member states) as a hypothetical aggregate economy without considering cross-country interactions (Stockhammer et al., 2009; Onaran and Galanis, 2014). To the best of our knowledge, Onaran and Galanis (2014) were the first to develop a theoretical and empirical multi-country model for the G20 countries, which inspired the empirical model in this paper. 1 Countries covered in the cited studies include Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Spain, Sweden and the UK. 4

5 We first provide new estimates for some individual EU15 countries previously not covered in the empirical literature. Second, we go beyond the nation state analysing the effects of a simultaneous fall in the wage share and its impact on growth in a highly integrated European economy. Third, we present different wage-led recovery scenarios and further effects of an increase in the wage share on prices, nominal unit labour costs, nominal wages, investment, and net exports. We first estimate the effects of a change in the wage share on individual components of private aggregate demand, which are consumption, investment and net exports for each EU15 country in isolation. Next, we calculate the effects of a simultaneous decline in the wage share, as has been the case in the majority of countries in the post-1980s. Finally, we estimate the response of each country to not only the domestic wage share but also the trade partners wage share, which affects the import prices and foreign demand of each country. The paper is structured as follows: Section 2 presents data and stylised facts. Section 3 presents the theoretical model. Sections 4 and 5 discuss the estimation methodology and results. Section 6 compares the findings to the empirical literature and section 7 presents different wage-led recovery scenarios and further effects. Section 8 summarises the key findings and discusses policy conclusions. 2. Data and Stylized Facts The definitions, calculations and sources of the variables in the model are presented in appendix A. C, I, X, M, Y, W and R are consumption expenditures, private investment expenditures, exports, imports, GDP, adjusted wages and adjusted profits, all variables are in real terms. Profit share, π, is adjusted gross operating surplus as a ratio to GDP at factor cost, Y f ; wage share, ws, is 1 π. Returns from self-employment income in national accounts accrue 5

6 to capital income and hence leads to lower wage shares, particularly in countries where selfemployment income plays a significant part in the economy. The adjusted wage share allocates a labour compensation for each self-employed equivalent to the average compensation of the dependent employees 2. The sample is restricted to EU15 countries 3, due to a lack of sufficient time series data for the new EU member states. The sample period is Figure 1 shows the wage share (in percentages) in the EU15 countries. There is an overall decline in the wage share in the majority of the countries, particularly pronounced between the early 1980s and mid-2000s. The fall is more moderate in Belgium, Denmark, and Luxembourg. In the UK, the fall in the ws is relatively lower. However, this may be due to a sharp increase in managerial income (OECD, 2012). Greece experienced a pronounced fall in the 1960s coming to a stop with the ending of the military dictatorship in the mid-1970s. Portugal exhibits an exceptional upswing followed by a significant downswing during the revolutionary period between 1974 and 1976 (Lagoa et al., 2014). Luxembourg, as an outlier, exhibits a significant increase starting in the early 1970s followed by a moderate decline after the early 1980s. Overall, the share of wages in national income has declined by roughly 10 percentage points in the EU15 countries between their latest peak levels (in the mid-1970s or early 1980s) and. Appendix B Table B1 presents average annual growth rates of GDP for 6 sub periods and shows that the secular decline in the wage share was associated with a weaker growth performance. For instance, average growth in France declined from 5.7% in the 1960s to roughly 2% in the 1990s. In Italy, average growth dropped significantly from almost 6% in the 1960s to roughly 1.5% in the 1990s. This trend holds true for the majority of countries. 2 This methodology is used by the European Commission to calculate the adjusted labour share. 3 Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom. 6

7 However, growth rates increased in the case of Ireland and Luxembourg. In the 1990s, Ireland experienced high growth rates of almost 7% followed by a slight decline to 5.5% in the 2000s, until the Great Recession in In the UK, average growth remained relatively stable, with values between 2% and 3% between the 1960s and 2000s. Overall, growth in the EU15 has declined along with the lower wage share since the 1980s. It has often been argued that job creation requires wage moderation. However, the association of a lower wage share with weaker GDP growth does not provide evidence in favour of wage-suppression policies. [Figure 1] 3. The Theoretical Model We model the effects of a change in the profit share on growth by analysing the country level effects on the components of private aggregate demand: consumption, investment, exports and imports. We then estimate European interactions resulting from the effects of a change in the profit share of other EU15 countries. The model is post-kaleckian, however, the behavioural functions also encompass standard Keynesian models (Blanchard, 2006). Consumption is commonly estimated as a function of income. In order to include the distributional effects, we estimate Consumption (C) as a function of adjusted profits (R) and adjusted wages (W) 4 : logc = c 0 + c R logr + c W logw (1) 4 All variables will be used in logarithmic form due to the fact that they exhibit exponential growth. 7

8 We calculate the marginal effects of a change in the profit share on C through multiplying the estimated coefficients (elasticities) of R and W by mean values of our sample C/R and C/W respectively. (C/Y) (π) C = c R c C R W W (2) The estimates are equivalent to the difference in marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of profits and wages, and are expected to be negative. Private Investment (I) is modelled as a positive function of output (accelerator effect) and the profit share as an indicator for expected profitability as well as for the availability of internal finance: logi = i A + i Y logy + i π logπ + i r r (3) where i A is autonomous investment, Y is real output, π is the profit share and all parameters are expected to be positive. As a control variable, we include real long-term interest rate r that represents a cost factor and is expected to have negative effects on investment 5. The marginal effect of π on I Y is calculated as follows: (I/Y) (π) = i π (4) The details of the derivation of the marginal affects can be found in appendix C. I R 5 We do not take log of the real interest rate since it includes negative values. 8

9 We model the effects of distribution on net exports using a stepwise approach that follows Stockhammer et al. (2009), Onaran et al. (2011) and Onaran and Galanis (2014). First, domestic prices (P) and export prices (P x ) are a function of nominal unit labour costs and import prices based on a mark-up pricing model in an imperfectly competitive economy. logp = p 0 + p ulc log (ulc) + p m log (Pm) (5) logp x = px 0 + p ulc log (ulc) + p m log (Pm) (6) where ulc is nominal unit labour costs and Pm is import prices, as a proxy for non-labour input costs and all parameters are expected to be positive. Exports (X) are a function of relative prices and GDP of the rest of the world: logx = x 0 + x pxm log (Px Pm) + x Yrw log (Yrw) + x e log (E) (7) where Px/Pm are relative prices of exports to imports and Yrw is the GDP of the rest of the world. We include exchange rate, E, as a control variable. Imports (M) are a function of relative prices and domestic GDP. logm = m 0 + m ppm log (P Pm) + m Y log (Y) + m e log (E) (8) where P/Pm is domestic prices relative to import prices and Y represents domestic GDP. Again, we include exchange rate E as a control variable. We calculate the marginal effect of a change in the profit share on exports/gdp as follows: 9

10 ( X Y ) (π) = ( ) ( logx logp x log(ulc) logp x log(ulc) log(rulc) log(rulc) log(ws) ) X/Y rulc = ( ) (e XPe Px 1 1 e P Yf Y ) X/Y rulc (9) where e Px illustrates the effect of nominal unit labour costs (ulc) on P x and e XP is the effect of P x on exports. The wage share is real unit labour costs (rulc) multiplied by GDP at market prices divided by GDP at factor costs (Y Y f ). Thus, the total effect of a change in ws on exports includes the effect of rulc on ulc, the effect of ulc on export prices, and the effect of P x on exports. The average values of X/Y for the sample mean are used to convert the elasticity to rulc marginal effects. Finally, we take the negation of the total effect 6. A similar procedure is followed for imports: (M/Y) (π) = ( ) ( logm logp logp log(ulc) log(rulc) M ) Y log(ulc) log(rulc) log(ws) (10) rulc = ( ) (e MP e PULC 1 1 e PULC Y f Y ) M/Y rulc The sum of partial effects of a change in π on consumption, investment, and net exports (NX = X M) is the effect on private excess demand. This, in turn, will further affect consumption, investment, and imports through the multiplier mechanism. 3.1 Effects of a simultaneous change in the profit share Until now, the unit of analysis has been the nation state. However, ignoring the effects due to a simultaneous change in distribution in Europe overestimates the positive effects of a fall in the ws on net exports. While higher openness of an economy increases the relevance of the positive effects of a fall in the ws due to a higher share of net exports in GDP, it is important to recognise that European economies are integrated and there has been a contagion effect of 6 The marginal effect of a 1%-point increase in π on exports and imports is the negation of the effect of a 1%- point increase in ws. 10

11 wage moderation policies as countries are trying to compete on the basis of wage costs. This decreases the effects of a fall in the ws on net exports when it is implemented simultaneously in a variety of countries, as relative prices of exports and imports do not change significantly when all countries reduce their ulc. As a result, analysing the full effects of the fall in the ws requires an integrated analysis that incorporates cross-country interactions 7. In the following, we present the European-wide effects of a simultaneous change in π in all economies based on the multi-country model developed in Onaran and Galanis (2014). This European multiplier mechanism incorporates the effects of a change in π on the aggregate demand of each economy through the changes in import prices and the GDP of trade partners. For the case of n countries, the percentage change in GDP of each country is Y 1 Y 1 Y n Y n π 1 = E nxn [ π n ] + H nxn Y 1 Y 1 Y n Y n π 1 + P nxn [ π n ] + W nxn Y 1 Y 1 Y n Y n (11) The matrices E and H represent the effects of a change in each country s own π on demand in that particular country. Matrices P and W add the effects of changes in import prices and GDP of trade partners on net exports of each country. E is a matrix, whose diagonal elements are the effect of a change in π in country j on private excess demand (C + I + NX/Y) in country j. Matrix H reflects the national multiplier effects and hence shows the effect of an autonomous change in private excess demand on aggregate demand. Matrix P illustrates the effect of a change in trade partners` π on import prices and hence on net exports in each country. Finally, matrix W shows effects of a change 7 Rezai (2011) and von Arnim et al. (2012) present theoretical models similar to the analysis in this paper. 11

12 in trade partners GPD on exports of each country. Solving equation (11) for [ Y ] gives us the Y equivalent of a European multiplier effect: Y 1 Y 1 Y n Y n π 1 = (I nxn H nxn W nxn ) 1 (E nxn + P nxn ) [ ] (12) π n The details on each matrix are shown in appendix D. Given the high economic integration of the European economy a full understanding of the simultaneous fall in the wage share requires an integrated European wide analysis. In, the greater proportion of a member states total trade in goods was with partners within the EU-28 with an average of 62% share of total exports (Eurostat, 2015). 3.2 Total effects on investment, net exports, and inflation Next we model the effects on investment to determine the character of the accumulation regime as defined in Bhaduri and Marglin (1990). A strong partial effect of π and a weak partial effect of Y on I favour a positive impact of pro-capital redistribution on investment, resulting in a I Y profit-led investment regime ( > 0). In the reverse constellation a pro-capital π redistribution would have a negative effect on investment leading to a wage-led investment I Y regime ( < 0). Therefore, the total effects will depend on whether the profitability or the π accelerator effects dominate as well as the sign and size of the overall effect of π on Y. We calculate the total effects on investment as follows: (13) I Y π Y = [( Y e I π IY Y ) + i π I R ] 12

13 where Y Y π illustrates the change in aggregate demand in the economy and e IY reflects the elasticity of investment to GDP. In order to convert elasticities into marginal effects we multiply with the sample mean of I. The first term is the ex-post multiplier indirect effect, Y whereas the second term is the direct partial profitability effect as calculated in equation (3). Regarding the trade balance, the total effect of a 1%-point increase in π on net exports in wage-led countries will be positive and larger after the multiplier due to a fall in imports following lower growth; however the effect in profit-led countries is theoretically ambiguous. There will be a positive effect on imports due to the rise in GDP in profit-led countries, which partially offsets the positive price competition effects and deteriorates the trade balance position. Furthermore, when there is a simultaneous change in all countries, and if the EU15 as a whole is wage-led, this leads to a decrease in trade partners GDP, and a negative effect on exports. This may offset the positive effects via prices; hence the total effect on trade balance is ambiguous in both the wage-led and profit-led economies. We calculate the post-multiplier net export effects as: where and NX/Y 1 π 1 NX/Y n π n π 1 = (NX nxn + P nxn ) [ ] + (W nxn M nxn ) π n NX nxn = M nxn = NX Y1 π NX Yn π n M 1 Y M n Y n Y/Y 1 π 1 Y/Y n π n (14) (15) (16) 13

14 where NX ii is X Y1 π 1 M Y1 π 1 calculated as in Equations (9) and (10) and M ii is calculated as e MYi M i Y i. NX represents a n x n matrix which includes the effects of a change in π in country i on net exports in country i. M is a n x n matrix which includes the effects of a change in π in country i on imports in country i. Next, we analyse the price effects of changes in income distribution. We calculate the percentage change in the domestic price level, i.e. inflation ( logp) as a response to an isolated change in π in one country as: logp π = [ logp logulc logulc logrulc logrulc logws ] 1 rulc = (e PULC 1 1 e PULC Y f Y ) 1 rulc (17) where e PULC illustrates the effect of ulc on P. We multiply with 1 rulc to convert elasticities to marginal effects. We take the negation of the total effect in order to simulate an increase in π. Next, we calculate the effects of a simultaneous change in π on prices in each country as: where ΔlogP π 1 ΔlogP π n π 1 = (DP nxn [ ] + PM nxn [ π n 0 π 2 π n π 1 π 1 π 2 0 p m1 ] [ ]) (18) p mn and DP nxn = ΔlogP π ΔlogP π n (19) PM nxn = 0 log(p x ) 2 M 21 log(p x) n M n1 π 2 M 1 π n M 1 log(p x ) 1 M 12 π 1 M 2 0 log(p x ) 1 π 1 M 1n M n log(p x ) 2 π 2 M 2n M n 0 (20) 14

15 where DP ii is logp π as calculated in equation (17) and PM ijis calculated as: PM ij = log(p x) j M ji 1 = (e π j M Pxj i Yf j 1 ) M ji 1 e pj Y j rulc j M i (21) DP represents a n x n matrix which includes the effects of a change in π in country i on domestic prices in country i. PM is a n x n matrix which includes the effects of a change in π in country j on inflation in country i via changes in the import prices of country i. As wage negotiations are conducted in nominal terms we are also interested in the relationship between nominal wages and the ws. However, this includes also changes in productivity growth. We derive the required % change in the nominal wage rate as follows: log (ulc) = Δlogw Δlogz (22) where Δlog (ulc) illustrates a log change in nominal unit labour costs and is the difference between a log change in the nominal wage rate, Δlogw and a log change in total labour productivity, Δlogz. Hence, to calculate the required % change in the w we rearrange: Δlogw = Δlog (ulc) + Δlogz (23) 4. Estimation methodology We apply a single-equation approach in order to analyse the effects of the changes in the ws on growth for EU15 countries. We estimate the distributional effects on individual components of private aggregate demand, which are consumption, investment, exports and imports for each country as is widely applied in the literature (Stockhammer et al., 2009; Onaran and Galanis, 2014; Hein and Vogel, 2008). Unit root tests suggest that most of our variables are integrated of order one. Therefore, we will take first differences of the variables to avoid possible spurious regressions. The profit share is stationary in Greece, Netherlands, Spain, Sweden and the UK and hence we use this variable in its level 15

16 in these countries. Error-correction models (ECM) are applied wherever statistically significant 8. In all estimations we start with general specifications with both the contemporaneous values and first lags of the variables as well as a lagged dependent variable, and keep those variables, which are statistically significant. Wherever there is autocorrelation, either the lagged dependent variable is kept or an AR(1) term is added. The single equation approach has several advantages. It allows for flexible modelling of the individual behavioural functions for single countries and to detect the precise economic relationships between demand and changes in income distribution (Onaran and Galanis, 2014). Moreover, it is possible to distinguish between domestic and total effects that include international trade. However, it fails to account for the fact that C, I and NX add up to private demand. The main alternative, a vector autoregression model, estimates the goods market equilibrium in a full model and has been applied by Onaran and Stockhammer (2005) or Stockhammer and Onaran (2004), among others. The advantage of this approach is that the interaction between the variables can be incorporated and it allows for tracing effects through an entire system rather than analysing one equation at a time. Also, it is more suitable to deal with simultaneity bias. However, using this approach would require a substantial simplification of the model since it cannot handle more than five endogenous variables (Onaran and Galanis, 2014). In the context of our analysis, this would lead to a misspecification of the behavioural functions and does not give a precise account of the effects of the ws on C, I and NX. The second major qualification relates to changes in the functional income distribution. In order to focus on the determinants of demand we take the ws as exogenous assuming that the time lag of potential feedback effects takes longer than one year. However, it is important to recognize that income distribution is endogenous (i.e. a higher unemployment rate lowers the wage share) in reality. Endogenising income distribution is not feasible in the absence of appropriate instrumental variables and using earlier lags is also not possible due to the short time series data. 8 The t-ratios reported by Banerjee et al. (1998) are used for the speed of adjustment coefficient to test whether there is cointegration among the variables. 16

17 5. Estimation Results The regression results for consumption are in Table 1. The hypothesis that the marginal propensity to consume between profit income and wage income differs is confirmed in all countries. The estimation results for investment are given in Table 2. In all countries, GDP has strong and significant accelerator effects on private investment. The effects of π are less robust across countries; it has no statistically significant effect in Austria, Finland, Germany 9, Greece, Luxembourg, Portugal and the UK. In these cases the effects are treated as zero when we calculate the total effects on private excess demand. [Table 1] [Table 2] Comparing these results to previous findings in the empirical literature (Onaran and Galanis, 2014; Hein and Vogel, 2008; Stockhammer et al., 2009) we find a general breakdown of the profit-investment nexus since the start of the Great Recession in Onaran et al. (2011) find that in the case of the US when interest and dividend payments are deducted from the profit share, there is a positive effect on investment illustrating the impact of financialisation on the sensitivity of investment to π. Such a correction, however, is beyond the scope of this paper due to limited time series data on dividend payments in most EU15 countries. The estimation results for domestic prices, export prices as well as exports and imports are given in Tables 3 to 6 respectively. The results are in line with our expectations, except in Belgium, Ireland, Luxembourg, Netherlands, and Portugal there are no significant effects of export prices relative to import prices on exports. Similarly, we find no statistically significant effects of domestic prices relative to import prices on imports in the case of Denmark, Finland, Germany, Greece, and Luxembourg. Table E1 in appendix E summarises the effects of a change in π on X/Y and M Y as described in Equations 9 While Onaran and Galanis (2014) found π to be significant in the investment equation in Germany we found it to be insignificant with revised data for both samples and Our findings are in accordance with Stockhammer et al. (2011) and Hein and Vogel (2008). 17

18 9 and 10. The total effect does depend not only on the elasticity of exports and imports to relative prices and the pass through from labour costs to prices, but also on the share of the respective component in GDP. As a result, in small open economies the effects are likely to be much larger compared to large relatively closed economies. [Table 3] [Table 4] [Table 5] [Table 6] 5.1 National effects Table 7 summarizes the effects of a 1%-point increase in π on components of private aggregate demand: consumption, investment, exports and imports. The first column reports the partial effects on consumption. The marginal propensity to consume out of wages is higher than out of profits, thus a rise in π negatively affects consumption. The differences between marginal propensities to consume range mostly between (Ireland) and (Greece). However, Belgium, Denmark and Luxembourg have relatively low (-0.15) albeit statistically significant negative consumption differentials 10. The second column gives the partial effects on private investment. A 1%-point increase in π in the EU15 countries leads to an increase in investment with values ranging between 0.07%-points (Netherlands) to 0.20%-points (Belgium) as a ratio to GDP. If we sum up the effects of an increase in π on domestic private demand the negative effect on consumption is substantially larger than the positive effect on investment in absolute values in 13 out of 15 countries 11. Thus, domestic demand in the EU15 is clearly wage-led. 10 The results are robust when we use unadjusted wages or wage share as the regressors. Our mean differential is minus and hence in alignment with previous studies, i.e. Marglin and Bhaduri (1992) find a savings differential of 0.37 for a sample of sixteen OECD countries. 11 Belgium and Denmark are two exceptions in our sample. 18

19 The integration of the foreign sector, however, has a crucial role in determining whether an economy is wage-led or profit-led (Blecker, 1989). The effects of a 1%-point increase in π on net exports range between 0.05%-points (Germany) to 0.40%-points (Austria) as a ratio to GDP. Column F sums up the partial effects on private excess demand when π increases in each country in isolation. Overall, large economies such as the UK, Germany, France, Italy, Spain as well as some small economies such as Greece, Portugal, Sweden, Finland, Netherlands, Luxemburg are wageled.. Two small economies, Austria and Ireland are profit-led when integrating the foreign sector, as well as Belgium and Denmark, which already had profit-led domestic demand due to low consumption differentials and high investment effects. Column G reports the multiplier, which was calculated using the elasticities of C, I, and M with regard to Y. The details of this calculation are presented in appendix F table F1. The multipliers are mostly above one and range between 1.03 in Austria and 2.1 in Spain, with only three small open countries having a multiplier less than one (Belgium, Ireland, Luxembourg, Netherlands) 12. When multiplier effects are taken into account, the effect of a change in distribution on demand becomes amplified (for countries with multipliers larger than one). Column H in Table 7 reports the %-change in equilibrium aggregate demand after the multiplier mechanism. [Table 7] 5.2 Europe-wide effects Next, we analyse the effects of a simultaneous 1%-point increase in π taking place in all EU15 countries. Column I in Table 7 presents the results. Most strikingly, two economies, which were profit-led in isolation Austria and Ireland, also start to contract after the incorporation of further effects on their net exports due to decreasing wage shares of their trade partners, which reduce export prices and GDP of the trade partners, which are wage-led. Thus, when everyone is pursuing the same wage competition 12 The IMF (2009) reports capital spending multipliers between 0.5 and

20 strategy in Europe the expansionary effects of an increase in π are reversed as relative price effects are moderated and external demand dampens. Comparing columns H and I in table 7, wage-led economies experience even stronger negative effects on demand. Demand in the large economies (rather closed) such as Germany, France, Spain, Italy and the UK now decrease by 0.23% to 0.54%. Demand in small open economies such as Ireland, Greece, Austria, Sweden, Finland, and Portugal decrease by 0.07% and 1.03%. Greece, albeit a small open economy, stands out as a strongly wage-led economy due to very low sensitivity of exports to labour costs, no significant effect of labour costs on imports and no significant effects of profitability on private investment. Even in isolation, a rise in the profit share leads to a 0.92% fall in demand, and the effect increases further after a race to the bottom in the wage share in Europe. Indeed, only Belgium and Denmark do not contract as an outcome of a simultaneous increase in π; however, the effects on growth diminish significantly in these countries as well and become almost economically insignificant, close to zero in the case of Belgium. Overall, a simultaneous decline in the ws in all countries leads to a decline in the EU15 GDP by 0.30%. 5.3 Robustness Checks In order to account for the exceptional behaviour of the economies during the crisis years we have checked the robustness of our results using a reduced sample size between 1960 and However, the results are overall robust when estimations are repeated excluding the Great Recession years. As a second robustness check, we used unadjusted wages. We again found that the results are robust. Furthermore, since the European effects are estimated on the basis of separate equations for each country, we also tested a seemingly unrelated regression model (SUR) to check for the robustness of our results. Indeed, we found the cross-correlation among the error terms of all six equations (C, I, P, P x, X, M) for the EU15 countries to be statistically significant. In other words, there is a common factor that simultaneously affects all EU15 countries. This is plausible since the EU15 represent a highly 13 Results are available upon request. 20

21 integrated economy, i.e. are affected by a common monetary policy. However, SUR methodology comes at a cost. First, our SUR estimations show that we do not increase statistical significance by applying a systems approach 14. In contrast, in the investment specifications effects of π on investment becomes insignificant in the case of France, Spain, and Sweden, as opposed to the significant effects in the single equation estimations. Moreover, there are strong contagion effects within the systems approach; thus a missspecified equation in one country leads to a change in otherwise significant results in other country specifications. Most importantly, our overall findings remain robust when estimating a SUR model, e.g. the EU15 GDP declines by 0.34%-points according to the SUR results, which is very close to the result based on single country simulations and still indicates that Europe as a whole is wageled. 6. Comparison with the literature Our results are in alignment with those of Onaran and Galanis (2014), Storm and Naastepad (2012), Stockhammer et al. (2011), Stockhammer and Ederer (2008) for Austria, Finland, Germany, France, Italy, Netherlands, Spain, Sweden and the UK 15. Storm and Naastepad (2012) find Denmark to be wage-led in domestic demand as well as total demand and Belgium to be undefined. However, their estimations do not pay attention to unit root issues. Furthermore, international trade is modelled by means of estimating the effects of real unit labour costs directly on exports, and they do not estimate the effects on imports. Bowles and Boyer (1995) find profit-led regimes in total demand in Germany and France. However, while their paper is seminal in terms of testing strategy, they do not discuss the time series properties of their variables and hence do not apply difference or error correction models. 14 Results are available upon request. 15 In alignment with our estimation strategy we focus on the empirical literature employing a single equation approach. Other studies (i.e. Onaran and Stockhammer, 2005) have applied a vector autoregressive approach. Stockhammer et al. (2009) and Onaran and Galanis (2014) provide more extensive reviews of the empirical literature. 21

22 Stockhammer and Stehrer (2011), focusing on domestic demand only, find mixed results for Ireland, depending on the amount of lags included. However, they find perverse but statistically insignificant consumption effects. In alignment with our findings, the authors find domestic demand in Luxembourg to be wage-led. Hein and Vogel (2008) differ from our results regarding the Netherlands only, which they find to be profit-led. However, the unconventional finding that domestic demand is profit-led drives these results. Overall, our results confirm the findings of the majority of studies that domestic demand tends to be wage-led; aggregate demand in large economies also tend to be wage-led, whereas small open economies may be profit-led due to international trade effects. To the best of our knowledge, this paper is the first to estimate the aggregate demand regime in Greece, Portugal, Ireland and Luxembourg. 7. Wage-led recovery scenarios In this section, we set out the effects on growth of an alternative scenario of a simultaneous wage-led recovery in the EU15 countries over the next 5 years. Obviously, if all countries increase their wage share by 1%-point EU15 GDP would go up by 0.30%. In this scenario, however, the small open economies Belgium and Denmark would contract. In table 8, we illustrate three alternative scenarios that take into account country specific room for manoeuvre to increase the wage share. In the first scenario in Table 8, all EU15 countries increase their wage shares back to the latest peak level, which would trigger an increase in EU15 GDP of 2.56%. However, Denmark would again contract. In the second scenario, all EU15 countries follow a differentiated increase in the ws with a 5%- point increase in the wage-led countries, a 3%-point increase in the intermediate group of Ireland and Austria which become wage-led in the race to the bottom scenario, and a 1%-point increase in Belgium and Denmark, which remain profit-led countries also in the race to the bottom scenario. In this scenario, 22

23 all EU15 countries can grow along with an improvement in the ws leading to an increase in EU15 GDP of 1.51%. Finally, we can simulate a mix of the first and second scenario by outlining a wage share recovery back to the peak level in wage-led countries and a homogenous 3%-point increase in profitled countries. In this scenario, all countries can grow along with an increase in the ws and EU15 GDP increases by 3.15%. [Table 8] 7.1 Effects on Investment and Trade Balance In this section, we focus on the effects on investment and net exports. Appendix G Table G1 shows the total effects of a 1%-point increase in π on investment and net exports in the EU15 countries in isolation. The effects of a 1%-point increase in π are on investment are diverse. In isolation, investment regime is wage-led, i.e. the effect of a rise in π on I/Y is negative in Finland, Germany, Greece, Luxembourg, Portugal, Spain, and the UK whereas the investment regime is profit led in Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands, and Sweden. The effects are ranging from strong negative effects in wage-led countries such as Greece (-0.43) to moderate positive effects in profit-led countries (0.27) in Denmark. The effects on the trade balance are almost always positive. Belgium is an exception with a negative effect of due to very low positive net export effects via the price channel and a strong increase in imports following the increase in aggregate demand. In other countries, the effects on net exports/gdp are ranging between 0.07 (Ireland) and 0.32 (Austria). The total effects on net exports are larger than the partial effects via price channels in wage-led economies, and lower in profit-led countries (compared to the partial effects reported in Column E in Table 7). Next, we report the total effects on investment and net exports following a simultaneous 1%- point increase in π in the EU15 countries in Appendix G table G2. In this case Austria also experiences a decline in investment following a simultaneous 1%-point increase in π and hence 8 countries have a wage-led investment regime. The negative effects of a simultaneous rise in π on investment is larger 23

24 (in absolute value) in countries with wage-led investment regimes, and countries with profit-led investment regimes now experience smaller increases in investment due to more moderate growth effects (comparing columns one in Tables G1 and G2). Regarding the net exports effects, in all countries, the total effects of a simultaneous rise in π is lower (reported in the second column of Table G2) compared to the effects of an isolated change in π (reported in the second column of Table G1) due to the fall in external demand. On average, however, net exports would still increase by 0.16%-points in the EU15 as a whole. Net exports decline only in Belgium. Finally, Table 9 column C and D show the effects of a (simultaneous) differentiated increase in the ws based on scenario 2 in Table 8 (column A and B in Table 9), on investment and trade balance in the EU15 countries. In 9 European countries the positive accelerator effects overpower the negative profitability effects leading to a wage-led investment regime. Greece experiences the strongest positive effects on I Yof roughly 2.4%-points. We find a profit-led investment regime in Belgium, France, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands and Sweden with negative effects ranging between -0.05%-points and -0.41%-points. While further investment policies are undoubtedly required, particularly in countries with profit-led investment regimes, overall, due to increasing GDP and hence strong accelerator effects a wage-led recovery could generate an increase of 0.24%-points in I/Y in the EU15. The effects of a differentiated increase in the ws on net exports are negative in the majority of the EU15 except Belgium and Denmark as can be seen in Table 9 column D. While net exports/gdp decrease by only 0.05%-points in Ireland, it decreases by 1.40%-points in Greece. [Table 9] 7.2 Effects on Prices and Nominal Unit Labour Costs In this section, we analyse to what extent a wage stimulus in the EU15 countries would exert inflationary pressures. 24

25 Appendix G table G3 summarises the effects of a 1%-point increase in the wage share in isolation and simultaneously as well as a differentiated simultaneous increase in the ws on annual inflation. On average, annual inflation would rise by 1.4%-point as an outcome of a simultaneous 1%-point increase in the wage share in the EU15 countries, and 1.2%-point following a differentiated increase in the ws as suggested in Scenario 2 in Table 8. It is plausible that the effects on inflation are not as strong as the effects on nominal ulc since firms might not be able translate higher costs into higher prices, particularly in relatively open economies 16. As an outcome of our wage-led recovery Scenario 2, the majority of countries would experience increasing inflation rates well below the ECB target inflation rate, which is below (but close to) 2%. In Spain and the UK the increase in annual inflation marginally exceeds this limit, and in Italy it would lead to an increase in inflation rate of 2.7%-points. In light of a risk of deflation in the Eurozone our findings indicate that a wage stimulus in the EU15 would indeed help keeping the European economy away from deflation. Since collective wage bargaining negotiations are conducted in nominal terms, we also calculate the required annual increase in the nominal wage rate to increase the ws by 1%-point. On average, a 1% point increase in the ws would increase ulc by 2.8% in the EU15 countries (appendix G table G3). Labour factor productivity in the EU15 countries increased by roughly 0.7% in the decade between 1997 and 2007 on average excluding the crisis years. Scenario 2 would be consistent with an annual nominal wage increase of 3.1% in the EU15 on average (e.g. 1.9% in Ireland, 3.6% in Greece). 8. Conclusions The empirical analysis in this paper has highlighted that a simultaneous decline in the wage share in a highly integrated European economy leads to a decline in growth, although the magnitude of the effect is not large. Hence there is room to stimulate demand in the current economic climate of deficient 16 Stockhammer et al. (2011) find that a change in rulc by 1% will come with an increase of 0.72% in inflation in the case of Germany. They analyse different sub-sample periods and their results indicate that an increased openness of the German economy limits the ability of firms to pass on an increase in ulc. 25

26 demand and sluggish growth: A 1%-point increase in the wage share at the European level could lead to a 0.30% increase in EU15 GDP. In alignment with previous research, the negative effects of a fall in the wage share on consumption overpower the positive effects on investment in 13 European countries. Domestic demand is hence clearly wage-led in the EU15. Small open economies may have a profit-led regime when the foreign sector is included due to a higher degree of openness of the economy, whereas the net export effects tend not to dominate in relatively closed large economies. In isolation, we have found 11 countries to be wage-led and 4 countries to be profit-led. This paper went beyond the nation state and estimated the impact of a simultaneous decline in the wage share on demand and hence growth in EU15 countries. In a scenario of a simultaneous fall in the wage share, the positive net export effects are essentially wiped out leaving profit-led demand regimes in only Belgium and Denmark. Thus, when all EU15 countries pursue beggar thy neighbour policies, the competitiveness effects will be minor while the domestic effects dominate. A cautious interpretation of the empirical results suggests that a more equal income distribution does not hamper growth in Europe. The results also illustrate a fallacy of composition issue between the micro rationale and macro outcomes of a pro-capital redistribution. While a higher profit share seems to be beneficial to the individual firm, in a wage-led economy it creates a problem of realisation of profits due to deficient demand. By the same token, even if increasing profit shares seem to promote growth at the national level in some profit-led economies, at the European level a simultaneous fall in the wage share leads to European demand deficiency as well as contraction, even in originally profit-led economies such as Austria and Ireland. The estimated model in this paper has been kept simple to analyse the role of income distribution in determining private demand. Possible extensions include a richer modelling of the government sector, i.e. the potential crowding in effects on private investment. The applied estimation approach might introduce some bias resulting from endogeneity issues and single-equation-based estimations. However, our results are robust across different sample sizes, and 26

27 estimation methods (i.e. the use of SUR) and in alignment with the findings of the majority of previous studies. Moreover, our results are consistent with the intuition that the EU15 countries have low extra regional trade and hence represent a rather closed economy. Policies of internal devaluation have been negative for demand and growth in the EU15 countries. In an alternative scenario of a wage-led recovery, we have shown that it is possible for all countries to grow along a simultaneous differentiated increase in the wage share. If large wage-led economies take the initiative, egalitarian growth becomes feasible including in small open economies. Furthermore, as a result of a wage-led recovery policy, annual inflation in the EU15 countries would remain well below the ECB target inflation rate. Therefore, a coordinated wage stimulus can keep the European economy away from deflation. An increase in the wage share, interestingly, does not negatively impact the investment performance in the EU15 as a whole with most countries experiencing an increase in investment. The impact of wage increases on trade imbalances across countries require further targeted industrial policy at the European level. Achieving convergence in the level of nominal unit labour costs and overcoming persistent imbalances requires a more comprehensive policy mix of wage policies, investment and industrial policies. Our results have important policy implications. First, if a country is wage-led, increasing the wage share is not an impediment to growth. Second, wage policy coordination in a highly integrated Europe, which tends to be wage-led, can improve growth and employment. Third, a coordinated wage stimulus does not have negative effects on investment in aggregate and induced inflation does not conflict with the ECB inflation target. Finally, a wage-led recovery scenario as an alternative to the current strategy of wage moderation implemented in the European countries is feasible, given that the coordination problem can be overcome. 27

28 References Atkinson, A.B Factor shares: the principal problem of political economy? Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol. 25, no. 1, 3-16 Banerjee, A., Dolado, J.J. and Mestre, R Error-correction Mechanism Tests for Cointegration in a Single-equation Framework, Journal of Time Series Analysis, vol. 19, no. 3, Bhaduri, A. and Marglin, S Unemployment and the real wage - The Economic- Basis for contesting political ideologies, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 14, no.4, Blanchard, O Macroeconomics, 4 ed., New York, Prentice Hall Blecker, R.A International competition, Income Distribution and Economic Growth, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 13, no.3, Blecker, R. A Distribution, Demand, and Growth in Neo-Kaleckian Macro Models. In: Setterfield, M. (ed.) The Economics of Demand-Led Growth: Challenging the Supply-Side Vision of the Long Run, Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA, Edward Elgar Bowles, S. and Boyer, R Wages, aggregate demand, and employment in an open economy: an empirical investigation. In: Epstein, G.A. and Gintis, H. (eds.). Macroeconomic policy after the conservative era, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press Daudey, E. and Garcia-Penalosa, C The personal and the factor distributions of income in a cross-section of countries, Journal of Development Studies, vol. 43, no. 5, European Commission, Time to move up a gear: the new partnership for jobs and growth, Commission's January 2006 Annual Progress Report, European Commission [date last accessed 01 February 2015] Eurostat Intra-EU27 trade, by Member State, total product, dplugin=1, [date last accessed 01. March 2015] Glyn, A Functional distribution and inequality. In: Salverda, W., Nolan, B. and Smeeding, T.M. (eds.). The Oxford Handbook of Economic Inequality, Oxford, Oxford University Press Hein, E. and Vogel, L Distribution and growth reconsidered: empirical results for six OECD Countries, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 32, no. 3, IMF, Global Economic Policies and Prospects, Meeting of the Ministers and Central Bank Governors, March 13 14, London, UK, [date last accessed 02 February 2015] Lagoa, S., Leao, E., Mamede, R. and Barradas, R Report on the financial system in Portugal, FESSUD studies, [date last accessed 01. February 2015] Marglin, S.A. and Bhaduri, A Profit Squeeze and Keynesian Theory. In: Marglin, S.A. and Schor, J.B. (eds.). The Golden Age of Capitalism: Reinterpreting the Postwar Experience, Oxford, Oxford University Press Naastepad, C.W. and Storm, S OECD demand regimes ( ), Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, vol. 29, no. 2, OECD OECD Employment Outlook [date last accessed ] Onaran, O. and Galanis, G Income distribution and growth: a global model, Environment and Planning A, vol. 46, no. 10, Onaran, O. and Stockhammer, E Two different export-oriented growth strategies Accumulation and distribution in Turkey and South Korea, Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, vol. 41, no. 1, Onaran, O., Stockhammer, E. and Grafl, L Financialisation, income distribution and aggregate demand in the USA, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 35, no. 4, Rezai, A The political economy implications of general equilibrium analysis in open economy macro models, Working Paper 11/2011, Department of Economics, New School for Social 28

The Case for a Coordinated Policy Mix of Wage-led Recovery and Public

The Case for a Coordinated Policy Mix of Wage-led Recovery and Public In partnership with The Case for a Coordinated Policy Mix of Wage-led Recovery and Public Investment in the G20 Economic Modelling Results prepared for the L20 * By Professor Ozlem Onaran, University of

More information

The working people of the UK are stronger in Europe

The working people of the UK are stronger in Europe The working people of the UK are stronger in Europe Özlem Onaran www.gre.ac.uk/gperc Outline The working people in the UK have good reasons to vote to stay in the European Union, but not for the same reasons

More information

Productivity puzzle? Financialization, inequality, investment in the UK

Productivity puzzle? Financialization, inequality, investment in the UK Productivity puzzle? Financialization, inequality, investment in the UK Özlem Onaran and Daniele Tori, University of Greenwich 2017: No. #PB16-2017 GREENWICH POLITICAL ECONOMY RESEARCH CENTRE (GPERC) 1

More information

WORKINGPAPER SERIES. Income Distribution and Aggregate Demand: A Global Post-Keynesian Model. Özlem Onaran and Giorgos Galanis.

WORKINGPAPER SERIES. Income Distribution and Aggregate Demand: A Global Post-Keynesian Model. Özlem Onaran and Giorgos Galanis. Income Distribution and Aggregate Demand: A Global Post-Keynesian Model Özlem Onaran and Giorgos Galanis RESEARCH INSTITUTE POLITICAL ECONOMY Gordon Hall 418 North Pleasant Street Amherst, MA 01002 April

More information

Wage- versus Profit-led Growth in the Context of International. Interactions and Public Spending: The Political Aspects of Wage-led Recovery

Wage- versus Profit-led Growth in the Context of International. Interactions and Public Spending: The Political Aspects of Wage-led Recovery Wage- versus Profit-led Growth in the Context of International Interactions and Public Spending: The Political Aspects of Wage-led Recovery Özlem Onaran February 2016 PKSG Post Keynesian Economics Study

More information

Policy Paper. State intervention for wage-led development. Professor Özlem Onaran

Policy Paper. State intervention for wage-led development. Professor Özlem Onaran Policy Paper State intervention for wage-led development Professor Özlem Onaran September 2014 Policy Series In the public interest: the role of the modern state All societies across the world have some

More information

Functional Income Distribution and Growth in Thailand: Single Equation Estimations Based on Bhaduri/Marglin Model

Functional Income Distribution and Growth in Thailand: Single Equation Estimations Based on Bhaduri/Marglin Model Functional Income Distribution and Growth in Thailand: Single Equation Estimations Based on Bhaduri/Marglin Model Second draft, please do not quote. Bruno Jetin Ozan Ekin Kurt Centre d Économie de Paris

More information

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area Presentation by Val Koromzay, Director for Country Studies, OECD to the Brussels Forum, April 2004 1 1 I. Introduction: Why is the issue important?

More information

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 ) II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 ) There have been significant fluctuations in the euro exchange rate since the start of the monetary union. This section assesses

More information

2 nd Kazimierz Łaski Lecture

2 nd Kazimierz Łaski Lecture The origins and evolution of the debate on wage-led and profit-led regimes Marc Lavoie Université Paris 13 2 nd Kazimierz Łaski Lecture Kazimierz Łaski and me! Krakow, EAEPE, 2012 Buenos Aires, CBRA, June

More information

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study 47 Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study Jacob Isaksen, Paul Lassenius Kramp, Louise Funch Sørensen and Søren Vester Sørensen, Economics INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY What are the

More information

Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model

Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model By Ana Buisán, Juan Carlos Caballero and Noelia Jiménez, Directorate General Economics, Statistics and Research

More information

Danmarks Nationalbank. Monetary Review 2nd Quarter

Danmarks Nationalbank. Monetary Review 2nd Quarter Danmarks Nationalbank Monetary Review 2nd Quarter 1999 D A N M A R K S N A T I O N A L B A N K 1 9 9 9 Danmarks Nationalbank Monetary Review 2nd Quarter 1999 The Monetary Review is published by Danmarks

More information

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE This article was downloaded by: [Hein, Eckhard] On: 5 May 2009 Access details: Access Details: [subscription number 910948191] Publisher Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered

More information

II. Underlying domestic macroeconomic imbalances fuelled current account deficits

II. Underlying domestic macroeconomic imbalances fuelled current account deficits II. Underlying domestic macroeconomic imbalances fuelled current account deficits Macroeconomic imbalances, including housing and credit bubbles, contributed to significant current account deficits in

More information

PUBLIC FINANCE IN THE EU: FROM THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA TO THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT

PUBLIC FINANCE IN THE EU: FROM THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA TO THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT 8 : FROM THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA TO THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT Ing. Zora Komínková, CSc., National Bank of Slovakia With this contribution, we open up a series of articles on public finance

More information

INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC STUDIES

INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC STUDIES ISSN 1011-8888 INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC STUDIES WORKING PAPER SERIES W17:04 December 2017 The Modigliani Puzzle Revisited: A Note Margarita Katsimi and Gylfi Zoega, Address: Faculty of Economics University

More information

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001 4 The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 200 Tina Winther Frandsen, International Relations INTRODUCTION The EU member states' public finances showed remarkable development during the 990s. In 993, the

More information

Fiscal devaluation and Economic Activity in the EU

Fiscal devaluation and Economic Activity in the EU Fiscal devaluation and Economic Activity in the EU Piotr Ciżkowicz*, Bartosz Radzikowski**, Andrzej Rzońca*, Wiktor Wojciechowski* *Warsaw School of Economics, **Centrum for Social and Economic Research

More information

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries PAOLA PROFETA RICCARDO PUGLISI SIMONA SCABROSETTI June 30, 2015 FIRST DRAFT, PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE WITHOUT THE AUTHORS PERMISSION Abstract Focusing

More information

Volume 29, Issue 4. Spend-and-tax: a panel data investigation for the EU

Volume 29, Issue 4. Spend-and-tax: a panel data investigation for the EU Volume 29, Issue 4 Spend-and-tax: a panel data investigation for the EU António Afonso ISEG/TULisbon; UECE; European Central Bank Christophe Rault LEO, University of Orléans Abstract Using bootstrap panel

More information

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD European Economic Review 42 (1998) 887 895 The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD Philip R. Lane *, Roberto Perotti Economics Department, Trinity College Dublin, Dublin 2, Ireland Columbia University,

More information

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY Alan J. Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko University of California, Berkeley January 2013 In this paper, we estimate the cross-country spillover effects of government

More information

Egalitarian Policies and Effective Demand: Considering Balance of Payments

Egalitarian Policies and Effective Demand: Considering Balance of Payments Kyoto University, Graduate School of Economics Discussion Paper Series Egalitarian Policies and Effective Demand: Considering Balance of Payments Taro Abe Discussion Paper No. E-17-002 Graduate School

More information

Wage-led versus profit-led demand regimes: The long and the short of it

Wage-led versus profit-led demand regimes: The long and the short of it Wage-led versus profit-led demand regimes: The long and the short of it Robert A. Blecker* Revised October 24, 2014 Abstract Empirical studies have found mixed results regarding whether various countries

More information

Decomposition of GDP-growth in some European Countries and the United States 1

Decomposition of GDP-growth in some European Countries and the United States 1 CPB Memorandum CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis Sector : Conjunctuur en Collectieve Sector Unit/Project : Conjunctuur Author(s) : Henk Kranendonk and Johan Verbrugggen Number : 203 Date

More information

Check against delivery.

Check against delivery. Bullet Points for intervention delivered at the OECD-IMF Conference on structural reforms by Jürgen Stark Member of the Executive Board and the Governing Council of the European Central Bank 17 March 2008

More information

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s As part of its monetary policy strategy, the ECB regularly monitors the development of a wide range of indicators and assesses their implications

More information

National and global effects Conditions of Work and employment Series No. 40 Özlem Onaran Giorgos Galanis

National and global effects Conditions of Work and employment Series No. 40 Özlem Onaran Giorgos Galanis For information on the Conditions of Work and Employment Branch, please contact: Phone: (+41 22) 799 67 54 Fax: (+41 22) 799 84 51 travail@ilo.org Is aggregate demand wage-led or profit-led? International

More information

Income Distribution and Economic Growth in a. Multi-Sectoral Kaleckian Model

Income Distribution and Economic Growth in a. Multi-Sectoral Kaleckian Model Kyoto University, Graduate School of Economics Research Project Center Discussion Paper Series Income Distribution and Economic Growth in a Multi-Sectoral Kaleckian Model Hiroshi Nishi Discussion Paper

More information

Consumption, Income and Wealth

Consumption, Income and Wealth 59 Consumption, Income and Wealth Jens Bang-Andersen, Tina Saaby Hvolbøl, Paul Lassenius Kramp and Casper Ristorp Thomsen, Economics INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY In Denmark, private consumption accounts for

More information

Exchange Rates and Inflation in EMU Countries: Preliminary Empirical Evidence 1

Exchange Rates and Inflation in EMU Countries: Preliminary Empirical Evidence 1 Exchange Rates and Inflation in EMU Countries: Preliminary Empirical Evidence 1 Marco Moscianese Santori Fabio Sdogati Politecnico di Milano, piazza Leonardo da Vinci 32, 20133, Milan, Italy Abstract In

More information

Insolvency forecasts. Economic Research August 2017

Insolvency forecasts. Economic Research August 2017 Insolvency forecasts Economic Research August 2017 Summary We present our new insolvency forecasting model which offers a broader scope of macroeconomic developments to better predict insolvency developments.

More information

Aggregate demand, income distribution, unemployment Özlem Onaran,

Aggregate demand, income distribution, unemployment Özlem Onaran, Aggregate demand, income distribution, unemployment Özlem Onaran, Professor of Economics, Director of Greenwich Political Economy Research Centre Outline Post-Keynesian/Post-Kaleckian theory and contesting

More information

What Can Macroeconometric Models Say About Asia-Type Crises?

What Can Macroeconometric Models Say About Asia-Type Crises? What Can Macroeconometric Models Say About Asia-Type Crises? Ray C. Fair May 1999 Abstract This paper uses a multicountry econometric model to examine Asia-type crises. Experiments are run for Thailand,

More information

CRISIS MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE EUROZONE. Paul De Grauwe (LSE) Yuemei Ji (Brunel University)

CRISIS MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE EUROZONE. Paul De Grauwe (LSE) Yuemei Ji (Brunel University) CRISIS MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE EUROZONE Paul De Grauwe (LSE) Yuemei Ji (Brunel University) Stagnation in Eurozone Figure 1: Real GDP in Eurozone, EU10 and US (prices of 2010) 135 130 125

More information

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Has the Inflation Process Changed? Has the Inflation Process Changed? by S. Cecchetti and G. Debelle Discussion by I. Angeloni (ECB) * Cecchetti and Debelle (CD) could hardly have chosen a more relevant and timely topic for their paper.

More information

Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components

Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components Expert Journal of Economic s (2 0 1 3 ) 1, 13-18 2013 Th e Au thor. Publish ed by Sp rint In v estify. Econ omics.exp ertjou rn a ls.com Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components Simona

More information

The Short and Long-Run Implications of Budget Deficit on Economic Growth in Nigeria ( )

The Short and Long-Run Implications of Budget Deficit on Economic Growth in Nigeria ( ) Canadian Social Science Vol. 10, No. 5, 2014, pp. 201-205 DOI:10.3968/4517 ISSN 1712-8056[Print] ISSN 1923-6697[Online] www.cscanada.net www.cscanada.org The Short and Long-Run Implications of Budget Deficit

More information

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings J Econ Finan (2010) 34:23 29 DOI 10.1007/s12197-008-9070-2 Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings Faruk Balli Rosmy J. Louis Mohammad Osman Published online: 24 December 2008 Springer Science + Business

More information

School of Economics and Management

School of Economics and Management School of Economics and Management TECHNICAL UNIVERSITY OF LISBON Department of Economics Carlos Pestana Barros & Nicolas Peypoch António Afonso and Cristophe Rault A Comparative Analysis of Productivity

More information

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy ECO 209Y Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Lecture 3: Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Income Gustavo Indart Slide 1 Assumptions We will assume that: There is no depreciation There are no indirect taxes

More information

Consequences of the 2013 FP7 call for proposals for the economy and employment in the European Union

Consequences of the 2013 FP7 call for proposals for the economy and employment in the European Union Consequences of the 2013 FP7 call for proposals for the economy and employment in the European Union Paul Zagamé, Arnaud Fougeyrollas Pierre le Mouël ERASME, Paris, 31 May 2012 1 Executive Summary We present

More information

Demographics and Secular Stagnation Hypothesis in Europe

Demographics and Secular Stagnation Hypothesis in Europe Demographics and Secular Stagnation Hypothesis in Europe Carlo Favero (Bocconi University, IGIER) Vincenzo Galasso (Bocconi University, IGIER, CEPR & CESIfo) Growth in Europe?, Marseille, September 2015

More information

Long run consequences of a Capital Market Union in the European Union

Long run consequences of a Capital Market Union in the European Union 1 Policy Brief Long run consequences of a Capital Market Union in the European Union Policy Brief No. 2018-1 Thomas Davoine January 2018 Capital markets are more and more integrated but remain partially

More information

The costs of internal devaluation in the EA

The costs of internal devaluation in the EA The costs of internal devaluation in the EA Engelbert Stockhammer Kingston University, UK. Dimitris P. Sotiropoulos The Open University Business School, UK. Presentation prepared for the 17th Conference

More information

Fiscal Reaction Functions of Different Euro Area Countries

Fiscal Reaction Functions of Different Euro Area Countries Fiscal Reaction Functions of Different Euro Area Countries Klaus Weyerstrass Institute for Advanced Studies Department of Economics and Finance Josefstädter Strasse 39, A-1080 Vienna, Austria E-Mail: klaus.weyerstrass@ihs.ac.at;

More information

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment International Journal of Business and Economics, 2002, Vol. 1, No. 1, 59-67 Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment Rosemary Rossiter * Department of Economics, Ohio University,

More information

International Seminar on Strengthening Public Investment and Managing Fiscal Risks from Public-Private Partnerships

International Seminar on Strengthening Public Investment and Managing Fiscal Risks from Public-Private Partnerships International Seminar on Strengthening Public Investment and Managing Fiscal Risks from Public-Private Partnerships Budapest, Hungary March 7 8, 2007 The views expressed in this paper are those of the

More information

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU Tatjana Dahlhaus Danilo Leiva-Leon November 7, VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper assesses the effect of monetary policy during

More information

Economic state of the union, EuroMemo Engelbert Stockhammer Kingston University

Economic state of the union, EuroMemo Engelbert Stockhammer Kingston University Economic state of the union, EuroMemo 2013 Engelbert Stockhammer Kingston University structure Economic developments Background: export-led growth and debt-led growth Growth, trade imbalances, ages and

More information

Key Elasticities in Job Search Theory: International Evidence

Key Elasticities in Job Search Theory: International Evidence DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1314 Key Elasticities in Job Search Theory: International Evidence John T. Addison Mário Centeno Pedro Portugal September 2004 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit

More information

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Spring edition March 2013

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Spring edition March 2013 Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Spring edition March 2013 Austria Belgium Cyprus Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Portugal Slovakia Slovenia Spain

More information

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation ECONOMIC BULLETIN 3/218 ANALYTICAL ARTICLES Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation Ángel Estrada and Francesca Viani 6 September 218 Following

More information

ILO World of Work Report 2013: EU Snapshot

ILO World of Work Report 2013: EU Snapshot Greece Spain Ireland Poland Belgium Portugal Eurozone France Slovenia EU-27 Cyprus Denmark Netherlands Italy Bulgaria Slovakia Romania Lithuania Latvia Czech Republic Estonia Finland United Kingdom Sweden

More information

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018. The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, th September 08. This note reports estimates of the economic impact of introducing a carbon tax of 50 per ton of CO in the Netherlands.

More information

Is planet Earth as a whole likely to be wage-led?

Is planet Earth as a whole likely to be wage-led? Is planet Earth as a whole likely to be wage-led? Arslan Razmi October 6, 2016 Abstract Evidence regarding the relationship between distribution, demand, and growth in the short run has been mixed. Open

More information

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU?

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU? JEL classification: C3, C33, E31, F15, F2 Keywords: common and country-specific shocks, output and inflation dispersions, convergence What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU? Emil STAVREV

More information

IS THERE ANY PREFERED COMPETITIVENESS INDICATOR IN EXPLAINING FOREING TRADE IN EURO AREA COUNTRIES? COMPNET December 12 th 2013

IS THERE ANY PREFERED COMPETITIVENESS INDICATOR IN EXPLAINING FOREING TRADE IN EURO AREA COUNTRIES? COMPNET December 12 th 2013 IS THERE ANY PREFERED COMPETITIVENESS INDICATOR IN EXPLAINING FOREING TRADE IN EURO AREA COUNTRIES? COMPNET December 12 th 2013 Styliani Christodoulopoulou Based on joint work with Olegs Tkacevs With input

More information

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHANNES KEPLER UNIVERSITY LINZ Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison by Burkhard Raunig and Johann Scharler* Working Paper

More information

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners Bahmani-Oskooee and Ratha, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 1-13 1 The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee and Artatrana Ratha

More information

Europe 2020 targets: Redening linkages and a modied inequality index

Europe 2020 targets: Redening linkages and a modied inequality index Europe 2020 targets: Redening linkages and a modied inequality index Deniz Sevinc Regional Studies Association Winter Conference 28 Nov 2014 Agenda Rising income inequalities in Europe Modied Inequality

More information

HOUSEHOLD DEBT AND FINANCIAL STABILITY

HOUSEHOLD DEBT AND FINANCIAL STABILITY JANA KASK HOUSEHOLD DEBT AND FINANCIAL STABILITY Jana Kask Introduction Household debt has been soaring in Estonia in recent years. This has been underpinned by easy access to loans due to low interest

More information

LONG TERM EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON THE SIZE AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF THE PIE IN THE UK

LONG TERM EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON THE SIZE AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF THE PIE IN THE UK LONG TERM EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON THE SIZE AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF THE PIE IN THE UK Xavier Ramos & Oriol Roca-Sagalès Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona DG ECFIN UK Country Seminar 29 June 2010, Brussels

More information

A NOTE ON PUBLIC SPENDING EFFICIENCY

A NOTE ON PUBLIC SPENDING EFFICIENCY A NOTE ON PUBLIC SPENDING EFFICIENCY try to implement better institutions and should reassign many non-core public sector activities to the private sector. ANTÓNIO AFONSO * Public sector performance Introduction

More information

Aggregate demand &long-run unemployment L. Ball 1999

Aggregate demand &long-run unemployment L. Ball 1999 Aggregate demand &long-run unemployment L. Ball 1999 Standard theory: equilibrium unemployment depends on labour market rigidities and institutional variables Monetary policy should focus on nominal stability,

More information

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016 Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to.4% in the third quarter of 26 Growth in unit labour costs (ULCs) in the OECD area slowed to.4% in the third quarter of 26 (compared with.6% in the previous quarter)

More information

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014 UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session Geneva, 15 26 September 2014 Item 3: High-level segment Tackling inequality through trade and development:

More information

APPENDIX: Country analyses

APPENDIX: Country analyses APPENDIX: Country analyses Appendix A Germany: Low economic momentum The economic situation in Germany continues to be lackluster in 2014. Strong growth in the first quarter was followed by a decline

More information

Europe Outlook. Third Quarter 2015

Europe Outlook. Third Quarter 2015 Europe Outlook Third Quarter 2015 Main messages 1 2 3 4 5 Moderation of global growth and slowdown in emerging economies, with downside risks The recovery continues in the eurozone, but still marked by

More information

INDICATORS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN MATURE ECONOMIES

INDICATORS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN MATURE ECONOMIES B INDICATORS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN MATURE ECONOMIES This special feature analyses the indicator properties of macroeconomic variables and aggregated financial statements from the banking sector in providing

More information

52 ECB. The 2015 Ageing Report: how costly will ageing in Europe be?

52 ECB. The 2015 Ageing Report: how costly will ageing in Europe be? Box 7 The 5 Ageing Report: how costly will ageing in Europe be? Europe is facing a demographic challenge. The old age dependency ratio, i.e. the share of people aged 65 or over relative to the working

More information

74 ECB THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE

74 ECB THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE Box 7 THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE This year s European Semester (i.e. the framework for EU policy coordination introduced in 2011) includes, for the first time, the implementation of the

More information

OVERVIEW. The EU recovery is firming. Table 1: Overview - the winter 2014 forecast Real GDP. Unemployment rate. Inflation. Winter 2014 Winter 2014

OVERVIEW. The EU recovery is firming. Table 1: Overview - the winter 2014 forecast Real GDP. Unemployment rate. Inflation. Winter 2014 Winter 2014 OVERVIEW The EU recovery is firming Europe's economic recovery, which began in the second quarter of 2013, is expected to continue spreading across countries and gaining strength while at the same time

More information

Life Insurance and Euro Zone s Economic Growth

Life Insurance and Euro Zone s Economic Growth Available online at www.sciencedirect.com Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 57 ( 2012 ) 126 131 International Conference on Asia Pacific Business Innovation and Technology Management Life Insurance

More information

Spain s insurance sector: Profitability, solvency and concentration

Spain s insurance sector: Profitability, solvency and concentration INSURANCE Spain s insurance sector: Profitability, solvency and concentration Spain s insurance sector currently outperforms the country s banking sector, as well as the EU average. That said, challenging

More information

Response of Output Fluctuations in Costa Rica to Exchange Rate Movements and Global Economic Conditions and Policy Implications

Response of Output Fluctuations in Costa Rica to Exchange Rate Movements and Global Economic Conditions and Policy Implications Response of Output Fluctuations in Costa Rica to Exchange Rate Movements and Global Economic Conditions and Policy Implications Yu Hsing (Corresponding author) Department of Management & Business Administration,

More information

Financialisation and distribution in the US, the UK, Spain, Germany, Sweden and France before and after the crisis

Financialisation and distribution in the US, the UK, Spain, Germany, Sweden and France before and after the crisis Institute for International Political Economy Berlin Financialisation and distribution in the US, the UK, Spain, Germany, Sweden and France before and after the crisis Author: Eckhard Hein, Petra Dünhaupt,

More information

Lecture 1: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn 2012

Lecture 1: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn 2012 Lecture 1: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn 2012 Lars Calmfors Literature: Mankiw, Chapters 3 and 5. 1 Topics 1. The relationship between saving, investment and the interest rate in a closed economy

More information

Competitiveness, Income Distribution and Economic Growth in a Small Economy

Competitiveness, Income Distribution and Economic Growth in a Small Economy Competitiveness, Income Distribution and Economic Growth in a Small Economy Jose Antonio Cordero Department of Economics Universidad de Costa Rica San Jose, COSTA RICA October, 2007 1. Introduction The

More information

V. MAKING WORK PAY. The economic situation of persons with low skills

V. MAKING WORK PAY. The economic situation of persons with low skills V. MAKING WORK PAY There has recently been increased interest in policies that subsidise work at low pay in order to make work pay. 1 Such policies operate either by reducing employers cost of employing

More information

Fragmentation of the European financial market and the cost of bank financing

Fragmentation of the European financial market and the cost of bank financing Fragmentation of the European financial market and the cost of bank financing Joaquín Maudos 1 European market fragmentation following the crisis has resulted in a widening of borrowing costs across Euro

More information

Open economy models of distribution and growth

Open economy models of distribution and growth Open economy models of distribution and growth Robert A. Blecker* Paper to be presented at the Eastern Economic Association annual meeting, Philadelphia, PA, February 28, 2010. *Professor of Economics

More information

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for? Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for? Syed M. Hussain Lin Liu August 5, 26 Abstract In this paper, we estimate the

More information

Recent developments in the euro area suggest. What caused current account imbalances in euro area periphery countries?

Recent developments in the euro area suggest. What caused current account imbalances in euro area periphery countries? No. 31 October 16 What caused current account imbalances in euro area periphery countries? Daniele Siena Directorate General Economics and International Relations The views expressed here are those of

More information

6. CHALLENGES FOR REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT POLICY

6. CHALLENGES FOR REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT POLICY 6. CHALLENGES FOR REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT POLICY 83. The policy and institutional framework for regional development plays an important role in contributing to a more equal sharing of the benefits of high

More information

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence ISSN 2029-4581. ORGANIZATIONS AND MARKETS IN EMERGING ECONOMIES, 2012, VOL. 3, No. 1(5) Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence from and the Euro Area Jolanta

More information

End of year fiscal report. November 2008

End of year fiscal report. November 2008 End of year fiscal report November 2008 End of year fiscal report November 2008 Crown copyright 2008 The text in this document (excluding the Royal Coat of Arms and departmental logos) may be reproduced

More information

to 4 per cent annual growth in the US.

to 4 per cent annual growth in the US. A nation s economic growth is determined by the rate of utilisation of the factors of production capital and labour and the efficiency of their use. Traditionally, economic growth in Europe has been characterised

More information

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY Neil R. Mehrotra Brown University Peterson Institute for International Economics November 9th, 2017 1 / 13 PUBLIC DEBT AND PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH

More information

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh Volume 29, Issue 3 Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh Yu Hsing Southeastern Louisiana University A. M. M. Jamal Southeastern Louisiana University Wen-jen Hsieh

More information

Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox

Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox Felix FitzRoy School of Economics and Finance University of St Andrews St Andrews, KY16 8QX, UK Michael Nolan* Centre for Economic Policy

More information

Technical report on macroeconomic Member State results of the EUCO policy scenarios

Technical report on macroeconomic Member State results of the EUCO policy scenarios Technical report on macroeconomic Member State results of the EUCO policy scenarios By E3MLab, December 2016 Contents Introduction... 1 Modelling the macro-economic impacts of the policy scenarios with

More information

INCOME DISTRIBUTION SLOVAKIA WORKING AND ECONOMIC GROWTH; EMPIRICAL RESULTS FOR JURAJ ZEMAN

INCOME DISTRIBUTION SLOVAKIA WORKING AND ECONOMIC GROWTH; EMPIRICAL RESULTS FOR JURAJ ZEMAN INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH; EMPIRICAL RESULTS FOR SLOVAKIA JURAJ ZEMAN WORKING PAPER National Bank of Slovakia www.nbs.sk Imricha Karvaša 1 813 25 Bratislava research@nbs.sk February 2018

More information

International Income Smoothing and Foreign Asset Holdings.

International Income Smoothing and Foreign Asset Holdings. MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive International Income Smoothing and Foreign Asset Holdings. Faruk Balli and Rosmy J. Louis and Mohammad Osman Massey University, Vancouver Island University, University

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 9.4.2018 COM(2018) 172 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on Effects of Regulation (EU) 575/2013 and Directive 2013/36/EU on the Economic

More information

46 ECB FISCAL CHALLENGES FROM POPULATION AGEING: NEW EVIDENCE FOR THE EURO AREA

46 ECB FISCAL CHALLENGES FROM POPULATION AGEING: NEW EVIDENCE FOR THE EURO AREA Box 4 FISCAL CHALLENGES FROM POPULATION AGEING: NEW EVIDENCE FOR THE EURO AREA Ensuring the long-term sustainability of public finances in the euro area and its member countries is a prerequisite for the

More information

ANNUAL REPORT 2015 CHAPTER 2 COMPETITIVE ADJUSTMENT AND RECOVERY IN THE SPANISH ECONOMY DIRECTORATE GENERAL ECONOMICS, STATISTICS AND RESEARCH

ANNUAL REPORT 2015 CHAPTER 2 COMPETITIVE ADJUSTMENT AND RECOVERY IN THE SPANISH ECONOMY DIRECTORATE GENERAL ECONOMICS, STATISTICS AND RESEARCH ANNUAL REPORT 215 CHAPTER 2 COMPETITIVE ADJUSTMENT AND RECOVERY IN THE SPANISH ECONOMY THE RECOVERY IN COMPETITIVENESS There has been a significant improvement in price/cost competitiveness since 28, although

More information

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis Jan Kuckuck and Frank Westermann Working Paper 96 June 213 INSTITUTE OF EMPIRICAL ECONOMIC RESEARCH Osnabrück University Rolandstraße 8 4969

More information

Keynesian-oriented literature has developed growth models in

Keynesian-oriented literature has developed growth models in Economic growth regimes in Brazil: empirical evidence and policy implications Eliane Araújo and Paulo Gala Introduction Keynesian-oriented literature has developed growth models in which aggregate demand

More information