TAX-PREFERRED ASSETS AND DEBT, AND THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 1986: SOME IMPLICATIONS FOR FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORM ERIC M. ENGEN * & WILLIAM G.

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "TAX-PREFERRED ASSETS AND DEBT, AND THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 1986: SOME IMPLICATIONS FOR FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORM ERIC M. ENGEN * & WILLIAM G."

Transcription

1 TAX-PREFERRED ASSETS AND DEBT, AND THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 1986: SOME IMPLICATIONS FOR FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORM ERIC M. ENGEN * & WILLIAM G. GALE ** Abstract - This paper focuses on two aspects of the tax changes enacted in the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA86). First, the TRA86 phased out tax deductions for interest on consumer debt, which contributed to a marked shift in the composition of household debt. Second, the TRA86 restricted the tax deductibility of contributions to individual retirement accounts (IRAs) for some higher-income households. This appears to have contributed to, but is not solely responsible for, the shift in the composition of some households portfolios of tax-preferred saving incentive plans. This paper also discusses the interaction of household debt and 401(k) plans following the TRA86. The aspects of the TRA86 focused upon in this paper appear to represent examples of more typical responses to tax changes: changes in the composition of economic activity but with little change in the real level of * Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, D.C ** The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C economic activity. This conclusion is consistent with the hierarchy of taxpayer responses suggested by Slemrod (1990, 1995) and yields some potentially relevant implications for fundamental tax reform. INTRODUCTION The current debate on fundamental tax reform is often described as merely a choice between an income tax and a consumption tax. 1 This characterization can easily lead to the general conclusion that the effects of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA86) have little to offer in the way of guidance concerning the effects of a fundamental tax reform. The TRA86 enacted broad changes in the personal and corporate income taxes by reducing marginal tax rates and by broadening the tax base via a reduction in tax preferences, but did not embody a fundamental shift from an incomebased tax toward a consumption tax. 331

2 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 3 While the shift to a consumption base is an important part of fundamental tax reform proposals, it may not be the only relevant issue. For example, the flat tax, which expenses investment at the business level, is appropriately considered a consumption-based tax. If the flat tax instead provided depreciation allowances for investment, rather than expensing, it would be an income-based tax (Slemrod, 1995b). Our conjecture is that, for a number of issues involved with tax reform, a switch to a flat-taxwith-expensing might not lead to dramatically different conclusions from switching to a flat-tax-with-depreciation. 2 If so, then at least for some issues, the crucial point may not be the distinction between an income tax base and a consumption tax base, but rather the desirability of broadening the current hybrid income-consumption tax base whether the ultimate base is consumption or income and flattening the current increasing tax rate structure. The latter two issues, however, are exactly the focus of the changes in the TRA86, and potentially make the effects of TRA86 relevant for understanding at least some aspects of the debate on fundamental tax reform. In this paper, we focus on two aspects of the tax changes enacted in the TRA86 and discuss some of their effects on households saving and debt decisions. First, TRA86 phased out tax deductions for interest on consumer debt. This contributed to a marked shift in the composition of household debt away from consumer borrowing and toward mortgages, the interest on which remained tax deductible. Second, TRA86 restricted the tax deductibility of contributions to Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs) for higher-income households with a retirement plan; deductibility is phased out (eliminated) when adjusted gross income exceeds $40,000 ($50,000) for joint taxfilers and $25,000 ($35,000) for single taxfilers. This appears to have contributed to, but is not solely responsible for, the shift in the composition of the portion of households asset portfolios allocated to tax-preferred saving incentive plans, such as IRAs and 401(k) plans. Before the TRA86, IRAs constituted the majority of total saving incentive contributions. However, IRA contributions plummeted following the restrictions imposed by the TRA86. By 1992, IRA contributions comprised less than one-fifth of total saving incentive contributions, while contributions to 401(k) plans grew to constitute about three-quarters of total saving incentive contributions. Household debt and contributions to tax-based saving incentives can also interact in important ways. It is important to recall that household saving and wealth are ultimately net concepts assets minus debt. Hence, studies should also focus on how tax changes affect household wealth, rather than just assets or debt. However, these two components of household wealth, and the effects of tax changes on household asset accumulation or household debt, typically have been analyzed separately. This paper discusses the interaction of household debt and tax-preferred saving following the TRA86. The aspects of the TRA86 focused upon in this paper appear to represent examples of more typical responses to tax changes. They represent primarily changes in the composition of economic activity but with little change in the real level of economic activity. This conclusion is consistent with the hierarchy of taxpayer responses suggested by Slemrod (1990, 1995a) and yields some potentially relevant implications for fundamental tax reform. 332

3 The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section examines trends in debt before and after the TRA86. The subsequent section analyzes interactions between IRAs and 401(k) plans following the tax changes in the TRA86. The following section examines the interaction between households accumulation of debt and their accumulation of assets, particularly tax-preferred assets, in the period following the TRA86. The final section concludes with a discussion of some implications for the design and implementation of fundamental tax reform. TAX REFORM AND THE ALLOCATION OF HOUSEHOLD DEBT Since the early 1980s, the level of debt held by U.S. households has risen significantly. Data on aggregate trends in household debt holdings compiled by the Federal Reserve Board (1995) show that nominal household debt, defined as the sum of mortgage and consumer debt, grew at an annual rate of 12 percent in the 1970s, 10 percent between 1980 and 1986, and 8 percent since This growth in debt outpaced inflation, which (measured by the CPI-U-X1) averaged 7.1 percent in the 1970s, 4.9 percent between 1980 and , and 3.8 percent from 1986 to Moreover, household debt has undergone long-term growth relative to disposable personal income or relative to 1 household financial and housing assets. Mortgage debt defined by the presence of a residence as collateral, rather than by the use of the loan proceeds grew at annual rates of 12.7 percent in the 1970s, 9.7 percent between 1980 and 1986, and 9.1 percent from 1986 to Relative to the value of owner-occupied real estate, mortgage debt rose from 27.5 percent in 1980 to 31.6 percent in 1986 to 42.8 percent by Consumer debt also grew rapidly over much of this period, rising at an annual rate of 10.3 percent in the 1980s and 10.8 percent from 1980 to The TRA86 phased out deductions for consumer interest payments, but retained the deduction for mortgage interest for almost all taxpayers. 4 This reduced the price of borrowing through mortgages relative to consumer debt. From 1986 to 1994, consumer debt outstanding grew at only 5.1 percent per year, and fell from 21 percent of disposable personal income in 1986 to less than 19 percent in 1991 through The composition of household debt shifted toward mortgages during the 1970s housing boom, was roughly constant 2 from 1980 to 1986, and has shifted further toward mortgages since 1986, even with flat housing prices. An increase in mortgage lending can occur through increased home equity lending, refinancing of first mortgages that extract equity, and higher loan-tovalue ratios on new purchases of homes. Manchester and Poterba (1989) cite data showing that home equity loans rose from 3.6 percent of outstanding mortgages in 1980 to 10.8 percent in The U.S. General Accounting Office (1993) cites different data with similar ratios: 3.8 percent in 1981, 10.6 percent in 1986, and 12.2 percent in Most of the growth in home equity lines of credit occurred after 1986: balances rose from $1 billion in 1981 to $32 billion in 1986 and $132 billion in Eugeni (1993) estimates that outstanding home equity balances rose from $268 billion in 1988 to about $469 billion in Canner, Fergus, and Luckett (1989) estimate outstanding home equity balances in 1988 of between $210 and $265 billion. 333

4 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 3 These different studies are roughly consistent and suggest rapid growth of home equity lending in the 1980s. 5 Home equity lending can account for a sizable portion of the increase in mortgage debt before 1986, but a smaller portion of the increase after Nonetheless, in the post-86 period, home equity lending may have played an important role in enabling households to change the composition of their debt. Mortgage refinancing represents an alternative way to extract housing equity. In a 1989 survey reported in Canner and Luckett (1990), 20 percent of households with mortgages had refinanced their mortgage. Of those, 57 percent had extracted equity at the time of refinancing. The mean and median amounts extracted were $25,145 and $15,941. These are roughly similar to the mean and median for home equity loans, $22,534 and $15,905. Higher initial loan-to-value ratios (i.e., smaller down payments) are another channel through which mortgage debt can rise relative to the house value backing the debt. Data from the Federal Housing Finance Board (1995) shows that aggregate loan-to-value ratios on purchase money mortgages (i.e., primary mortgages that are not refinancings) rose from 72.9 percent in 1980 to 77 percent in 1984, fell to 74.4 percent by 1991, and then rose to 79.9 percent in Similar time patterns occur for the proportion of new loans with loan-to-price ratios that exceed 90 percent. Skinner and Feenberg (1990) use a panel of taxpayers from 1984 through 1987 who itemize their tax deductions. Their estimates imply that limiting the deductibility of consumer interest in TRA86 significantly reduced consumer interest payments. They also find that a dollar of reduced consumer interest is associated with a 67 to 86 cents increase in mortgage interest payments. Using interest rate data from Canner, Fergus, and Luckett (1988), these estimates 3 suggest that a dollar in reduced consumer debt raised mortgage debt by between $0.87 and $ Scholz (1994) uses cross sections from the 1983 and 1989 Surveys of Consumer Finances. He finds that household debt rose between 1983 and Among higher-income homeowners, property-backed debt rose rapidly. Among low-income renters, who presumably had less access to deductible borrowing after the TRA86, debt holdings fell. Maki (1995) uses successive cross sections of the Consumer Expenditure Survey. He shows that high income homeowners reduced their consumer debt and raised their mortgage debt after the TRA86, relative to other households. He also shows that highincome renters did not reduce their consumer debt holdings relative to other renters and that households increased their total debt. Engen and Gale (1995) used successive cross sections of the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP) in 1984, 1987, and 1991 to look at household debt. Mortgage debt rose across all income and age groups. Median mortgage debt rose by 14 percent from 1984 to 1987 and by an additional 37 percent from 1987 to Virtually all of this increase was due to an increase in the ratio of mortgage debt to house value, rather than changes in house value. 7 From 1987 to 1991, homeowners with family earnings above $50,000 reduced their holdings of consumer debt, while 334

5 renters in the same earnings classes raised their consumer debt holdings. These studies have important implications for studying household saving behavior and its response to tax changes. First, these studies are consistent with the conclusion that the composition of household debt portfolios is sensitive to the tax treatment of different types of debt. Second, the trends suggest the importance of analyzing the effects of tax reforms on broad measures of household wealth which include liabilities as well as assets. TAX REFORM AND THE ALLOCATION OF TAX-PREFERRED SAVING In this section, we examine the relationship between IRAs and 401(k) plans. Since the early 1980s, tax-based saving incentives plans, such as IRAs and 401(k) plans, gained tremendous popularity. 8 Total contributions to IRAs, 401(k)s, SEPs, and Keoghs increased from less than 4 percent of personal saving in 1981 to about 35 percent of personal saving by 1985, and then continued to comprise about one-third of personal saving through However, the restrictions imposed by the TRA86 on deductible IRA contributions significantly changed the composition of saving incentive contributions. Before the TRA86, IRAs constituted the majority of total saving incentive contributions. However, contributions plummeted following the change in the treatment of IRAs enacted in TRA86. By 1992, IRA contributions comprised less than 20 percent of total saving incentive contributions. In contrast, contributions to 401(k) plans grew steadily since their tax treatment was clarified in 1981 and constituted about three-quarters of total saving incentive contributions by IRAs and 401(k) plans are unlikely to be perfect substitutes. 401(k) plans are tied to the work place, while IRAs are not. 401(k)s usually have employer matching of employee contributions, while IRAs do not. 401(k)s and IRAs generally have different contribution limits, withdrawal and loan provisions, and investment opportunities. 401(k) contributions tend to be regular salary reductions; IRAs can be funded anytime. For example, people may want to put some money into a 401(k) but then keep the flexibility of contributing more to an IRA at a later date in the tax year, depending on their income and expenses. Nevertheless, IRAs and 401(k)s could very well be good substitutes for some people (particularly those who hold both 401(k)s and IRAs). The plans represent alternative ways to save for retirement, and 401(k)s should be particularly attractive for high-income households after the removal of tax deductibility for IRA contributions in One way to test for substitutability is to exploit the removal of tax deductibility of IRA contributions for some higher income families in the TRA86. If households find IRAs and 401(k)s to be substitutes, controlling for other factors, the decline in IRA participation after TRA86 should be larger for 401(k) eligible households than for noneligible households among income groups who lost deductibility of IRA contributions. Poterba, Venti, and Wise (1992) present evidence related to this issue using data from the Employee Benefits Supplement of the 1988 Current Population Survey. They find that for families with incomes above $75,000, the IRA participation rate dropped substantially more for 401(k) eligibles than for noneligibles. In this group, the IRA participation rate fell by 57 percentage points for eligibles compared to 27 percentage points for ineligibles. 335

6 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 3 Engen, Gale, and Scholz (1994) examined the relationship between IRAs and 401(k)s after TRA86, using data from the SIPP. If 401(k)s and IRAs are substitutes, 401(k)-eligible families whose IRA deductibility was restricted in 1986 should funnel more money into 401(k) plans from 1987 to 1991 than eligible families whose deductibility was not removed, controlling for other factors such as income and net worth. They find that among 401(k)-eligible families, not being allowed to make deductible IRA contributions raised 401(k) balances by $2,538 from 1987 to This result is consistent with the hypothesis that there is substitution between 401(k) plans and IRAs. Moreover, they note that the average real 401(k) balance among eligibles in the effected group rose by about $4,300 between 1987 and Hence, the removal of deductibility potentially can account for half of the increase in 401(k) balances in the higher-income group affected by the removal of IRA tax deducibility in the TRA86. Thus, there exists some evidence implying that some households substituted away from IRAs into 401(k)s following the TRA86. The TRA86 probably contributed to, but is almost certainly not solely responsible for, the shift in the composition of households holdings of tax-preferred financial assets. This is consistent with the conclusion that the composition of household asset portfolios is sensitive to the tax treatment of different types of assets. INTERACTIONS BETWEEN ASSETS AND DEBT Engen and Gale (1995) examined interactions between household assets and liabilities by examining the effects of eligibility for, and participation in, 401(k) plans on households accumulation of wealth, where wealth is defined as the sum of net financial assets (financial assets minus consumer debt) and housing equity (house value minus morgage debt). Their analysis used data from successive cross sections in 1987 and 1991 of the SIPP. They obtained several results that point to important interactions between household assets and liabilities following the TRA86. 9 First, between 1987 and 1991, controlling for IRA status and other factors, households with at least one worker eligible for a 401(k) plan did accumulate more financial assets and net financial assets than observationally equivalent households that did not contain a 401(k)-eligible worker. 10 But they also show that 401(k)-eligible households did not accumulate more wealth when housing equity is included. House values rose for eligibles relative to noneligibles, but mortgage debt grew even faster, so that housing equity fell for 401(k)- eligible households relative to ineligible households. Second, they split the sample into homeowners and renters. For renters, being eligible for a 401(k) has no effect on holdings of financial assets or net financial assets. For homeowners, 401(k) eligibility raises gross financial assets and net financial assets, but has no effect on a broader measure of wealth defined to include housing equity. Third, similar results apply to the effects of 401(k) participation in a set of analogous tests that control for IRA status and other factors. The results imply that groups of families that were eligible for 401(k)s or participated in 401(k)s and that had access to mortgage debt, which was still tax deductible after TRA86, raised their financial assets and net financial assets relative to other groups; but this 336

7 increase in one component of their portfolio was fully offset by reductions in housing equity, relative to the other groups. 401(k)-eligible families, or participants, that did not have access to tax-preferred debt after the TRA86 did not raise their financial or net financial assets relative to other groups. In summary, we find that no group of families that was eligible for, or participated in, 401(k)s significantly raised its wealth (including housing equity) from 1987 to 1991 relative to the observationally equivalent group of families that was not eligible or did not participate. In showing that borrowing and saving at the household level can interact in important ways, these results have direct implications for the effects of tax changes on household portfolios and saving. DISCUSSION Slemrod (1990, 1995a) has categorized a hierarchy of taxpayer responses to tax reform. The behavioral response most sensitive to tax reform involves the timing of economic transactions; altering the timing of economic activity in reponse to permanent variations in the time pattern of tax rates or in anticipation of future changes in the tax law. The next most sensitive type of taxpayer response involves avoidance activities, including the reallocation of asset and debt portfolios outlined above. The smallest responses should be expected in real economic behavior: saving, labor supply, etc. 11 The evidence discussed in this paper is consistent with this hierarchy. We note as well that, typically, the timing and avoidance effects are unintended consequences of tax reform, while the real effects are intended. This suggests some implications for the design and implementation of fundamental tax reform. First, the anticipation of tax reform may have important effects on economic activity that serve to offset some of the intended effects. Virtually all analyses of fundamental tax reform assume that the new system is unanticipated and is imposed immediately. This eliminates the possibility of timing responses in the economic models being used, but does not eliminate those responses in the real world. Second, if a fundamental reform from the current tax system to a consumption-based tax includes transitional relief for existing capital, then this will create differential tax treatment across assets. The studies outlined above suggest that these tax differences could create large reshuffling of portfolios. A case in point is the mortgage interest deduction. If the deduction is removed, then we expect households to substitute out of mortgage debt, either by raising their invest- ment debt (Maki, 1996) or by paying down their loan with accumulated assets. If the mortgage deduction is retained in a switch to a consumptionbased tax, then tax reform will have created a conduit for tax-deductible borrowing in a system that does not tax interest income. Creating such arbitrage possibilities could lead to large shifting into mortgages. A final note of caution is warranted. The top few percent of households, by income or wealth, account for a very large share of the net wealth accumulation in the United States. There is little conclusive evidence on how such house holds responded to the TRA86 (Slemrod, 1995a), but their impact on assets, debt, and saving in any fundamental tax reform proposal could prove decisive. ENDNOTES We thank Jane Gravelle for her comments on this paper. All opinions are our own and should not be 337

8 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 3 ascribed to the staff, officers, or trustees of the Federal Reserve Board or The Brookings Institution. 1 A third possibility is a wage tax. Because future consumption may be financed only from existing assets and future wage income, a consumption tax that allows for transitional tax relief on consumption financed out of existing assets is essentially a wage tax. 2 Note also that a consumption-based flat tax would only exempt the portion of the overall return to capital that reflects the opportunity cost of capital. The portion of the return to capital that reflects rents would be taxed in the same way under both a consumption-based and an income-based flat tax (Bradford, 1996). 3 See Engen and Gale (1995) for a more detailed discussion of these trends in debt. 4 The phaseout of deductibility of consumer interest occurred over five years. Deductibility was retained on debt backed by a taxpayer s first or second residence, up to the taxpayer s basis in the property. The Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1987 restricted deductibility of mortgage interest to the first $1 million of acquisition debt and the first $100,000 of home equity loans. Maki (1995) provides further information. 5 Besides tax policy, the growth in home equity lending has been attributed also to changes in home values, changes in banking laws, and other factors. See GAO (1993) and Canner, Fergus, and Luckett (1988, 1989). 6 Canner, Fergus, and Luckett (1988) show average rates in 1984 through 1987 of 11.6 percent for home equity lines of credit, 18.4 percent for credit card debt, 12.1 percent for new 48-month car loans, and 15.3 percent for 24-month personal loans. If the average rate on consumer debt (the last three categories) is 15 percent, the estimates in Skinner and Feenberg (1990) suggest that a dollar reduction in consumer interest corresponds to a $6.67 decline in consumer debt. At an 11.6 percent rate on home equity loans, a 67 (86) cent increase in mortgage interest corresponds to an increase of $5.78 ($7.41) in mortgage debt. Hence, reducing consumer debt by a dollar would raise mortgage debt by between 87 cents (5.78/ 6.67) and $1.11 (7.41/6.67). 7 The median house value (1991 dollars) in the SIPP was about $77,000 in 1984, $79,000 in 1987, and $75,000 in These patterns are consistent with data reported by Poterba (1991) on U.S. housing prices. The mean ratio of mortgage to house value in the SIPP rose 9 percent from 1984 to 1987 and 24 percent from 1987 to See Engen, Gale, and Scholz (1994, 1996) for a more detailed discussion of these trends in taxbased saving incentive plans. 9 See Engen, Gale, and Scholz (1996) also for more discussion of the interaction between households contributions to tax-preferred 401(k) plans and their accumulation of tax-preferred mortgage debt. 10 Poterba, Venti, and Wise (1995) obtained similar findings for gross financial assets using similar data from the SIPP. 11 Engen (1994) and Engen and Gale (1996) explicitly analyze the potential real effects of fundamental tax reform on household saving. These studies conclude that switching to a consumption-based tax would modestly increase household saving. In assessing the effects of fundamental tax reform, Engen and Gale (1996) note the importance of realizing that in the current hybrid incomeconsumption tax, much of household saving is already done through tax-preferred forms such as pensions, saving incentive acounts, and owneroccupied housing. Sabelhaus (1996) documents the importance of tax-preferred saving in aggregate household saving. REFERENCES Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Balance Sheets for the U.S. Economy Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June, Bradford, David F. Consumption Taxes: Some Fundamental Transition Issues. In Frontiers of Tax Reform edited by Michael J. Boskin. Stanford: Hoover Institution Press, Canner, Glenn B., James T. Fergus, and Charles A. Luckett. Home Equity Lines of Credit. Federal Reserve Bulletin 74 (June, 1988): Canner, Glenn B., James T. Fergus, and Charles A. Luckett. Home Equity Lending. Federal Reserve Bulletin 75 (May, 1989): Canner, Glenn B., and Charles A. Luckett. Mortgage Refinancing. Federal Reserve Bulletin 76 (August, 1990): Engen, Eric M. Precautionary Saving and the Structure of Taxation. Federal Reserve Board. Mimeo, Engen, Eric M., and William G. Gale. Debt, Taxes, and the Effects of 401(k) Plans on Household Wealth Accumulation. Federal Reserve Board and The Brookings Institution. Mimeo, Engen, Eric M., and William G. Gale. The Effects of Fundamental Tax Reform on Saving. In The Economic Effects of Fundamental Tax Reform, edited by Henry Aaron and William Gale. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1996 (forthcoming). Engen, Eric M., William G. Gale, and John Karl Scholz. Do Saving Incentives Work? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1 (1994):

9 Engen, Eric M., William G. Gale, and John Karl Scholz. Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Saving and Wealth: A Critical Review of the Literature. Federal Reserve Board, The Brookings Institution, and the University of Wisconsin Madison. Mimeo, Eugeni, Francesca. Consumer Debt and Home Equity Borrowing. Economic Perspective 17 No. 2 (March April, 1993): Federal Housing Finance Board. News. FHFB 95-55, Washington, D.C., September, Maki, Dean M. Household Debt and the Tax Reform Act of Federal Reserve Board. Mimeo, Maki, Dean M. Portfolio Shuffling and Tax Reform. National Tax Journal 49 No. 3 (September, 1996): Manchester, Joyce M., and James M. Poterba. Second Mortgages and Household Saving. Regional Science and Urban Economics 19 No. 2 (May, 1989): Poterba, James M. House Price Dynamics: The Role of Tax Policy and Demography. Brookings Papers on Economics Activity 2 (1991): Poterba, James M., Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise. 401(k) Plans and Tax-Deferred Saving. NBER Working Paper No Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, Poterba, James M., Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise. Do 401(k) Contributions Crowd Out Other Personal Saving? Journal of Public Economics 58 (September, 1995): Sabelhaus, John. Public Policy and Saving Behavior in the U.S. and Canada. Congressional Budget Office. Mimeo, Scholz, John Karl. Tax Progressivity and Household Portfolios: Descriptive Evidence from the Surveys of Consumer Finances. In Tax Progressivity and Income Inequality, edited by Joel Slemrod, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Skinner, Jonathan, and Daniel Feenberg. The Impact of the 1986 Tax Reform on Personal Saving. In Do Taxes Matter?: The Impact of the Tax Reform Act of 1986, edited by Joel Slemrod, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, Slemrod, Joel. The Economic Impact of the Tax Reform Act of In Do Taxes Matter?: The Impact of the Tax Reform Act of 1986, edited by Joel Slemrod, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, Slemrod, Joel. Income Creation or Income Shifting? Behavioral Responses to the Tax Reform Act of American Economic Review 85 No. 2 (May, 1995a): Slemrod, Joel. What Makes Some Consumption Taxes So Simple, and Others So Complicated? Paper presented at the Conference on Fundamental Tax Reform, sponsored by the Center for Economic Policy Research at Stanford University, Stanford, CA, 1995b. U.S. General Accounting Office. Tax Policy: Many Factors Contributed to the Growth in Home Equity Financing in the 1980 s. GAO/ GGD-93-63, Washington, D.C., March,

10 TAX-PREFERRED ASSETS AND DEBT, AND THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 1986: SOME IMPLICATIONS FOR FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORM ERIC M. ENGEN * & WILLIAM G. GALE ** Abstract - This paper focuses on two aspects of the tax changes enacted in the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA86). First, the TRA86 phased out tax deductions for interest on consumer debt, which contributed to a marked shift in the composition of household debt. Second, the TRA86 restricted the tax deductibility of contributions to individual retirement accounts (IRAs) for some higher-income households. This appears to have contributed to, but is not solely responsible for, the shift in the composition of some households portfolios of tax-preferred saving incentive plans. This paper also discusses the interaction of household debt and 401(k) plans following the TRA86. The aspects of the TRA86 focused upon in this paper appear to represent examples of more typical responses to tax changes: changes in the composition of economic activity but with little change in the real level of * Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, D.C ** The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C economic activity. This conclusion is consistent with the hierarchy of taxpayer responses suggested by Slemrod (1990, 1995) and yields some potentially relevant implications for fundamental tax reform. INTRODUCTION The current debate on fundamental tax reform is often described as merely a choice between an income tax and a consumption tax. 1 This characterization can easily lead to the general conclusion that the effects of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA86) have little to offer in the way of guidance concerning the effects of a fundamental tax reform. The TRA86 enacted broad changes in the personal and corporate income taxes by reducing marginal tax rates and by broadening the tax base via a reduction in tax preferences, but did not embody a fundamental shift from an incomebased tax toward a consumption tax. 331

11 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 3 While the shift to a consumption base is an important part of fundamental tax reform proposals, it may not be the only relevant issue. For example, the flat tax, which expenses investment at the business level, is appropriately considered a consumption-based tax. If the flat tax instead provided depreciation allowances for investment, rather than expensing, it would be an income-based tax (Slemrod, 1995b). Our conjecture is that, for a number of issues involved with tax reform, a switch to a flat-taxwith-expensing might not lead to dramatically different conclusions from switching to a flat-tax-with-depreciation. 2 If so, then at least for some issues, the crucial point may not be the distinction between an income tax base and a consumption tax base, but rather the desirability of broadening the current hybrid income-consumption tax base whether the ultimate base is consumption or income and flattening the current increasing tax rate structure. The latter two issues, however, are exactly the focus of the changes in the TRA86, and potentially make the effects of TRA86 relevant for understanding at least some aspects of the debate on fundamental tax reform. In this paper, we focus on two aspects of the tax changes enacted in the TRA86 and discuss some of their effects on households saving and debt decisions. First, TRA86 phased out tax deductions for interest on consumer debt. This contributed to a marked shift in the composition of household debt away from consumer borrowing and toward mortgages, the interest on which remained tax deductible. Second, TRA86 restricted the tax deductibility of contributions to Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs) for higher-income households with a retirement plan; deductibility is phased out (eliminated) when adjusted gross income exceeds $40,000 ($50,000) for joint taxfilers and $25,000 ($35,000) for single taxfilers. This appears to have contributed to, but is not solely responsible for, the shift in the composition of the portion of households asset portfolios allocated to tax-preferred saving incentive plans, such as IRAs and 401(k) plans. Before the TRA86, IRAs constituted the majority of total saving incentive contributions. However, IRA contributions plummeted following the restrictions imposed by the TRA86. By 1992, IRA contributions comprised less than one-fifth of total saving incentive contributions, while contributions to 401(k) plans grew to constitute about three-quarters of total saving incentive contributions. Household debt and contributions to tax-based saving incentives can also interact in important ways. It is important to recall that household saving and wealth are ultimately net concepts assets minus debt. Hence, studies should also focus on how tax changes affect household wealth, rather than just assets or debt. However, these two components of household wealth, and the effects of tax changes on household asset accumulation or household debt, typically have been analyzed separately. This paper discusses the interaction of household debt and tax-preferred saving following the TRA86. The aspects of the TRA86 focused upon in this paper appear to represent examples of more typical responses to tax changes. They represent primarily changes in the composition of economic activity but with little change in the real level of economic activity. This conclusion is consistent with the hierarchy of taxpayer responses suggested by Slemrod (1990, 1995a) and yields some potentially relevant implications for fundamental tax reform. 332

12 The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section examines trends in debt before and after the TRA86. The subsequent section analyzes interactions between IRAs and 401(k) plans following the tax changes in the TRA86. The following section examines the interaction between households accumulation of debt and their accumulation of assets, particularly tax-preferred assets, in the period following the TRA86. The final section concludes with a discussion of some implications for the design and implementation of fundamental tax reform. TAX REFORM AND THE ALLOCATION OF HOUSEHOLD DEBT Since the early 1980s, the level of debt held by U.S. households has risen significantly. Data on aggregate trends in household debt holdings compiled by the Federal Reserve Board (1995) show that nominal household debt, defined as the sum of mortgage and consumer debt, grew at an annual rate of 12 percent in the 1970s, 10 percent between 1980 and 1986, and 8 percent since This growth in debt outpaced inflation, which (measured by the CPI-U-X1) averaged 7.1 percent in the 1970s, 4.9 percent between 1980 and , and 3.8 percent from 1986 to Moreover, household debt has undergone long-term growth relative to disposable personal income or relative to 1 household financial and housing assets. Mortgage debt defined by the presence of a residence as collateral, rather than by the use of the loan proceeds grew at annual rates of 12.7 percent in the 1970s, 9.7 percent between 1980 and 1986, and 9.1 percent from 1986 to Relative to the value of owner-occupied real estate, mortgage debt rose from 27.5 percent in 1980 to 31.6 percent in 1986 to 42.8 percent by Consumer debt also grew rapidly over much of this period, rising at an annual rate of 10.3 percent in the 1980s and 10.8 percent from 1980 to The TRA86 phased out deductions for consumer interest payments, but retained the deduction for mortgage interest for almost all taxpayers. 4 This reduced the price of borrowing through mortgages relative to consumer debt. From 1986 to 1994, consumer debt outstanding grew at only 5.1 percent per year, and fell from 21 percent of disposable personal income in 1986 to less than 19 percent in 1991 through The composition of household debt shifted toward mortgages during the 1970s housing boom, was roughly constant 2 from 1980 to 1986, and has shifted further toward mortgages since 1986, even with flat housing prices. An increase in mortgage lending can occur through increased home equity lending, refinancing of first mortgages that extract equity, and higher loan-tovalue ratios on new purchases of homes. Manchester and Poterba (1989) cite data showing that home equity loans rose from 3.6 percent of outstanding mortgages in 1980 to 10.8 percent in The U.S. General Accounting Office (1993) cites different data with similar ratios: 3.8 percent in 1981, 10.6 percent in 1986, and 12.2 percent in Most of the growth in home equity lines of credit occurred after 1986: balances rose from $1 billion in 1981 to $32 billion in 1986 and $132 billion in Eugeni (1993) estimates that outstanding home equity balances rose from $268 billion in 1988 to about $469 billion in Canner, Fergus, and Luckett (1989) estimate outstanding home equity balances in 1988 of between $210 and $265 billion. 333

13 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 3 These different studies are roughly consistent and suggest rapid growth of home equity lending in the 1980s. 5 Home equity lending can account for a sizable portion of the increase in mortgage debt before 1986, but a smaller portion of the increase after Nonetheless, in the post-86 period, home equity lending may have played an important role in enabling households to change the composition of their debt. Mortgage refinancing represents an alternative way to extract housing equity. In a 1989 survey reported in Canner and Luckett (1990), 20 percent of households with mortgages had refinanced their mortgage. Of those, 57 percent had extracted equity at the time of refinancing. The mean and median amounts extracted were $25,145 and $15,941. These are roughly similar to the mean and median for home equity loans, $22,534 and $15,905. Higher initial loan-to-value ratios (i.e., smaller down payments) are another channel through which mortgage debt can rise relative to the house value backing the debt. Data from the Federal Housing Finance Board (1995) shows that aggregate loan-to-value ratios on purchase money mortgages (i.e., primary mortgages that are not refinancings) rose from 72.9 percent in 1980 to 77 percent in 1984, fell to 74.4 percent by 1991, and then rose to 79.9 percent in Similar time patterns occur for the proportion of new loans with loan-to-price ratios that exceed 90 percent. Skinner and Feenberg (1990) use a panel of taxpayers from 1984 through 1987 who itemize their tax deductions. Their estimates imply that limiting the deductibility of consumer interest in TRA86 significantly reduced consumer interest payments. They also find that a dollar of reduced consumer interest is associated with a 67 to 86 cents increase in mortgage interest payments. Using interest rate data from Canner, Fergus, and Luckett (1988), these estimates 3 suggest that a dollar in reduced consumer debt raised mortgage debt by between $0.87 and $ Scholz (1994) uses cross sections from the 1983 and 1989 Surveys of Consumer Finances. He finds that household debt rose between 1983 and Among higher-income homeowners, property-backed debt rose rapidly. Among low-income renters, who presumably had less access to deductible borrowing after the TRA86, debt holdings fell. Maki (1995) uses successive cross sections of the Consumer Expenditure Survey. He shows that high income homeowners reduced their consumer debt and raised their mortgage debt after the TRA86, relative to other households. He also shows that highincome renters did not reduce their consumer debt holdings relative to other renters and that households increased their total debt. Engen and Gale (1995) used successive cross sections of the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP) in 1984, 1987, and 1991 to look at household debt. Mortgage debt rose across all income and age groups. Median mortgage debt rose by 14 percent from 1984 to 1987 and by an additional 37 percent from 1987 to Virtually all of this increase was due to an increase in the ratio of mortgage debt to house value, rather than changes in house value. 7 From 1987 to 1991, homeowners with family earnings above $50,000 reduced their holdings of consumer debt, while 334

14 renters in the same earnings classes raised their consumer debt holdings. These studies have important implications for studying household saving behavior and its response to tax changes. First, these studies are consistent with the conclusion that the composition of household debt portfolios is sensitive to the tax treatment of different types of debt. Second, the trends suggest the importance of analyzing the effects of tax reforms on broad measures of household wealth which include liabilities as well as assets. TAX REFORM AND THE ALLOCATION OF TAX-PREFERRED SAVING In this section, we examine the relationship between IRAs and 401(k) plans. Since the early 1980s, tax-based saving incentives plans, such as IRAs and 401(k) plans, gained tremendous popularity. 8 Total contributions to IRAs, 401(k)s, SEPs, and Keoghs increased from less than 4 percent of personal saving in 1981 to about 35 percent of personal saving by 1985, and then continued to comprise about one-third of personal saving through However, the restrictions imposed by the TRA86 on deductible IRA contributions significantly changed the composition of saving incentive contributions. Before the TRA86, IRAs constituted the majority of total saving incentive contributions. However, contributions plummeted following the change in the treatment of IRAs enacted in TRA86. By 1992, IRA contributions comprised less than 20 percent of total saving incentive contributions. In contrast, contributions to 401(k) plans grew steadily since their tax treatment was clarified in 1981 and constituted about three-quarters of total saving incentive contributions by IRAs and 401(k) plans are unlikely to be perfect substitutes. 401(k) plans are tied to the work place, while IRAs are not. 401(k)s usually have employer matching of employee contributions, while IRAs do not. 401(k)s and IRAs generally have different contribution limits, withdrawal and loan provisions, and investment opportunities. 401(k) contributions tend to be regular salary reductions; IRAs can be funded anytime. For example, people may want to put some money into a 401(k) but then keep the flexibility of contributing more to an IRA at a later date in the tax year, depending on their income and expenses. Nevertheless, IRAs and 401(k)s could very well be good substitutes for some people (particularly those who hold both 401(k)s and IRAs). The plans represent alternative ways to save for retirement, and 401(k)s should be particularly attractive for high-income households after the removal of tax deductibility for IRA contributions in One way to test for substitutability is to exploit the removal of tax deductibility of IRA contributions for some higher income families in the TRA86. If households find IRAs and 401(k)s to be substitutes, controlling for other factors, the decline in IRA participation after TRA86 should be larger for 401(k) eligible households than for noneligible households among income groups who lost deductibility of IRA contributions. Poterba, Venti, and Wise (1992) present evidence related to this issue using data from the Employee Benefits Supplement of the 1988 Current Population Survey. They find that for families with incomes above $75,000, the IRA participation rate dropped substantially more for 401(k) eligibles than for noneligibles. In this group, the IRA participation rate fell by 57 percentage points for eligibles compared to 27 percentage points for ineligibles. 335

15 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 3 Engen, Gale, and Scholz (1994) examined the relationship between IRAs and 401(k)s after TRA86, using data from the SIPP. If 401(k)s and IRAs are substitutes, 401(k)-eligible families whose IRA deductibility was restricted in 1986 should funnel more money into 401(k) plans from 1987 to 1991 than eligible families whose deductibility was not removed, controlling for other factors such as income and net worth. They find that among 401(k)-eligible families, not being allowed to make deductible IRA contributions raised 401(k) balances by $2,538 from 1987 to This result is consistent with the hypothesis that there is substitution between 401(k) plans and IRAs. Moreover, they note that the average real 401(k) balance among eligibles in the effected group rose by about $4,300 between 1987 and Hence, the removal of deductibility potentially can account for half of the increase in 401(k) balances in the higher-income group affected by the removal of IRA tax deducibility in the TRA86. Thus, there exists some evidence implying that some households substituted away from IRAs into 401(k)s following the TRA86. The TRA86 probably contributed to, but is almost certainly not solely responsible for, the shift in the composition of households holdings of tax-preferred financial assets. This is consistent with the conclusion that the composition of household asset portfolios is sensitive to the tax treatment of different types of assets. INTERACTIONS BETWEEN ASSETS AND DEBT Engen and Gale (1995) examined interactions between household assets and liabilities by examining the effects of eligibility for, and participation in, 401(k) plans on households accumulation of wealth, where wealth is defined as the sum of net financial assets (financial assets minus consumer debt) and housing equity (house value minus morgage debt). Their analysis used data from successive cross sections in 1987 and 1991 of the SIPP. They obtained several results that point to important interactions between household assets and liabilities following the TRA86. 9 First, between 1987 and 1991, controlling for IRA status and other factors, households with at least one worker eligible for a 401(k) plan did accumulate more financial assets and net financial assets than observationally equivalent households that did not contain a 401(k)-eligible worker. 10 But they also show that 401(k)-eligible households did not accumulate more wealth when housing equity is included. House values rose for eligibles relative to noneligibles, but mortgage debt grew even faster, so that housing equity fell for 401(k)- eligible households relative to ineligible households. Second, they split the sample into homeowners and renters. For renters, being eligible for a 401(k) has no effect on holdings of financial assets or net financial assets. For homeowners, 401(k) eligibility raises gross financial assets and net financial assets, but has no effect on a broader measure of wealth defined to include housing equity. Third, similar results apply to the effects of 401(k) participation in a set of analogous tests that control for IRA status and other factors. The results imply that groups of families that were eligible for 401(k)s or participated in 401(k)s and that had access to mortgage debt, which was still tax deductible after TRA86, raised their financial assets and net financial assets relative to other groups; but this 336

16 increase in one component of their portfolio was fully offset by reductions in housing equity, relative to the other groups. 401(k)-eligible families, or participants, that did not have access to tax-preferred debt after the TRA86 did not raise their financial or net financial assets relative to other groups. In summary, we find that no group of families that was eligible for, or participated in, 401(k)s significantly raised its wealth (including housing equity) from 1987 to 1991 relative to the observationally equivalent group of families that was not eligible or did not participate. In showing that borrowing and saving at the household level can interact in important ways, these results have direct implications for the effects of tax changes on household portfolios and saving. DISCUSSION Slemrod (1990, 1995a) has categorized a hierarchy of taxpayer responses to tax reform. The behavioral response most sensitive to tax reform involves the timing of economic transactions; altering the timing of economic activity in reponse to permanent variations in the time pattern of tax rates or in anticipation of future changes in the tax law. The next most sensitive type of taxpayer response involves avoidance activities, including the reallocation of asset and debt portfolios outlined above. The smallest responses should be expected in real economic behavior: saving, labor supply, etc. 11 The evidence discussed in this paper is consistent with this hierarchy. We note as well that, typically, the timing and avoidance effects are unintended consequences of tax reform, while the real effects are intended. This suggests some implications for the design and implementation of fundamental tax reform. First, the anticipation of tax reform may have important effects on economic activity that serve to offset some of the intended effects. Virtually all analyses of fundamental tax reform assume that the new system is unanticipated and is imposed immediately. This eliminates the possibility of timing responses in the economic models being used, but does not eliminate those responses in the real world. Second, if a fundamental reform from the current tax system to a consumption-based tax includes transitional relief for existing capital, then this will create differential tax treatment across assets. The studies outlined above suggest that these tax differences could create large reshuffling of portfolios. A case in point is the mortgage interest deduction. If the deduction is removed, then we expect households to substitute out of mortgage debt, either by raising their invest- ment debt (Maki, 1996) or by paying down their loan with accumulated assets. If the mortgage deduction is retained in a switch to a consumptionbased tax, then tax reform will have created a conduit for tax-deductible borrowing in a system that does not tax interest income. Creating such arbitrage possibilities could lead to large shifting into mortgages. A final note of caution is warranted. The top few percent of households, by income or wealth, account for a very large share of the net wealth accumulation in the United States. There is little conclusive evidence on how such house holds responded to the TRA86 (Slemrod, 1995a), but their impact on assets, debt, and saving in any fundamental tax reform proposal could prove decisive. ENDNOTES We thank Jane Gravelle for her comments on this paper. All opinions are our own and should not be 337

POLICY BRIEF: THE INTERACTION BETWEEN IRAS AND 401(K) PLANS IN SAVERS PORTFOLIOS

POLICY BRIEF: THE INTERACTION BETWEEN IRAS AND 401(K) PLANS IN SAVERS PORTFOLIOS POLICY BRIEF: THE INTERACTION BETWEEN IRAS AND 401(K) PLANS IN SAVERS PORTFOLIOS William Gale, Aaron Krupkin, and Shanthi Ramnath October 25, 2017 The opinions represent those of the authors and are not

More information

DEBT, TAXES, AND THE EFFECTS OF 401(k) PLANS ON HOUSEHOLD WEALTH ACCUMULATION*

DEBT, TAXES, AND THE EFFECTS OF 401(k) PLANS ON HOUSEHOLD WEALTH ACCUMULATION* DEBT, TAXES, AND THE EFFECTS OF 401(k) PLANS ON HOUSEHOLD WEALTH ACCUMULATION* Eric M. Engen Federal Reserve Board Mail Stop 83 Washington, DC 20551 (202) 452-2980 eengen@frb.gov William G. Gale The Brookings

More information

Some Considerations for Empirical Research on Tax-Preferred Savings Accounts.

Some Considerations for Empirical Research on Tax-Preferred Savings Accounts. Some Considerations for Empirical Research on Tax-Preferred Savings Accounts. Kevin Milligan Department of Economics University of British Columbia Prepared for: Frontiers of Public Finance National Tax

More information

THE INTERACTION BETWEEN IRAS AND 401(K) PLANS IN SAVERS PORTFOLIOS

THE INTERACTION BETWEEN IRAS AND 401(K) PLANS IN SAVERS PORTFOLIOS THE INTERACTION BETWEEN IRAS AND 401(K) PLANS IN SAVERS PORTFOLIOS William Gale, Aaron Krupkin, and Shanthi Ramnath October 25, 2017 TAX POLICY CENTER URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

More information

In the United States, most tax incentives for saving are. The Taxation of Retirement Saving: Choosing Between Front Loaded and Back Loaded Options

In the United States, most tax incentives for saving are. The Taxation of Retirement Saving: Choosing Between Front Loaded and Back Loaded Options The Taxation of Retirement Saving The Taxation of Retirement Saving: Choosing Between Front Loaded and Back Loaded Options Abstract - We examine retirement savers choices between front and back loaded

More information

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code RL30351 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Consumption Taxes and the Level and Composition of Saving Updated January 11, 2001 Steven Maguire Analyst in Public Finance Government

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRANSITION TO PERSONAL ACCOUNTS AND INCREASING RETIREMENT WEALTH: MACRO AND MICRO EVIDENCE

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRANSITION TO PERSONAL ACCOUNTS AND INCREASING RETIREMENT WEALTH: MACRO AND MICRO EVIDENCE NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRANSITION TO PERSONAL ACCOUNTS AND INCREASING RETIREMENT WEALTH: MACRO AND MICRO EVIDENCE James M. Poterba Steven F. Venti David A. Wise Working Paper 8610 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8610

More information

Summary The Administration s 2010 and 2011 budget outlines contain a proposal to cap the value of itemized deductions at 28%, for high-income taxpayer

Summary The Administration s 2010 and 2011 budget outlines contain a proposal to cap the value of itemized deductions at 28%, for high-income taxpayer Charitable Contributions: The Itemized Deduction Cap and Other FY2011 Budget Options Jane G. Gravelle Senior Specialist in Economic Policy Donald J. Marples Specialist in Public Finance March 18, 2010

More information

Volume Title: The Effects of Taxation on Capital Accumulation. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press

Volume Title: The Effects of Taxation on Capital Accumulation. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Effects of Taxation on Capital Accumulation Volume Author/Editor: Martin Feldstein, ed.

More information

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code RL30255 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs): Issues, Proposed Expansion, and Retirement Savings Accounts (RSAs) Updated September 15, 2000

More information

The Changing Composition of Tax Incentives

The Changing Composition of Tax Incentives The Changing Composition of Tax Incentives 1980-99 Eric Toder The nonpartisan Urban Institute publishes studies, reports, and books on timely topics worthy of public consideration. The views expressed

More information

HOW DO INHERITANCES AFFECT THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX?

HOW DO INHERITANCES AFFECT THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX? September 2015, Number 15-15 RETIREMENT RESEARCH HOW DO INHERITANCES AFFECT THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX? By Alicia H. Munnell, Wenliang Hou, and Anthony Webb* Introduction Today s working-age households,

More information

Demographic Change, Retirement Saving, and Financial Market Returns

Demographic Change, Retirement Saving, and Financial Market Returns Preliminary and Partial Draft Please Do Not Quote Demographic Change, Retirement Saving, and Financial Market Returns James Poterba MIT and NBER and Steven Venti Dartmouth College and NBER and David A.

More information

Six Tax Laws Later How Individuals' Marginal Federal Income Tax Rates Changed Between 1980 and 1995 Leonard E. Burman, William G. Gale, David Weiner

Six Tax Laws Later How Individuals' Marginal Federal Income Tax Rates Changed Between 1980 and 1995 Leonard E. Burman, William G. Gale, David Weiner Six Tax Laws Later How Individuals' Marginal Federal Income Tax Rates Changed Between 1980 and 1995 Leonard E. Burman, William G. Gale, David Weiner Reprinted with permission of the National Tax Journal.

More information

THE EFFECTS OF 401(k) PLANS ON HOUSEHOLD WEALTH: DIFFERENCES ACROSS EARNINGS GROUPS *

THE EFFECTS OF 401(k) PLANS ON HOUSEHOLD WEALTH: DIFFERENCES ACROSS EARNINGS GROUPS * THE EFFECTS OF 401(k) PLANS ON HOUSEHOLD WEALTH: DIFFERENCES ACROSS EARNINGS GROUPS * Eric M. Engen William G. Gale Federal Reserve Board The Brookings Institution Mail Stop 93 1775 Massachusetts Avenue,

More information

HOW DOES 401(K) AUTO-ENROLLMENT RELATE TO THE EMPLOYER MATCH AND TOTAL COMPENSATION?

HOW DOES 401(K) AUTO-ENROLLMENT RELATE TO THE EMPLOYER MATCH AND TOTAL COMPENSATION? October 2013, Number 13-14 RETIREMENT RESEARCH HOW DOES 401(K) AUTO-ENROLLMENT RELATE TO THE EMPLOYER MATCH AND TOTAL COMPENSATION? By Barbara A. Butrica and Nadia S. Karamcheva* Introduction Many workers

More information

WikiLeaks Document Release

WikiLeaks Document Release WikiLeaks Document Release February 2, 2009 Congressional Research Service Report RL30255 Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs): Issues and Proposed Expansion Thomas L. Hungerford, Specialist in Public

More information

The Changing Distribution of Pension Coverage*

The Changing Distribution of Pension Coverage* The Changing Distribution of Pension Coverage* Industrial Relations, April 2000 William E. Even David A. Macpherson Department of Economics Department of Economics Miami University Florida State University

More information

THE EFFECTS OF TAX-BASED INCENTIVES ON SAVmG AND WEALTH. Eric M. Engen William G. Gale John Karl Scholz. Working Paper 5759

THE EFFECTS OF TAX-BASED INCENTIVES ON SAVmG AND WEALTH. Eric M. Engen William G. Gale John Karl Scholz. Working Paper 5759 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECTS OF TAX-BASED SAV~G INCENTIVES ON SAVmG AND WEALTH Eric M. Engen William G. Gale John Karl Scholz Working Paper 5759 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

center for retirement research

center for retirement research SAVING FOR RETIREMENT: TAXES MATTER By James M. Poterba * Introduction To encourage individuals to save for retirement, federal tax policy provides various tax advantages for investments in self-directed

More information

July 17, Summary

July 17, Summary 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org July 17, 2006 PENSION BILL CONFERENCE REPORT MAY MAKE SOME 2001 TAX CUTS PERMANENT WITHOUT

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DISTRIBUTION OF PAYROLL AND INCOME TAX BURDENS, Andrew Mitrusi James Poterba

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DISTRIBUTION OF PAYROLL AND INCOME TAX BURDENS, Andrew Mitrusi James Poterba NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DISTRIBUTION OF PAYROLL AND INCOME TAX BURDENS, 1979-1999 Andrew Mitrusi James Poterba Working Paper 7707 http://www.nber.org/papers/w7707 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

Summary Preparing for financial security in retirement continues to be a concern of working Americans and policymakers. Although most Americans partic

Summary Preparing for financial security in retirement continues to be a concern of working Americans and policymakers. Although most Americans partic Ownership of Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs) and Policy Options for Congress John J. Topoleski Analyst in Income Security January 7, 2011 Congressional Research Service CRS Report for Congress Prepared

More information

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE November 2011, Number 11-13 RETIREMENT RESEARCH HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE RETIREMENT By Alicia H. Munnell, Francesca Golub-Sass, and Anthony Webb* Introduction One of the major challenges facing Americans

More information

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY Institute of Business and Economic Research Fisher Center for Real Estate and Urban Economics PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY WORKING PAPER SERIES WORKING PAPER NO. W06-001B HOUSING POLICY IN THE UNITED

More information

WikiLeaks Document Release

WikiLeaks Document Release WikiLeaks Document Release February 2, 2009 Congressional Research Service Report RL30708 Social Security, Saving, and the Economy Brian W. Cashell, Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy January 8, 2009 Abstract.

More information

Tanzi (1987) studies the sweeping tax reform that occurs

Tanzi (1987) studies the sweeping tax reform that occurs Tanzi (1987): A Retrospective Tanzi (1987): A Retrospective Abstract - This empirical research extends the work of Tanzi (1987) and provides comparative 1985 99 corporate income tax (CIT) rates for 29

More information

MEASURING THE IMPACT OF TAX REFORM ALAN J. AUERBACH *

MEASURING THE IMPACT OF TAX REFORM ALAN J. AUERBACH * MEASURING THE IMPACT OF TAX REFORM ALAN J. AUERBACH * Abstract - This paper considers why so many questions about the economic effects of tax reforms remain unanswered, and draws implications for how economics

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAX EVASION AND CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION. James M. Poterba. Working Paper No. 2119

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAX EVASION AND CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION. James M. Poterba. Working Paper No. 2119 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAX EVASION AND CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION James M. Poterba Working Paper No. 2119 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 January 1987

More information

Despite tax cuts enacted in 1997, federal revenues for fiscal

Despite tax cuts enacted in 1997, federal revenues for fiscal What Made Receipts Boom What Made Receipts Boom and When Will They Go Bust? Abstract - Federal revenues surged in the past three fiscal years, with receipts growing much faster than the economy and nearly

More information

Revenue and Incentive Effects of Basis Step-Up at Death: Lessons from the 2010 Voluntary Estate Tax Regime

Revenue and Incentive Effects of Basis Step-Up at Death: Lessons from the 2010 Voluntary Estate Tax Regime Revenue and Incentive Effects of Basis Step-Up at Death: Lessons from the 2010 Voluntary Estate Tax Regime The MIT Faculty has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits

More information

Saving, wealth and consumption

Saving, wealth and consumption By Melissa Davey of the Bank s Structural Economic Analysis Division. The UK household saving ratio has recently fallen to its lowest level since 19. A key influence has been the large increase in the

More information

The current recession has renewed interest in the extent

The current recession has renewed interest in the extent Is the Corporation Tax an Effective Automatic Stabilizer? Is the Corporation Tax an Effective Automatic Stabilizer? Abstract - We investigate the extent to which the corporation tax can act as an automatic

More information

Access to Retirement Savings and its Effects on Labor Supply Decisions

Access to Retirement Savings and its Effects on Labor Supply Decisions Access to Retirement Savings and its Effects on Labor Supply Decisions Yan Lau Reed College May 2015 IZA / RIETI Workshop Motivation My Question: How are labor supply decisions affected by access of Retirement

More information

Enhancing Future Retirement Income through 401 (k)s

Enhancing Future Retirement Income through 401 (k)s The Regional Economist October 1998 Enhancing Future Retirement Income through 401 (k)s by Kevin L. Kliesen With the retirement of the baby boom generation slated to get under way in about a decade, retirement

More information

A Look at the End-of-Life Financial Situation in America, p. 2

A Look at the End-of-Life Financial Situation in America, p. 2 April 2015 Vol. 36, No. 4 A Look at the End-of-Life Financial Situation in America, p. 2 A T A G L A N C E A Look at the End-of-Life Financial Situation in America, by Sudipto Banerjee, Ph.D., EBRI This

More information

Universal Savings Account Proposal in New Republican Tax Bill Is Ill-Conceived

Universal Savings Account Proposal in New Republican Tax Bill Is Ill-Conceived 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org Updated September 19, 2018 Universal Savings Account Proposal in New Republican Tax

More information

Hoover Classics : Flat Tax hcflat ch6 Mp_201 rev0 page 201. Notes and References

Hoover Classics : Flat Tax hcflat ch6 Mp_201 rev0 page 201. Notes and References Hoover Classics : Flat Tax hcflat ch6 Mp_201 rev0 page 201 1. meet the federal income tax The Declaration of Independence is on display in the main lobby of the National Archives in Washington, D.C. Standard

More information

RETIREMENT PLAN COVERAGE AND SAVING TRENDS OF BABY BOOMER COHORTS BY SEX: ANALYSIS OF THE 1989 AND 1998 SCF

RETIREMENT PLAN COVERAGE AND SAVING TRENDS OF BABY BOOMER COHORTS BY SEX: ANALYSIS OF THE 1989 AND 1998 SCF PPI PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE RETIREMENT PLAN COVERAGE AND SAVING TRENDS OF BABY BOOMER COHORTS BY SEX: ANALYSIS OF THE AND SCF D A T A D I G E S T Introduction Over the next three decades, the retirement

More information

WOULD RAISING IRA CONTRIBUTION LIMITS BOLSTER RETIREMENT SECURITY FOR LOWER AND MIDDLE-INCOME FAMILIES? by Peter Orszag and Jonathan Orszag 1

WOULD RAISING IRA CONTRIBUTION LIMITS BOLSTER RETIREMENT SECURITY FOR LOWER AND MIDDLE-INCOME FAMILIES? by Peter Orszag and Jonathan Orszag 1 820 First Street, NE, Suite 510, Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org http://www.cbpp.org April 2, 2001 WOULD RAISING IRA CONTRIBUTION LIMITS BOLSTER RETIREMENT SECURITY

More information

Tax Incentives for Household Saving and Borrowing

Tax Incentives for Household Saving and Borrowing Tax Incentives for Household Saving and Borrowing Tullio Jappelli CSEF, Università di Salerno, and CEPR Luigi Pistaferri Stanford University, CEPR and SIEPR 21 August 2001 This paper is part of the World

More information

TRENDS AND ISSUES. Do People Save Enough for Retirement?

TRENDS AND ISSUES. Do People Save Enough for Retirement? Do People Save Enough for Retirement? Alicia H. Munnell, Boston College May 2005 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This report looks at how much income individuals need in retirement and summarizes results from economic

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EXCHANGE TRADED FUNDS: A NEW INVESTMENT OPTION FOR TAXABLE INVESTORS. James M. Poterba John B. Shoven

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EXCHANGE TRADED FUNDS: A NEW INVESTMENT OPTION FOR TAXABLE INVESTORS. James M. Poterba John B. Shoven NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EXCHANGE TRADED FUNDS: A NEW INVESTMENT OPTION FOR TAXABLE INVESTORS James M. Poterba John B. Shoven Working Paper 8781 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8781 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Comment on "The Impact of Housing Markets on Consumer Debt"

Comment on The Impact of Housing Markets on Consumer Debt Federal Reserve Board From the SelectedWorks of Karen M. Pence March, 2015 Comment on "The Impact of Housing Markets on Consumer Debt" Karen M. Pence Available at: https://works.bepress.com/karen_pence/20/

More information

The unprecedented surge in tax receipts beginning in fiscal

The unprecedented surge in tax receipts beginning in fiscal Forecasting Federal Individual Income Tax Receipts Challenges and Uncertainties in Forecasting Federal Individual Income Tax Receipts Abstract - Forecasting individual income receipts has been greatly

More information

A pril 15. It causes much anxiety, with

A pril 15. It causes much anxiety, with Peter S. Yoo is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Richard D. Taylor provided research assistance. The Tax Man Cometh: Consumer Spending and Tax Payments Peter S. Yoo A pril 15. It

More information

INTRODUCTION: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF TAX EXPENDITURES

INTRODUCTION: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF TAX EXPENDITURES National Tax Journal, June 2011, 64 (2, Part 2), 451 458 Introduction INTRODUCTION: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF TAX EXPENDITURES James M. Poterba Many economists and policy analysts argue that broadening the

More information

ECONOMIC FACTORS ASSOCIATED WITH DELINQUENCY RATES ON CONSUMER INSTALMENT DEBT A. Charlene Sullivan *

ECONOMIC FACTORS ASSOCIATED WITH DELINQUENCY RATES ON CONSUMER INSTALMENT DEBT A. Charlene Sullivan * ECONOMIC FACTORS ASSOCIATED WITH DELINQUENCY RATES ON CONSUMER INSTALMENT DEBT A. Charlene Sullivan * Trends in loan delinquencies and losses over time and among credit types contain important information

More information

Measuring the Trends in Inequality of Individuals and Families: Income and Consumption

Measuring the Trends in Inequality of Individuals and Families: Income and Consumption Measuring the Trends in Inequality of Individuals and Families: Income and Consumption by Jonathan D. Fisher U.S. Census Bureau David S. Johnson* U.S. Census Bureau Timothy M. Smeeding University of Wisconsin

More information

A LOOK BEHIND THE NUMBERS

A LOOK BEHIND THE NUMBERS KEY FINDINGS A LOOK BEHIND THE NUMBERS Home Lending in Cuyahoga County Neighborhoods Lisa Nelson Community Development Advisor Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Prior to the Great Recession, home mortgage

More information

Fiscal Fact. Reversal of the Trend: Income Inequality Now Lower than It Was under Clinton. Introduction. By William McBride

Fiscal Fact. Reversal of the Trend: Income Inequality Now Lower than It Was under Clinton. Introduction. By William McBride Fiscal Fact January 30, 2012 No. 289 Reversal of the Trend: Income Inequality Now Lower than It Was under Clinton By William McBride Introduction Numerous academic studies have shown that income inequality

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES AGING AND HOUSING EQUITY: ANOTHER LOOK. Steven F. Venti David A. Wise. Working Paper 8608

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES AGING AND HOUSING EQUITY: ANOTHER LOOK. Steven F. Venti David A. Wise. Working Paper 8608 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES AGING AND HOUSING EQUITY: ANOTHER LOOK Steven F. Venti David A. Wise Working Paper 8608 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8608 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Introduction to "Pensions in the U.S. Economy"

Volume URL:  Chapter Title: Introduction to Pensions in the U.S. Economy This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Pensions in the U.S. Economy Volume Author/Editor: Zvi Bodie, John B. Shoven, and David A.

More information

CNA. Thrift Savings Plans: Effect on Savings and Tax Revenues. CRM D A2 / Final December Thomas A. Husted with Michael L.

CNA. Thrift Savings Plans: Effect on Savings and Tax Revenues. CRM D A2 / Final December Thomas A. Husted with Michael L. CRM D0002891.A2 / Final December 2001 Thrift Savings Plans: Effect on Savings and Tax Revenues Thomas A. Husted with Michael L. Hansen CNA 4825 Mark Center Drive Alexandria, Virginia 22311-1 850 Copyright

More information

SHOULD YOU CARRY A MORTGAGE INTO RETIREMENT?

SHOULD YOU CARRY A MORTGAGE INTO RETIREMENT? July 2009, Number 9-15 SHOULD YOU CARRY A MORTGAGE INTO RETIREMENT? By Anthony Webb* Introduction Although it remains the goal of many households to repay their mortgage by retirement, an increasing proportion

More information

1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 7+(())(&762)N3/$ (+2/':($/7+ ',))(5(1&(6$&5266($51,1*6*52836 (UL 0(QJHQ :LOOLDP**DOH :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ

1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 7+(())(&762)N3/$ (+2/':($/7+ ',))(5(1&(6$&5266($51,1*6*52836 (UL 0(QJHQ :LOOLDP**DOH :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ 1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 7+(())(&762)N3/$1621+286(+2/':($/7+ ',))(5(1&(6$&5266($51,1*6*52836 (UL 0(QJHQ :LOOLDP**DOH :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ 1$7,21$/%85($82)(&2120,&5(6($5&+ 0DVVD KXVHWWV$YHQXH

More information

Tax Reform and Charitable Giving

Tax Reform and Charitable Giving University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Economics Department Faculty Publications Economics Department 28 Reform and Charitable Giving Seth H. Giertz University

More information

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress Order Code RL33285 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Tax Reform and Distributional Issues February 27, 2006 Jane G. Gravelle Senior Specialist in Economic Policy Government and Finance

More information

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN *

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN * SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN * Abstract - This paper reexamines the results of my 1974 paper on Social Security and saving with the help

More information

VERY PRELIMINARY - DO NOT QUOTE OR DISTRIBUTE

VERY PRELIMINARY - DO NOT QUOTE OR DISTRIBUTE 0 VERY PRELIMINARY - DO NOT QUOTE OR DISTRIBUTE Do Required Minimum Distributions Constrain Household Behavior? The Effect of the 2009 Holiday on Retirement Savings Plan Distributions Jeffrey Brown University

More information

GEORGIA STATE UNIVERSITY ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES FISCAL RESEARCH CENTER May 14, 1999

GEORGIA STATE UNIVERSITY ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES FISCAL RESEARCH CENTER May 14, 1999 GEORGIA STATE UNIVERSITY ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES FISCAL RESEARCH CENTER May 14, 1999 SUBJECT: Addressing Noncompliance in the Earned Income Tax Credit Analysis Prepared by Dagney Faulk I.

More information

OVER THE PAST TWO DECADES THERE HAS BEEN

OVER THE PAST TWO DECADES THERE HAS BEEN RUNNING 401(k): KEEPING PACE FROM ACCUMULATION TO DISTRIBUTION* Sarah Holden and Michael Bogdan, Investment Company Institute INTRODUCTION OVER THE PAST TWO DECADES THERE HAS BEEN a shift in private-sector

More information

U.S. Household Savings for Retirement in 2010

U.S. Household Savings for Retirement in 2010 U.S. Household Savings for Retirement in 2010 John J. Topoleski Analyst in Income Security April 30, 2013 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Congressional Research

More information

Testimony to the President s Tax Reform Panel

Testimony to the President s Tax Reform Panel Testimony to the President s Tax Reform Panel John D. Podesta President Center for American Progress May 11, 2005 Overview The Center for American Progress Tax Reform Plan Fair and Responsible Reform The

More information

Diversity in Retirement Wealth Accumulation

Diversity in Retirement Wealth Accumulation URBAN INSTITUTE Brief Series No. 24 December 2008 Diversity in Retirement Wealth Accumulation Gordon B. T. Mermin, Sheila R. Zedlewski, and Desmond J. Toohey Americans save for retirement through a number

More information

Retirement Savings and Household Wealth in 2007

Retirement Savings and Household Wealth in 2007 Retirement Savings and Household Wealth in 2007 Patrick Purcell Specialist in Income Security April 8, 2009 Congressional Research Service CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of

More information

Federal Tax Treatment of Health Insurance Expenditures by the Self-Employed: Current Law and Issues for Congress Summary Current federal tax law allow

Federal Tax Treatment of Health Insurance Expenditures by the Self-Employed: Current Law and Issues for Congress Summary Current federal tax law allow Order Code RL33311 Federal Tax Treatment of Health Insurance Expenditures by the Self-Employed: Current Law and Issues for Congress Updated February 22, 2008 Gary Guenther Analyst in Public Finance Government

More information

Tax Rates and Economic Growth

Tax Rates and Economic Growth Jane G. Gravelle Senior Specialist in Economic Policy Donald J. Marples Section Research Manager December 5, 2011 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Congressional Research

More information

Retirement Security: What s Working and What s Not? James Poterba MIT, NBER, & TIAA-CREF. Bipartisan Policy Center 30 July 2014

Retirement Security: What s Working and What s Not? James Poterba MIT, NBER, & TIAA-CREF. Bipartisan Policy Center 30 July 2014 Retirement Security: What s Working and What s Not? James Poterba MIT, NBER, & TIAA-CREF Bipartisan Policy Center 30 July 2014 Retirement Support: A Three Legged Stool? Three Legs: Social Security, Private

More information

WikiLeaks Document Release

WikiLeaks Document Release WikiLeaks Document Release February 2, 2009 Congressional Research Service Report RL33168 Why is the Household Saving Rate So Low? Brian W. Cashell, Government and Finance Division January 9, 2008 Abstract.

More information

Volume Title: Studies in State and Local Public Finance. Volume URL:

Volume Title: Studies in State and Local Public Finance. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Studies in State and Local Public Finance Volume Author/Editor: Harvey S. Rosen, ed. Volume

More information

Chapter URL:

Chapter URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Taxing Multinational Corporations Volume Author/Editor: Martin Feldstein, James R. Hines

More information

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress Order Code RL32781 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Federal Deductibility of State and Local Taxes February 24, 2005 Steven Maguire Analyst in Public Finance Government and Finance

More information

The Tax Reform Act of 1986: Comment on the 25th Anniversary

The Tax Reform Act of 1986: Comment on the 25th Anniversary The Tax Reform Act of 1986: Comment on the 25th Anniversary The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Feldstein,

More information

Outsourcing and Insourcing Jobs in the U.S. Economy: An Overview of Evidence Based on Foreign Investment Data

Outsourcing and Insourcing Jobs in the U.S. Economy: An Overview of Evidence Based on Foreign Investment Data Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Federal Publications Key Workplace Documents 4-15-2010 Outsourcing and Insourcing Jobs in the U.S. Economy: An Overview of Evidence Based on Foreign Investment

More information

TAX EXPENDITURES FOR RETIREMENT PLANS

TAX EXPENDITURES FOR RETIREMENT PLANS TAX EXPENDITURES FOR RETIREMENT PLANS The tax law recently enacted by Congress includes a great many provisions Some are easy to understand Others are not Among the least understood provisions are those

More information

Current tax law allows workers to opt out, either partially

Current tax law allows workers to opt out, either partially Opting Out of Social Security: An Idea that s Already Arrived Opting Out of Social Security: An Idea that s Already Arrived Abstract - Under current law, workers can partially opt out of Social Security

More information

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default Trends and Issues October 2018 Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default Chester S. Spatt, Carnegie Mellon University and TIAA Institute Fellow 1. Introduction An

More information

Lump-Sum Distributions at Job Change, Distributions Through 2012, p. 2

Lump-Sum Distributions at Job Change, Distributions Through 2012, p. 2 November 2013 Vol. 34, No. 11 Lump-Sum Distributions at Job Change, Distributions Through 2012, p. 2 A T A G L A N C E Lump-Sum Distributions at Job Change, Distributions Through 2012, by Craig Copeland,

More information

Changes in the Distribution of After-Tax Wealth: Has Income Tax Policy Increased Wealth Inequality?

Changes in the Distribution of After-Tax Wealth: Has Income Tax Policy Increased Wealth Inequality? Changes in the Distribution of After-Tax Wealth: Has Income Tax Policy Increased Wealth Inequality? Adam Looney* and Kevin B. Moore** October 16, 2015 Abstract A substantial share of the wealth of Americans

More information

Wealth Dynamics during Retirement: Evidence from Population-Level Wealth Data in Sweden

Wealth Dynamics during Retirement: Evidence from Population-Level Wealth Data in Sweden Wealth Dynamics during Retirement: Evidence from Population-Level Wealth Data in Sweden By Martin Ljunge, Lee Lockwood, and Day Manoli September 2014 ABSTRACT In this paper, we document the wealth dynamics

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ASSET ALLOCATION AND ASSET LOCATION: HOUSEHOLD EVIDENCE FROM THE SURVEY OF CONSUMER FINANCES

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ASSET ALLOCATION AND ASSET LOCATION: HOUSEHOLD EVIDENCE FROM THE SURVEY OF CONSUMER FINANCES NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ASSET ALLOCATION AND ASSET LOCATION: HOUSEHOLD EVIDENCE FROM THE SURVEY OF CONSUMER FINANCES Daniel Bergstresser James Poterba Working Paper 9268 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9268

More information

WILL THE ADMINISTRATION S TAX CUTS GENERATE SUBSTANTIAL ECONOMIC GROWTH? by Richard Kogan

WILL THE ADMINISTRATION S TAX CUTS GENERATE SUBSTANTIAL ECONOMIC GROWTH? by Richard Kogan 820 First Street, NE, Suite 510, Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org March 3, 2003 WILL THE ADMINISTRATION S TAX CUTS GENERATE SUBSTANTIAL ECONOMIC GROWTH?

More information

JOB TENURE AND THE SPREAD OF 401(K)S

JOB TENURE AND THE SPREAD OF 401(K)S October 2006, Number 55 JOB TENURE AND THE SPREAD OF 401(K)S By Alicia H. Munnell, Kelly Haverstick, and Geoffrey Sanzenbacher* Introduction Commentators constantly cite an increase in labor mobility as

More information

STATE CORPORATE INCOME TAXES GENERALLY

STATE CORPORATE INCOME TAXES GENERALLY 102 ND ANNUAL CONFERENCE ON TAXATION A NEW APPROACH TO STATE CORPORATE TAXATION James R. Nunns and Swaroop R. Chary, Department of Taxation and Revenue, State of New Mexico INTRODUCTION STATE CORPORATE

More information

DID TAX FLATTENING AFFECT RRSP CONTRIBUTIONS? Michael R. Veall. QSEP Research Report No April 1999

DID TAX FLATTENING AFFECT RRSP CONTRIBUTIONS? Michael R. Veall. QSEP Research Report No April 1999 Research Institute for Quantitative Studies in Economics and Population Faculty of Social Sciences, McMaster University Hamilton, Ontario, Canada L8S 4M4 DID TAX FLATTENING AFFECT RRSP CONTRIBUTIONS? Michael

More information

IS PENSION INEQUALITY GROWING?

IS PENSION INEQUALITY GROWING? January 2010, Number 10-1 IS PENSION INEQUALITY GROWING? By Nadia Karamcheva and Geoffrey Sanzenbacher* Introduction Employer-sponsored pensions are an important source of retirement income and often make

More information

DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE?

DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE? March 2019, Number 19-5 RETIREMENT RESEARCH DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE? By Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher and Wenliang Hou* Introduction Households save for retirement to help

More information

TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND

TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND Roger Gordon Department of Economics University of California, San Diego 9500 Gilman Drive La Jolla, Ca 92093 858-534-4828 858-534-7040 (fax) rogordon@ucsd.edu Laura

More information

Extension of Saving and Investment Incentives

Extension of Saving and Investment Incentives Extension of Saving and Investment Incentives Testimony Submitted to Subcommittee on Taxation and IRS Oversight of the Committee on Finance United States Senate June 30, 2005 Eric J. Toder The Urban Institute

More information

OVERALL FEDERAL TAX BURDEN ON MOST FAMILIES AT LOWEST LEVELS SINCE AT LEAST Income Taxes for Median Family of Four at Lowest Level Since 1957

OVERALL FEDERAL TAX BURDEN ON MOST FAMILIES AT LOWEST LEVELS SINCE AT LEAST Income Taxes for Median Family of Four at Lowest Level Since 1957 820 First Street, NE, Suite 510, Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org http://www.cbpp.org Revised April 10, 200 OVERALL FEDERAL TAX BURDEN ON MOST FAMILIES AT LOWEST

More information

Retirement Tax Incentives Are Ripe for Reform

Retirement Tax Incentives Are Ripe for Reform 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org December 13, 2013 Retirement Tax Incentives Are Ripe for Reform Current Incentives Are

More information

The Effect of Tax Reform on Owner and Renter Taxes

The Effect of Tax Reform on Owner and Renter Taxes The Effect of Tax Reform on Owner and Renter Taxes Patric H. Hendershott Professor Emeritus: University of Aberdeen and The Ohio State University phh3939@gmail.com David C. Ling McGurn Professor of Real

More information

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact Georgia State University From the SelectedWorks of Fatoumata Diarrassouba Spring March 29, 2013 Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact Fatoumata

More information

Income Taxes and Tax Rates for Sample Families, 2006 Greg Leiserson. December 2006

Income Taxes and Tax Rates for Sample Families, 2006 Greg Leiserson. December 2006 Income Taxes and Tax Rates for Sample Families, 2006 Greg Leiserson December 2006 This article examines how much income tax families pay in different situations, as well as the effective marginal tax rates

More information

The Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA 86) substantially changed

The Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA 86) substantially changed The Tax Reform Act of 1986 and the Composition of Consumer Debt The Tax Reform Act of 1986 and the Composition of Consumer Debt Abstract - The Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA 86) phased out the deductibility

More information

New Jersey Public-Private Sector Wage Differentials: 1970 to William M. Rodgers III. Heldrich Center for Workforce Development

New Jersey Public-Private Sector Wage Differentials: 1970 to William M. Rodgers III. Heldrich Center for Workforce Development New Jersey Public-Private Sector Wage Differentials: 1970 to 2004 1 William M. Rodgers III Heldrich Center for Workforce Development Bloustein School of Planning and Public Policy November 2006 EXECUTIVE

More information

The Shrinking Tax Preference for Pension Savings: An Analysis of Income Tax Changes,

The Shrinking Tax Preference for Pension Savings: An Analysis of Income Tax Changes, March 29, 2010 The Shrinking Tax Preference for Pension Savings: An Analysis of Income Tax Changes, 1985-2007 by Gary Burtless THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION Washington, DC and Eric Toder URBAN INSTITUTE Washington,

More information

NRRI UPDATE SHOWS HALF STILL FALLING SHORT

NRRI UPDATE SHOWS HALF STILL FALLING SHORT December 2014, Number 14-20 RETIREMENT RESEARCH NRRI UPDATE SHOWS HALF STILL FALLING SHORT By Alicia H. Munnell, Wenliang Hou, and Anthony Webb* Introduction The release of the Federal Reserve s 2013 Survey

More information

CBO MEMORANDUM ESTIMATES OF FEDERAL TAX LIABILITIES FOR INDIVIDUALS AND FAMILIES BY INCOME CATEGORY AND FAMILY TYPE FOR 1995 AND 1999.

CBO MEMORANDUM ESTIMATES OF FEDERAL TAX LIABILITIES FOR INDIVIDUALS AND FAMILIES BY INCOME CATEGORY AND FAMILY TYPE FOR 1995 AND 1999. CBO MEMORANDUM ESTIMATES OF FEDERAL TAX LIABILITIES FOR INDIVIDUALS AND FAMILIES BY INCOME CATEGORY AND FAMILY TYPE FOR 1995 AND 1999 May 1998 PESTHBÖTIÖK 8TATCMEMT A Appfoyadl far prabkei r.tea» K> CONGRESSIONAL

More information