Aggregate Demand and the Top 1% AEA Meetings, Chicago January 7, 2017

Similar documents
Inequality and Aggregate Demand. November 2017

Inequality and Aggregate Demand. USC/INET Conference on Inequality, Globalization, and Macroeconomics April 28, 2017

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S.

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

Discussion of The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durables Purchases by Silvana Tenreyro and Vincent Sterk

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Monetary Economics. Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk. June 2012

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

Welfare Evaluations of Policy Reforms with Heterogeneous Agents

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

Household Leverage and the Recession Appendix (not for publication)

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Tobin s Q and Inequality

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default

A model to help guide monetary (and fiscal) policy-making that isn t a sticky-price Ricardian cashless NK model. David Andolfatto

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Monetary Policy According to HANK

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

Inequality and Aggregate Demand

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Online Appendix to The Dynamics of Inequality Xavier Gabaix, Jean-Michel Lasry, Pierre-Louis Lions, Benjamin Moll August 4, 2016

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB

Understanding Predictability (JPE, 2004)

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Intermediary Asset Pricing

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Continuous Time Bewley Models

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY FOR

Age, Luck, and Inheritance

Why are Banks Exposed to Monetary Policy?

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Endogenous employment and incomplete markets

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances

The stochastic discount factor and the CAPM

Economics 8106 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 2

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Problem set Fall 2012.

Econ / Summer 2005

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Oil Shocks and the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates

A Production-Based Model for the Term Structure

Aggregate Demand I, II March 22-31

Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Interest Rate Curves Calibration with Monte-Carlo Simulatio

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2007, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

A Demand Theory of the Price Level

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

A Model with Costly Enforcement

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis

Dynamic Asset Pricing Models: Recent Developments

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

Uninsured Unemployment Risk and Optimal Monetary Policy

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

"Option Value of Consumer Bankruptcy"

Effectiveness of CPPI Strategies under Discrete Time Trading

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

Transcription:

Aggregate Demand and the Top 1% Adrien Auclert Stanford Matthew Rognlie Northwestern AEA Meetings, Chicago January 7, 2017

Two canonical models of inequality 1. Income inequality literature: Considers random growth income processes Gets Pareto tail of the income distribution 2. Incomplete markets literature: Considers variety of income processes (typically lognormal) Gets predictions for aggregate consumption, savings and wealth

Two canonical models of inequality 1. Income inequality literature: Considers random growth income processes Gets Pareto tail of the income distribution 2. Incomplete markets literature: Considers variety of income processes (typically lognormal) Gets predictions for aggregate consumption, savings and wealth This paper: combines 1 and 2 to examine macro consequences of an increase in top 1% of labor incomes, leaving average income cst

Two canonical models of inequality 1. Income inequality literature: Considers random growth income processes Gets Pareto tail of the income distribution 2. Incomplete markets literature: Considers variety of income processes (typically lognormal) Gets predictions for aggregate consumption, savings and wealth This paper: combines 1 and 2 to examine macro consequences of an increase in top 1% of labor incomes, leaving average income cst Focus on aggregate demand (partial equilibrium) outcomes Top 1% desired consumption in short run, wealth in long run

Two canonical models of inequality 1. Income inequality literature: Considers random growth income processes Gets Pareto tail of the income distribution 2. Incomplete markets literature: Considers variety of income processes (typically lognormal) Gets predictions for aggregate consumption, savings and wealth This paper: combines 1 and 2 to examine macro consequences of an increase in top 1% of labor incomes, leaving average income cst Focus on aggregate demand (partial equilibrium) outcomes Top 1% desired consumption in short run, wealth in long run General equilibrium consequences depend on mon. policy response See Inequality and Aggregate Demand

Two canonical models of inequality 1. Income inequality literature: Considers random growth income processes Gets Pareto tail of the income distribution 2. Incomplete markets literature: Considers variety of income processes (typically lognormal) Gets predictions for aggregate consumption, savings and wealth This paper: combines 1 and 2 to examine macro consequences of an increase in top 1% of labor incomes, leaving average income cst Focus on aggregate demand (partial equilibrium) outcomes Top 1% desired consumption in short run, wealth in long run General equilibrium consequences depend on mon. policy response See Inequality and Aggregate Demand Case study: US labor income inequality, 1980 today

Simple random growth income process Suppose process for gross labor income z it follows d log z it = µdt + σdz it with Z it standard Brownian motion and reflecting barrier at z it = z stationary distribution is Pareto with tail coefficient P (z i z) z α α = 2µ σ 2 Parsimonious, explains incomes within top 1% well

Top 1% labor income shares in US (wages and salaries) α = 1 1 log(top 1% share) log(1%) Share of total labor income 12 10 8 6 4 2 Top 1% share Top 0.1% share 0 1980 1990 2000 2010 Year Source: World Top Incomes Database

Top 1% labor income shares in US (wages and salaries) α = 1 1 log(top 1% share) log(1%) { α 1980 = 2.47 Share of total labor income 12 10 8 6 4 2 Top 1% share Top 0.1% share 0 1980 1990 2000 2010 Year Source: World Top Incomes Database

Top 1% labor income shares in US (wages and salaries) α = 1 1 log(top 1% share) log(1%) { α 1980 = 2.47 α today = 1.91 Share of total labor income 12 10 8 6 4 2 Top 1% share Top 0.1% share 0 1980 1990 2000 2010 Year Source: World Top Incomes Database

Parameterizing the model Estimates of income risk: σ 2 [0.01, 0.04], possibly rising over time Set σ1980 2 = 0.02 Then µ 1980 = 0.024 matches α 1980 Consider three explanations for fall in α: α = 2µ σ 2, 2µ σ 2, 2µ σ 2 ie ( α1980 ) k k = 0, 1, 2 σtoday 2 = σ2 1980 α today Our benchmark is k = 2 Transitions between income percentiles unchanged, but levels spread Interpretation: secular trend in relative skill prices Transition can be infinitely fast: Gabaix, Lasry, Lions and Moll (2016)

Model: households Mass 1 of ex-ante identical households. Purely idiosyncratic risk: pre-tax income zit, discretized version of above process stationary (Pareto) distribution of income states, E [z] = 1 Separable preferences, constant EIS ν: u (c) = c1 ν 1 1 ν 1 Incomplete markets: trade in risk-free asset a it with return r t [ ] max E β t u (c it ) s.t. t=0 c it + a it = y it + (1 + r t 1 ) a it 1 a it 0 Post-tax income: affine transformation of pre-tax y it = τ r + (1 τ r ) z it

Model calibration and experiment Calibration to 1980 steady-state: σ 1980 = 2%, µ 1980 = 2.4% τ r = 17.5% consistent with progressivity of US tax system β = 0.95 generates wealth/post-tax income ratio W1980 when r = 4% Our quantitative experiment: Achieve α through k = 0, 1, 2; leaving E [z] = E [y] = 1 Phased in between 1980 and today Maintain r = 4% constant Trace out impact on consumption path dct and ss wealth dw W

Why this matters In Auclert-Rognlie Inequality and Aggregate Demand, we embed above framework in general equilibrium: Neoclassical GE same as Aiyagari (1994) full employment at all times With downward nominal wage rigidities and binding zero lower bound can have depressed employment temporarily or permanently ( secular stagnation )

Why this matters In Auclert-Rognlie Inequality and Aggregate Demand, we embed above framework in general equilibrium: Neoclassical GE same as Aiyagari (1994) full employment at all times With downward nominal wage rigidities and binding zero lower bound can have depressed employment temporarily or permanently ( secular stagnation ) Key result: dc t and dw W sufficient statistics for effects on macro aggregates of changes in income inequality real interest rates, consumption, employment, and output, e.g. Output effect = (GE multiplier) (PE sufficient statistic)

Partial eqbm path for aggregate wealth dw t /W 1.8 1.6 k = 0 k = 1 k = 2 dwt/w 1.4 1.2 1 2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 Year Recall k = 0 has constant σ and lower µ not just a precautionary savings effect

Decomposing steady-state dw /W When k = 2 dw W = 1.98 = Cov (ɛ W,y, dy) where ɛ Wy is effect of only increasing income level y Income change, relative to mean 3 dy 2 1 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Income percentile ɛ W,y 40 20 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 20 Income percentile Sensitivity ɛw, y

Decomposing impact effect dc When change in distribution is temporary dc = 1.8% = Cov (MPC y, dy) where dc is effect, MPC is average for income y at t = 0 Income change, relative to mean 3 dy 2 1 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Income percentile MPC y 0.4 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 0 Income percentile MPC

Conclusion Rise in top 1% may have depressed aggregate demand: Lower aggregate consumption via MPC channel (likely small effect) Raise aggregate savings via precautionary savings + wealth effect channels (possibly very large) Macroeconomic consequences depend on monetary policy: Away from the ZLB, lowers equilibrium interest rate In our experiments dr = 45bp to 85bp

Predicted path for equilibrium interest rates 4.2 4 k = 0 k = 1 k = 2 3.8 rt 3.6 3.4 3.2 2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 Year

Conclusion Rise in top 1% may have depressed aggregate demand: Lower aggregate consumption via MPC channel (likely small effect) Raise aggregate savings via precautionary savings + wealth effect channels (possibly very large) Macroeconomic consequences depend on monetary policy: Away from the ZLB, lowers equilibrium interest rate In our experiments dr = 45bp to 85bp One factor contributing to bringing economy to ZLB, may persist At the ZLB, generates unemployment Model implies permanent depression (secular stagnation) Mitigated by expansionary fiscal policy see Auclert-Rognlie