POSITION. ECPA Position on Taxes on Crop Protection Products. Brussels October 16, 2000 D/00/HA/6008

Similar documents
THE OECD S REPORT ON HARMFUL TAX COMPETITION JOANN M. WEINER * & HUGH J. AULT **

REPORT On the public consultation on new initiative regarding dismantling of ships

Licensing Team (Consultations), Babergh District Council, Corks Lane, Hadleigh, IPSWICH, Suffolk, IP7 6SJ 16th October 2015

The Agri-taxation Review Teagasc Farm Business Conference 26 November Seán Bell, FCCA

Introduction 1-2. Key point summary 3 7. General comments Detailed comments 18-31

2 WORKPLACE AND CO-WORKERS Mutual Respect, Honesty and Integrity Conflicts of Interest Data Protection 4

THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY AFTER RISK MANAGEMENT TOOLS -

Table of Contents. A RZB Group Code of Conduct

Tax harmonisation versus tax competition in Europe

We have seen and generally support the comments made by Law Society of England and Wales in its response (the Law Society Response).

Marks and Spencer Pension Scheme - Responsible Ownership Policy Statement GENERAL APPROACH Marks & Spencer Pension Scheme ( M&S PS ) believes that

2. Constitutional principles or rules with influence on the legislative procedure regarding non-fiscal purposed tax rules

EFAMA s comments on ESMA s Consultation Paper Guidelines on certain aspects of the MiFID II suitability requirements [ESMA ]

Taxation, Innovation and the Environment:

CONFERENCE ON ENVIRONMENTAL FISCAL REFORM

EFAMA CONFERENCE ON GREEN PAPER ON PENSIONS 4 OCTOBER 2010 PHILIPPE DE BUCK, DIRECTOR GENERAL

Speech at the International tax symposium "Dynamics of International Tax Competition: Opportunity or Threat?"

BUSINESSEUROPE PRIORITIES FOR THE FUTURE OF THE SINGLE MARKET

FAO Ms Jenny Frost Advice and Distribution Financial Conduct Authority 25 The North Colonnade Canary Wharf London E14 5HS. 3 rd November 2015

Official Journal of the European Union. (Non-legislative acts) REGULATIONS

HAZARD MANAGEMENT POLICY Page 1 of 7 Reviewed: October 2018

Alternative Investment Management Association

GREENING TAXATION. Approaches to Agriculture. Andrew Kelly. 24 th April TFIAM/TFRN

IRSG Opinion on Potential Harmonisation of Recovery and Resolution Frameworks for Insurers

CONFLICTS OF INTERESTS OF CIS OPERATORS

BANK DEBT - CONTINGENT CAPITAL AND BAIL-IN

The CAP after Round tables on the green architecture of the CAP. #FutureofCAP. Brussels, 12 November 2018

Recommendation of the Council on Good Practices for Public Environmental Expenditure Management

Models for Management of Banks' Credit Risk

SUBMISSION IN RESPONSE TO AGRICULTURAL AND VETERINARY CHEMICALS LEGISLATION AMENDMENT BILL 2012 SECOND EXPOSURE DRAFT

SOUTH CAMBRIDGESHIRE DISTRICT COUNCIL HOUSING REVENUE ACCOUNT (HRA) REFORM CONSULTATION

AmCham EU s position on the Commission Anti-Tax Avoidance Package

FSA Consultation Paper 176. Bundling and Softing. Response from The UK Society of Investment Professionals

Food Drink Ireland Budget 2018 Submission

We have a number of issues with regard to the jurisdictional application of the EU Merger Regulation to real estate transactions.

Common Corporate Tax Base (CCTB) and Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB)

EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 12 December 2013 (OR. en) 2011/0280 (COD) PE-CONS 95/13 AGRI 637 AGRIFIN 154 CODEC 2209

ECONOMIC SURVEY OF NEW ZEALAND 2007: TWO BROAD APPROACHES FOR TAX REFORM

HMRC Consultation: Large Business compliance enhancing our risk assessment approach Response by the Chartered Institute of Taxation

POLICY BRIEFING The Private Finance Initiative: Treasury Select Committee report

EU VAT Forum. Consolidated report on Cooperation between Member States and Businesses in the field of e-commerce/modern commerce

Markets in Financial Instruments Directive (MiFID): Frequently Asked Questions

EFAMA s comments on the European Commission s proposal for a Regulation on a pan-european personal pension product (PEPP)

DESIGNING GOOD TAX POLICY: A PRIMER

TO SOCIAL PROTECTION FOR PEOPLE IN ALL FORMS OF EMPLOYMENT IN THE FRAMEWORK OF THE EUROPEAN PILLAR OF SOCIAL RIGHTS

Statistics: Public consultation - Excise duties applied to manufactured tobacco

EUROPE S RURAL FUTURES

Subsidies in the fiscal system would be considerably understated if one

Competition for R&D tax incentives in the European Union how an optimal R&D system shall be designed

European Commission Green Paper on the Future of VAT Towards a simpler, more robust and efficient VAT system

FTT Non-technical answers to some questions on core features and potential effects

Engagement between external auditors and supervisors and commencing the PRA s disciplinary powers over external auditors and actuaries

FAQ - Environmental Pollution Tax Law in Viet Nam -

Chapter 12 The recommendations of the Commission

KEY ELEMENTS OF THE AGREEMENT ON CAP REFORM nd July 2013

The Danish Experience With A Financial Activities Tax

Financial Ombudsman Service s consultation transparency and the Financial Ombudsman Service publishing ombudsman decisions: next steps

Discussion draft on Action 6 (Prevent Treaty Abuse) of the BEPS Action Plan

Alternative Investment Management Association

Regulatory Implications under BREXIT

Ontario s Fiscal Competitiveness in 2004

IFA Submission to Government on Reform of PRSI, Levies and Income Tax System

1. Executive summary Ownership of land is not a very reliable proxy for wealth at a level that should be visited with a wealth tax.

P1 Performance Operations

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES

ACI EUROPE POSITION on AVIATION TAXES IN THE EU Putting the economic recovery at risk

Inducements under MiFID

COMMITTEE OF EUROPEAN SECURITIES REGULATORS

Deficit Financing. Two Aspects of Deficit Financing Deficit financing as an income generating expenditure has two aspects:

The comments in this response reflect the global nature of ISDA and its members.

Special feature: Current issues on reporting tax revenues

INCENTIVISING HOUSEHOLD ACTION ON FLOODING AND OPTIONS FOR USING INCENTIVES TO INCREASE THE TAKE UP OF FLOOD RESILIENCE AND RESISTANCE MEASURES

General Comments. Action 6 on Treaty Abuse reads as follows:

Towards a post-2020 CAP that supports farmers and delivers public goods to Europeans Avoiding a race to the bottom - An ambitious and better targeted

4 Bank failing or likely to fail

EUROPEAN COMMISSION Background and objectives of the notified project

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 6 July 2012 (OR. en) 11273/12 UEM 224 ECOFIN 598 SOC 575 COMPET 443 ENV 539 EDUC 216 RECH 279 ENER 308

Assessing the financial efficiency of the Green Climate Fund: leverage ratios - from theory to practice

A Scottish approach to taxation: call for evidence by the Scottish Parliament, Finance Committee

Comments on behalf of The Association of Corporate Treasurers on: Discussion Paper 05/5: Trading transparency in the Secondary bond markets

TYRES AND WASTE TYRES Questions and Answers September 2017

FOOD SAFETY RISK ANALYSIS

A. Introduction. client.

A New European Regime for Venture Capital

FSB options: A new approach to simplifying taxation for smaller businesses December 2015

Proposal for a regulation on the establishment of a framework to facilitate sustainable investment Contact person:

Monetary policy in Sweden

MID-TERM REVIEW OF EU GSP REGULATION FERM COMMENTS FEBRUARY 2017

Standard contractual clauses for the transfer of personal data to third countries - Frequently asked questions

Decommissioning Basis of Estimate Template

Severn Estuary Flood Risk Management Strategy. Report on 2013 Consultation

INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT

Policy Statement PS28/17 PRA fees and levies: model transaction fees, fees and FSCS levies for insurers and fees for designated investment firms

WSBI-ESBG Position Regarding the Implementation of Automatic Exchange of Information within the EU and Globally

FAQs Selection criteria

Excerpt from White paper on the requirements of the GDPR to business activities of debt collection agencies

o by banning the production, use, or trade of certain persistent organic pollutants:

RISK MANAGEMENT POLICY

FESE views on the Review of the Prudential Framework for Investment Firms

September 2014 Pagham Neighbourhood Plan

Transcription:

POSITION Brussels October 16, 2000 D/00/HA/6008 ECPA Position on Taxes on Crop Protection Products ECPA 6, Avenue E. Van Nieuwenhuyse. 1160 Brussels. Belgium Tel: +32 2 663 15 50. Fax: +32 2 663 15 60. VAT: BE 447.618.871

- 1 - ECPA Position on Taxes on Crop Protection Products Summary Crop Protection Products (CPPs) are thoroughly tested and evaluated by Government Authorities for possible adverse effects, including those to the environment, before marketing is permitted. This authorization process ensures that the use of CPPs does not pose any undue risk, when they are used as recommended. There is little doubt that the imposition of a tax on CPPs would further reduce risk to the environment. Taxes are not an effective way of achieving this. However, the introduction of a tax would have serious consequences for agricultural production and farmers income. ECPA believes that the ultimate stage of risk reduction, ie use reduction, should not be considered a target of environmental policy per se, since CPPs have passed a rigorous registration process and their potential environmental impact has thus been assessed acceptable when used as recommended. Environmental objectives should be more specific and, in this respect, existing industry policies and voluntary measures are more effective than a general tax on CPPs. Not only do they address concerns over the risk of CPPs, but they can also achieve further improvements in the environment in a sustainable way. Efficient risk reduction that effectively lower adverse environmental impact has come through product innovation, improved application technology, farmer-training, general improvement in user education and adoption of integrated crop management (ICM) systems. These methods examine and control adverse environmental impacts. ECPA recognises the great value of voluntary measures, which address the environmental concerns associated with the use of CPPs in agriculture and believes that these approaches and not taxation is the best way to reach an environmental objective.

- 2 - ECPA Position on Taxes on Crop Protection Products 1. The concept of taxation of Crop Protection Products The concept of green taxes on Crop Protection Products (CPPs) is being considered in many countries of the European Union. Although advocated for environmental reasons the use of taxation is usually politically driven. Environmental taxes and charges are seen as an appropriate way of implementing the polluter pays principle, by including the perceived environmental cost in the price of the goods. Some consider that the use of such instruments can induce consumers and producers into environmentally more sustainable behaviour. This theory presumes that taxes have a direct effect on the market and that revenues from environmental taxes will be used to finance environmental protection activities. Whenever environmental taxes are introduced there should be a sound justification provided on the exact nature of the perceived environmental problem. The purpose of the tax must be clear and there must be certainty that the tax will deliver the benefits claimed. The mandatory registration process for CPPs ensures that the use of CPPs does not lead to any undue risk, when they are used as recommended. Despite the theoretical arguments in favour of environmental taxes, experience in several European countries has shown that taxes are not an effective way to further reduce any remaining environmental impact (which has been assessed as not being unacceptable during the regulatory process). Efficient risk reduction with real effects on lowering adverse environmental impacts from the use of CPPs have come through product innovation, improved application technology, farmer-training, general improvement in user education and adoption of integrated crop management (ICM) systems. These methods examine and control environmental effects. In contrast, taxes are relatively blunt in their effect and may not have the desired results at lowering the environmental impact of CPPs. 2. Effects of implementation of taxes One of the purposes of environmental taxes is to successfully achieve a beneficial environmental objective. The ECPA believes that such a tax would not deliver any gains in terms of changing user behaviour and/or beneficial environmental effects. On the contrary, a tax would have serious consequences for agricultural production and farmers income. 2.1 Environmental benefits It is claimed that the ultimate measure of risk reduction, i.e. use reduction, would have direct benefit with respect to environmental impact and that taxes would aid this process. However, due to the high efficiency of CPPs, their use is unlikely to be significantly reduced by price increases, which would result from taxation. Their optimal use is not only determined by the price but is based on their impact upon yield and product quality. Therefore price increases would not necessarily cause a significant use reduction. Only a very high tax level would cause farmers to reduce their usage. The use is to a large extent determined by need and not cost. Also, bearing in mind that CPPs have passed a rigorous registration process and their

- 3 - potential environmental impact has thus been assessed acceptable, ECPA believes that use reduction per se should not be considered a target of environmental policy. Instead, ECPA suggest to focus on more specific issues such as risks arising from misuse and incorrect application, the protection of environmentally sensitive areas, and the universal application of Good Agricultural Practice. All of these objectives cannot, of course, be achieved by a general tax on CPPs. 2.2 Farmers income losses A tax would have a significant impact on the competitiveness and profitability of the farming sector and therefore reduce sustainability. Farmers will suffer losses in terms of reduced production and income. The loss of production could amount to 20% to 50% depending on the level of the tax and the type of crop. Small farmers would be disproportionately harmed and might turn to older, cheaper and sometimes less environmentally friendly products or practices. The distributional impact of a tax is likely to be inequitable. The economic burden of the tax will fall on arable and horticultural farmers so that certain crops of regional importance and food processing sectors will be particularly affected. A tax would have a significant impact on the economy as a whole. For example, a Danish study (The Bichel Committee, 1999) showed that the consequences of a total or partial phase-out of CPP use would not only have drastic consequences for Danish agriculture but also for the Danish economy as a whole. Innovation and investment by farmers would be slowed. Agricultural processing industries would also suffer due to increased costs of raw materials. Food imports may increase, thus affecting the balance of payments. It is estimated that in Denmark the consequences of a total phase-out of CPP use would cause a decrease of the GDP by 0.8%. Employment throughout the food chain would drop by approximately 16,000 workers. 2.3 Effectiveness of Taxes on CPPs The design of a tax on CPPs, which takes into account the risk, the active ingredient used and environmental effects, is complex to implement and is likely to create many undesired negative side-effects. A tax would not be an effective solution in terms of cost-effectiveness. If considered politically desirable it is not easy to determine the optimum rate of a tax. Ideally, the total tax revenue should be equivalent to the marginal external cost of the CPPs. If set at this rate the marginal social cost will match the marginal social benefits. Since the environmental effects of CPPs cannot always be calculated a tax would be subjective and politically biased. A tax based solely on the value of the individual CPP is unlikely to be effective. It would be counter-productive since it would counteract the efforts of the Crop Protection industry to innovate towards more environmentally-friendly CPPs. In addition, it would increase the possibility that farmers turn to older, cheaper and less environmentally-friendly CPPs thereby undermining the environmental benefits of the tax. The tax could only be effective if it aims to differentiate between the CPPs involved on the basis of their potential negative effects to the environment. However, such a complex classification would need a ranking on the environmental impact of CPPs. It also implies that suitable alternative products are available to which users can switch. In practice, such a banding system would inevitably result in perverse effects such as the increased use of products that are considered more environmentally unfriendly.

- 4 - A large part of the revenues of a tax could be absorbed by the cost of administration, implementation, compliance and enforcement. In some regimes the Government may increase the administrative burden on industry by using it to collect and pass on the revenues of the tax. Fraud practices and illegal importation of CPPs are likely to result. Setting a uniform tax across the European Union could possibly counteract this. However, this course of action would have enormous problems. Currently, even VAT is levied at different levels for the same products throughout the EU15. Revenues derived from the tax should be ring-fenced and remain in the agricultural sector to further stimulate farmers to follow good agricultural practice and adopt environmentally beneficial measures. However, experience in different member states shows that revenues of taxes often go directly to the Treasury. 3. Alternative instruments The ECPA is of the opinion that environmental objectives can be reached in a more costeffective way than via taxation or levies. Existing industry policies and voluntary measures undertaken by the industry are more effective and efficient than a tax to address environmental concerns. A continuing goal of the industry is to minimise the risks associated with the use of CPPs. In response to environmental concerns, the industry has developed new and better products with improved environmental profiles, which are used at much lower dose rates but higher levels of specific targeted effectiveness. In addition, the extremely thorough approval procedures by regulatory authorities in the EU include risk assessments and safeguard the environmentally sound use of CPPs. As a consequence, the number of active ingredients on the internal market has decreased drastically with many more hazardous products being removed from the market. Numerous epidemiological studies confirm that CPPs cause no significant harm to the general population when used correctly. A tax would be in contradiction to the existing approval system, which is effective and ensures no adverse effects on health and the environment. Initiatives from the Crop Protection industry include the use of integrated control methods or Integrated Farm Management (IFM), which are broadly recognised as environmentally-friendly practices, as well as stewardship activities. These, further demonstrate the commitment of the industry to a responsible approach. The industry has been a prime mover in the production of Codes of Good Practice for users, programmes of research and development after the launch of products onto the market, the promotion of Integrated Crop Management (ICM) and the provision of reliable local agronomic advice. The ECPA believes that ICM and IFM are the cornerstones for sustainable agriculture. Additional voluntary measures undertaken by the crop protection and farming industries, like mandatory training of sprayer operators, licences for users, safe waste disposal of containers and an annual inspection of sprayers are used to further minimise the perceived environmental impact of CPPs. Although much has already been achieved on a voluntary basis, the industry remains committed to doing more. Improved application technologies allow for improving the effectiveness of treatment against weed, insects and diseases and allow substantial reductions of CPPs usage.

- 5 - It is widely recognised that further technological developments will have a significant influence on the long-term pattern of product usage. The use of information technology in decision support systems and precision agriculture helps end-users to apply the products in an optimal way and also supports the implementation of ICM practices. First experiences with decision support systems for crop protection are currently in Denmark. There are other efficient alternatives and additional policy measures, which could provide the required level of protection in environmentally sensitive areas. For example, site specific measures for the preservation of habitats and high nature value landscapes instead of the broad approach of taxation would be more effective. Farmers could be compensated for specific and additional environmental initiatives, going beyond the basic level of good agricultural practices and adhering to environmental law through agri-environment programs. 4. Conclusion There is little doubt that the imposition of a tax on CPPs would have very few beneficial environmental effects. If policy objectives focus on long-term environmental perspectives, the objective may not just be to reduce risk from CPP usage itself, but to encourage environmentally sound practices. The ECPA concludes that existing industry policy, in particular the adoption of ICM/IFM and other voluntary measures already undertaken by the industry, are the most effective means of achieving further sustainable improvements in the environment. The ECPA sees great benefits in the voluntary approach that addresses the environmental concerns of the public and politicians.