The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Similar documents
The Historical Evolution of the Wealth Distribution: A Quantitative-Theoretic Investigation

A Comprehensive Quantitative Theory of the U.S. Wealth Distribution

Online Appendix to The Dynamics of Inequality Xavier Gabaix, Jean-Michel Lasry, Pierre-Louis Lions, Benjamin Moll August 4, 2016

Distribution of Wealth: Mechanisms

Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S.

Aggregate Demand and the Top 1% AEA Meetings, Chicago January 7, 2017

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman

Earnings Inequality and Other Determinants of. Wealth Inequality

Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Wealth Returns Dynamics and Heterogeneity

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WEALTH DISTRIBUTION AND SOCIAL MOBILITY IN THE US: A QUANTITATIVE APPROACH. Jess Benhabib Alberto Bisin Mi Luo

Earnings Inequality and Other Determinants of Wealth Inequality

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

USE IT OR LOSE IT: EFFICIENCY GAINS FROM WEALTH TAXATION

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

Macroeconomic Implications of Tax Cuts for the Top Income Groups:

Wealth distribution and social mobility: A quantitative analysis of U.S. data

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Distribution of Wealth: Mechanisms

Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. Inequality between labor and capital. Gabriel Zucman

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach

Determinants of Wage and Earnings Inequality in the United States

Cahier de recherche/working Paper Inequality and Debt in a Model with Heterogeneous Agents. Federico Ravenna Nicolas Vincent.

Accounting for the determinants of wealth concentration in the US

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Income and Wealth Inequality in America,

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Rich Entrepreneurs and Wealth Inequality

Heterogeneity and Persistence in Returns to Wealth

Wealth Distribution. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. Econ821. February 9, / 25

Working paper series. Wealth distribution and social mobility in the US: A quantitative approach. Jess Benhabib Alberto Bisin Mi Luo.

The Research Agenda: The Evolution of Factor Shares

The role of credit on wealth inequality in the USA:

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

The macroeconomic and distributional effects of progressive wealth taxes

Homework #4. Due back: Beginning of class, Friday 5pm, December 11, 2009.

Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Lecture 4: From capital/income ratios to capital shares

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle?

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Cologne, December 5 th 2013

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives

Accounting for Wealth Inequality Dynamics: Methods, Estimates and Simulations for France ( )

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Fiscal Policy and MPC Heterogeneity

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE IMPLICATIONS OF RICHER EARNINGS DYNAMICS FOR CONSUMPTION AND WEALTH

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Visby, June

Inequality in 3-D: Income, Consumption, and Wealth

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PARETO AND PIKETTY: THE MACROECONOMICS OF TOP INCOME AND WEALTH INEQUALITY. Charles I. Jones

Income and Wealth Inequality in America,

Entrepreneurs, Managers and Inequality

USE IT OR LOSE IT: EFFICIENCY GAINS FROM WEALTH TAXATION

Measuring Income and Wealth at the Top Using Administrative and Survey Data

Inequality and Aggregate Demand. November 2017

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Age, Luck, and Inheritance

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

Balance Sheet Recessions

Wealth Distribution and Taxation. Frank Cowell: MSc Public Economics 2011/2

Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks

Household Debt and Income Inequality,

Since the early 2000s, research by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez (and

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

The Idea. Friedman (1957): Permanent Income Hypothesis. Use the Benchmark KS model with Modifications. Income Process. Progress since then

Precautionary Savings or Working Longer Hours?

The Job Ladder and its Implications for Earnings Risk

LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE 2017 CORPORATE TAX CUTS. Jorge Barro, Ph.D. Fellow in Public Finance

Pareto Distribution of Income in Neoclassical Growth Models

CONSUMPTION, SAVINGS, AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF PERMANENT INCOME *

Devaluation Risk and the Business Cycle Implications of Exchange Rate Management

Human Capitalists. Abstract

Welfare Evaluations of Policy Reforms with Heterogeneous Agents

Do credit shocks matter for aggregate consumption?

CONSUMPTION, SAVINGS, AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF PERMANENT INCOME *

Understanding the U.S. Distribution of Wealth

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

HARD VS. SOFT FINANCIAL CONSTRAINTS IMPLICATIONS FOR THE EFFECTS OF A CREDIT CRUNCH

Lecture 5. Key Facts on Income and Wealth Distribution. ECO 521: Advanced Macroeconomics I. Benjamin Moll. Princeton University, Fall

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings

Inequality and growth Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics

Optimal Income tax rates with non-democratic political constraints: case of Armenia

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings FESAMES 2009

A Statistical Model of Inequality

The Distribution of Wealth and the Marginal Propensity to Consume

Personal Bankruptcy Law and Entrepreneurship A Quantitative Assessment

Long Term Rates, Capital Shares, and Income Inequality

Capital in the 21 st century

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

Transcription:

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation Joachim Hubmer, Per Krusell, and Tony Smith Yale, IIES, and Yale March 2016

Evolution of top wealth inequality (Kopczuk 2015) Wealth Share in % 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 Capitalization, Top 1% Capitalization, Top 0.1% SCF, Top 1% SCF, Top 0.1% Estate tax multiplier, Top 1% Estate tax multiplier, Top 0.1% 15 10 5 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960

Overview: objective calibrate a quantitative macro model that accounts for the full US wealth distribution, including the Pareto tail study the transition path: starting in the 1960s, feeding in observed changes in earnings inequality and tax rates can the standard macro-inequality framework explain movements in the wealth distribution?

Overview: findings model is partially successful in explaining the evolution of the wealth distribution magnitude of increase in inequality explained for bulk of distribution misses speed of changes at the very top and short-run dynamics active channels: decreasing tax progressivity has a dramatic effect on the wealth distribution increase in idiosyncratic labor income risk has in general a dampening effect on wealth inequality via the precautionary savings channel (vanishes at the top) changes in r g not important, partly working in the opposite direction cautious prediction for 21st century: long-term effects of decreasing tax progressivity on wealth inequality

Trends in wealth inequality: recent literature Data: Saez and Zucman (2015); Kopczuk; Bricker, Henriques, Krimmel, and Sabelhaus (2016). Models of Pareto tails: Piketty and Zucman (2015); Benhabib, Bisin, and Luo (2015); Nirei and Aoki (2015). Models of transitions: Kaymak and Poschke (2016); Gabaix, Lasry, Lions, and Moll (2016).

Quantitative model Aiyagari 94 framework: log labor income as sum of persistent and transitory component; adjusted at the top to match the observed Pareto tail in labor income stochastic discount factor follows AR1 process (Krusell-Smith 98 extended) stochastic i.i.d. return on capital progressive taxation: use data on federal effective tax rates for 11 income brackets (Piketty & Saez 2007) parsimonious modeling of social safety net: 60% of tax revenues rebated as lump-sum transfers time-varying tax system and labor income process

The consumer s problem V t (x t, p t, β t ) = max a t+1 a {u(x t a t+1 ) + β t E [V t+1 (x t+1, p t+1, β t+1 ) p t, β t ]} subject to x t+1 =a t+1 + y t+1 τ t+1 (y t+1 ) + T t+1 (2) y t+1 =r t+1 η t+1 a t+1 + w t+1 l t+1 (p t+1, ν t+1 ) (3) (1) x t cash on hand p t persistent component of earnings process l t+1 (, ) efficiency units of labor, moves over time ν t+1 transitory earnings shock η t+1 return to capital shock τ t (y t ) tax function based on gross income, moves over time T t lump-sum transfer

Main qualitative mechanism stochastic-β alone generates a Pareto tail in the wealth distribution add stochastic return to capital and Pareto tail in labor income to improve quantitative properties of the model Pareto tail in labor income alone would be inherited by wealth distribution, but tail coefficient would be too high (top inequality inequality too low) follows from random growth theory (Kesten 1973, see also Gabaix 2009) mechanism has been employed by Benhabib, Bisin and Zhu (2011), Nirei & Aoki (2015), Piketty & Zucman (2015) main alternative calibration (Castañeda, Días-Giménez, Ríos-Rull 2003) cannot deliver this Pareto tail

Stochastic-β yields stochastic, linear savings decisions marginal propensity to save 1 0.95 0.9 0.85 high beta, high earnings high beta, low earnings low beta, high earnings low beta, low earnings 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 log(k)

Gives rise to a Pareto tail in the wealth distribution 0-2 -4-6 log-log plot of countercumulative distribution function log(1-f(k)) Top 10% Top 1% Top 0.1% Top 0.01% log(1-f(k)) -8-10 -12-14 -16-18 -5 0 5 10 15 log(k)

Calibration strategy earnings process, tax rates, social safety net calibrated to observables randomness in discount factor and return to capital calibrated to replicate the wealth distribution in the initial steady state (1960s) focus on tail coefficient alone misleading: even if say the richest 10% can be described exactly by a Pareto distribution, the shape parameter only tells us how wealth is distributed within these 10%, not how much wealth the top 10% control as a fraction of total wealth

Calibration: stochastic-β and r Stochastic-β: follows AR(1) process µ = 0.92, ρ = 0.992, σ = 0.0019 i.e in cross-section, standard deviation = 0.0148 i.e. over 50 years, mean reversion is 1/3 Stochastic Return to Capital: pre-tax return (1 + r t η t ) η t i.i.d N(1, 0.725) i.e. in steady state, standard deviation of 0.048 or 90% have return (1 + r η t ) [0.9874, 1.1437] Fagereng, Guiso, Malacrino & Pistaferri (2016) find a standard deviation of 0.04 in Norwegian data

Matching the wealth distribution US Wealth distribution in 1967: Top 10% Share Top 1% Top 0.1% Top 0.01% Data* 70.8% 27.8% 9.4% 3.1% Model 70.6% 28.1% 9.5% 2.9% fraction w negative wealth Bottom 50% share Data* 8.0% 4.0 % Model 7.0% 3.1 % (* Top wealth shares (capitalization): Saez & Zucman, 2014; bottom 50% share (SCF): Kennickell, 2012) model matches wealth distribution well on its entire domain

Observed change 1: decrease in tax progressivity federal effective tax rates (Piketty & Saez 2007): income, payroll, corporate and estate taxes 0.8 0.7 0.6 top rate 5 * average income 3 * average income average income 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

Observed change 2: increase in labor income risk estimates for variance of persistent and temporary components 1967-2000 (Heathcote, Storesletten & Violante 2010) 0.6 0.55 0.5 Cross-sectional Standard Deviations persistent component transitory component 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Observed change 3: increase in top labor income shares adjust standard AR1 in idiosyncratic productivity by imposing a Pareto tail for the top 10 % earners: calibrated tail coefficient decreases from 2.8 to 1.9 (Piketty & Saez, 2003 [updated series -2011]) 35 top 10% share 14 12 top 1% share 30 10 25 model data 8 6 top 0.1% share 5 4 3 2 1 top 0.01% share 2 1.5 1 0.5

Main result: evolution of top wealth shares 80 75 top 10% wealth share model data (SZ) data (SCF) 40 35 top 1% wealth share 70 30 65 25 top 0.1% wealth share 12 top 0.01% wealth share 20 10 15 8 6 10 4 2

Other statistics 6 5.5 capital - net output ratio model (capital) data (national wealth) data (private wealth) 4 3.5 bottom 50% share 5 3 4.5 2.5 4 2 3.5 1.5 model data (SCF) 3 1 captures dynamics of capital stock (but capital wealth) and share of wealth held by asset-poor

Summary of transitional dynamics model captures the salient features of the evolution of the US wealth distribution perfect foresight assumption does not seem to be critical ( myopic transition ) robust to CES production function with elasticity > 1 ( CES ) shortcomings: miss on short-run dynamics (heterogeneous portfolios and valuation effects?) explosion of wealth concentration at the very top (0.1 % and above) as measured by Saez & Zucman (2014) not explained well

Main channels what fraction of the increase in the top wealth shares do the three channels account for? Earnings Risk Top Earnings Taxes Combined Top 10 % -0.78 0.22 1.89 1.32 Top 1 % -0.19 0.05 0.82 0.65 larger earnings risk induces higher precautionary savings (vanishes for the rich), depressing the interest rate and thus increasing the Pareto tail coefficient (i.e. decreasing top wealth inequality) in general equilibrium, the average tax level does not matter much for wealth inequality, but changing progressivity has a large effect

Only Changes in Earnings Risk I top 10% wealth share top 1% wealth share 75 70 model data (SZ) data (SCF) 40 35 30 65 25 top 0.1% wealth share 12 top 0.01% wealth share 20 15 10 10 8 6 4 2

Only Changes in Earnings Risk II 6 capital - net output ratio 4 bottom 50% share 5.5 5 model (capital) data (national wealth) data (private wealth) 3.5 3 4.5 2.5 4 3.5 2 1.5 model data (SCF) 3 1

Only Changes in Top Earnings Shares I top 10% wealth share top 1% wealth share 75 70 model data (SZ) data (SCF) 40 35 30 65 25 top 0.1% wealth share 12 top 0.01% wealth share 20 15 10 10 8 6 4 2

Only Changes in Top Earnings Shares II 6 capital - net output ratio 4 bottom 50% share 5.5 5 model (capital) data (national wealth) data (private wealth) 3.5 3 4.5 2.5 4 2 model data (SCF) 3.5 1.5 3 1

Only Changes in Taxes I top 10% wealth share top 1% wealth share 80 75 70 model data (SZ) data (SCF) 40 35 30 65 25 top 0.1% wealth share 12 top 0.01% wealth share 20 15 10 10 8 6 4 2

Only Changes in Taxes II 6 capital - net output ratio 4 bottom 50% share 5.5 model (capital) data (national wealth) data (private wealth) 3.5 5 3 4.5 2.5 4 2 3.5 1.5 model data (SCF) 3 1

Capital in the 21st century? 85 top 10% wealth share 50 top 1% wealth share 80 75 45 40 35 70 65 model data (SZ) 30 25 1980 2000 2020 2040 2060 2080 2100 1980 2000 2020 2040 2060 2080 2100 top 0.1% wealth share 12 top 0.01% wealth share 20 10 15 8 6 10 4 2 1980 2000 2020 2040 2060 2080 2100 1980 2000 2020 2040 2060 2080 2100 long-run effects of decrease in tax progressivity

Other channels: what about r g? increase in r g decreases wealth inequality in the medium run (a few decades) Pareto tail coefficient decreases (i.e., top wealth inequality increases), but very slowly r-g graphs more important in short-run: low-asset agents savings decisions more elastic w.r.t. the interest rate random growth models generally feature slow transitions, it takes long to fill a thick long tail (see Gabaix, Lasry, Lions, and Moll [2015])

Conclusion: where next? speed of changes at the very top hard to match asset price movements and portfolio choice? why are portfolios heterogeneous? why are asset prices moving that much? (outside the scope of our model - What would Shiller say? )

Price-earnings ratio (Shiller) return

Perfect foresight vs myopic transition I return 80 78 top 10% wealth share perfect foresight myopic 38 36 top 1% wealth share 76 34 74 32 72 70 top 0.1% wealth share 13 12 11 10 30 28 top 0.01% wealth share 4 3.5 3

Perfect foresight vs myopic transition II return capital - net output ratio 3.5 bottom 50% share 4.2 4.1 4 3.9 perfect foresight myopic 3 2.5 2 3.8 3.7 1.5 1

CES with elasticity of substitution > 1 σ = 1.25 (Karabarbounis and Neiman, 2014) return 4.3 4.2 4.1 4 3.9 3.8 38 36 34 32 30 capital - net output ratio Cobb-Douglas CES sigma=1.25 top 1% wealth share 0.065 0.06 0.055 0.5 0.45 interest rate (pre-tax) Gini gross income 28 0.4

r g? return model increase in r g as temporary 50% - increase in interest rate partial equilibrium, holding wage and transfers constant

r g experiment return 10 pre-tax interest rate 29 top 1% wealth share 9 28 % 8 % 27 7 26 6 0 20 40 60 80 100 year Gini Coefficient for Wealth 0.82 0.81 0.8 0.79 0.78 0 20 40 60 80 100 year 25 0 20 40 60 80 100 year Gini Coefficient for Income 0.5 0.45 0.4 0.35 pre-tax income post-tax income 0.3 0 20 40 60 80 100 year