Potential Causes and Implications of the Rise in Long-Term Unemployment 1

Similar documents
PERSPECTIVES ON LABOR MARKETS AND MONETARY POLICY

2010 Annual Report The Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. The Rise in Long-Term Unemployment Potential Causes and Implications

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Unemployment after the Recession: A New Natural Rate? Murat Tasci and Saeed Zaman

KEY THINGS TO KNOW ABOUT UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE by Hannah Shaw and Chad Stone

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Comment. John Kennan, University of Wisconsin and NBER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Edinburgh Research Explorer

The Outlook for Employment and Unemployment

Yes, We Can Reduce the Unemployment Rate

Beveridge Curve Shifts across Countries since the Great Recession

Economic Brief. Does Money Still Matter for Monetary Policy?

The Labor Market in the Great Recession An Update to September 2011

ECONOMY IN THE LONG RUN. Chapter 6. Unemployment. October 23, Chapter 6: Unemployment. ECON204 (A01). Fall 2012

The Labor Market in the Great Recession

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Estimating Key Economic Variables: The Policy Implications

Should We Worry about Trade Imbalances?

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Unemployment CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

FRBSF Economic Letter

The Ins and Outs of European Unemployment

When will US Employment Recover from the Great Recession?

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

The Labor Force Participation Rate (LFPR): A Closer Look

Did Banking Reforms of the Early 1990s Fail? Lessons from Comparing Two Banking Crises

Wage Flexibility in Texas May Ease Impact of Tighter Monetary Policy

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF Economic Letter

Left Out of the Boom Economy: UI Recipients in the Late 1990s

Vol 2017, No. 9. Abstract

Analysis of Change. 1 Economically speaking, the natural rate of unemployment is a theoretical concept, rather than an agreed upon

Global Business Cycles

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Equal pay for breadwinners

CHAPTER 13. Duration of Spell (in months) Exit Rate

Measuring labor market slack building the right underlying data Peterson Institute Conference on Labor Market Slack September 24, 2014

Unemployment and Economic Recovery

The Economic Case for Unemployment Insurance and the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Wage Growth after the Great Recession Roberto Pinheiro and Meifeng Yang

INCREASING THE RATE OF CAPITAL FORMATION (Investment Policy Report)

FRBSF Economic Letter

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

On the Limits to Monetary Policy

Output and Unemployment

Equitable Growth. Extended Unemployment Insurance Remains Critical. Washington Center for

Research Brief 09/47

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF Economic Letter

Unemployment Insurance Primer: Understanding What s At Stake as Congress Reopens Stimulus Package Debate. Wayne Vroman January 2002

FRBSF Economic Letter

Many economists believe that the recent recession

by Rob Valletta and Leila Bengali - FRBSF Economic Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

Principles of Macroeconomics. Twelfth Edition. Chapter 13. The Labor Market in the Macroeconomy. Copyright 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

SENATE PROPOSAL TO ADD UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE BENEFITS IMPROVES EFFECTIVENESS OF STIMULUS BILL by Chad Stone, Sharon Parrott, and Martha Coven

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Economic Brief. How Might the Fed s Large-Scale Asset Purchases Lower Long-Term Interest Rates?

The Labor Force Participation Puzzle

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF Economic Letter

THE GREAT RECESSION: UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE AND STRUCTURAL ISSUES

POLICY BRIEF. Monetary Policy as a Jobs Guarantee. Joshua R. Hendrickson July 2018

Figure Sarver

Expansions (periods of. positive economic growth)

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

Economic Outlook and Monetary Policy

How Congress Can Support, Not Hinder, Labor Market Recovery

Ben S Bernanke: Recent developments in the labor market

Job Polarization and the Natural Rate of Unemployment in the United States

Assignment 2: Due day. This Friday. Send this answer sheet via . Subject: Assignment 2.

Long-Term Nonemployment and Job Displacement

ADDRESSING LONGSTANDING GAPS IN UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE COVERAGE By Chad Stone, Robert Greenstein, and Martha Coven

Deficits and Debt: Economic Effects and Other Issues

15 Unemployment CHAPTER 15 UNEMPLOYMENT 0

REPORT #02-04 O L A OFFICE OF THE LEGISLATIVE AUDITOR STATE OF MINNESOTA PROGRAM EVALUATION REPORT. Financing Unemployment Insurance

Testimony before the Equal Employment Opportunity Commission. Heather Boushey, Senior Economist, Center for American Progress Action Fund

Chapter 9: Unemployment and Inflation

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 7 - Labor markets: Introduction & the search model March. Sciences Po

Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program participation during the economic recovery of 2003 to 2007

3. The phase of the business cycle in which real GDP is at a minimum is called: A. the peak. B. a recession. C. the trough. D. the underside.

CRS Report for Congress

download instant at

A Rising Natural Rate of Unemployment: Transitory or Permanent?

Automatic Stabilizers

Equality in Job Loss:

Chapter 6 Classical Theory of. Unemployment

Discussion of paper: Quantifying the Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy from the Financial Crisis. By Robert E. Hall

CHAPTER 6: MONITORING CYCLES, JOBS, AND THE PRICE LEVEL

Statistical information can empower the jury in a wrongful termination case

Economic Brief. Welfare Analysis of Debit Card Interchange Fee Regulation

The Ins and Outs of European Unemployment

Happy Birthday!...but will the Fed spoil the party?

Weekly Economic Commentary

Economic Brief. A Citizen s Guide to Unconventional Monetary Policy

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

Unemployment and Inflation

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Transcription:

Economic Brief September 2011, EB11-09 Potential Causes and Implications of the Rise in Long-Term Unemployment 1 By Andreas Hornstein, Thomas A. Lubik, and Jessie Romero Long-term unemployment rose dramatically during the recent recession and remains elevated. A primary cause may be the fact that more workers with inherently low job finding rates have become unemployed. This would suggest that the natural rate of unemployment has increased, and that additional monetary stimulus may have only a limited effect on reducing unemployment. The recession of 2007 09 has had a major impact on labor markets in the United States. The unemployment rate peaked at.1 percent in October 2009 and has remained around 9 percent throughout the recovery. More striking is the long-term unemployment rate: nearly half of unemployed workers, 44 percent, have been unemployed for longer than 26 weeks. 2 The share of long-term unemployment has been more than 40 percent since the beginning of 20, peaking at nearly 46 percent in the second quarter of that year. Even during the recession of 1981 82, when the total unemployment rate reached.8 percent, the peak share of longterm unemployment was only 26 percent. Figure 1: Long-Term Unemployment 12 Unemployment Rate (Percent) 8 6 4 Unemployment Rate (left axis) Share of Long-Term Unemployment (right axis) 50 40 30 20 Share of Long-Term Unemployment (Percent) 2 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 20 Note: Data are through July of 2011. Shaded areas denote recessions. Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Haver Analytics, authors' calculations 0 EB11-09 - The Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Page 1

For most of the post World War II era, unemployment has been a relatively short-lived experience for the average worker. Between 1960 and 20, the average duration of unemployment was about 14 weeks. The duration always rose during recessions, but relatively quick upticks in hiring after recessions kept the long-term unemployment rate fairly low. Even during the two jobless recoveries that followed the 1990 91 and 2001 recessions, the peak shares of long-term unemployment were 21 percent and 23 percent, respectively. But the 2007 09 recession represents a marked departure from previous experience: the average duration has increased to 40 weeks, and the share of long-term unemployment remains high more than two years after the official end of the recession. 3 Never before in the postwar period have the unemployed been unemployed for so long. The Effects of Unemployment Insurance One possible explanation for the rise in long-term unemployment is the extension of unemployment insurance. Unemployment benefits typically expire after 26 weeks, with some variation across states. The duration and the level of benefits tend to increase in response to recessions. By January of 20, workers across the country were eligible to collect unemployment benefits for up to 99 weeks. In contrast, the maximum duration in any state in response to the 1981 82 recession was 55 weeks. 4 Unemployment insurance is extended in order to lessen the negative financial impact of unemployment on workers, but this also can affect their incentives to look for jobs and accept job offers. On one hand, a worker receiving unemployment benefits might become more willing to reject job offers in the hope of receiving a better offer in the future. Extension of benefits thus would lower the exit rate from unemployment and increase unemployment duration. On the other hand, some workers might become more likely to accept job offers. In order to qualify for unemployment insurance, a worker must be employed and then get laid off involuntarily. An unemployed worker who does not qualify now might become more willing to accept a job to become eligible for benefits in the future. Research generally shows that, on net, unemployment insurance increases unemployment duration. Studies of the current recession suggest that the extension might have lengthened the average unemployment spell by between two and six weeks. 5 This is significant, but given that the average duration increased by a total of 18 weeks, the extension of unemployment benefits cannot fully account for the dramatic rise in long-term unemployment. Inflows and Outflows The total number of unemployed workers can be thought of as being determined by two factors: the inflow of workers to unemployment (the entry rate) and the outflow of workers from unemployment (the exit rate). Workers flow into unemployment by separating from a job either involuntarily (by a layoff) or voluntarily (by quitting), or by re-entering the labor force to start looking for work. They exit unemployment by finding a job or by discontinuing their job searches and leaving the labor force. The unemployment rate rises whenever the entry rate exceeds the exit rate. Total unemployment depends on both the inflow and outflow rates, but average duration depends mainly on the exit rate. The lower the exit rate, the longer the average duration and the larger the share of workers who have been unemployed for a long time. During recessions, the increase in total unemployment is accompanied by a large increase in the average duration of unemployment, which suggests that a decline in exit rates is an important source of high unemployment. We recover the entry and exit rates for unemployed workers between 1960 and 20 using a model developed by Robert Shimer of the University of Chicago. 6 Shimer s model uses data on total unemployment and on workers who have been unemployed for fewer than five weeks. A simplifying assumption is that all workers are homogeneous, that is, they face the same exit rate. We find that while this model does predict the qualitative features of long-term unemployment in recessions, it does not match the magnitude observed in the actual data. The model predicts that the exit rate in a given month declines Page 2

to about 35 percent during recessions, and it also shows a steep decline to 20 percent during the 2007 09 recession. However, the model only predicts about one-third of workers who actually are unemployed for longer than 26 weeks during recessions. Duration Dependence in Unemployment Some characteristics that are relevant to the chances of an unemployed worker finding work might be quite persistent yet unobservable. These characteristics might be related to the unemployment experience itself. For example, consider two equal groups of unemployed workers. Initially, they share the same observable characteristics, except for the time that they have been unemployed. On average, workers who have been unemployed for a shorter time will be more likely to find work and exit unemployment. Put another way, the longer workers have been unemployed, the less likely it is that they will find jobs. This is called negative duration dependence. Shimer s model is inconsistent with negative duration dependence. It assumes that all workers face the same exit rate regardless of how long they have been unemployed. This might be why the model underpredicts the number of long-term unemployed workers. Previously, we used Shimer s data on workers who have been unemployed for fewer than five weeks to recover exit rates from unemployment. When we use data on workers who have been unemployed for fewer than 5 weeks, fewer than 15 weeks, and fewer than 27 weeks, we find that the exit rates predicted using these different segments decline monotonically as the unemployment duration increases. These predictions are consistent with negative duration dependence. There are two possible explanations for negative duration dependence. The first, true duration dependence, assumes that for every worker, the exit rate is a declining function of unemployment duration. The exit rate for the entire pool of unemployed workers declines with the length of time that the workers have been unemployed. True duration dependence could occur for several reasons, including loss of human capital, loss of attachment to people and networks that could help in finding a job, or employer discrimination against unemployed workers. It s also possible that if the average wage being offered declines the longer a worker is unemployed, while unemployment benefits remain constant, then the worker would become less likely to accept an offer. Figure 2: Duration Dependence in Exit Rates 0 Exit Probability within the Next Month (Percent) 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 Fewer than 5 weeks Fewer than 15 weeks Fewer than 27 weeks 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 20 Note: Figure depicts implied exit rates based on workers unemployed for fewer than 5, 15, and 27 weeks. Shaded areas denote recessions. Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Haver Analytics, authors calculations Page 3

The other explanation is that newly unemployed workers have inherently different exit rates some lower and some higher. Over time, the composition of the pool will shift to more workers with low exit rates, which means that the average exit rate for the entire pool also declines. This unobserved heterogeneity of unemployed workers could occur because some workers lose jobs in declining industries, and their skills don t transfer easily to other industries. Other workers might lose jobs for reasons idiosyncratic to their employers, but have skills that are valued by a wide range of employers. These workers will tend to find work quickly. Which explanation best matches the data? One of the authors of this article (Hornstein) has constructed a framework with two types of unemployed workers, those with a high exit rate and those with a low exit rate. This framework allows for two special cases. The first case involves only true duration dependence: all unemployed workers start out with a high exit rate, but at some point they make a random transition from having a high exit rate to having a low exit rate. In the second case, there is unobserved heterogeneity: workers are either short-term unemployed or long-term unemployed from the beginning, and they never change types. The two cases provide different accounts of changes in unemployment. In the first case, almost all of the movements in unemployment are due to exit rate fluctuations of the two types. The true duration mechanism itself changes in entry rates of short-term unemployed workers and transition rates from short-term to long-term unemployment has only a limited effect. In the second case, however, changes in the entry and exit rates of long-term unemployed workers, that is, changes due to unobserved heterogeneity, account for about two-thirds of the unemployment rate volatility. The unobserved heterogeneity approach is a better match for the unemployment duration distribution. Implications for Monetary Policy A simple view of the relationship between unemployment and inflation suggests that the choices for monetary policymakers are clear: unemployment is high and inflation is low, so monetary policy should be expansionary. But many modern macroeconomists argue that movements in real quantities affect inflation only to the extent that they depart from their natural level. The natural rate of unemployment is the hypothetical rate of unemployment attainable in the absence of any distortions, such as impediments to the free adjustment of nominal prices and wages. The difference between the actual and natural rates is the unemployment gap, which represents the degree of slack in the economy. If there is a large pool of unemployed workers to choose from if the unemployment gap is large and positive wages are unlikely to increase, which limits pricing pressures stemming from rising input costs. However, this argument is useful for monetary policymakers only insofar as they are able to discern the natural rate. There is much debate over the effect the recession of 2007 09 has had on the natural rate. 7 We argue that the prevalence of long-term unemployment is related to the decline in the exit rate from unemployment that occurs as unemployment duration increases. In addition, it seems that overall unemployment has increased because of the increased entry of workers with inherently low exit rates. After a long period of unemployment, affected workers may become effectively unemployable. If a large portion of long-term unemployed workers now finds it difficult to transition to employment, this suggests that the natural rate of unemployment may have increased, making the unemployment gap smaller than it appears. In this case, the level of unemployment may not be responsive to monetary stimulus, and inflationary pressures may be less constrained than it appears based on the unemployment numbers alone. Policy options that increase the ability of unemployed workers to find work and reduce the costs of generating and maintaining employment relationships thus may be more effective at reducing unemployment than additional monetary stimulus. Page 4

Andreas Hornstein is a vice president, Thomas A. Lubik is a senior economist and research advisor, and Jessie Romero is a writer in the Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Endnotes 1 This brief is based on the essay The Rise in Long-Term Unemployment: Potential Causes and Implications by Andreas Hornstein and Thomas A. Lubik. The essay was published in the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond s 20 Annual Report. 2 Long-term unemployment is defined as longer than 26 weeks because unemployment benefits typically last for about half a year. 3 The Bureau of Labor Statistics revised its data-collection method for unemployment duration in January 2011. Based on the previous method, the average unemployment duration would be about 37 weeks rather than 40 weeks. For more information, see http://www.bls.gov/cps/duration.htm. 4 Daniel Aaronson, Bhashkar Mazumder, and Shani Schechter, What is Behind the Rise in Long-Term Unemployment, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives, Second Quarter 20, vol. 34, no. 2, pp. 28-51. 5 See Aaronson et al. (20) and Michael Elsby, Bart Hobijn, and Ayșegül Șahin, The Labor Market in the Great Recession, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 20. 6 Robert Shimer, Reassessing the Ins and Outs of Unemployment, Mimeo, October 2007, University of Chicago. Available online at http://sites.google.com/site/robertshimer/research/ workingpapers. 7 See, for example, Narayana Kocherlakota, Inside the FOMC, Speech in Marquette, Michigan, August 17, 20, and Mary Daly, Bart Hobijn, and Rob Valletta, The Recent Evolution of the Natural Rate of Unemployment, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2011-05, January 2011. This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its entirety. Please credit the authors, source, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the italicized statement below. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. Page 5