Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Similar documents
Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Financial Heterogeneity and Monetary Union

Financial Heterogeneity and Monetary Union

Appendices For Online Publication

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

The Extensive Margin of Trade and Monetary Policy

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

Balance Sheet Recessions

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Reserve Requirements and Optimal Chinese Stabilization Policy 1

Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB

On the new Keynesian model

Default Risk and Aggregate Fluctuations in an Economy with Production Heterogeneity

Booms and Banking Crises

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

Risk-Adjusted Capital Allocation and Misallocation

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada

Extended DSGE Model of the Czech Economy

The CAPM Strikes Back? An Investment Model with Disasters

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Macroprudential Policy Implementation in a Heterogeneous Monetary Union

Credit Risk and the Macroeconomy

Credit Spreads and the Macroeconomy

Overborrowing, Financial Crises and Macro-prudential Policy. Macro Financial Modelling Meeting, Chicago May 2-3, 2013

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems?

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis

Have We Underestimated the Likelihood and Severity of Zero Lower Bound Events?

Resource Allocation within Firms and Financial Market Dislocation: Evidence from Diversified Conglomerates

Uninsured Unemployment Risk and Optimal Monetary Policy

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Taxes and the Fed: Theory and Evidence from Equities

Y t )+υ t. +φ ( Y t. Y t ) Y t. α ( r t. + ρ +θ π ( π t. + ρ

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk. June 2012

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern.

Delayed Capital Reallocation

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1.

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ariel Zetlin-Jones and Ali Shourideh

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation

The science of monetary policy

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates

A CONTAGIOUS MALADY? OPEN ECONOMY DIMENSIONS OF SECULAR STAGNATION

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

The Real Business Cycle Model

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns and Monetary Policy

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

Schäuble versus Tsipras: a New-Keynesian DSGE Model with Sovereign Default for the Eurozone Debt Crisis

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

International Debt Deleveraging

The Macroeconomics of Universal Health Insurance Vouchers

Credit Disruptions and the Spillover Effects between the Household and Business Sectors

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan

Unconventional Monetary Policy

Multinational Firms, Trade, and the Trade-Comovement Puzzle

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk

THE ZERO LOWER BOUND, THE DUAL MANDATE,

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

Optimality of Inflation and Nominal Output Targeting

On the Implications of Structural Transformation for Inflation and Monetary Policy (Work in Progress)

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Transcription:

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis S. Gilchrist 1 1 Boston University and NBER MFM Summer Camp June 12, 2016 DISCLAIMER: The views expressed are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of anyone else associated with the Federal Reserve System.

Cyclical Dynamics of Producer Prices and Inflation In particular, the absence of more substantial deflationary pressures during the "Great Recession" is difficult to square with the Phillips curve common to most macroeconomic models. Economic forces that dampen the response of inflation to adverse demand or financial shocks reflect Cyclical Dynamics of Producer Prices and Industrial Production Core producer prices* Industrial production* Percentage points Percentage points 5 0-5 -10 5 0-5 -10 Peak: Jan1980 Peak: Jul1981 Peak: Jul1990 Peak: Mar2001 Peak: Dec2007-15 -20 Peak: Jan1980 Peak: Jul1981 Peak: Jul1990 Peak: Mar2001 Peak: Dec2007-15 -20-25 -25-24 -16-8 0 8 16 24 Months to and from business cycle peaks * Deviations from a linear trend estimated over the 24 months preceding the specified recession. -30-24 -16-8 0 8 16 24 Months to and from business cycle peaks * Deviations from a linear trend estimated over the 24 months preceding the specified recession. -30 Our answer

MOTIVATION What accounts for the resilience of inflation in the face of significant and long-lasting economic slack? In particular, the absence of more substantial deflationary pressures during the Great Recession is difficult to square with the Phillips curve common to most macroeconomic models (including standard financial accelerator models). In a customer-markets model with financial frictions, firms have the incentive to raise prices to increase cash flow at the cost of future market share (Gottfries [1991]; Chevalier and Scharfstein [1996]).

DATA SOURCES GILCHRIST, SCHOENLE, SIM AND ZAKRAJSEK (2015) Monthly good-level price data underlying the PPI. (Nakamura & Steinsson [2008]; Goldberg & Hellerstein [2009]; Bhattarai & Schoenle [2010]) Match 584 PPI respondents to their income and balance sheet data from Compustat. Sample period: Jan2005 Dec2012

RELATIVE INFLATION Financially unconstrained vs constrained firms 3-month moving average Percent 4 2 0-2 Low liquidity firms High liquidity firms -4 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012-6 NOTE: Weighted average monthly inflation relative to industry (2-digit NAICS) inflation.

ACCUMULATED INDUSTRY-ADJUSTED PPI PPI INFLATION By By selected financial characteristics as inof 2006 Monthly Low liquidity firms High liquidity firms Index (Dec. 2007 = 100) 110 105 100 95 90 85 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 80 NOTE: NOTE: Relative Weighted to industry average (2-digit NAICS) monthly inflation. inflation relative to industry (2-digit NAICS) inflation.

PRICE ADJUSTMENT AND FIRM CHARACTERISTICS Multinomial logit specification: + Pr(p i,j,t+3 p i,j,t ) = 0 (base) Price change regression: = Λ(X jt ; β t ) log(p i,j,t+3 ) log(p i,j,t ) = βx j,t + ɛ i,j,t+3 X jt = liquidity ratio and other controls. Includes fixed time effects and 3-digit inflation. Estimated using four-quarter rolling window.

DIRECTIONAL PRICE CHANGE REGRESSIONS Explanatory Variables + LIQ j,t 1[CRISIS t = 1] -0.433-12 (0.107) (72) LIQ j,t 1[CRISIS t = 0] -0.143-44 (68) (50) log(s j,t /S j,t 12 ) -20-42 (25) (25) log(c j,t /C j,t 12 ) 17 20 (13) (11) [N/S] j,t -22-20 (21) (24) π IND(3m) t 1.182-0.127 (0.333) (0.170)

DIRECTIONAL PRICE CHANGE REGRESSIONS Coefficient on liquidity ratio (4-quarter rolling window estimates) Negative price changes Positive price changes Coefficient 0.4 Coefficient 0.4 Estimate +/- 2 S.E. 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1-0.2-0.4-0.1-0.6 2006 2008 2010 2012-0.2 2006 2008 2010 2012 Quantitative implication: a two std. dev. reduction in liquidity implies a 33% higher probability of a price increase. -0.8

INFLATION REGRESSIONS Explanatory Variables LIQ j,t 1[CRISIS t = 1] LIQ j,t 1[CRISIS t = 0] -29 (09) -12 (04) log(s j,t /S j,t 12 ) 04 (03) log(c j,t /C j,t 12 ) -02 (02) [N/S] j,t 01 (01) π IND(3m) t 0.134 (55)

INFLATION Marginal effect with respect to liquidity ratio Estimate +/- 2 S.E. Coefficient 4 2 0-2 -4-6 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012-8 Quantitative implication: A two std. dev. reduction in liquidity implies a 5% increase in annualized inflation.

Industry-level evidence (1973-2012 Examine sensitivity of 6-digit industry-level PPI inflation to changes in aggregate financial conditions. Regress industry-specific year-ahead inflation on Current and lagged inflation and industrial production. Current financial conditions excess bond premium (EBP) Coefficient on EBP varies across 4-digit industry groups. Is variation in industry-specific EBP coefficieent related to financial constraints across industries? Measure severity of financial constraints using size-age index.

Coefficients on EBP and commodity price inflation vary across 4-digit indu Inflation Response to EBP - Is variation in industry-specific EBP coefficients related to the likelihood across industries? - Use industry-specific size-age index to identify the likelihood of financia 12-month PPI inflation and commodity prices 4 12-month PPI inflation and financial conditions By industry-specific indicator of financial constraints Coefficient on EBP (4-digit NAICS) 2 0-2 -4-6 -8-10 -3.5-3.0-2.5-2.0-1.5-1.0-0.5 0.5 Median Size-Age Index (4-digit NAICS) p <.10 p >=.10 β ^ = 1.11 t = 4.88 R-sq = 0.29 Note: Smaller values of the size-age index indicate a smaller likelihood of financial constraints.

Output Response to the EBP Figure 7: Sensitivity of Industry-Level Output to Financial Conditions, 1973 2013 (By Industry-Specific Indicator of Financial Constraints) Coefficient on EBP 8 6 4 2 0-2 -4-6 -8-10 -12-3.5-3.0-2.5-2.0-1.5-1.0-0.5 0.5 Median Size-Age Index p <.10 p >=.10 β ^ = -1.88 t = -3.77 R-sq = 0.22 Note: No. of (4-digit NAICS) industries = 52. The figure shows the relationship between the median SA-index of financing constraints at the 4-digit NAICS level during the 1973 2013 period and the corresponding industry-specific estimates of the coefficient on the EBP; the dependent

GE MODEL Customer markets imply that firms trade off current profits for future market share. Financial market frictions imply that firms discount the future more when demand is low and therefore charge high markups. Embed this intuition into a GE model with nominal price rigidities.

Deep habits Ravn, Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe [2006] Demand for monopolistically competitive good: where c it = ( pit p t ) η s θ(1 η) i,t 1 c t s it = ρs i,t 1 + (1 ρ)c it Firms are forward looking set low price today to build future stock of customer base.

FINANCIAL FRICTIONS Firms make production decisions prior to realization of marginal cost. [ ] α hit y it = φ i ; 0 < α 1 a it If realized operating income is negative, firms must raise costly equity finance: ϕ (0, 1) = constant per-unit dilution costs of new equity Expected shadow value of internal funds: E a t [ξ it ] > 1

Optimal Pricing without Deep Habits Assume flexible prices and no customer markets. When α = 1, optimal pricing p i,t = η η 1 }{{} accounting markup Ea t [ξ it a it ] E a t [ξ it] } {{ } economic markup [ ] wt /p t A t }{{} real marginal cost Financial frictions E a t [ξ it a it ] E a t [ξ it] = 1 + Cov[ξ it a it ] 1

Optimal Pricing with Deep Habits Bring back customer markets (still flexible prices!) Growth-adjusted, compounded discount rate: s s+1 /s s ρ β t,s m s,s+1 1 ρ s t Optimal pricing p i,t = j=1 η E a t [ξ it a it ] η 1 E a t [ξ it] [ χ η 1 E t [ ρ + χ s t+j/s t+j 1 ρ 1 ρ [ ] wt /p t s=t+1 A t β t,s E a s[ξ i,s ] E a t [ξ i,t] ] m t+j 1,t+j ( p h,s w ) ] s/p h,s A s

Optimal Pricing with Deep Habits Bring back customer markets (still flexible prices!) Growth-adjusted, compounded discount rate: s s+1 /s s ρ β t,s m s,s+1 1 ρ s t Optimal pricing p i,t = j=1 η E a t [ξ it a it ] η 1 E a t [ξ it] [ χ η 1 E t [ ρ + χ s t+j/s t+j 1 ρ 1 ρ [ ] wt /p t s=t+1 A t β t,s E a s[ξ i,s ] E a t [ξ i,t] ] m t+j 1,t+j ( p h,s w ) ] s/p h,s A s

LOG-LINEARIZED PHILLIPS CURVE New Keynesian model with cost channel [ ω(η 1) ] ˆπ t = ˆµ t + E t χ δ s t+1 ˆµ s+1 + βe t [ˆπ t+1 ] γ p s=t + 1 [ ] [η ω(η 1)] E t χ δ s t+1 (ˆξ t γ ˆξ s+1 ) ˆβ t,s+1 p s=t ˆµ t = (financially-adjusted) mark-up ˆβ t,s+1 = capitalized growth of customer base ˆξ t = shadow value of internal funds

LOG-LINEARIZED PHILLIPS CURVE The role of deep habits [ ω(η 1) ] ˆπ t = ˆµ t + E t χ δ s t+1 ˆµ s+1 + βe t [ˆπ t+1 ] γ p s=t + 1 [ ] [η ω(η 1)] E t χ δ s t+1 (ˆξ t γ ˆξ s+1 ) ˆβ t,s+1 p s=t ˆµ t = (financially-adjusted) mark-up ˆβ t,s+1 = capitalized growth of customer base ˆξ t = shadow value of internal funds

LOG-LINEARIZED PHILLIPS CURVE The role of financial frictions [ ω(η 1) ] ˆπ t = ˆµ t + E t χ δ s t+1 ˆµ s+1 + βe t [ˆπ t+1 ] γ p s=t + 1 [ ] [η ω(η 1)] E t χ δ s t+1 (ˆξ t γ ˆξ s+1 ) ˆβ t,s+1 p s=t ˆµ t = (financially adjusted) mark-up ˆβ t,s+1 = capitalized growth of customer base ˆξ t = shadow value of internal funds

CALIBRATION Benchmark model: homogeneous firms Parameter Value Preferences and Technology Relative risk aversion: γ x 1.00 Deep habit: θ -0.80 Persistence of deep habit: ρ 0.95 Elasticity of labor supply: 1/γ h 5.00 Elasticity of substitution: η 2.00 Fixed operating costs: φ 0.21 Idiosyncratic volatility (a.r.): σ 0.20 Financial Frictions Equity dilution costs: ϕ 0.30 0.50 Persistence of financial shock: ρ ϕ 0.90

DEMAND SHOCK: FINANCIAL CRISIS(ϕ = 0.5) (a) Output w/o FF w/ FF % -0.5-1.0-1.5 (b) Hours worked % -0.5-1.0-1.5 (c) Inflation pps. 0.2 0.1-0.1-0.2-0.3 (d) Real wage % 0.2 0.1-0.1-0.2 (e) Markup pps. 0.4 (f) Value of internal funds pps. 2.0 (g) Value of marginal sales % 1.5 (h) Interest rate pps. 0.1 0.2 1.5 1.0 0.5 1.0 0.5-0.1-0.2-0.5-0.5-0.2

FINANCIAL SHOCK:(ϕ = 0.3) WITH VS WITHOUT CUSTOMER MARKETS (a) Output w/ deep habit w/o deep habit % -0.2-0.4 (b) Hours worked % -0.2-0.4 (c) Inflation pps. 1.5 1.0 0.5 (d) Real wage % 0.2-0.2-0.6-0.8-0.6-0.8-0.4-0.6 (e) Markup pps. 1.0 (f) Value of internal funds pps. 5 (g) Value of marginal sales % 5 (h) Interest rate pps. 0.8 4 4 0.6 0.6 3 3 0.4 0.4 0.2 2 1 0-1 2 1 0-1 0.2

Alternative monetary policy rules DEMAND SHOCK DURING A FINANCIAL CRISIS (a) Markup pps. τ y = 0 τ y = 0.125 τ y = 0.250 0.4 0.3 (b) Inflation pps. 0.6 0.5 0.4 (c) Output % 0.3-0.3 (d) Real interest rate pps. 0.2 0.2 0.3-0.6 0.1 0.2-0.9-0.2 0.1-1.2-1.5-0.4-0.1-0.1-1.8 Policy Implications: Divine Coincidence breaks down!

HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS Sectors differ by operating efficiency: 0 φ 1 < φ 2 Fixed measures of firms: Ξ 1 = Ξ 2 = 1 2 Equilibrium dispersion of relative prices: π t = [ 2 k=1 Ξ k p 1 η k,t 1 π1 η kt ] 1 1 η p kt P kt P t = sector-specific relative price π kt = sector-specific inflation rate P kt P k,t 1 Benchmark case: φ 1 = 0 financially strong firms φ 1 = 0.3 financially weak firms

PRICE WAR IN RESPONSE TO FINANCIAL SHOCKS Heterogeneous firms (a) Relative prices (b) Output % % 0.5 0.6 Financially strong Financially weak 0.4 0.2-0.5-0.2 Financially weak -1.0 Financially strong -0.4-1.5 Aggregate 0 10 20 30 40-0.6 Aggregate 0 10 20 30 40-2.0 Case I: φ 1 = 0.8 φ, φ 2 = φ and ω 1 = ω 2 = 0.5 Case II: φ 1 = 0, φ 2 = φ and ω 1 = ω 2 = 0.5

PARADOX OF FINANCIAL STRENGTH Heterogeneous firms (a) Relative prices % (b) Output % 0.6 Financially strong 0.5 Financially weak 0.4 0.2 Financially weak -0.5-0.2-1.0 Financially strong -0.4-1.5 Aggregate 0 10 20 30 40-0.6 Aggregate 0 10 20 30 40-2.0 Case I: φ 1 = 0.8 φ, φ 2 = φ and ω 1 = ω 2 = 0.5 Case II: φ 1 = 0, φ 2 = φ and ω 1 = ω 2 = 0.5

PARADOX OF FINANCIAL STRENGTH Heterogeneous firms (a) Relative prices % (b) Output % 0.6 Financially strong 0.5 Financially weak 0.4 0.2 Financially weak -0.5-0.2-1.0 Financially strong -0.4-1.5 Aggregate Aggregate 0 10 20 30 40-0.6 Aggregate Aggregate 0 10 20 30 40-2.0 Case I: φ 1 = 0.8 φ, φ 2 = φ and ω 1 = ω 2 = 0.5 Case II: φ 1 = 0, φ 2 = φ and ω 1 = ω 2 = 0.5

CONCLUSION Empirical results imply that financially healthy firms decreased prices, while financially weak firms increased prices during the financial crisis. Industry-level and Eurozone evidence suggest this is a regular feature of business cycles. DSGE model: financial theory of countercylical markups implies attenuation of inflation dynamics in response to demand shocks and severe contraction in response to temporary financial shocks. Implications for monetary policy: Tradeoff between inflation and output in response to demand and financial shocks.