Insider trading, stochastic liquidity, and equilibrium prices

Similar documents
Insider trading, stochastic liquidity, and equilibrium prices

Insider Trading, Stochastic Liquidity and Equilibrium Prices

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INSIDER TRADING, STOCHASTIC LIQUIDITY AND EQUILIBRIUM PRICES. Pierre Collin-Dufresne Vyacheslav Fos

Hostile Corporate Governance and Stock Liquidity

Moral Hazard, Informed Trading, and Stock Prices

An Introduction to Market Microstructure Invariance

Information and Inventories in High-Frequency Trading

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

THE LINK BETWEEN ASYMMETRIC AND SYMMETRIC OPTIMAL PORTFOLIOS IN FADS MODELS

Dynamic Portfolio Choice with Frictions

Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing

Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information

Asymmetric information in trading against disorderly liquidation of a large position.

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

The stochastic calculus

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Kyle Model Governance Atoms Bonds. Presence of an Informed Trader and Other Atoms in Kyle Models. Kyle Model Governance Atoms Bonds

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Outline. and Governance. Presence of an Informed Trader and Other Atoms in Kyle Models. Stock and Bond Volume. Kyle Model Governance Atoms Bonds

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

Imperfect Competition, Information Asymmetry, and Cost of Capital

Optimal Execution: IV. Heterogeneous Beliefs and Market Making

Dynamic Information Acquisition and Strategic Trading

On modelling of electricity spot price

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Time-changed Brownian motion and option pricing

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Arbitrageurs, bubbles and credit conditions

Hedging under Arbitrage

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

LectureNote: MarketMicrostructure

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

Risk-Neutral Modeling of Emission Allowance Prices

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

The Self-financing Condition: Remembering the Limit Order Book

The Term Structure of Interest Rates under Regime Shifts and Jumps

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Quantitative Modelling of Market Booms and Crashes

Informed Trading with Dynamic Information Dissemination

Limited liability, or how to prevent slavery in contract theory

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

News Trading and Speed

Dynamic Information Acquisition and Strategic Trading

Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

How to Compute the Liquidity Cost in a Market Governed by Orders?

The value of foresight

Convenience Yield-Based Pricing of Commodity Futures

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

Supplementary online material to Information tradeoffs in dynamic financial markets

Interest Rate Volatility

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Identifying Information Asymmetry in Securities Markets

Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

Valuing volatility and variance swaps for a non-gaussian Ornstein-Uhlenbeck stochastic volatility model

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Bid-Ask Spreads and Volume: The Role of Trade Timing

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

(A note) on co-integration in commodity markets

Research Proposal. Order Imbalance around Corporate Information Events. Shiang Liu Michael Impson University of North Texas.

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Linearity-Generating Processes, Unspanned Stochastic Volatility, and Interest-Rate Option Pricing

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property

Asymptotic Theory for Renewal Based High-Frequency Volatility Estimation

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Statistical methods for financial models driven by Lévy processes

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Trading and Liquidity with. Bruno Biais (Toulouse), Johan Hombert (HEC)

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Transcription:

Insider trading, stochastic liquidity, and equilibrium prices Pierre Collin-Dufresne EPFL, Columbia University and NBER Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign April 24, 2013 Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 1/ 30

Do measures of stock liquidity reveal the presence of informed traders? Measures of trading liquidity should be informative about the presence of adverse selection (Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Kyle, 1985; Easley and O Hara, 1987) Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 2/ 30

Do measures of stock liquidity reveal the presence of informed traders? Measures of trading liquidity should be informative about the presence of adverse selection (Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Kyle, 1985; Easley and O Hara, 1987) For example, Kyle (1985) proposes seminal model of insider trading: Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 2/ 30

Do measures of stock liquidity reveal the presence of informed traders? Measures of trading liquidity should be informative about the presence of adverse selection (Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Kyle, 1985; Easley and O Hara, 1987) For example, Kyle (1985) proposes seminal model of insider trading: Insider knows terminal value of the firm that will be revealed to all at T. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 2/ 30

Do measures of stock liquidity reveal the presence of informed traders? Measures of trading liquidity should be informative about the presence of adverse selection (Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Kyle, 1985; Easley and O Hara, 1987) For example, Kyle (1985) proposes seminal model of insider trading: Insider knows terminal value of the firm that will be revealed to all at T. Market marker sets price equal to expected value given total order flow which is the sum of uninformed noise trader demand and insider trades. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 2/ 30

Do measures of stock liquidity reveal the presence of informed traders? Measures of trading liquidity should be informative about the presence of adverse selection (Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Kyle, 1985; Easley and O Hara, 1987) For example, Kyle (1985) proposes seminal model of insider trading: Insider knows terminal value of the firm that will be revealed to all at T. Market marker sets price equal to expected value given total order flow which is the sum of uninformed noise trader demand and insider trades. Insider trades proportionally to difference between private valuation and price, and inversely related to time and price impact. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 2/ 30

Do measures of stock liquidity reveal the presence of informed traders? Measures of trading liquidity should be informative about the presence of adverse selection (Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Kyle, 1985; Easley and O Hara, 1987) For example, Kyle (1985) proposes seminal model of insider trading: Insider knows terminal value of the firm that will be revealed to all at T. Market marker sets price equal to expected value given total order flow which is the sum of uninformed noise trader demand and insider trades. Insider trades proportionally to difference between private valuation and price, and inversely related to time and price impact. In equilibrium, price responds to order flow linearly. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 2/ 30

Do measures of stock liquidity reveal the presence of informed traders? Measures of trading liquidity should be informative about the presence of adverse selection (Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Kyle, 1985; Easley and O Hara, 1987) For example, Kyle (1985) proposes seminal model of insider trading: Insider knows terminal value of the firm that will be revealed to all at T. Market marker sets price equal to expected value given total order flow which is the sum of uninformed noise trader demand and insider trades. Insider trades proportionally to difference between private valuation and price, and inversely related to time and price impact. In equilibrium, price responds to order flow linearly. In cross-section, Kyle s λ, which can be estimated from a regression of price changes on order flow, should be higher for stocks with more informed trading (relative to liquidity/noise trading) Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 2/ 30

Do measures of stock liquidity reveal the presence of informed traders? Measures of trading liquidity should be informative about the presence of adverse selection (Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Kyle, 1985; Easley and O Hara, 1987) For example, Kyle (1985) proposes seminal model of insider trading: Insider knows terminal value of the firm that will be revealed to all at T. Market marker sets price equal to expected value given total order flow which is the sum of uninformed noise trader demand and insider trades. Insider trades proportionally to difference between private valuation and price, and inversely related to time and price impact. In equilibrium, price responds to order flow linearly. In cross-section, Kyle s λ, which can be estimated from a regression of price changes on order flow, should be higher for stocks with more informed trading (relative to liquidity/noise trading) Several empirical measures of adverse selection proposed in the literature. (e.g., Glosten, 1987; Glosten and Harris, 1988; Hasbrouck, 1991) Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 2/ 30

Do measures of stock liquidity reveal the presence of informed traders? Measures of trading liquidity should be informative about the presence of adverse selection (Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Kyle, 1985; Easley and O Hara, 1987) For example, Kyle (1985) proposes seminal model of insider trading: Insider knows terminal value of the firm that will be revealed to all at T. Market marker sets price equal to expected value given total order flow which is the sum of uninformed noise trader demand and insider trades. Insider trades proportionally to difference between private valuation and price, and inversely related to time and price impact. In equilibrium, price responds to order flow linearly. In cross-section, Kyle s λ, which can be estimated from a regression of price changes on order flow, should be higher for stocks with more informed trading (relative to liquidity/noise trading) Several empirical measures of adverse selection proposed in the literature. (e.g., Glosten, 1987; Glosten and Harris, 1988; Hasbrouck, 1991) Question: how well do these measures perform at picking up the presence of informed trading? Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 2/ 30

Empirical motivation Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 3/ 30

Empirical motivation In recent paper Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading?, we hand-collect data on informed trades from Schedule 13D filings Rule 13d-1(a) of the 1934 Securities Exchange Act that requires the filer to... describe any transactions in the class of securities reported on that were effected during past 60 days... Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 3/ 30

Empirical motivation In recent paper Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading?, we hand-collect data on informed trades from Schedule 13D filings Rule 13d-1(a) of the 1934 Securities Exchange Act that requires the filer to... describe any transactions in the class of securities reported on that were effected during past 60 days... Trades executed by Schedule 13D filers are informed: Announcement returns Profits of Schedule 13D filers Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 3/ 30

Empirical motivation In recent paper Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading?, we hand-collect data on informed trades from Schedule 13D filings Rule 13d-1(a) of the 1934 Securities Exchange Act that requires the filer to... describe any transactions in the class of securities reported on that were effected during past 60 days... Trades executed by Schedule 13D filers are informed: Announcement returns Profits of Schedule 13D filers Find that measures of adverse selection are lower on days with informed trading Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 3/ 30

Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Return Two month excess return is around 9% Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 4/ 30

Do informed trades move stock prices? days with days with no informed trading informed trading difference t-stat (1) (2) (3) (4) excess return 0.0064-0.0004 0.0068*** 9.94 turnover 0.0191 0.0077 0.0115*** 21.67 Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 5/ 30

Is adverse selection higher when informed trade? days with days with no informed trading informed trading difference (1) (2) (3) Adverse Selection Measures λ 10 6 14.3311 20.1644-5.8334*** [-8.38] pimpact 0.0060 0.0064-0.0004** [-2.18] cumir 0.0013 0.0015-0.0002** [-2.06] trade related 0.0654 0.0673-0.0019 [-0.99] Other Liquidity Measures rspread 0.0081 0.0089-0.0008*** [-3.43] espread 0.0145 0.0155-0.001*** [-3.25] Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 6/ 30

of Empirical Paper Schedule 13D filers have valuable information when they purchase shares of targeted companies Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 7/ 30

of Empirical Paper Schedule 13D filers have valuable information when they purchase shares of targeted companies Thus, the information asymmetry is high when Schedule 13D filers purchase shares Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 7/ 30

of Empirical Paper Schedule 13D filers have valuable information when they purchase shares of targeted companies Thus, the information asymmetry is high when Schedule 13D filers purchase shares We find that excess return and turnover are higher when insiders trade, which seems to indicate that they have price impact Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 7/ 30

of Empirical Paper Schedule 13D filers have valuable information when they purchase shares of targeted companies Thus, the information asymmetry is high when Schedule 13D filers purchase shares We find that excess return and turnover are higher when insiders trade, which seems to indicate that they have price impact However, we find that measures of information asymmetry and liquidity indicate that stocks are more liquid when informed trades take place Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 7/ 30

of Empirical Paper Schedule 13D filers have valuable information when they purchase shares of targeted companies Thus, the information asymmetry is high when Schedule 13D filers purchase shares We find that excess return and turnover are higher when insiders trade, which seems to indicate that they have price impact However, we find that measures of information asymmetry and liquidity indicate that stocks are more liquid when informed trades take place This evidence seems at odds with our intuition. Biais, Glosten, and Spatt (2005): As the informational motivation of trades becomes relatively more important, price impact goes up. [page 232] Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 7/ 30

of Empirical Paper Schedule 13D filers have valuable information when they purchase shares of targeted companies Thus, the information asymmetry is high when Schedule 13D filers purchase shares We find that excess return and turnover are higher when insiders trade, which seems to indicate that they have price impact However, we find that measures of information asymmetry and liquidity indicate that stocks are more liquid when informed trades take place This evidence seems at odds with our intuition. Biais, Glosten, and Spatt (2005): As the informational motivation of trades becomes relatively more important, price impact goes up. [page 232] The endogeneity issue seems more problematic than the literature may have previously recognized. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 7/ 30

Abnormal Share Turnover - Revisited Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 8/ 30

Theoretical Contribution We extend Kyle s (insider trading) model to allow for general stochastic changes in volatility of uninformed order flow. Main results: Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 9/ 30

Theoretical Contribution We extend Kyle s (insider trading) model to allow for general stochastic changes in volatility of uninformed order flow. Main results: Equilibrium price displays (endogenous) stochastic volatility if noise trader vol is predictable. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 9/ 30

Theoretical Contribution We extend Kyle s (insider trading) model to allow for general stochastic changes in volatility of uninformed order flow. Main results: Equilibrium price displays (endogenous) stochastic volatility if noise trader vol is predictable. Price impact (Kyle s lambda) is stochastic: lower (higher) when noise trading volatility is higher (lower). Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 9/ 30

Theoretical Contribution We extend Kyle s (insider trading) model to allow for general stochastic changes in volatility of uninformed order flow. Main results: Equilibrium price displays (endogenous) stochastic volatility if noise trader vol is predictable. Price impact (Kyle s lambda) is stochastic: lower (higher) when noise trading volatility is higher (lower). Price impact (Kyle s lambda) is submartingale: execution costs are expected to deteriorate over time. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 9/ 30

Theoretical Contribution We extend Kyle s (insider trading) model to allow for general stochastic changes in volatility of uninformed order flow. Main results: Equilibrium price displays (endogenous) stochastic volatility if noise trader vol is predictable. Price impact (Kyle s lambda) is stochastic: lower (higher) when noise trading volatility is higher (lower). Price impact (Kyle s lambda) is submartingale: execution costs are expected to deteriorate over time. Informed trade more aggressively when noise trading volatility is higher and when measured price impact is lower. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 9/ 30

Theoretical Contribution We extend Kyle s (insider trading) model to allow for general stochastic changes in volatility of uninformed order flow. Main results: Equilibrium price displays (endogenous) stochastic volatility if noise trader vol is predictable. Price impact (Kyle s lambda) is stochastic: lower (higher) when noise trading volatility is higher (lower). Price impact (Kyle s lambda) is submartingale: execution costs are expected to deteriorate over time. Informed trade more aggressively when noise trading volatility is higher and when measured price impact is lower. More information makes its way into prices when noise trading volatility is higher. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 9/ 30

Theoretical Contribution We extend Kyle s (insider trading) model to allow for general stochastic changes in volatility of uninformed order flow. Main results: Equilibrium price displays (endogenous) stochastic volatility if noise trader vol is predictable. Price impact (Kyle s lambda) is stochastic: lower (higher) when noise trading volatility is higher (lower). Price impact (Kyle s lambda) is submartingale: execution costs are expected to deteriorate over time. Informed trade more aggressively when noise trading volatility is higher and when measured price impact is lower. More information makes its way into prices when noise trading volatility is higher. Aggregate adverse selection execution costs for uninformed noise traders can be higher when noise trading is higher (and lambda is lower). Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 9/ 30

Insider Empirical Motivation Setup Equilibrium We follow Back (1992) and develop a continuous time version of Kyle (1985) Risk-neutral insider s maximization problem: [ T ] max E (υ P t)θ tdt Ft Y, υ θ t 0 (1) As in Kyle, we assume there is an insider trading in the stock with perfect knowledge of the terminal value υ It is optimal for the insider to follow absolutely continuous trading strategy (Back, 1992). Related work: Back and Pedersen (1998), Admati Pfleiderer (1988) and others... Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 10/ 30

Market Maker Empirical Motivation Setup Equilibrium The market maker is also risk-neutral, but does not observe the terminal value. Instead, he has a prior that the value υ is normally distributed N(µ 0, Σ 0) The market maker only observes the total order flow: dy t = θ }{{} tdt informed order flow + σ } tdz {{} t uninformed order flow (2) where σ t is the stochastic volatility of the uninformed order flow: dσ t = m(t, σ t )dt + ν(t, σ t )dm t and M t is orthogonal (possibly discontinuous) martingale. Since the market maker is risk-neutral, equilibrium imposes that [ ] P t = E υ Ft Y (3) We assume that the market maker and the informed investor observe σ t. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 11/ 30

Preview of Results Empirical Motivation Setup Equilibrium This may seem like a trivial extension of the Kyle (1985) model, as one might conjecture that one can simply paste together Kyle economies with different noise-trading volatilities...... But, not so! The insider will optimally choose to trade less in the lower liquidity states than he would were these to last forever, because he anticipates the future opportunity to trade more when liquidity is better and he can reap a larger profit Of course, in a rational expectations equilibrium, the market maker foresees this, and adjusts prices accordingly. Therefore, if noise trader volatility is predictable, price dynamics are more complex than in the standard Kyle model: Price displays stochastic volatility Price impact measures are time varying and not necessarily related to informativeness of order flow. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 12/ 30

Solving for Equilibrium Setup Equilibrium First, we conjecture a trading rule followed by the insider: θ t = β(t, σ t, Σ t)(υ P t) Second, we derive the dynamics of the stock price consistent with the market maker s filtering rule, conditional on a conjectured trading rule followed by the insider dp t = λ(t, σ t, Σ t)dy t Then we solve the insider s optimal portfolio choice problem, given the assumed dynamics of the equilibrium price Finally, we show that the conjectured rule by the market maker is indeed consistent with the insider s optimal choice Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 13/ 30

General Features of Equilibrium Setup Equilibrium Price impact is stochastic: Σt λ t = (4) G t where Σ t is remaining amount of private information [ ] Σ t = E (υ P t) 2 Ft Y (5) and G t is remaining amount of uninformed order flow variance, solves the Backward stochastic differential equation (BSDE): [ T ] σs 2 Gt = E 2 ds σ t (6) G s Optimal strategy of insider is: θ t = 1 λ t σ 2 t G t (υ P t) (7) Insider trades more aggressively when the ratio of private information (σ t) to equilibrium-expected noise trading volatility (G t) is higher, and when price impact λ t is lower. t Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 14/ 30

General Features of Equilibrium Setup Equilibrium Stock price displays time-varying volatility: dp t = (υ Pt) G t σ 2 t dt + Σt G t σ t dz t (8) Note, that information asymmetry is necessary for price process to be non-constant. G t is the crucial quantity to characterize equilibrium. Its BSDE solution satisfies: G t E[ T t σ 2 s ds] If σ σ t σ then we can show that there exists a maximal bounded solution to the recursive equation for G with: σ 2 (T t) G t σ 2 (T t) (9) For several special cases we can construct an explicit solution to this BSDE: σ t deterministic. σ t general martingale. log σ t Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process. σ t continuous time Markov Chain. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 15/ 30

General Features of Equilibrium Setup Equilibrium lim t T P t = υ Stochastic bridge property of price in insider s filtration. Market depth (1/λ t) is martingale. Price impact (λ t) is a submartingale (liquidity is expected to deteriorate over time). dσ t = dpt 2 (stock price variance is high when information gets into prices faster, which occurs when noise trader volatility is high). Total profits of the insider are equal to Σ 0G 0. Realized execution costs of uninformed can be computed pathwise as T 0 (P t+dt P t)σ tdz t = T 0 λ tσ 2 t dt Unconditionally, expected aggregate execution costs of uninformed equal insider s profits. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 16/ 30

General martingale dynamics Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain We assume that uninformed order flow volatility is unpredictable (a martingale): We can solve for G(t) = σ 2 t (T t), Then market depth is a martingale: where σ 2 υ = Σ 0 T dσ t σ t = ν(t, σ t )dm t, (10) 1 λ t = σt σ υ, is the annualized initial private information variance level. The trading strategy of the insiders is θ t = σt σ υ(t (υ Pt) t) Equilibrium price dynamics are identical to the original Kyle (1985) model: dp t = (υ Pt) dt + σ υdz t. (11) T t Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 17/ 30

Implications of martingale dynamics Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain This example shows we can extend Kyle s equilibrium by simply plugging-in stochastic noise trading volatility: Market depth varies linearly to noise trading volatility, Insider s strategy is more aggressive when noise trading volatility increases, Both effects offset perfectly so as to leave prices unchanged (relative to Kyle): Prices display constant volatility. Private information gets into prices linearly and independently of the rate of noise trading volatility (as in Kyle). In this model empirical measures of price impact will be time varying (and increasing over time on average), but do not reflect any variation in asymmetric information of trades. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 18/ 30

General Diffusion Dynamics Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain Suppose that volatility follows a strictly positive process of the form: dσ t σ t = m(t, σ t )dt + ν(t, σ t )dw t (12) If the expected growth rate of noise trading volatility follows a deterministic process m t: G(t) admits the solution: G(t) = σt 2 T u t e t 2m s ds du Private information enters prices at a deterministic rate Equilibrium price volatility is deterministic For the insider to change his strategy depending on the uncertainty about future noise trading volatility, the growth rate of noise trading volatility m t has to be stochastic. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 19/ 30

Constant Expected growth rate Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain We assume that uninformed order flow volatility follows a geometric Brownian Motion: dσ t σ t = mdt + νdw t, (13) We can solve for G(t) = σ 2 t B t where B t = e2m(t t) 1 2m, Then market depth is 1 λ t = e mt σ t B 0 Σ 0 Equilibrium price dynamics follow a one-factor Markov non-homogenous bridge process: (υ Pt) dp t = dt + e mt Σ0 dz t. (14) B t B 0 Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 20/ 30

Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain Implications of constant growth rate As soon as there is predictability in noise trader volatility, equilibrium prices change (relative to Kyle): Price volatility increases (decreases) deterministically with time if noise trading volatility is expected to increase (decrease). Private information gets into prices slower (faster) if noise trading volatility is expected to increase (decrease). Interesting separation result obtains: Strategy of insider and price impact measure only depends on current level of noise trader volatility. Equilibrium is independent of uncertainty about future noise trading volatility level (ν). As a result, equilibrium price volatility is deterministic Private information gets into prices at a deterministic rate, despite measures of price impact (and the strategy of the insider) being stochastic! Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 21/ 30

Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain Implications of constant growth rate E Θ v v P0 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 m 0.5 m 0 m 0.5 0.4 0.2 e Figure: The Trading Strategy of the Insider Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 22/ 30

Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain A two-state Continuous Markov Chain example Assume uninformed order flow volatility can take on two values σ(0) < σ(1) where regime indicator S t [0, 1] follows: ds t = (1 s t)dn 0(t) s tdn 1(t), (15) where N i (t) is a standard Poisson counting process with jump intensity η i respectively The solution is G(t, s t) = 1 {s t =0} G 0 (T t) + 1 {s t =1} G 1 (T t), where the deterministic functions G 0, G 1 satisfy the system of ODE (with boundary conditions G 0 (0) = G 1 (0) = 0): G 0 τ (τ) = σ(0) 2 + 2η 0( G 1 (τ)g 0 (τ) G 0 (τ)) (16) G 1 τ (τ) = σ(1) 2 + 2η 1( G 1 (τ)g 0 (τ) G 1 (τ)) (17) We compute execution costs of uninformed numerically in this case. Show that uninformed execution costs can be higher when noise trading volatility is higher (and Kyle lambda is actually lower). Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 23/ 30

Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain Σ 1 2 T t 0.15 G1 T t G0 T t 0.10 Σ 0 2 T t 0.05 Figure: G function in high and low state Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 24/ 30

Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain high t 0 1.0 0.8 0.6 high low low high low Kyle 0.4 0.2 Figure: Four Private information paths Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 25/ 30

Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain high Λ t 5 4 3 2 high low low high low kyle high kyle low 1 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Figure: Four paths of price impact λ t Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 26/ 30

Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain high high low low high low time Figure: Four paths of Stock price volatility Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 27/ 30

Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain high high low low high low time Figure: Four paths of uninformed traders execution costs Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 28/ 30

Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain Noise trading volatility paths high low high/low low/high Total number of uninformed ( T 0 σ2 t dt) 0.16 0.01 0.085 0.085 Average price impact ( T λtdt) 0.487 1.740 1.023 0.853 0 Execution costs ( T 0 λtσ2 t dt) 0.078 0.017 0.054 0.057 T0 λ Normalized execution costs ( t σt 2 dt T0 ) 0.487 1.740 0.636 0.671 σt 2dt Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 29/ 30

Martingale noise trading volatility General Diffusion Dynamics Constant expected growth rate Two State Markov Chain Noise trading volatility paths high low high/low low/high Total number of uninformed ( T 0 σ2 t dt) 0.16 0.01 0.085 0.085 Average price impact ( T λtdt) 0.487 1.740 1.023 0.853 0 Execution costs ( T 0 λtσ2 t dt) 0.078 0.017 0.054 0.057 T0 λ Normalized execution costs ( t σt 2 dt T0 ) 0.487 1.740 0.636 0.671 σt 2dt Average price-impact is not informative about execution costs to uninformed traders. Normalizing by abnormal trading volume is crucial. Even so, average execution costs to uninformed are path-dependent. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 29/ 30

Empirical Motivation Recent empirical paper finds that standard measures of adverse selection and stock liquidity fail to reveal the presence of informed traders Propose extension of Kyle (1985) to allow for stochastic noise trading volatility. Seems more consistent with evidence: Insider conditions his trading on liquidity state. Price impact measures are time-varying, and not necessarily higher when more private information flows into prices. Execution costs can be higher when measured price impact is lower. Generates stochastic price volatility. Future work: Better measure of liquidity/adverse selection? Model of activist insider trading with endogenous terminal value. Why the 5% rule? Absence of common knowledge about informed presence. Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? 30/ 30