A Pigovian Approach to Liquidity Regulation

Similar documents
UvA-DARE (Digital Academic Repository) A pigovian approach to liquidity regulation Perotti, E.C.; Suarez, J. Link to publication

Regulation of Liquidity Risk

Discussion of A Pigovian Approach to Liquidity Regulation

The Procyclical Effects of Basel II

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Banks Endogenous Systemic Risk Taking. David Martinez-Miera Universidad Carlos III. Javier Suarez CEMFI

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Optimal margins and equilibrium prices

The Socially Optimal Level of Capital Requirements: AViewfromTwoPapers. Javier Suarez* CEMFI. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, November 2012

Markets, Banks and Shadow Banks

Bank Regulation under Fire Sale Externalities

Intermediate public economics 5 Externalities Hiroaki Sakamoto

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

DYNAMIC DEBT MATURITY

Clearing, Counterparty Risk and Aggregate Risk

Government Safety Net, Stock Market Participation and Asset Prices

Convertible Bonds and Bank Risk-taking

Maturity Transformation and Liquidity

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

A Tale of Fire-Sales and Liquidity Hoarding

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Convertible Bonds and Bank Risk-taking

Liquidity Regulation and the Implementation of Monetary Policy

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

A Macroeconomic Model of Endogenous Systemic Risk Taking. David Martinez-Miera Universidad Carlos III. Javier Suarez CEMFI

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

CONVENTIONAL AND UNCONVENTIONAL MONETARY POLICY WITH ENDOGENOUS COLLATERAL CONSTRAINTS

The Expansionary Lower Bound: A Theory of Contractionary Monetary Easing *

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Characterization of the Optimum

A POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH TO BANKING REGULATION

MONOPOLY (2) Second Degree Price Discrimination

Internet Taxation. Francis Bloch. Toulouse, Postal Conference, April 16, Université Paris 1 and PSE

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

Location, Productivity, and Trade

Fire sales, inefficient banking and liquidity ratios

Liquidity Regulation and Credit Booms: Theory and Evidence from China. JRCPPF Sixth Annual Conference February 16-17, 2017

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Monetary Economics. Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable)

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

The Design of Optimal Education Policies

Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Global Games and Financial Fragility:

LECTURE 12: FRICTIONAL FINANCE

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Equilibrium Fast Trading

Pareto Efficient Income Taxation

Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

Monetary Easing, Investment and Financial Instability

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

A Theoretical Foundation for the Stakeholder Corporation

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Princeton University. Updates:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL. Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka. Working Paper

Working Paper S e r i e s

The science of monetary policy

Adverse Selection When Agents Envy Their Principal. KANGSIK CHOI June 7, 2004

Scarce Collateral, the Term Premium, and Quantitative Easing

New Keynesian Model. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame. Sims (ND) New Keynesian Model Fall / 20

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

Political Economics - Explaining Economic Policy

Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint

Liquidity Policies and Systemic Risk Tobias Adrian and Nina Boyarchenko

SOCIAL SECURITY: UNIVERSAL VS. EARNINGS DEPENDENT BENEFITS WORKING PAPER SERIES

The I Theory of Money

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

Pseudo-Wealth Fluctuations and Aggregate Demand Effects

Models of Directed Search - Labor Market Dynamics, Optimal UI, and Student Credit

Equity versus Bail-in Debt in Banking: An Agency Perspective. Javier Suarez (CEMFI) Workshop on Financial Stability CEMFI, Madrid, 13 May 2016

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comments on Michael Woodford, Globalization and Monetary Control

Reflections on capital taxation

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

A key characteristic of financial markets is that they are subject to sudden, convulsive changes.

Unemployment, tax evasion and the slippery slope framework

Counterparty risk externality: Centralized versus over-the-counter markets. Presentation at Stanford Macro, April 2011

A Model of Principles-Based vs. Rules-Based Standards

Booms and Banking Crises

Technical Appendix to Asset Prices in a Huggett Economy

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation

Large Multi-Unit Auctions with a Large Bidder

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Sequential versus Static Screening: An equivalence result

Macroprudential Bank Capital Regulation in a Competitive Financial System

Allocating and Funding Universal Service Obligations in a Competitive Network Market

Transcription:

12TH JACQUES POLAK ANNUAL RESEARCH CONFERENCE NOVEMBER 10 11, 2011 A Pigovian Approach to Liquidity Regulation Enrico C. Perotti University of Amsterdam Javier Suarez CEMFI Presentation presented at the 12th Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference Hosted by the International Monetary Fund Washington, DC November 10 11, 2011 The views expressed in this presentation are those of the author(s) only, and the presence of them, or of links to them, on the IMF website does not imply that the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management endorses or shares the views expressed in the paper.

A Pigovian approach to liquidity regulation Enrico Perotti University of Amsterdam Javier Suarez CEMFI IMF Twelfth Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference Washington, November 10-11, 2011 1

INTRODUCTION Paper studies effectiveness of different approaches to regulation of banks refinancing risk Short-term (ST) funding helps banks expand their credit activity but makes them more vulnerable to systemic liquidity problems Because of fire sales or counterparty risk externalities... Each bank s individual funding decision has an impact on the vulnerability of other banks In the absence of regulation, banks rely excessively on ST funding We provide a theoretical assessment of the performance of Pigovian taxes: levies on banks short-term funding Quantity regulations: ratios introduced by Basel III 2

The analysis stresses bank heterogeneity & potential constraints to making regulation contingent on the relevant bank characteristics: Depending on the dominant source of heterogeneity, the socially efficient solution may be attained with Pigovian taxes, quantity regulations or a combination of both Two main sources of heterogeneity: Credit ability/quality of investment opportunities better banks want to expand more Incentives to take risk overconfident managers & less capitalized banks want to gamble more (e.g. because they shift downside risk to the safety net) [We first analyze each of them separately, then jointly] 3

Key findings: 1. Strong case for simple Pigovian tax when banks differ in credit ability/quality of investment opportunities 2. Strong case for quantity regulation (net stable funding ratio) if banks differ in risk-shifting incentives 3. Skepticism about effectiveness and efficiency of a liquidity coverage ratio (in both scenarios) 4. Potential optimality of a mixed approach if the two sources of heterogeneity are important 4

Outline 1. Baseline case: heterogeneity in credit ability 2. Equilibrium vs. social optimum 3. The simple Pigovian solution 4. Quantity-based alternatives 5. Case for quantity regulation: heterogeneity in gambling incentives 6. Other issues 5

1. Baseline case: heterogeneity in credit ability Simple one-period model in which agents are risk neutral Single round of ST funding decisions Relevant trade-off are captured by reduced-form payoff functions [Compatible with broad set of structural models] Measure-one continuum of banks characterized by type θ [0, 1], distributed with density f(θ) across banks Bank owners: Make a ST funding decision x [0, ) Maximize bank value (NPV of their claims) Other investors: (i) could invest at some exogenous market rates (ii) provide funding at competitive terms 6

Without regulation, bank value is v(x, X, θ) =π(x, θ) ε(x, θ)c(x) where: π(x, θ) :value generated in the absence of systemic crisis risk π x > 0, π θ > 0, π xx < 0, π xθ > 0 ε(x, θ) :contribution to expected crisis costs due to individual (x, θ) ε x > 0, ε θ 0, ε xx 0, ε xθ 0 c(x) :contribution to crisis costs due to systemic risk X c 0 > 0, c 00 0 Hence, net marginal benefit from ST funding x is (i) decreasing in x (ii) increasing in θ 7

X is determined by the ST funding decisions of all banks. For simplicity, we assume X = Z 1 0 x(θ)f(θ)dθ, where x(θ) is the decision made by each bank of type θ Social welfare: If other investors obtain zero NPV from the banks, a natural measure of social welfare is just W = R 1 0 v(x(θ),x,θ)f(θ)dθ= R 1 0 [π(x(θ),θ) ε(x(θ),θ)c(x)]f(θ)dθ (The total NPV of cash flows received by bank owners) 8

Unregulated equilibrium: 2. Equilibrium vs. social optimum 1. x e (θ) =argmax x {π(x, θ) ε(x, θ)c(x e )} for all θ [0, 1], 2. X e = R 1 0 x e (θ)f(θ)dθ. If interior, FOCs imply: π x (x e (θ),θ) ε x (x e (θ),θ)c(x e )=0 Socially optimal allocation: R max 1 {x(θ)},x 0 [π(x(θ),θ) ε(x(θ),θ)c(x )]f(θ)dθ s.t.: X = R 1 0 x(θ)f(θ)dθ. If interior, π x (x (θ),θ) ε x (x (θ),θ)c(x ) E z (ε(x (z),z))c 0 (X )=0 [3rd term = Mg External Costs of each x(θ)] 9

Proposition 1: The equilibrium allocation is not socially efficient Systemic externalities imply X e >X x(θ 1 ) 1.8 1.7 1.6 Unregulated equilibrium allocation Socially efficient allocation 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 0.9 0.8 0.00 0.17 0.33 0.50 0.67 0.83 1.00 θ 1 10

3. The simple Pigovian solution As in textbook discussions on negative production externalities: Efficiency can be restored by imposing a Pigovian tax: Tax rate = Social MgC Private MgC In our case: τ = E z (ε(x (z),z))c 0 (X ) Independent of θ! Proposition 2 With heterogeneity in investment opportunities, social efficiency of equilibrium can be restored by charging tax τ on banks ST funding 11

4. Quantity-based alternatives Pure quantity regulation (prescribing x (θ) to each θ)... Would require bank-level knowledge of π x (x, θ) & ε x (x, θ) Strong informational requirements not considered in practice Proposals considered in practice are ratio-based In Basel III: Liquidity coverage ratio Net stable funding ratio 12

4.1 Net stable funding requirement: Stable funding regulatory minimum Non-liquid assets [Stable funding = equity+customer deposits+other LT debt] If stable funding'given: Requirement is equivalent to upper limit x to ST funding x could be endogenized as a result of prior decisions [e.g. on asset maturity/liquidity or LT funding] Assume implied x is the same for all banks Then, in an equilibrium with a stable funding requirement x : x x (θ) =argmax x x {π(x, θ) ε(x, θ)c(xx )} 13

Three cases: If x x e (1) not binding for any θ, no effect If x x e (0) binding for all θ, very rough If x (x e (0),x e (1)) asymmetric & inefficient Banks with largest θs: x x (θ) =x<x e (θ) Paradoxically, other banks: x x (θ) >x e (θ) [since X x <X e ] Proposition 3 A net stable funding requirement may reduce X, but at the cost of redistributing ST funding inefficiently across banks. [Second best x can be found] 14

x(θ 1 ) 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.5 Unregulated equilibrium allocation Socially efficient allocation Allocation under best stable funding requirement 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 0.9 0.8 0.00 0.17 0.33 0.50 0.67 0.83 1.00 θ 1 15

4.2 Liquidity coverage requirement: ST funding x must be backed with high-quality liquid assets m [e.g. so as to confront one-month disruption in markets] How can it be captured in the model? Like fractional reserve requirement m φx with φ 1 Two adaptations: What matters for individual & systemic risk are net positions bx = x m & b X = X M But holding liquidity may have a cost δ = r b r m 0 [source of a deadweight loss!] 16

In an equilibrium with liquidity requirement φ : bx φ (θ) = arg max bx {π(bx, θ) ε(bx, θ)c( b X φ ) Equivalent to equilibrium with tax τ(θ) = δφ 1 φ But δ>0 implies social deadweight losses: DW φ = δ Z 1 0 δφ 1 φ bx} on ST funding m φ (θ)f(θ)dθ δm φ = τx τ 17

Proposition 4 (δ =0)[normal times?] With δ =0,φ is innocuous, except because it generates artificial demand for liquid assets ------ [Formally, M φ = Proposition 5 (δ >0) φ 1 φ E θ(x e (θ)) ] With δ>0, φcan be set so as to seemingly replicate any flat-tax τ on ST funding but at a deadweight cost τx τ ------ Seemingly replicating efficient Pigovian tax τ is feasible, but generically not optimal in 1st or 2nd best sense (Prop. 6) Second best requirement φ SB must move in response to fluctuations in δ, producing variability in M φ 18

5. Case for quantity regulation: heterogeneity in gambling incentives What if some crazy, risk-inclined banks are willing to pay the tax and abuse of ST funding? Add a new dimension of heterogeneity: Assume bank owners do not internalize fraction θ 2 of crisis losses [due to, say, diff. in governance, charter value, capitalization,...] Fraction θ 2 is (uncompensatedly) passed to other stakeholders [e.g. the deposit insurer] Bank owners payoff function becomes: v(x, X, θ 1,θ 2 )=π(x, θ 1 ) (1 θ 2 )ε(x, θ 1 )c(x) Social welfare W must account for the missed losses θ 2 ε(x, θ)c(x) 19

5.1 Gambling as the sole source of heterogeneity: Fix θ 1 = θ 1 for all banks π x (x ee (θ 2 ), θ 1 ) (1 θ 2 )ε x (x ee (θ 2 ), θ 1 )c(x ee )=0 vs. π x (x (θ 2 ), θ 1 ) ε x (x (θ 2 ), θ 1 )c(x ) E z (ε(x (z), θ 1 ))c 0 (X )=0 Inefficiency of equilibrium : x ee (θ 2 ) is increasing, while x (θ 2 )=x is constant The efficient Pigovian tax schedule is now dependent on θ 2 20

Proposition 7 If gambling incentives constitute the only source of heterogeneity: A flat tax on ST funding does not implement the first best A stable funding requirement implying x = x can do it [For liquidity requirements, same conclusions obtained above apply] 21

1.6 x(θ 2 ) 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 Unregulated equilibrium allocation 1 Socially efficient allocation 0.9 Allocation under best flat Pigovian tax 0.00 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 θ 2 22

5.2 The general case Most likely, not clear-cut results: 1st best is generally not attainable with instruments non-contingent on θ 1 or θ 2 Second best performance: Continuity argument: If θ 1 is the dominant source of heterogeneity, Flat tax on ST funding  Stable funding requirement Vice versa if θ 2 is the dominant source of heterogeneity More generally, a combination may be optimal [If stronger capital regulation, pushes θ 2 towards zero, greater room for a tax on ST funding] 23

6. Other issues A straight Pigovian approach provides direct control on the externality correction mechanism (the tax rate) Allows the response in quantities to be as smooth as the industry finds it optimal to pay for No need for gradualism or long implementation calendars Quantity regulation faces a problem of controllability when the market or shadow price of the limiting quantity fluctuates Potential source of procyclicality With adjustment costs in the limiting quantity, tightening the requirements may produce rationing 24

Institutionally, involving treasuries&parliaments is a nuisance BUT: Liquidity risk levies will reinforce the commitment to act promptly in a systemic crisis May encourage explicit international arrangements for crisis resolution & burden sharing 25

CONCLUSIONS Addressing implications of liquidity risk for systemic risk is a key regulatory challenge Taxes on banks ST funding are a reasonable response Perform better than quantity-based regulation if credit ability/quality of investment opportunities is key source of bank heterogeneity Can be complementary to quantity regulation if heterogeneity in risk-shifting incentives is also large A net stable funding ratio limits ST funding too roughly, if credit ability is the main source of heterogeneity A liquidity coverage ratio is either ineffective or inefficient [With stronger capital requirements, a straightforward Pigovian approach is probably superior to relying on the Basel III liquidity ratios] 26