The Welfare Effects of Welfare and Tax Reform during the Great Recession

Similar documents
Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation:

Effective Policy for Reducing Inequality: The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Distribution of Income

Heterogeneity in the Impact of Economic Cycles and the Great Recession: Effects Within and Across the Income Distribution

Living Arrangements, Doubling Up, and the Great Recession: Was This Time Different?

The State of the Safety Net in the Post- Welfare Reform Era

Using Differences in Knowledge Across Neighborhoods to Uncover the Impacts of the EITC on Earnings

THE GREAT RECESSION: UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE AND STRUCTURAL ISSUES

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES OPTIMAL INCOME TAXATION WITH UNEMPLOYMENT AND WAGE RESPONSES: A SUFFICIENT STATISTICS APPROACH

Analyzing Female Labor Supply: Evidence from a Dutch Tax Reform

Tax Transfer Policy and Labor Market Outcomes

Do In-Work Tax Credits Serve as a Safety Net?

Labour Supply and Taxes

Poverty, the Social Safety Net and the Great Recession

Taxes and Time Allocation: Evidence from Single Women and Men * Alexander M. Gelber The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, and NBER

Taxes and Time Allocation: Evidence from Single Women and Men * Alexander M. Gelber The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, and NBER

SNAP Eligibility and Participation Dynamics: The Roles of Policy and Economic Factors from 2004 to

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits

EC426-Public Economics. Class 2, Question1

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics

CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EFFECTIVE POLICY FOR REDUCING INEQUALITY? THE EARNED INCOME TAX CREDIT AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME

What is the Federal EITC? The Earned Income Tax Credit and Labor Market Participation of Families on Welfare. Coincident Trends: Are They Related?

The Earned Income Tax Credit, Welfare Reform, and the Employment of Low Skill Single Mothers

Living Arrangements, Doubling Up, and the Great Recession: Was This Time Different?

Optimal Income Taxation with Unemployment and Wage Responses: A Sufficient Statistics Approach

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation:

POLICY BRIEF: UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE AND WORKER MOBILITY Ryan Nunn, Laura Kawano, and Ben Klemens February 8, 2018

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAXES AND TIME ALLOCATION: EVIDENCE FROM SINGLE WOMEN. Alexander M. Gelber Joshua W. Mitchell

Do State Earned Income Tax Credits Increase Participation in the Federal EITC?

The Rise of the In-Work Safety Net: Implications for Income Inequality and Family Health and Well-being

The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Labor Supply of Married Couples

Poverty and the Safety Net After the Great Recession

Redistribution and Tax Expenditures: The Earned Income Tax Credit

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings

The Costs of Job Displacement over the Business Cycle and Its Sources: Evidence from Germany

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Labor-force dynamics and the Food Stamp Program: Utility, needs, and resources. John Young

TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Topic 2-3: Policy Design: Unemployment Insurance and Moral Hazard

FIGURE I.1 / Per Capita Gross Domestic Product and Unemployment Rates. Year

The Impact of the Earned Income Tax Credit and Welfare Reform on Work Entry and Exit Yucong Jiao University of Illinois at Chicago.

Lecture 2: Taxation of Earnings. Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation

Does Reducing Unemployment Benefits During a Recession Reduce Youth Unemployment? Evidence from a 50 Percent Cut in Unemployment Assistance

Do In-Work Tax Credits Serve as a Safety Net?

How did medicaid expansions affect labor supply and welfare enrollment? Evidence from the early 2000s

LECTURE: WELFARE REFORM HILARY HOYNES UC DAVIS EC230 OUTLINE OF LECTURE

Do In-Work Tax Credits Serve as a Safety Net? Marianne Bitler Department of Economics, UC Irvine and NBER

COMPARING RECENT DECLINES IN OREGON'S CASH ASSISTANCE CASELOAD WITH TRENDS IN THE POVERTY POPULATION

Do In-Work Tax Credits Serve as a Safety Net? Marianne Bitler Department of Economics, UC Davis and NBER

The Impact of Minimum Wage Increases on Single Mothers. By Joseph J. Sabia University of Georgia August 2007

Evaluation of Four Tax Reforms in the United States: Labor Supply and Welfare Effects for Single Mothers

Empirical Evidence and Tax Reform: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

The Effects of Welfare Reform and Related Policies on Single Mothers Welfare Use and Employment in the 1990s

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE INTEGRATION OF CHILD TAX CREDITS AND WELFARE: EVIDENCE FROM THE NATIONAL CHILD BENEFIT PROGRAM

Families, Taxes and the Welfare System

Average Earnings and Long-Term Mortality: Evidence from Administrative Data

LECTURE: MEDICAID HILARY HOYNES UC DAVIS EC230 OUTLINE OF LECTURE: 1. Overview of Medicaid. 2. Medicaid expansions

Tuning unemployment insurance to the business cycle Unemployment insurance generosity should be greater when unemployment is high and vice versa

The EITC: What Have Economists Learned? Kartik Athreya, Dec 8 th, 2014

The EITC and Employment Transitions: Labor Force Attachment, Annual Exit, and the Role of Information

Taxation of Earnings and the Impact on Labor Supply and Human Capital. Discussion by Henrik Kleven (LSE)

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review

ECONOMETRIC ISSUES IN ESTIMATING THE BEHAVIORAL RESPONSE TO TAXATION: A NONTECHNICAL INTRODUCTION ROBERT K. TRIEST *

Working Papers Series

Chart Book: TANF at 20

Optimal Labor Income Taxation. Thomas Piketty, Paris School of Economics Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley PE Handbook Conference, Berkeley December 2011

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE MORE THINGS CHANGE, THE MORE THEY STAY THE SAME? THE SAFETY NET AND POVERTY IN THE GREAT RECESSION

Does It Pay to Move from Welfare to Work? Reply to Robert Moffitt and Katie Winder

Simulating the Effect of the Great Recession on Poverty. Emily Monea and Isabel Sawhill 1. September 10, 2009

Deficit Reduction Act s Effect on the Working Poor

The Effects of Medicaid Earnings Limits on Earnings Growth Among Poor Workers. Sarah Hamersma University of Florida 9/3/07

by sheldon danziger and rucker c. johnson

THE INTERACTION OF METROPOLITAN COST-OF-LIVING AND THE FEDERAL EARNED INCOME TAX CREDIT: ONE SIZE FITS ALL? Katie Fitzpatrick and Jeffrey P.

Disincentive Effects of Unemployment Benefits and the Role of Caseworkers

Evaluation of Four Tax Reforms in the United States: Labor Supply and Welfare Effects for Single Mothers

The EITC and Employment Transitions: Labor Force Attachment, Annual Exit, and the Role of Information

The current study builds on previous research to estimate the regional gap in

The Effect of Unemployment Benefits on the Duration of. Unemployment Insurance Receipt: New Evidence from a

A DECADE OF WELFARE REFORM: FACTS AND FIGURES

Married Women s Labor Force Participation and The Role of Human Capital Evidence from the United States

What You Don t Know Can t Help You: Knowledge and Retirement Decision Making

Few public policy issues receive greater attention than the

The More Things Change, the More They Stay the Same: The Safety Net, Living Arrangements, and Poverty in the Great Recession

Optimal Income Taxation with Unemployment and Wage Responses: A Sufficient Statistics

Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records

The Employment, Earnings, and Income of Single Mothers in Wisconsin Who Left Cash Assistance: Comparisons among Three Cohorts. Daniel R.

Introduction. Many of the papers included are preliminary and subject to revision - please contact the author before quoting or citing.

EITC and South Carolina. Jessica Hennessey Assistant Professor of Economics Furman University May 21, 2015

Dynamic Analysis of EITC Expansion

WHY ARE OLDER WORKERS AT GREATER RISK OF DISPLACEMENT?

Two New Indexes Offer a Broad View of Economic Activity in the New York New Jersey Region

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

)*+,($&''( -#./))0 1!!7#8".1.8.!"3

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: Tax Policy and the Economy, Volume 20

Redistributiontoward Low Incomes inricher Countries

Recent Extensions of U.S. Unemployment Benefits: Search Responses in Alternative Labor Market States

Health Insurance Tax Credits and Health Insurance Coverage of Low-Earning Single Mothers

Transcription:

The Welfare Effects of Welfare and Tax Reform during the Great Recession PROJECT DESCRIPTION - PRELIMINARY Kavan Kucko Johannes F. Schmieder Boston University Boston University, NBER, and IZA October 2012 Abstract Recent decades have witnessed a large shift in the U.S. tax and transfer system away from unconditional transfers to aid the poor towards making transfers and tax credits conditional on working. In particular for single mothers incentives to work increased dramatically through the Welfare reform in 1997 and the stepwise expansion of the Earned Income Tax Credits (EITC). In this research project we investigate whether the shift towards making transfers conditional on working comes with costs during deep recessions, such as the 2008/2009 recession, when labor markets are particularly bad. In such an environment the targeted population may be unable to find jobs at all and thus rather than moving people from non-employment to employment, making benefits conditional on working only leads to large cuts in transfers to the affected (very poor) population. To analyze this we use data from the CPS and state-year level variation in taxes and transfers to measure how labor supply elasticities vary with the economic environment and show how these estimates can be used to determine how the design of the optimal tax and transfer system depends on labor market conditions. We would like to thank Kevin Lang, Claudia Olivetti, Daniele Paserman, as well as seminar participants at Boston University for many helpful comments on this project. All errors are our own. kavan.kucko@gmail.com johannes@bu.edu

1 Project Description The two decades between the mid-1980s and early 2000s have witnessed a large shift in the U.S. tax and transfer system away from unconditional transfers to aid the poor towards making transfers and tax credits conditional on working. In particular for single mothers incentives to work increased dramatically: welfare benefits were cut and time limits introduced, the Earned Income Tax Credits was expanded and changes in Medicaid, training programs and child care provision encouraged work. The literature evaluating these policy changes seems to largely view them as successful. On the one hand the reforms sharply reduced welfare caseloads and increased labor force participation of single Mothers (e.g. Eissa and Liebman 1996, Meyer and Rosenbaum 2001, and Eissa and Hoynes 2006) while on the other hand consumption levels have slightly increased or remained the same (Meyer and Sullivan 2004, 2008) over the 1990 and early 2000s. Furthermore within an optimal income taxation framework, the various tax policy changes seem to have had a substantially positive effect on welfare (see Eissa, Kleven and Kreiner 2008). It is important to note however, that these policy evaluations are all based mainly on experiences from the 1990s and early 2000s when the economy was performing quite well and unemployment rates were declining dramatically or at least remained at historically relatively low levels (even the peak of the 2003 recession had unemployment at only 6.3 percent). Since 2008, the economic environment has changed dramatically with unemployment rising above 10 percent and remaining high for a prolonged period of time. This raises a potential concern: Increasing the returns to work, by making transfers and tax credits conditional on working, may be an effective tool to increase labor force participation when it is relatively easy for single mothers to enter the labor force and find jobs. However, when there are no jobs available then making transfers conditional on working may not lead to increased employment but instead may sharply reduce consumption and 1

wellbeing of the targeted population. In this case it may in fact be preferable to have the design of transfers to the poor depend on the state of the business cycle, with less work requirements during economic downturns and more work incentives during upswings. In this paper we address this concern by assessing how the optimal tradeoff between unconditional transfers and providing work incentives through conditionality depends on the economic environment. Building on prior theory (e.g. Saez 2002), we show that the optimal tradeoff depends on how extensive and intensive labor supply elasticities vary with the economic environment. 1 This is in spirit of the recent focus in public finance on describing optimal policy in a sufficient statistics framework, which allows for directly linking policies to statistics that are easily estimated in the data (see Chetty 2009). Using data from the Current Population Survey (CPS) and state-year level variation in welfare policies (AFDC, TANF, SNAP and Medicaid), as well as state and federal income taxes (incl. EITC) for over 20 years, we estimate how the labor supply effects of these programs vary with state unemployment rates. The implied labor supply elasticities can then be used to calculate how the tax and transfer reforms have affected overall welfare during the 2008 and 2009 recession. This paper is also closely related to recent research on whether the generosity of unemployment benefits should vary over the business cycle. Unemployment benefits create a similar problem as traditional welfare benefits in that they provide transfers that are conditional on not working (or at least are at their maximum) and thus provide incentives not to work, while at the same time providing important insurance against hardship. Just as in the optimal taxation literature, the efficiency loss from providing unemployment insurance (UI) is inversely related to the labor supply elasticities. Schmieder, von Wachter and Bender (2012), Landais, Michaillat, and Saez (2010), Kroft and Notowidigdo (2011) derive welfare formulas where the marginal effect of increasing the generosity of unemployment benefits depends on the elasticity of unemployment durations with respect to the benefit generosity. 1 Saez (2002) extends the Mirrlees (1971) and Diamond (1980) framework to show that for optimal policy the tradeoff between conditional and unconditional transfers depends on the relative magnitude of extensive versus intensive margin labor supply elasticities. However, while a large literature has estimated these effects, little is known about the cyclicality of these elasticities. 2

These papers provide evidence that the labor supply elasticities determining the optimal benefit durations (Schmieder et al.) and levels (Landais et al. and Kroft and Notowidigdo) decline during recessions and that the generosity of the UI system should therefore increase during a recession. 2 Preliminary Evidence Previous work (Saez, 2002) shows that the optimal tax and transfer schedule, especially towards the lower end of the income distribution, depends critically on the magnitudes of two elasticities: the extensive elasticity, or the propensity to leave or enter the workforce in response to potential income changes, and the intensive elasticity, the propensity to adjust the number of hours worked in response to changes in the marginal tax rate implied by the tax schedule. A sizable unconditional transfer phased out with high marginal tax rates is optimal when the intensive elasticity is large and the extensive elasticity is small. The high phase out rates limits the number of individuals exposed to the incentive to reduce hours worked provided by the high marginal tax rate. When the extensive elasticity is high and the intensive is low, a negative marginal rate may be optimal since it encourages people who where not working into the labor force without encouraging higher wage earners to reduce hours. We hypothesize that the elasticities fluctuate with changes in the labor market, implying that the optimal tax and transfer schedule should adjust with labor market conditions. To support this hypothesis we first look the EITC reform that began in 1993. Figure 1 plots the maximum EITC benefits depending on the number of children in the household. The highlighted region, 1992-1997 contains a major expansion of EITC benefits, especially for individuals with children. Figure 2 plots labor force participation rates for single women with children across the highlighted timeframe. The first row considers all single mothers with children, the second row isolates the subsample of single mothers in states with low unemployment and the third column considers only the subsample of single mothers in 3

states with relatively high unemployment rates. Single mothers with lower education tend to be those that are affected most by changes in EITC. As expected, women with higher education tend to be working at higher rates. Across all samples we see increased labor force participation by the lower educated women relative to women with higher education. The narrowing employment gap could be in part due to the increased incentives resulting from the EITC changes. The employment gap narrows to a much greater extent in the states with low unemployment than in high unemployment states. Furthermore, the greatest narrowing of the employment gap for high unemployment states occurs only after average unemployment in those states dips below a historically modest 6 percent. This relationship is consistent with our hypothesis that individuals are more responsive to changes in work incentives when labor market conditions are favorable. Regression analysis confounds the relationship in Figure 2. Table 1 reports the results of a linear probability model of the following specification: Employed i = β 1 MaxEIT C i + β 2 State Unemp i + β 3 MaxEIT C State Unemp + γx i + ε i Where Employed i equals one if the individual reported working at all in the previous year, MaxEIT C i is the maximum EITC benefit individual i could have received in the same year given their family composition and State Unemp is the state unemployment rate. X i is a vector of observable characteristics including, at a minimum the number of children individual i has. Standard errors are clustered at the state level to control for correlation of employment at the state level. Columns one and two display results when using the entire sample of single women from 1980-1997. We truncate at 1997 here because there is little variation in EITC benefits after 1997 and other (currently) unobserved explanatory variables are changing significantly, for instance the switch from AFDC to TANF. This timeframe allows us to exploit changes in EITC benefit levels from the tax reform act of 1986 as well as the variation in EITC benefits through the early 1990s. The first two columns 4

report results for all single women. The second column contains controls for education and race. As expected, individuals with higher potential EITC benefits tend to be employed at higher rates. The higher the unemployment rate in an individuals state, the lower the probability that individual is working. Importantly, the interaction term is both negative and signifiant. The regressions suggest that an increase in EITC benefits increases the probability individuals work, but the effect diminishes with higher state unemployment. Column three restricts the sample to individuals with twelve or fewer years of education. Individuals in this sample are more likely to have lower potential earnings, and therefor exhibit a higher probability of EITC eligibility. Notice that the coefficients on EITC, state unemployment and the interaction term all remain significant and in the direction predicted by theory. Column four, on the other hand, contains estimates generated from a sample of single women with at least 16 years of education. These women are likely to have at least a bachelors degree and therefore a higher potential wage. An individual in this sample is less likely to be eligible for EITC benefits. Indeed, we find that the coefficient on EITC benefits, and the interaction term are no longer significant. It also appears that higher educated single mothers are more insulated from cyclical employment fluctuations as evidenced by the insignificant coefficient on state unemployment. 3 Proposed Research In his 2002 paper, Saez derives optimal tax schedules that depend on the intensive and extensive elasticities of labor supply. Related work shows that welfare gains from changes to the tax schedule also depend on these elasticities (Eissa, Kleven and Kreiner 2008). Our preliminary evidence suggests a variable extensive labor elasticities across labor market conditions, which supports a flexible tax and transfer schedule. Specifically, since the extensive elasticity appears to decline during times of high unemployment, the optimal tax schedule should shift some resources from transfers conditional on work to an unconditional transfer, assuming the intensive elasticity changes little. However one cannot estimate the degree to which 5

the tax schedule should change without estimating the magnitude of the elasticities. The regressions in table 1 shed light on with EITC benefits. is P r(employed i) (w i w 0 ) w i w o P r(employed i ) P r(employed), how the probability of employment changes maxeit C However, the relevant extensive elasticity for optimal tax schedules where w i is the potential income net of taxes and transfers if individual i works and w 0 is the net of transfer income to individual i if they do not work. Furthermore, the intensive elasticity, HoursW orked MarginalRate MarginalRate HoursW orked depends on the marginal tax rate. While the CPS contains information on pre-tax wage earnings and hours worked, it does not contain information on the marginal tax rate of wage earners nor the value tax liability (or transfer) regardless of work status. To estimate the intensive and extensive elasticities, we propose using a tax and benefit calculator to estimate post-tax and transfer earnings (w i for each i) and the value of individual i s outside option of not working (w 0 ). Models such as the Urban Institute s TRIM3 are capable of this type of calculation. Related work routinely make use of tax and transfer calculators (see Eissa and Hoynes, 2006 or Eissa, Kelven and Kreiner, 2008 for example). The estimation could be done in one of two ways: at the observational level of the CPS data, or by creating representative agents. First, we would like to consider each observation in our CPS data set and calculate the net value of the benefits and tax liability that each individual is eligible for given their level of earnings, number of children, state of residence, and so forth. Then we would like to re-evaluate the benefit levels and tax liabilities for a series of hypothetical earnings, while holding all other observed characteristics constant. For each observation we would like to calculate the value of benefits at all income levels, perhaps in $100 increments. Alternatively, we could hold hourly wages constant and vary the number of hours worked. From these estimates, the goal is to construct menu of posttax-and-transfer income levels the individual could choose from if she could precisely choose her pre-tax earnings level. Second, we would like to run similar simulations for a set of representative agents instead of individual CPS observations. An example representative agent might be a single mother 6

of two in Wisconsin in 1997. We could fabricate a data set in which each observation is a representative individual and fill in all of the requisite variables for a tax and benefit calculator. The resulting output would give us after-tax-and-transfer income at the given pre-tax earnings level. Then we could re-run the simulation across all levels of pre-tax earnings. Aggregating and plotting the pre-tax earnings, post-tax income estimate pairs from the from the benefit calculator would result in a unique budget set for each of the representative individuals. Each of the the individuals in our CPS sample could then be mapped to the representative agent s budget set that most closely resembles the observable characteristics of the CPS individual. Hypothetical potential wages for those who report not working could be imputed using a Heckman selection model. For those that do report earnings, we will have an estimate for their income if they choose not to work, w 0, from the tax-benefit calculator as well. Then a regression of the form log(p r(employed)) = α 1 log(w i w 0 )+α 2 StateUnemp+α 3 log(w i w 0 ) StateUnemp+γX i +ε i form yields and estimate of the extensive elasticity of labor supply. While a regression of the log(hoursw orked) = β 1 log(marginalrate) + β 2 StateUnemp +β 3 log(marginalrate) StateUnemp + γx i + ε i yields and estimate of the intensive elasticity of labor supply. Estimates for α 3 and β 3 will describe the degree to which the elasticities change across the business cycle. From these estimates we can calculate the degree to which the optimal tax and transfer schedule should change as labor market conditions evolve through business cycles. 7

4 Conclusion Recent changes in the tax code and welfare legislation shifted a substantial amount of transfers from non-working individuals to low income individuals. The resulting negative effective marginal tax rates create work incentives that have been shown to be welfare improving in some settings, specifically when the labor supply elasticity along the participation margin is large relative to the intensive elasticity. When unemployment is high it may be more difficult for non-working individuals to respond to work incentives compared to a low unemployment environment. We propose a study of the intensive and extensive elasticities across cyclical changes in the labor market. Our results could provide insight regarding how responsive a tax and transfer schedule should be labor market conditions. 8

References Blundell, Richard, Alan Duncan, and Costas Meghir, Estimating Labor Supply Responses Using Tax Reforms, Econometrica, 66 (4), (1998), pp. 827-861. Chetty, Raj, Sufficient Statistics for Welfare Analysis: A Bridge Between Structural and Reduced-Form Methods, Annu. Rev. Econ., 1 (1), (2009), 451 488. Diamond, Peter, Income taxation with fixed hours of work, Journal of Public Economics, 13 (1), (1980), 101 110. Eissa, N., H.J. Kleven, and C.T. Kreiner, Evaluation of four tax reforms in the United States: Labor supply and welfare effects for single mothers, Journal of Public Economics, 92 (3), (2008), 795 816. Eissa, Nada and Hilary W. Hoynes, Behavioral Responses to Taxes: Lessons from the EITC and Labor Supply, Tax Policy and the Economy, 20 (2006), pp. 73-110. and Jeffrey B. Liebman, Labor Supply Response to the Earned Income Tax Credit, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111 (2), (1996), pp. 605-637. Kroft, K. and M.J. Notowidigdo, Should unemployment insurance vary with the unemployment rate? Theory and evidence, Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research (2011). Landais, C., P. Michaillat, and E. Saez, Optimal unemployment insurance over the business cycle, Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research (2010). Meyer, B.D. and J.X. Sullivan, The effects of welfare and tax reform: the material well-being of single mothers in the 1980s and 1990s, Journal of Public Economics, 88 (7), (2004), 1387 1420. Meyer, Bruce D. and Dan T. Rosenbaum, Welfare, the Earned Income Tax Credit, and the Labor Supply of Single Mothers, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116 (3), (2001), pp. 1063-1114. and James X. Sullivan, Changes in the Consumption, Income, and Well-Being of Single Mother Headed Families, The American Economic Review, 98 (5), (2008), pp. 2221-2241. Mirrlees, J. A., An Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Income Taxation, The Review of Economic Studies, 38 (2), (1971), pp. 175-208. Saez, Emmanuel, Optimal Income Transfer Programs: Intensive versus Extensive Labor Supply Responses, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (3), (2002), pp. 1039-1073. Schmieder, J.F., T. Von Wachter, and S. Bender, The Effects of Extended Unemployment Insurance Over the Business Cycle: Evidence from Regression Discontinuity Estimates Over 20 Years, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127 (2), (2012), 701 752. 9

Table 1: The Effect of the Earned Income Tax Credit on the Probability of Working (1980-1997) Dependent Variable: (1) (2) (3) (4) Worked in Previous Year All All HS or Less Bachelor or More Maximum EITC in 0.063 0.046 0.039 0.0059 1000 Real USD (0.0087) (0.0077) (0.0098) (0.0060) State unemployment rate -0.0089-0.0062-0.012-0.00075 (0.0015) (0.0012) (0.0020) (0.00052) EITC Max*State Unemployment -0.0080-0.0057-0.0043-0.00024 (0.0015) (0.0013) (0.0016) (0.0010) 1 Child -0.14-0.069-0.077-0.019 (0.015) (0.011) (0.013) (0.0092) 2 Children -0.22-0.12-0.13-0.030 (0.020) (0.014) (0.015) (0.011) 3+ Children -0.38-0.21-0.21-0.073 (0.026) (0.017) (0.014) (0.017) Other Income (1000s) -0.011-0.028-0.0024 (0.00062) (0.0022) (0.00037) HS Dropout -0.22-0.20 (0.0092) (0.0073) Some College 0.072 (0.0037) Bachelors Degree 0.079 (0.0041) Post Bachelors (edu 16) 0.073 0.0040 (0.0040) (0.0019) Non-white -0.090-0.13-0.024 (0.0063) (0.0078) (0.0035) Hispanic -0.063-0.090-0.022 (0.021) (0.025) (0.0041) Constant 1.38 1.81 2.22 0.90 (0.093) (0.090) (0.13) (0.11) Observations 180802 180802 91134 34527 R 2 0.100 0.215 0.208 0.022 Standard errors clustered at the state level (* P<.05, ** P<.01). Year fixed effects are included in all specifications. Maximum EITC benefit data is from the Tax Policy center. EITC benefit levels depend on the number of children in the household, income and vary across years. EITC data is lagged one year to match the employment data. The dependent variable equals one if reported weeks worked last year is greater than zero. 10

Figure 1: Maximum EITC benefits Real 2000$ Thds. 0 2 4 6 1980 1990 2000 2010 No Children 1 Child 2 Children 3 Children Notes: EITC benefit data are from the Tax Policy Center. 11

Figure 2: Rates of Employment: Single Mothers All States Low Unemployment States High Unemployment States Rate of Employment.6.65.7.75.8.85.9.95 1 4 6 8 10 12 14 Unemployment Rate Rate of Employment.6.65.7.75.8.85.9.95 1 4 6 8 10 12 14 Unemployment Rate Rate of Employment.6.65.7.75.8.85.9.95 1 4 6 8 10 12 14 Unemployment Rate 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Tax Year 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Tax Year 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Tax Year Low Education High Education Low Education High Education Low Education High Education Unemployment Rate Unemployment Rate Unemployment Rate All States Low Unemployment States (Difference) High Unemployment States (Difference) Difference.1.15.2.25.3.35 Difference.1.15.2.25.3.35 Difference.1.15.2.25.3.35 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Tax Year 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Tax Year 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Tax Year Notes: The time frame corresponds tot he grey area in Figure 1. Low education is defined as twelve or fewer years of schooling. High education is defined as 16 or more years of schooling. The unemployment rate is the average state unemployment rate in the sample. 12