Macro Vision November 23, 2017

Similar documents
Macro Vision February 20, 2017

FX and Capital Markets

FX and Capital Markets

FX and Capital Markets

Macro Vision June 13, 2017

Macro Vision October 2, 2017

Macro Vision December 12, 2016

Brazil: FX and Capital Markets Highlights of the Week

Brazil: FX and Capital Markets Highlights of the Week

Macro Brazil July 21, 2017

Macro Research Economic outlook

Electoral Polls: Datafolha

Daniel Scioli leads the race to the presidency in October, but a runoff with Mauricio Macri in November is likely.

Macro Vision December 16, 2016

Macro Vision June 13, 2017

Public Sector Posts a Primary Deficit in May

Sector Insights. Autos. Sales Performance Remains Strong. Passenger Cars and Light Commercial Vehicles

Macro Research Economic outlook

Macro Vision July 25, 2016

Macro Research Economic outlook

Commodities Monthly Review

Brazil Review March 1, 2018

Brazil Review. Depreciation of the Real Sharpens. The Brazilian Economy in March 2015

Global Monetary Policy Monitor

Macro Research Economic outlook

Weakening Fiscal Performance in the 1Q14

Scenario Review - Brazil

Scenario Review - Brazil

Commodities Monthly Review

IU-MCI measures the market conditions and is also a good leading indicator of economic growth in the country, as indicated by econometric exercises.

Macro Vision June 13, 2018

Commodities Monthly Review

Global Monetary Policy Monitor

Macro Vision August 30, 2017

Brazil Review June 1, 2018

Markets Stabilize, GDP Grows 2.3% in 2013

Brazil Review March 1, 2017

Real Estate The pace of sales continues to fall in the residential market. The number of launches came down, but inventories remain high.

Released last Friday, industrial production came at 3.57% year-on-year in August, weaker than market estimates (3.8) and higher than our call (2.5).

Global Monetary Policy Monitor

The peace deal advances, while the economy slows

Macro Vision. Uncertain Recoupling Road for Latin America

Labor Market, Production Costs and Prices Faced with low growth, the appetite for hiring is low, and more sectors are announcing forced vacations.

Scenario Review Chile

Global Monetary Policy Monitor

Global Monetary Policy Monitor

Emerging Markets Debt: Outlook for the Asset Class

Sector Insights. Brazil s Steel Industry: Still a Challenging Scenario Ahead

Macro Vision August 4, 2017

Latin America: the shadow of China

Economic activity gathers pace

Brazil Currency Perspectives

Recovery Disappoints, Real Depreciates

Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy

Economic Outlook January, 2012

Economic Outlook. Macro Research Itaú Unibanco

Scenario Review - Brazil

Brazil Review. Rising Concerns about Inflation. The Brazilian economy in February 2013

Meeting with Analysts

Executive Directors welcomed the continued

Olivier Blanchard Economic Counsellor and Director of the Research Department, International Monetary Fund

Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy Responses to the Global Financial Crisis: The Case of Colombia

Macro Research Economic outlook

Outlook for the Chilean Economy

Monetary Policy under Fed Normalization and Other Challenges

Monetary Policy Statement: March 2010

Eurozone Economic Watch Higher growth forecasts for January 2018

W-3 Monetary Policy in IT Regimes: Chile in the Aftermath of the Financial Crisis

Quarterly Currency Outlook

Latin America Outlook. 1st QUARTER 2018


Czech Koruna and the Economic Outlook

Saudi Arabian economy Moderation in 2013 and rebound in 2014

Eurozone. Economic Watch FEBRUARY 2017

Eurozone Economic Watch. July 2018

Market Bulletin. Earnings will set you free. October 20, In brief. The benefits of breadth

LATIN AMERICA OUTLOOK 4Q2016 OUTLOOK LATIN AMERICA. 4th QUARTER 2016

LatAm Talking Points: Brazilian Economic Activity Edges Up in October

Economic policy-making in a small and open economy the case of Suriname

Inflation Report. January March 2013

Eurozone Economic Watch. May 2018

FOMC preview: Status quo on expected lines

Quarterly Economic Outlook: Quarter on 25 September 2018 Strong Economic Expansions amidst Uncertainty of Trade War

The Argentine Economy in the year 2006

Europe Outlook. Third Quarter 2015

Global growth fragile: The global economy is projected to grow at 3.5% in 2019 and 3.6% in 2020, 0.2% and 0.1% below October 2018 projections.

Appendix: Analysis of Exchange Rates Pursuant to the Act

On public finances; On financial asset prices; The risks seem to come from:

Flash Economics. 11 January

Macro Focus. From austerity to growth? 30 May Group Economics Macro Research

Hong Kong Economic Update

Inflation Targeting Under a Crawling Band Exchange Rate Regime: Lessons from Israel

Karnit Flug: Macroeconomic policy and the performance of the Israeli economy

Mexico s Macroeconomic Outlook and Monetary Policy

Saudi Arabian economy

Market E-digest October 2018 Issue

Governor Central Bank of Argentina

International Monetary Fund. World Economic Outlook. Jörg Decressin Senior Advisor Research Department, IMF

19.2 Exchange Rates in the Long Run Introduction 1/24/2013. Exchange Rates and International Finance. The Nominal Exchange Rate

Transcription:

Macro Vision November 23, 217 Argentina Facing the moderate inflation challenge While the Central Bank of Argentina has made progress in fighting inflation since 21, consumer prices continue expanding at a rate far above the target, in spite of higher (and rising) real interest rates. The international experience shows that countries that have ended moderate inflation (defined as inflation that persists for at least three years in the 15-3 range) used a mix of policies, and there is no evident growth cost during the disinflation process. The nominal exchange rate has almost always been used as anchor. However, as exchange-rate-based stabilization programs often lead to real exchange-rate appreciation, the conditions for adopting an exchange-rate anchor in Argentina are not there: the wide current-account deficit indicates that there is not much room for real exchange-rate gains. In addition, net reserves seem too low to defend a peg, should that become necessary. In the absence of help from the exchange rate, Argentina could usefully add faster fiscal-policy tightening to its anti-inflationary toolkit. Income policies, such as those guiding wage agreements, could also help, but are no substitute for credible macro policies. In addition authorities should use potential exogenous shocks as an opportunity to bring inflation down faster, as many countries that ended moderate inflation have done. How did we get here? Inflation in Argentina fluctuated between 15 and 3 in the period from 27-215, with an average of 25. Inflation would have been even higher if it were not for the frozen regulated prices and other price controls implemented during the second term of Cristina Kirchner. Persistently lax fiscal and monetary policies were the factors responsible for the high inflation. In fact, general government expenditures as a proportion of GDP increased from 22.7 in 23 to 1.7 in 215, with a turnaround of the fiscal balance, from a 1.2 of GDP surplus to a 5.9 deficit. Real interest rates were negative throughout this period. In fact, the Badlar rate (a 1- month wholesale deposit rate paid by private banks) averaged -. in real terms between 23 to 215. 2-2 Lax Policies led to high inflation in Argentina Inflation (yoy) Badlar rate in real terms (rhs) General government expenditures ( of GDP) 23 25 27 29 211 213 215 Source: Bloomberg, Haver and Itaú -2-3 -5 - - -9-11 -12-1 -15 Please refer to the last page of this report for important disclosures, analyst and additional information. Itaú Unibanco or its subsidiaries may do or seek to do business with companies covered in this research report. As a result, investors should be aware that the firm may have a conflict of interest that could affect the objectivity of this report. Investors should not consider this report as the single factor in making their investment decision.

Macro Vision November 23, 217 A new and reformist administration took office in December 215 and made single-digit inflation one of its goals. Exchange-rate controls were quickly removed and the central bank adopted an inflation-targeting framework with a floating exchange-rate, a policy regime that has been tried and tested in the region. A reference monetary-policy rate was chosen (initially the yield of the short-term sterilization bill, the 3-day Lebac and then the 7-day repo rate). The inflation target was set at 12-17 for 217, 1 +/- 2 for 21, and 5 +/- 1.5 in 219. With the liberalization of exchange-rate and unfreezing of utility prices, inflation spiked, peaking at 7.2 (YoY) in July 21. Monetary policy has been tightened substantially, and the ex-ante real policy rate currently stands at 13. (using annualized core inflation expectations for the next three months). However, as the government also sought to reduce the tax burden on the economy (in particular on exporters), fiscal policy has not been tightened: the primary and nominal fiscal deficits remained broadly unchanged between 215 and 21 (in spite of heavy reductions in the subsidy bill), while in 217 a one-off boost to revenues from the tax-amnesty bill is contributing to narrow the fiscal deficit. To be sure, Argentina has made progress in fighting inflation since the new administration stepped in. Headline inflation in Greater Buenos Aires area is currently at 22.9 year over year, while the three-month annualized core inflation a measure that excludes prices that exhibit seasonality and regulated items is at 19. So inflation is currently below the average level it was during Cristina Kirchner s second term (29.2) in spite of rapid price liberalization. Inflation expectations and the exchange rate helped in this process. The real bilateral exchange rate is significantly stronger than it was right after the new government let the peso float, and 12-month-forward inflation expectations have consistently run below current inflation since the central bank started to publish surveys with market analysts in mid-21. 5 Expectations helped to contain inflation Inflation (YoY) Core inflation 3mma (annualized) 12-month inflation expectations 3 2 1 Jun-1 Oct-1 Feb-17 Jun-17 Oct-17 Source: BCRA, Itaú Still, these inflation levels remain far above the ambitious targets set by the central bank. A tight monetary policy has not been able, or has not been able yet, to bring inflation below 2. At the same time, in spite of high real interest rates, economic and credit growth have been strong, as confidence improves with the power consolidation of a market-friendly administration. Moreover, Argentina s inflation stands out in a world of subdued price pressures, even in Latin America, a region long plagued by inflationary problems and monetary instability. Current price pressures in Argentina are a stark outlier and erode its global competitiveness. Page 2

Macro Vision November 23, 217 Anti-inflation tools According to Dornbusch and Fischer`s (1993) classic analysis, moderate inflation is characterized as an inflationary process that persists for at least three years in the 15-3 annualized range. As Burton and Fischer (199) put it, moderate inflation can be beaten, but there is no single magic formula. Countries that have ended moderate inflation used a mix of fiscal, monetary, exchange-rate and income policies, and many opportunistically used exogenous shocks to reduce inflation. Fiscal and monetary policies affect inflation not only because of their impact on aggregate demand. Both fiscal and monetary policies also have an effect on domestic prices by influencing exchange-rate and inflation expectations, although in the case of fiscal policy, the impact could be non-linear (that is, only when the fiscal balance or public debt reaches worrying levels, fiscal policy has the capacity to alter the exchange-rate path and inflation expectations). Exchange-rate anchors have also been used as tools to reduce inflation from high or moderate levels in many cases. One issue with this approach is that the exchange-rate anchors are often not fully credible at first, meaning that the central banks adopting them face higher inflation (at least in the initial stages of stabilization) than would be justified by inflation abroad and the productivity growth differential. This residual inflation leads to real exchange-rate appreciation and a widening of the current-account deficit. This is why exchange-rate pegs typically work if set when the real exchange rate is undervalued; in these cases, real appreciation does not lead to a balance-of-payment problem. Policy makers can also use exogenous shocks as an opportunity to anchor inflation at lower levels. This is the so-called opportunistic approach to disinflation. A boom of capital inflows, unforeseen recessions, positive supply or terms-of-trade shocks, and reforms (such as trade liberalization) are all examples of events that policy makers can use to permanently reduce inflation. Of course, this strategy deprives the authorities of much control over the timing of the disinflation process. Income policies, such as wage agreements and temporary price freezes, are quite unlikely to work on their own, but experience shows that they can be part of a stabilization strategy. A problem with price freezes is that they may foster the view that disinflation is temporary, lasting only while the sector freezes are in place. Moreover, reliance of the previous administration on price controls might exacerbate this credibility shortfall. How moderate inflation ended in other countries Burton and Fischer (199) explore five examples of countries that ended moderate inflation between the late s and early 9s (Chile, Egypt, Iceland, Kenya and Paraguay). Except for Kenya, the countries in this study resorted to exchange-rate anchors (although in the Chilean case the effectiveness of the anchor is unclear, as it aimed at the real exchange rate, not the nominal rate). In many cases monetary policy had a supporting role, often subordinated to exchange-rate management. In Kenya, there was no exchange-rate peg, but the currency seems to have helped in the disinflation process anyway, as monetary-policy tightening contributed to attract inflows and the real exchange rate strengthened. In Egypt and Kenya, the fall of inflation was accompanied by significant fiscal tightening, while in Paraguay and Chile a prudent fiscal policy (general government surpluses) was already in place before the disinflation process started. In Iceland, Chile and Paraguay, exogenous factors played an important role in the disinflation process. A slump in the Icelandic fishing industry drastically reduced growth, helping to cool inflationary pressures. In Paraguay, a strong harvest brought food inflation down sharply. In Chile, productivity-enhancing reforms and an improvement in terms of trade helped. The end of moderate inflation in Iceland also got a hand from income policies (wage agreements). Importantly, these five countries experiences indicate that there is no obvious ex-post growth cost from disinflation, as in many countries growth remained robust throughout the period when inflation was falling to below-moderate levels. Page 3

Macro Vision November 23, 217 Since then, other examples of countries that managed to end moderate inflation have emerged. Colombia, for instance, ended moderate inflation in two stages. In the first stage, disinflation seems to have resulted from a capital-inflow boom (partly related to financial liberalization, exploration of new oil fields and privatizations). Inflation fell from 32. to 19.5 between 199 and 1995, as the real effective exchange rate appreciated by around 25 and the current account swung from a surplus to a deficit. During this period, growth remained solid. In the second stage, when capital flows reversed in the late 9s, Colombia experienced a financial crisis, and GDP dropped by.2 in 1999. Inflation converged to single digits (from 1.7 in 199 to 9.2 in 1999) and has not climbed above 1 since then. Our interpretation is that the disinflation process in Colombia followed the opportunistic approach: in the first stage, the opportunity came from a boom in capital inflows, which were at least partly exogenous to macro policies. In the second stage, a non-policy induced recession provided the opportunity to reduce inflation. During the disinflation period, fiscal policy was not a relevant factor for disinflation. The central bank had set inflation targets since the beginning of the 9 s. The exchange rate was managed, but the regime went through many changes until a free floating currency was finally adopted at the end of the 9s. Interestingly, the economic slowdown in Colombia following the global financial crisis in 2 gave the country another opportunity to consolidate inflation at a level closer to the 3 long-term target set in 21: inflation from 29 to 21 averaged 3.7, compared with.2 between 21 and 2. 2-2 - - Disinflation process in Colombia GDP growth Current account balance ( of GDP) Inflation (yoy, rhs) 199 1992 199 199 199 2 22 Source: IMF, Itaú 35 3 25 2 15 1 5 Israel also successfully ended moderate inflation during the 9s. In the early 9s, the central bank adopted a forward-looking crawling peg, based on the projected inflation differential. Only gradually, the band fluctuation limits were widened and the interest-rate policy started to focus on the inflation targets, instead of supporting the exchange-rate regime. Inflation also benefited from an exogenous shock: an immigration boom following the end of the Soviet Union, which created slack in the labor market and put downward pressure on wages. In fact, during the 9s, Israel s population increased by 27 (compared with 1 the previous decade), so the opportunistic approach was a key part of the disinflationary strategy in Israel. Inflation had fallen to levels slightly above 1 (above the 7-1 inflation target) already in 1992, but it was only in 1997 that inflation reached single digits. Page

Macro Vision November 23, 217 2 1 1 1 12 1 2 Immigration helped to bring inflation down in Israel GDP growth (rhs) Population growth (rhs) Inflation 12 1 2 199 1991 1992 1993 199 1995 199 1997 199 1999 Source: IMF, Itaú How to end moderate inflation in Argentina Beating moderate inflation is unlikely to be easy - the gap between current inflation and the 21 target is some ten percentage points. Policy makers need to be willing to tighten macro policies to the point of significantly slowing aggregate demand, even if at the cost of risking a recession, to achieve the targets set by the central bank, even more so if inflationary expectations remain high. Maintaining real interest rates at positive (and high) levels can certainly help to lower inflation expectations, but it is not working as fast as the Argentine authorities would like, and would have activity costs if the authorities selection of the policy mix overburdens monetary policy. Easing monetary policy prematurely, however, would be detrimental to the credibility of the disinflation effort. So, while the room for further tightening may be limited (absent willingness to face a slowdown), there is scant room for early monetary accommodation either. One way to bring inflation expectations down faster is borrowing credibility from another central bank, through exchange rate pegs, as suggested by some prominent Argentine economists. As mentioned above, countries that ended moderate inflation often adopted exchange-rate anchors in their stabilization programs. The problem with such a strategy in the case of Argentina is that the valuation of the exchange rate already seems stretched (we forecast a current-account deficit of.3 of GDP this year) and international reserves are too low to defend a peg (approximately 5 of GDP netting short-term foreign-currency liabilities of the central bank, or 9 in gross terms). So, most likely a peg would not be completely credible: after the exchange-rate anchor is adopted, inflation would be higher than would be justified by inflation abroad and the productivity growth differential, at least for some time, strengthening even more the real exchange rate and worsening the balance of payments even further. Besides the capacity to implement a credible peg, it is widely recognized that Argentina s experience with a fixed exchange-rate regime during the 9s ended badly, turning policy makers, and the society, averse to exchange-rate based stabilization. Page 5

Macro Vision November 23, 217 12 11 1 9 No room for exchange rate appreciation Dec 15=1 of GDP RER Multilateral Current account deficit (RHS) Net International reserves (RHS) 7 5 3 2 1 7 Mar-12 Mar-13 Mar-1 Mar-15 Mar-1 Mar-17 Source: BCRA, Itaú -1 So, without the conditions necessary to adopt an exchange-rate anchor, policy makers could usefully add fiscal-policy tightening to bring inflation down more rapidly. In fact, fiscal consolidation is a key feature in many examples of countries that reduced inflation to single digits. Aggressive fiscal tightening would help not by (or at least not only by) slowing demand fiscal consolidation reduces the probability that the government will rely on monetary financing in the future, therefore contributing to lower inflation expectations. Since Argentina s new administration started, policy makers have emphasized that they would target a gradual reduction of the fiscal deficit. With ample funding availability and poor growth, gradualism was the strategy to maintain political support and ensure governability. In particular, the government targets a primary deficit of.2, 3.2 and 2.2 of GDP for 217, 21 and 219, respectively. Currently, the primary deficit stands at around.9 of GDP once the one-off revenues related to the tax amnesty are excluded. -1-2 of GDP Gradual Fiscal Correction Primary balance Primary balance (excluding tax amnesty) Primary balance targets -3 - -5 - IV-15 II-1 IV-1 II-17 IV-17 II-1 IV-1 II-19 IV-19 Source: Treasury, Itaú A gradual approach to fiscal deficit reduction can be good for protecting short-term growth, but at the cost of credibility. That is, with slower fiscal retrenchment, society tends to doubt that future governments will deliver medium- and long-term fiscal targets. So, inflation expectations fall only gradually, as the targets are effectively delivered. Also, a key source for fiscal adjustment in Argentina is the still-sizable subsidy bill (estimated at 2.5 of GDP this year, while the government plans to bring it to 1 in 219); cutting subsidies creates one-off upward pressure on consumer prices that could make managing inflation expectations difficult. Page

Macro Vision November 23, 217 Finally, the government s recently presented tax-reform proposal will involve fiscal costs (estimated at 1.5 of GDP in five years), even though it will have a positive impact on the investment climate. Thus, the tax proposal may play against reducing the fiscal deficit. 1 1 12 1 An unbalanced policy mix 2 Nominal balance ex-tax amnesty revenues (rhs)* Ex ante real interest rate** Jun-1 Oct-1 Feb-17 Jun-17 Oct-17 * Rolling 12-month as of GDP; ** Using 3-month core inflation expectations Source: Haver, BCRA, Itau -1-2 -3 - -5 - -7 - -9 Considering the political capital the government gained as a result of mid-term elections and the solid activity growth figures, the government could accelerate the pace of fiscal adjustment so as to help contain inflation expectations and support the central bank in its fight against inflation. In this context, there are some welcome initiatives. The government recently agreed with all but one provincial governments to support a fiscal responsibility bill in congress that would cap primary expenditures growth (of provinces and federal government) to zero in real terms. If approved, revenue surprises would boost the primary fiscal result (at least when the expenditure cap is binding) so authorities can potentially deliver fiscal adjustment faster than they are currently targeting. The governors of provinces also agreed to support modifications in the way pensions are readjusted, which could also contribute to reduce fiscal expenditures as a share of GDP. Income policies can help, if inflation expectations are well behaved. Wage agreements in Argentina are arguable a key immediate driver of inflation. Although wage agreements are usually based on past inflation, there is no formal indexation mechanism in Argentina. In this context, the government will try to coordinate the upcoming wage negotiations in a way that agreements are based on expected inflation in 21 rather than on past inflation. Although the strong economy, and some labor union reluctance, would make such an agreement difficult, readjustment triggers can be offered (like in 217): so if actual inflation surprises to the upside, wages would be readjusted. Finally, there is the opportunistic approach. For example, once the government is done with subsidy reductions, inflation for regulated items would fall substantially (in 217 it should contribute three percentage points to headline inflation), providing an opportunity to anchor inflation at lower levels. Negative shocks on activity can also be an opportunity. Reforms (such as the labor reform the government is trying to approve) and trade liberalization can also provide one-off downward pressure on prices and productivity boosts that could help reduce inflation permanently, while increasing growth at the same time. In all, international experience shows that it is possible to end moderate inflation relatively fast with no significant ex-post cost in terms of growth. While in these cases, stabilization packages usually involve the adoption of an exchange-rate anchor, in Argentina it doesn t look like the conditions for a peg are there - the temptation to rely on an exchange rate peg would actually be risky, from a macroeconomic balance viewpoint, given the starting point of an already wide current account deficit. In this context, a mix of other strategies could be used. Besides the Page 7

Macro Vision November 23, 217 already tight monetary policy (and we see no scope for easing in the near term), it is especially important to pursue a credible and faster fiscal consolidation in order to lower inflation expectations. A tight fiscal policy would also contribute to reducing the burden on monetary policy and consequently allow for a lower current-account deficit, which is already hovering near uncomfortable levels. Income policies could support the disinflation process, but evidently would only work, if they work at all, if a credible macro-policy mix is in place. During the disinflation process, authorities should use opportunities created by exogenous factors (such as unforeseen recessions or positive productivity and terms-of-trade shocks) to anchor inflation at lower levels. João Pedro Resende Juan Carlos Barboza REFERENCES: Burton, David and Fischer, Stanley, Ending Moderate Inflations. In Carlo Cottarelli and Gyorgy Szapary (eds.) Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transition Economies. Washington: IMF and National Bank of Hungary, 199. Dornbusch, Rudiger and Fischer, Stanley, Moderate Inflation. The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 7, No. 1, 1993, pp.1-. Macro Research Itaú Mario Mesquita Chief Economist Tel: +5511 37-29 Click here to visit our digital research library. Page

Macro Vision November 23, 217 Relevant Information 1. This report has been prepared and issued by the Macro Research Department of Banco Itaú Unibanco S.A. ( Itaú Unibanco ). This report is not a product of the Equity Research Department of Itaú Unibanco or Itaú Corretora de Valores S.A. and should not be construed as a research report ( relatório de análise ) for the purposes of the article 1 of the CVM Instruction NR. 3, dated July, 21. 2. This report aims at providing macroeconomics information, and does not constitute, and should not be construed as an offer to buy or sell, or a solicitation of an offer to buy or sell any financial instrument, or to participate in any particular trading strategy in any jurisdiction. The information herein is believed to be reliable as of the date on which this report was issued and has been obtained from public sources believed to be reliable. Itaú Unibanco Group does not make any express or implied representation or warranty as to the completeness, reliability or accuracy of such information, nor does this report intend to be a complete statement or summary of the markets or developments referred to herein. Opinions, estimates, and projections expressed herein constitute the current judgment of the analyst responsible for the substance of this report as of the date on which it was issued and are, therefore, subject to change without notice. Itaú Unibanco Group has no obligation to update, modify or amend this report and inform the reader accordingly. 3. The analyst responsible for the production of this report, whose name is highlighted in bold, hereby certifies that the views expressed herein accurately and exclusively reflect his or her personal views and opinions and were prepared independently and autonomously, including from Itaú Unibanco, Itaú Corretora de Valores S.A. and other group companies.. This report may not be reproduced or redistributed to any other person, in whole or in part, for any purpose, without the prior written consent of Itaú Unibanco. Additional information on the financial instruments discussed in this report is available upon request. Itaú Unibanco and/or any other group companies is not, and will not be liable for any investment decisions (or otherwise) based on the information provided herein. Additional Note to reports distributed in: (i) U.K. and Europe: The sole purpose of this material is to provide information only, and it does not constitute or should be construed as a proposal or request to enter into any financial instrument or to participate in any specific business strategy. The financial instruments discussed in this material may not be suitable for all investors, and are directed solely at Eligible Counterparties and Professionals as defined by the Financial Conduct Authority. This material does not take into consideration the objectives, financial situation or specific needs of any particular client. Clients must obtain financial, tax, legal, accounting, economic, credit and market advice on an individual basis, based on their personal characteristics and objectives, prior to making any decision based on the information contained herein. By accessing the material, you confirm that you are aware of the laws in your jurisdiction relating to the provision and sale of financial service products. You acknowledge that this material contains proprietary information and you agree to keep this information confidential. Itau BBA International plc (IBBAInt) exempts itself from any liability for any losses, whether direct or indirect, which may arise from the use of this material, from its content and is under no obligation to update the information contained in this document. Additionally, you confirm that you understand the risks related to the financial instruments discussed in this material. Due to international regulations not all financial instruments/services may be available to all clients. You should be aware of and observe any such restrictions when considering a potential investment decision. Past performance and forecast are not a reliable indicator of future results. The information contained herein has been obtained from internal and external sources and is believed to be reliable as of the date in which this material was issued, however IBBAInt does not make any representation or warranty as to the completeness, reliability or accuracy of information obtained by third parties or public sources. Additional information relative to the financial products discussed in this material is available upon request. Itau BBA International plc registered office is 2th floor, 2 Primrose Street, London, United Kingdom, EC2A 2EW and is authorised by the Prudential Regulation Authority and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority and the Prudential Regulation Authority (FRN 575225) Itau BBA International plc Lisbon Branch is regulated by Banco de Portugal for the conduct of business. Itau BBA International plc has representative offices in France, Germany, Spain which are authorised to conduct limited activities and the business activities conducted are regulated by Banque de France, Bundesanstalt fur Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (BaFin), Banco de España respectively. For any queries please contact your relationship manager; (ii) U.S.A: Itau BBA USA Securities, Inc., a FINRA/SIPC member firm, is distributing this report and accepts responsibility for the content of this report. Any US investor receiving this report and wishing to effect any transaction in any security discussed herein should do so with Itau BBA USA Securities, Inc. at 77 Fifth Avenue, 5th Floor, New York, NY 1153; (iii) Asia: This report is distributed in Hong Kong and Japan by Itaú Asia Securities Limited, which is licensed in Hong Kong by the Securities and Futures Commission for Type 1 (dealing in securities) regulated activity. Itaú Asia Securities Limited accepts all regulatory responsibility for the content of this report. In Hong Kong, any investors wishing to purchase or otherwise deal in the securities covered in this report should contact Itaú Asia Securities Limited at 29th Floor, Two IFC, Finance Street Central, Hong Kong; (iv) Middle East: This report is distributed by Itau Middle East Limited. Itau Middle East Limited is regulated by the Dubai Financial Services Authority and is located at Suite 35, Level 3, Al Fattan Currency House, Dubai International Financial Centre, PO Box 23, Dubai, United Arab Emirates. This material is intended only for Professional Clients (as defined by the DFSA Conduct of Business module) no other persons should act upon it; (v) Brazil: Itaú Corretora de Valores S.A., a subsidiary of Itaú Unibanco S.A authorized by the Central Bank of Brazil and approved by the Securities and Exchange Commission of Brazil, is distributing this report. If necessary, contact the Client Service Center: -3131* (capital and metropolitan areas) or -722-3131 (other locations) during business hours, from 9 a.m. to p.m., Brasilia time. If you wish to re-evaluate the suggested solution, after utilizing such channels, please call Itaú s Corporate Complaints Office: -57-11 (on business days from 9 a.m. to p.m., Brasilia time) or write to Caixa Postal 7., São Paulo-SP, CEP 312-971.* Cost of a local call. Page 9