Trade and Capital Flows: A Financial Frictions Perspective

Similar documents
Trade and Capital Flows: A Financial Frictions Perspective

Trade and Capital Flows: A Financial Frictions Perspective

ON THE ROLE OF FINANCIAL FRICTIONS AND THE SAVING RATE DURING TRADE LIBERALIZATIONS

Advanced International Finance Part 3

Exploding Bubbles In a Macroeconomic Model. Narayana Kocherlakota

Institutional Quality and International Trade

International Trade

An OLG Model of Two-Way Capital Flows: The Role of Financial Development

Financial Development and International Capital Flows

Topic 3: Global Imbalances Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 1: Ricardian Models (I)

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

Substitution in Markusen s Classic Trade and Factor Movement Complementarity Models* Maurice Schiff World Bank and IZA

CAPITAL CONSTRAINTS, TRADE

Stanford Economics 266: International Trade Lecture 8: Factor Proportions Theory (I)

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4

Capital Flows and Asset Prices

A Model of China s State Capitalism

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 5: The Ricardo-Viner and Heckscher-Ohlin Models (Theory I)

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Liquidity, Macroprudential Regulation, and Optimal Policy

Discussion of Chiu, Meh and Wright

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Globalization and Financial Development: A Model of the Dot-Com and the Housing Bubbles

O shoring in a Ricardian World

Lecture 13. Trade in Factors. 2. The Jones-Coelho-Easton two-factor, one-good model.

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions

The International Transmission of Credit Bubbles: Theory and Policy

Capital Flows and Asset Prices. Kosuke Aoki, Gianluca Benigno and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki

The Dynamic Heckscher-Ohlin Model: A diagrammatic analysis

Current Account Adjustment: Some New Theory and Evidence

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

ESSAYS ON TRADE LIBERALIZATION WITH FIRM HETEROGENEITY. Aleksandr Vashchilko. Dissertation. Submitted to the faculty of the

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Income Distribution and Growth under A Synthesis Model of Endogenous and Neoclassical Growth

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL SUPPLY CHAINS AND WAGE INEQUALITY. Arnaud Costinot Jonathan Vogel Su Wang

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERMEDIATION AND ECONOMIC INTEGRATION. Pol Antràs Arnaud Costinot. Working Paper

Heckscher Ohlin Model

1. Borrowing Constraints on Firms The Financial Accelerator

Macro (8701) & Micro (8703) option

Collateral and Amplification

Globalization. University of California San Diego (UCSD) Catherine Laffineur.

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

Lecture 12 International Trade. Noah Williams

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Human Capital, Technology Diffusion and Interdependencies

Midterm Exam International Trade Economics 6903, Fall 2008 Donald Davis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Bernanke and Gertler [1989]

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

A Model with Costly-State Verification

ECON 442: Quantitative Trade Models. Jack Rossbach

Banking across Borders with Heterogeneous Banks

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

A Model with Costly Enforcement

Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DOMESTIC INSTITUTIONS AND THE BYPASS EFFECT OF FINANCIAL GLOBALIZATION. Jiandong Ju Shang-Jin Wei

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Specific factor endowments and trade I

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Factor Endowments. Ricardian model insu cient for understanding objections to free trade.

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I)

MIDDLEMEN MARGINS AND GLOBALIZATION 1

A Model of Financial Intermediation

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

Financial Intermediation and Capital Reallocation

Industrial Structure and Financial Capital Flows

ECONOMICS 723. Models with Overlapping Generations

Topics in Trade: Slides

1 Dynamic programming

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

3. Trade and Development

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Heckscher-Ohlin Theory

1 Two Period Production Economy

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances

Booms and Banking Crises

The Seeds of a Crisis

Chapter 3. National Income: Where it Comes from and Where it Goes

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries

International Economic Issues. The Ricardian Model. Chahir Zaki

International Trade Lecture 3: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Transition to FDI Openness

Bubbles, Money and Liquidity Traps: an Analytical Perspective

Exercise Sheet 3: Short solutions.

Institution-Induced Productivity Differences. and Patterns of International Capital Flows

Transcription:

Trade and Capital Flows: A Financial Frictions Perspective Pol Antràs and Ricardo Caballero Harvard & MIT May 2009 Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 1 / 31

Introduction The process of globalization involves the integration of goods and nancial markets of heterogeneous economies: one central dimension of heterogeneity is nancial development; increasingly important role both in the macro and trade literatures. Rajan and Zingales (1998): nancial underdevelopment a ects di erent sectors di erently. di erences in nancial development can be determinants of comparative advantage. Our question: In such an environment with nancial frictions, how do goods and nancial markets integration interact? We develop a simple 2 2 general-equilibrium model with cross-country variation in nancial development and cross-sectoral variation in nancial dependence. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 2 / 31

Findings Main substantive result: in less nancially developed economies (South), trade and capital mobility are complements. i.e., trade integration raises the incentive for capital to ow into South; this contrasts with the prediction that emerges from standard Heckscher-Ohlin model. Rough Intuition: nancial frictions tend to depress the rental rate of capital, but...... in the presence of cross-sectoral heterogeneity in nancial dependence, specialization allows South to partially circumvent these frictions. Within a dynamic framework, the complementarity carries over to ( nancial) capital ows Implication: global imbalances may be worsened by protectionism. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 3 / 31

Related Literature One-Sector, Macro Models: Gertler and Rogo (1990), Boyd and Smith (1997), Shleifer and Wolfenzon (2002), Reinhart and Rogo (2004), Kraay et al. (2005), Caballero, Farhi and Gourinchas (2006), Aoki, Benigno and Kiyotaki (2007), and Mendoza, Quadrini and Rios-Rull (2007). Financial Development as a Source of Comparative Advantage: Bardhan and Kletzer (1987), Rajan and Zingales (1998), Beck (2002), Matsuyama (2005), Wynne (2005), Ju and Wei (2006), and Manova (2007). Trade and Capital Mobility as Complements: Markusen (1983). Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 4 / 31

Plan of the Talk 1 A Benchmark Static Model with Speci c Functional Forms 1 Closed Economy Equilibrium 2 Open Economy Equilibrium 3 Capital Mobility with and without Specialization 2 Discussion of Case with General Functional Forms and Heckscher-Ohlin Features 3 Dynamic Model with Capital Accumulation Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 5 / 31

A Benchmark Model Consider rst a closed economy that employs 2 factors (K and L) to produce 2 goods (1 and 2). The country is inhabited by: a continuum of measure µ of entrepreneurial capitalists a continuum of measure 1 µ of rentier capitalists a measure L of workers. All capitalists are endowed with K units of capital, so the aggregate capital-labor ratio of the economy is K /L. a fraction µ of K is entrepreneurial capital, the remaining fraction is rentier capital. All agents have identical Cobb-Douglas preferences: U = η 1 η C1 C2 (1) η 1 η Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 6 / 31

Production Production in both sectors combines capital and labor according to: X i = Z (K i ) α (L i ) 1 α, i = 1, 2 Goods and labor markets are perfectly competitive, and factors of production are freely mobile across sectors. Producers in sector 2 can freely hire factors at prices w and δ. If producers in sector 1 could also freely hire at w and δ, then MRT = 1 and relative price of good 2 would be p = 1. sector 1 would hire a fraction η of economy s labor and capital. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 7 / 31

Financial Friction There is a nancial friction in sector 1. Because of the complexity of its production: only entrepreneurs can run technology in that sector; investors are only willing to lend entrepreneurs a multiple θ 1 > 0 of the latter s capital endowment (limited commitment, moral hazard,...). Hence, capital invested by entrepreneur i is I i θk, for θ > 1. (2) If θ is su ciently large, (2) does not bind and entrepreneurs are able to allocate a fraction η of economy s capital to sector 1 ( rst-best). For nancial constraints to bind we need: Assumption 1: µθ < η. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 8 / 31

Closed Economy Equilibrium Under A.1, nancial constraint binds and K allocated to sector 1 is K 1 = µθk < ηk. Labor is allocated across sectors to equate the value of its MP: µθk α (1 α) Z = p (1 L 1 Goods market clearing imposes: (1 µθ) K α α) Z. L L 1 (1 η) Z (µθk ) α (L 1 ) 1 α = pηz ((1 µθ) K ) α (L L 1 ) 1 α, These two conditions yield: L 1 = ηl (3) µθ (1 η) α p = < 1. η (1 µθ) Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 9 / 31

E ect on Relative Prices: General Case Good 1 PPF N PPF S p N p S Good 2 Figure: E ect of θ on Autarky Relative Price p Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 10 / 31

Closed Economy Equilibrium: Factor Prices Note that a lower θ leads to a lower K 1 /L 1 and a higher K 2 /L 2. Wages equal the value of the marginal product in each sector: so w is low when θ is low, but w/p is high (still w/p 1 η is low) The rental rate of capital can be pinned down by the value of its marginal product in sector 2: hence, δ/p is low when θ is low; since p is low when θ is low, δ is also low relative to sector 1 s numeraire good. We also have that w/δ is high when θ is low: rentier capital su ers disproportionately more from nancial underdevelopment. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 11 / 31

Closed Economy Equilibrium: Entrepreneurs and Sum-Up Because their capital is scarce, entrepreneurs will obtain a premium over the rental rate. Their return per unit of capital is R = λθ + δ. λ is the Lagrange multiplier associated with the nancial constraint; λ is positive under Assumption 1 and rises as θ worsens. Proposition 1: In the closed economy equilibrium, a decline in nancial contractibility θ has the following e ects: it lowers the relative price of the good produced in the unconstrained sector, the real rental rate capital, real wages, and welfare; it raises the wage-rental ratio, and it has an ambiguous e ect on entrepreneurial income. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 12 / 31

Capital Mobility: A Preview Suppose capitalists are allowed to rent their capital abroad. Suppose trade in one good is free, so there is a vehicle to repatriate rental income (but still no specialization) Focus on movements of machines (so workers and entrepreneurs remain immobile). so relevant price is δ. Since δ is low when θ is low, nancial underdevelopment may lead to capital out ows. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 13 / 31

Small Open Economy Equilibrium Suppose now that the previous economy is open to international trade and faces exogenously given prices of goods 1 and 2. Let s rule capital movements for the time being. Rest of the world has access to same technology as South and also faces a nancial friction, though smaller, in sector 1, so p S aut < p < 1. South has comparative advantage in sector 2, so factors of production will move towards that sector. But capital will not move because of the rents it obtains in sector 1 (world is undersupplying good 1) the distribution of capital across sectors is identical to that in autarky (not in dynamic model); model inherits certain workings of the speci c-factors model. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 14 / 31

Small Open Economy Equilibrium The allocation of labor across sectors is still given by µθk α (1 α) Z = p (1 L 1 (1 µθ) K α α) Z. L L 1 But now we can immediately infer (ignore goods-market clearing) L 1 = L 1 is decreasing in p (for given θ). µθl (1 µθ) p 1/α + µθ. trade integration with relatively nancially developed North shifts resources to the unconstrained sector. L 1 is increasing in θ (for given p). SOE with worse nancial institutions specialize more in sector 2. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 15 / 31

Factor Prices in the Small Open Economy Note that a higher p leads to a higher K 1 /L 1 and a lower K 2 /L 2. This implies that w increases and w/p decreases with p. The lower K 2 /L 2 also implies a larger δ/p: and since p increases, δ increases as well. Because the wage-rental is pinned down by the ratio of marginal products in sector 2, we have that w/δ falls when p increases. this will remain true even when sector 1 is more capital intensive: anti-stolper-samuelson Key: as p increases, sector 1 releases labor but not capital (regardless of factor intensity). This is the essence of our central complementarity result. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 16 / 31

A Graphical Illustration MPL 1 /p MPL 2 MPL 2,aut MPL 2,open O 1 O 2 Labor in sector 1 Labor in sector 2 Figure: Trade Integration and the Rental Rate of Capital Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 17 / 31

Factor Prices in the Small Open Economy (cted.) Consider now changes in θ (for given p this corresponds to cross-section of factor prices). As before, wages are increasing in θ (see paper for details depends on symmetry). But note that the zero-pro t condition now implies: p = c 2 δ j, w j = ζ δ j α w j 1 α, for any country j producing good 2. This means that δ is now decreasing in θ. In words, as θ falls, wages are depressed and this raises the rental rate of capital for given prices. So moving from autarky to free trade reverses the ranking of rental rates! Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 18 / 31

Symmetry is Not Empirically Implausible Industry Financial Dependence 1 0 1 2.1.2.3.4.5.6 Industry Labor Share Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 19 / 31

Summary Suppose that a large nancially developed North pins down p at 0 1α p N = @ µθn (1 η) η 1 A < 1. µθ N North and South are identical except θ N > θ S. Proposition 2: In the free trade equilibrium, South produces both goods and is a net importer of the nancially dependent good 1. Furthermore, free trade does not result in factor price equalization and leads to w N > w S δ N < δ S λ N < λ S. Proposition 3: Trade integration raises the real rental rate of capital in the nancially underdeveloped South. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 20 / 31

Capital Mobility Suppose capitalists are allowed to rent their capital in either country. Since δ N < δ S, capital ows into South. But allocation of capital to sector 1 is such that K1 S µθs K, so Northern capital necessarily increases K only in Southern exporting sector, further increasing trade ows. hence, trade and capital ows are also complements à la Markusen. Furthermore, this capital opening brings about FPE; as a result, wages increase further after allowing for capital mobility. Contrast this to the autarky case, where δ N > δ S and hence capital moves from South to North; furthermore, w S falls further with that capital movement. Conclusion: e ects of allowing for capital mobility crucially depend on the extent of trade integration. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 21 / 31

Intermediate Trade Integration and Capital Mobility Consider the case of a technological trade barrier such that a fraction τ of Southern exports of good 2 is lost in transit (the particular sector is not important). Proposition 3: There exists a unique level of trade frictions τ such that for τ < τ we have δ N < δ S, while for τ > τ we have δ N > δ S. Consequently, (physical) capital migrates South when τ < τ and North if τ > τ. Remark: τ is such that τ/ θ S < 0 the lower θ, the lower the required τ (because the wage is very depressed) Also, with trade frictions, trade integration and capital mobility are not su cient for FPE. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 22 / 31

A Note on the General Heckscher-Ohlin Model The complementarity result is robust as long as p goes up in South with trade (which is empirically plausible). Industry Financial Dependence 1 0 1 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 log of (alpha/[sigma*(1 alpha)]) Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 23 / 31

Dynamics: Trade and Financial Flows as Complements Up to now we have focused on physical capital mobility. But physical capital is endogenous. Do credit constraints continue to bind in the long-run? Do nancially underdeveloped countries have lower K /L ratios? Does trade integration increase the K /L ratio in South? Does trade integration continue to raise the rental rate of capital in South? We incorporate the OLG framework in Caballero, Farhi and Gourinchas (2006) into our two-sector model above and answer all these questions in the a rmative. Dynamics: wealth distribution changes as a result of trade liberalization (e ect on cross-sectoral allocation of capital): nontrivial welfare e ects. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 24 / 31

Dynamic Model Time evolves continuously. In nitesimal agents are born at a rate φ per unit time and die at the same rate; population mass is L. All agents are endowed with one unit of labor services which they supply inelastically to the market. Intertemporal preferences are such that agents save all their income and consume only when they die (exit). instantaneous utility at the time of death is as in the static model. Physical capital is tradable and is the only store of value. initial stock of capital is equal to K j 0 and new physical capital can be produced one-to-one with a non-tradable nal good that combines goods 1 and 2 according to the utility aggregator in (1); no depreciation. Entrepreneurs are born as such, and always constitute a share µ of agents. entrepreneurial rents are not capitalizable (cannot be used as store of value). Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 25 / 31

Dynamic Model: Equilibrium Conditions At any point in time, factor prices are determined exactly as in the static model developed above (for a given µ j t = Kt j,e /Kt j ). Let qt j denote the value of one unit of capital in country j = N, S at 1 η. any instant t. Zero adjustment costs imply qt j = pt j The return on holding 1 unit of capital is equal to the dividend price ratio plus the capital gain: r j t = δj t q j t + qj t qt j. (4) Let Wt j,i denote the savings accumulated by agents of type i = e, u in country j up to date t: Ẇ j,r t = φw j,r t + (1 µ)w j t L + r j t W j,r t, (5) Ẇt j,e = φwt j,e + µw j t L + λ j t θ j µ j t K j t + r j t W j,e t. (6) Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 26 / 31

Determination of Interest Rates With a closed capital account, it must be the case that: W j,r t + W j,e t = q j tk j t. (7) The system is stable and yields a steady-state interest rate given by r j t = r j = δj (p j ) 1 η, (8) but note that δ j is a function of the endogenous value of K j. It is straightforward to show that the steady state value of µ j t is such that we always have µ j > µ but µ j θ < η (never grow out of constraint). We can now compute the value of the interest rate in our benchmark model with and without free trade. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 27 / 31

Interest Rates under Autarky Consider rst the case in which North and South are closed to international trade. Then we have: raut j 1 η = φα 1 µ j aut θ j. µ j aut is a complicated function, but is such that µ j aut θ j is increasing in θ j. The autarkic interest rate is thus an increasing function of θ j, which implies that South experiences a capital out ow if it integrates to global capital markets. This is despite the fact that the steady-state capital-labor ratio is increasing in θ j. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 28 / 31

Interest Rates under Free Trade With free trade we have p 1/α ropen j = φα µ j open θj + 1, (9) µ j open θj p 1/α where again µ j open is such that µj open θj is increasing in θ j. We thus have that r j open is decreasing in θ. That is, South experiences capital in ows if it integrates to global capital markets. by specializing in unconstrained sector, rentier capital works with a disproportionate amount of cheap labor and obtains a larger share of income. We can also show that µ j open < µj aut, which implies that trade liberalization not only shifts labor from sector 1 to sector 2, but also shifts capital (in the long-run). Also, the steady-state capital-labor ratio in South is increasing in p. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 29 / 31

An Application: Protectionism Back res Current global imbalances have rekindled protectionist proposals. Consider again the model with partial trade frictions in sector 2. Proposition 4: There exists a unique level of trade frictions τ such that for τ < τ we have r N < r S, while for τ > τ we have r N > r S. Consequently, nancial capital migrates South when τ < τ and North if τ > τ. Suppose that τ 0 τ so that r N r S. The larger is τ, the larger is the gap r N r S. Because of diminishing returns to capital, it then ows that the initial capital out ow (or trade surplus) in the South will be larger the larger is τ. Conclusion: protectionism may exacerbate the imbalances. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 30 / 31

Conclusions Main message of this paper: when variation in nancial development and nancial dependence are important in shaping comparative advantage, trade and capital ows become complements in nancially underdeveloped countries. This complementarity is in sharp contrast to the substitutability that arises in the standard Heckscher-Ohlin-Mundell framework, and has important practical implications. deepening trade liberalization in South raises this country s ability to attract foreign capital. at the global level, it implies that protectionist policies aimed at reducing the so called global imbalances may back re and exacerbate them. our framework hints that it may be important for developing economies to liberalize trade before the capital account, if capital out ows are to be averted. Antràs and Caballero (Harvard & MIT) Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions May 2009 31 / 31