Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity

Similar documents
Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

The New Keynesian Model

Monetary Economics Final Exam

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions

On the Business Cycle Effects of Government Spending

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

1 Dynamic programming

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

A Model with Costly-State Verification

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

On the new Keynesian model

THE ZERO LOWER BOUND, THE DUAL MANDATE,

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

A Model of Financial Intermediation

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

International recessions

Monetary Policy and the Great Recession

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

The new Kenesian model

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Macro (8701) & Micro (8703) option

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

AGGREGATE FLUCTUATIONS WITH NATIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL RETURNS TO SCALE. Department of Economics, Queen s University, Canada

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

... Monetary Policy and a Stock Market Boom-Bust Cycle. Lawrence Christiano, Roberto Motto, Massimo Rostagno

Foreign Exchange Market Intervention, Inflation and. Export Competitiveness

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Asset Prices and Business Cycles with. Financial Frictions

Adjustment Costs, Agency Costs and Terms of Trade Disturbances in a Small Open Economy

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

The Extensive Margin of Trade and Monetary Policy

The science of monetary policy

The Basic New Keynesian Model

International recessions

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

Aggregate Demand and the Dynamics of Unemployment

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

(Incomplete) summary of the course

Investment brings change: Implications for news driven business cycles

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary)

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Investment brings change: Implications for news-driven business cycles

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Endogenous Trade Participation with Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass-Through

Collateral constraint and news-driven cycles

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

In the Name of God. Macroeconomics. Sharif University of Technology Problem Bank

Leaning Against the Credit Cycle

For students electing Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) & Micro (8703/Prof. Glewwe) option

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

CAE Working Paper # Endogenous Money or Sticky Price? Comment on Monetary Non-Neutrality and Inflation Dynamics. Peng-fei Wang. and.

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

On the Optimal Labor Income Share

Financial Econometrics

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk. June 2012

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Introduction to DSGE Models

Country Spreads and Emerging Countries: Who Drives Whom? Martin Uribe and Vivian Yue (JIE, 2006)

Booms and Banking Crises

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy

Transcription:

Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity Pengfei Wang New York University April 17, 2013 Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 1 / 44

Introduction Firms and businesses face borrowing costs to finance their working capital that depends on the collateral value of their assets and output. Any positive shock that appreciates the value of a firm s collateral will decrease the cost of external finance, increase profitability and amplify the effect of the initial shock. This mechanism suggests the possibility of self-fulfilling multiple equilibria: Optimistic expectations of higher output may well lead increased lending to financially constrained firms. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 2 / 44

Mechanism Even though our model has no increasing returns in production, the relaxation of the borrowing constraint implies that unit marginal costs can increase with output as firms compete hire more labor and capital. In such a case markups can become countercyclical and factor returns can increase suffi ciently so that the expectation of higher output can become self-fulfilling. The purpose of this paper is to show that multiple equilibria and indeterminacies can easily arise in a simple financial accelerator model for realistic parameter calibrations, and that it can reasonably match some of the quantitative features of economic data. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 3 / 44

We introduce borrowing constraints into an otherwise standard Dixit-Stiglitz monopoly competition model. Firms rent capital and hire labor in the competitive markets to produce differentiated intermediate goods. The firms however may default on their promise or contract to repay their debt. We assume therefore that firms face borrowing constraints to finance their working capital, determined by the fraction of firm revenue and assets that the creditors can recover, minus some fixed collection costs. This constrains the output as well as the unit marginal costs of firms. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 4 / 44

Given the fixed collection costs however, if households expect a higher equilibrium output, they will be willing to increase their lending to firms, even if the marginal costs of firms increase and their markups decline as they compete for additional labor and capital. At the new equilibrium both output and factor returns will be higher. Despite the income effects on labor supply, the increase in wages associated with lower markups will allow employment and output to increase, so the optimistic expectations of higher output will be fulfilled. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 5 / 44

Final good Y t = [ ] σ Y σ 1 σ 1 σ t (i)di, The final goods producer solves [ Y σ 1 σ t (i)di max y t (i) ] σ σ 1 P t (i)y t (i)di. where P t (i) the price of the i th intermediate good. The first-order conditions lead to the following inverse demand functions for intermediate goods: P t (i) = Y σ 1 σ t (i)y 1 t, where the aggregate price index is [ ] 1 1 = Pt 1 σ 1 σ (i)di. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 6 / 44

The Financial Constraint. We assume that in the beginning of period, the ith intermediate goods firm decides to rent capital K t (i) from the households and hire labor N t (i). The firm promises to pay w t N t (i) + r t K t (i) b t (i) to the households. However the firm may default on their contract or promise. We assume that if the firm does not pay its debt b t (i), the households can recover a fraction ξ < 1 of the firm s revenue P t (i)y t (i) by incurring a liquidation cost f. One possibility is that the firm must pay the wages to labor as production takes place, and that creditors can always redeem the physical capital, but that the interest on borrowing may not be fully recoverable. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 7 / 44

So if the household can recover ξp t (i)y t (i) f, they will lend to the firm only if ξp t (i)y t (i) f will at least cover the wage bill plus principal and interest. Knowing that the household can not recover more than ξp t (i)y t (i) f, the firm will also has no incentive to repay more than ξp t (i)y t (i) f. The incentive-compatiblity constraint for the firm then is: P t (i)y t (i) [w t N t (i) + r t K t (i)] P t (i)y t (i) [ξp t (i)y t (i) f ], or w t N t (i) + r t K t (i) ξp t (i)y t (i) f. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 8 / 44

Cost Minimization Min r t K t + w t N t S.T. AKt a Nt 1 α Y t ( Max L = r t K t + w t N t φ t Yt A Kt a Nt 1 α ) FOC: r t = αφ t A Kt a 1 Nt 1 α ; w t = (1 α) φ t A Kt a Nt α where φ t is the Lagrange multiplier interpreted as marginal cost, the marginal effect of relaxing the income constraint on marginal costs. Then ( rt ) ( ) α ( = φt A Kt a 1 Nt 1 α ) 1 α α wt ; = ( φ α 1 α t A Kt a Nt α ) 1 α Mulltiplying: ( rt ) ( ) α 1 α wt α 1 α = ( φ t φ t = A 1 ( r t α A K α(α 1)+α(1 α) t ) α ( wt 1 α ) 1 α ) N α(1 α) α(1 α) t = Aφ t Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 9 / 44

After substituting P t (i), the profit maximization for the i th firm becomes σ max t (i)y 1 t φ t Y t (i), subject to Y t (i) Y 1 1 σ φ t Y t (i) + f ξy 1 σ 1 σ t (i)y 1 t. Given w t, r t, final output Y t, and the borrowing constraint, the feasible choice of Y t (i) can be illustrated by shaded area of Figure 1. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 10 / 44

Figure 1. The Credit Constraints and Feasible Ouptut Choice. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 11 / 44

Households subject to 0 [log C t ψ N1+χ t 1 + χ ]e ρt dt, K t = r t e t K t δ(e t )K t + w t N t C t + Π t, For simplicity we assume that the households choose the capacity utilization rate e t. A higher e t implies that the capital is more intensively utilized, at the cost of faster depreciation, so that δ(e t ) is convex increasing function. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 12 / 44

The first-order conditions for the consumer s optimization problem are given by equations: Ċ t C t = r t e t ρ δ(e t ), r t = δ (e t ), and ψn χ t = 1 C t w t. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 13 / 44

The equilibrium in the economy is a collection of price processes {w t, r t, P t (i)} and quantities {K t (i), N t (i), Y t (i), Y t, K t, N t, e t, Π t }, such that given the prices and the aggregate Π t, the households choose K t and N t to maximize their utility; Given P t (i), the final goods firm chooses {Y t (i)} to maximize its profits Given w t, r t, and the financial constraint (the intermediate goods maximizes its profit by choosing K t (i) and N t (i); and all markets clear. Since firms are symmetric, we have K t (i) = K t, N t (i) = N t, P t (i) = 1, Y t (i) = Y t and Π t (i) = Π t = Y t w t N t r t K t. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 14 / 44

The budget constraint becomes K t = Y t C t δk t. The wage w t and the interest rate r t are w t = (1 α)φ t Y t N t, and r t = αφ t Y t K t. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 15 / 44

Lemma: If ξ(1 1 σ ) < φ t < 1 1 σ, then the final constraint binds; that is φ t Y t (i) + f ξy 1 σ 1 σ t (i)y 1 t. Why? Marginal revenue = 1 1 σ > Marginal cost = φ t > Marginal Revenue in case of default = ξ ( 1 1 ) σ First inequality says firms want to borrow more to expand output, second inequality says they cannot because what the household can recover in case of default does not cover marginal cost. Using the fact Y t (i) = Y t, the constraint implies φ t = ξ f Y t Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 16 / 44

To summarize, the following system of equations fully characterize the equilibrium φ t Ċ t αy t = φ C t ρ δ(e t ), t K t K t = Y t δ(e t )K t C t, ψn χ t = 1 (1 α) Y t φ C t, t N t Y t = A(e t K t ) α Nt 1 α, αy t e t K t = δ (e t ) φ t = ξ f Y t, subject to the constraint ξ(1 1 σ ) < φ t < 1 1 σ. e Let the depreciation function be given by δ(e t ) = δ 1+µ t 0 1+µ.We then have φ αy ek = δ (e) = δ 0 e µ Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 17 / 44

We first solve deterministic steady state. We normalize δ 0 such that e = 1. δ(e) = 1 1 + µ φ αy K K = µ φα 1 + µ ρ Y [ (1 + µ)ρ e = µδ 0 C Y = 1 δ(e) K Y N = ] 1 1+µ µ 1 + µ = 1 ρ µ = 1 φα 1 + µ [ (1 α) 1 φ C ψ Y φα ρ ] 1 1+χ Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 18 / 44

( µ Y = 1 + µ ) α φα 1 α φ ρ (1 α) 1 1 φα ψ 1+µ 1 1+χ Y (φ) Finally from the definition of φ = ξ f Y, we have f = (ξ φ)y (φ) Ψ(φ) to determine the steady-state value of φ. For the existence of a steady state however we will need to assume ξ(1 1 σ ) < φ < 1 1 σ. See diagram: f cannot be too high, or alternatively constrain φ. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 19 / 44

ċ t = ρ[ŷ t ˆK t + ˆφ t ] k t = (1 + µ)δ (Ŷ t ˆK t ) αφ δ(ŷ t + ˆφ t ˆK t ) χ ˆN t = ˆφ t + Ŷ t ˆN t Ĉ t Ŷ t = α( ˆK t + ê t ) + (1 α) ˆN t ê t = 1 1 + µ ( ˆφ t + Ŷ t ˆK t ) ˆφ t = where we use δ = ρ µ. f /Y ξ f /Y Ŷt γŷ t ( (1 + µ)δ αφ ) δ (Ĉ t ˆK t ) Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 20 / 44

[ ] [ ] k t ˆK = J t ċ t Using the factor ρ = δµ, we have [ ] (1+µ) J = δ αφ λ (1+µ) 1 (1 + γ)λ 1 αφ (λ 2 1) + 1 (1 + γ)λ 2 µ [(1 + γ)λ 1 1] µ(1 + γ)λ 2 Ĉ t (1) Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 21 / 44

Proposition: Let γ and φ satisfy the following two constraints (1 + γ) > (1 + µ) (1 + χ) α(1 + χ) + (1 + µ)(1 α) and Then ( ) 1+µ 1 + γ < min( 1 + µ α, φ (1 + χ) α(1 + χ) + (1 + µ)(1 α), (1 α)(1 + χ) + 1) 1 (1 + µ)(1 α) 1+µ αφ + (1 + χ)α Trace (J) < 0, det(j) > 0 Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 22 / 44

To gain intuition for self-fulfilling expectations of higher output and higher factor rewards, we first focus on labor demand and supply curves incorporating the equilibrium effects of the borrowing constraint on marginal costs and markups. The labor demand curve is given by ŵ t = (1 + γ)ŷ t ˆN t ŵ t = αν 1 + ν (1 + γ)α ˆK t + and the labor supply curve in the economy is [ (1 + γ)(1 + ν)(1 α) 1 + ν (1 + γ)α (2) ] 1 ˆN t (3) ŵ t = Ĉ t + χ ˆN t (4) Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 23 / 44

This slope of the labor market demand curve is positive and steeper than the labor supply curve under the condition. (1 + γ) > (1 + µ) (1 + χ) α(1 + χ) + (1 + µ)(1 α) Unlike earlier works, our model has no increasing returns in the production technology. Instead indeterminacy arises from the borrowing constraints and their indirect effects on marginal costs through wages and the rental rate on capital. If households expect a higher equilibrium output, they will be willing to increase their lending to firms. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 24 / 44

Given the positive fixed collection costs f, an expected increase in output levels relaxes the borrowing constraint so that unit marginal costs of firms, φ t = ξ f Y t, can rise and markups can decline. This implies that as firms compete for inputs, factor rewards will also with increase with Y t. The labor demand curve incorporating these general equilibrium effects on marginal costs can now be positively sloped and steeper than the labor supply curve. Normally, higher output levels tend to increase the demand for leisure, so barring inferiorities in preferences, the higher demand for labor will be contained by the income effect on labor supply. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 25 / 44

However if the labor demand slopes up more steeply than labor supply, employment will increase robustly as the labor supply curve shifts to the left with income effects. The rise in labor hours as well as the accumulation of capital will raise output, so that optimistic output expectations of households will be self-fulfilling. We can show that these indeterminacy results can hold even in the absence of variable capacity utilization, but we include it into our model to improve calibration results in the next section. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 26 / 44

Figure 2 illustrates the combinations of f and ξ which may yield indeterminacy with the other parameters set at µ = 0.3, α = 1 3, ρ = 0.01. The shaded areas are the feasible ξ and f that support a steady state equilibrium with ξ σ 1 σ < φ < σ 1 σ. Figure 2. Parameter Spaces for Indeterminacy. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 27 / 44

Calibrations We write the model in discrete time and solve it by log-linearizing the equations that characterize the equilibrium around the steady state. We adopt standard parameterization: β = 1 1+ρ = 0.99, α = 1/3, δ = 0.033, σ = 10 and µ = 0.3. We set ξ = 0.9768, f = 0.1908 and fix the productivity level at A = 1. These parameter values imply steady state values φ = 0.88 and γ = f /Y ξ f /Y = 0.11. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 28 / 44

We begin without fundamental shocks. In the case of indeterminacy, the model s solution takes the form ( ) ( ) ( ) ˆK t+1 ˆK = M t 0 + ε t+1 Ĉ t+1 where M is a two by two matrix and ε t+1 = Ĉ t+1 E t Ĉ t+1 is the sunspot shock. The remaining variables can be written as functions of ˆK t and Ĉ t : Ŷ t Î t ˆN t ê t Ĉ t = H ( ˆK t Ĉ t ) Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 29 / 44

Figre 3. Impulse Responses to a Consumption Shock. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 30 / 44

From Figure 3 we see that output, investment, consumption and hours comove. The impulse responses also demonstrate that labor is slightly more volatile than output, an important feature of the data that the standard RBC model has diffi culty explaining with a T.F.P shock. The impulse responses also show cycles in output, investment, consumption and hours, so the model has the potential to explain the boom-bust patterns observed in many episodes in data. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 31 / 44

However, as in the models with increasing returns to scale, the extremely large impact of autonomous consumption on output and investment seems empirically unjustified. On the impact period, one percentage increase consumption leads to 27 percent increase in output and 116 percent increase in investment.. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 32 / 44

This volatile response of output and investment can be understood by studying the effect of consumption on labor. Equating the labor demand (2) and labor supply (4) we have where (1+γ)(1+µ)(1 α) 1+µ (1+γ)α ˆN t = 1 Ĉ (1+γ)(1+µ)(1 α) t. (5) 1 χ 1+µ (1+γ)α 1 is the slope of the labor demand curve and χ is the slope of labor supply curve. When these two slopes are close, a one percentage point of autonomous consumption increase can lead to a huge increase in labor and hence output. Denote s as the steady state investment to income ratio. Then from the resource constraint, sî t + (1 s)ĉ t = Ŷ t, (6) so it is clear that smooth consumption plus volatile income will make investment even more volatile as s << 1. In the current calibration s = 0.23. So it implies that response of investment at impact will be about 4.4 times that of output. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 33 / 44

Table 1: Sample and Model Moments US Sample Model var σ X /σ Y corr XY corr Xt X t 1 σ X /σ Y corr XY corr Xt X t 1 Y 1.00 1.00 0.87 1.00 1.00 0.91 N 1.01 0.88 0.92 1.08 0.99 0.91 C 0.52 0.83 0.90 0.07 0.48 0.97 I 3.33 0.92 0.92 4.31 0.99 0.91 φ 0.32 0.16 0.70 0.11 1.00 0.91 Note: Variables (Y, N, C, I, φ) stands for output, labor (hours), consumption, investment and marginal cost respectively. The marginal cost in the data can be computed via labor share φ = 1 α. σ X /σ Y is the relatively standard deviation of variable X to output, corr(x, Y ) computes the correlation between X and output and corr(x t, X t 1 ) compute the first-order autocorrelation of X t. ess Benhabib Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 34 / 44

To better match the relative volatility of consumption and output we now introduce a TFP shock into the model. We assume that the technology level in the economy follows an AR(1) process  t+1 = ρ a  t + σ a ε at+1 (7) Following Benhabib and Wen (2004), we assume the sunspots shocks and technology shocks are correlated. Following King and Rebelo (1999), we assume ρ a = 0.98. We assume the technology shock ε at and sunspots shocks ε t are perfectly correlated and the relative volatility of sunspots and technology shocks is set to σ s /σ ε = 1.5. These bring the relative volatility of consumption closer to data. The moments with correlated TFP shocks and sunspots shocks are in Table 2. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 35 / 44

Table 2: Moments with correlated TFP and Sunspot Shocks Model with Correlated Shocks The RBC Model var σ X /σ Y corr XY corr Xt X t 1 σ X /σ Y corr XY corr Xt X t 1 Y 1.00 1.00 0.98 1.00 1.00 0.95 N 0.96 0.95 0.99 0.53 0.73 0.90 C 0.37 0.55 0.99 0.62 0.86 0.99 I 3.38 0.96 0.98 2.65 0.88 0.91 φ 0.11 1.00 0.98 0 N.A N.A The RBC model refers to f = 0, so γ = 0, in which we have φ = ξ is a constant. We select the parameter values in a way such that these two models have the same steady state. For the RBC model, we use TFP shocks with ρ a = 0.98 as the only driving forces. ess Benhabib Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 36 / 44

Hump-Shaped output Dynamics We illustrate how our indeterminacy model can also predict some of the aspects of actual fluctuations that standard RBC models cannot explain, such as the hump-shaped, trend reverting impulse response of output to transitory demand shocks and the substantial serial correlation in the output growth rate in data (see Cogley and Nason(1995)). Since there is significant empirical evidence favoring demand shocks as a main source of business cycle, (e.g., see Blanchard and Quah(1989), Waston (1993), Cogley and Nason (1995) and Benhabib and Wen (2004), it is important to examine whether demand shocks can generate persistent business cycles. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 37 / 44

We consider two types of demand shocks as in Benhabib and Wen (2004): government spending shocks and preference shocks. With preference shocks the period-by-period utility function changes to U = exp( t ) log C t ψ N 1+χ t 1+χ. We assume that the preference shocks t follows an AR(1) process, namely t = ρ t 1 + ε t. With government spending, G t, in period t, the resource constraint changes to K t = Y t δ(e t )K t C t G t. We assume log(g t ) = ρ g log(g t 1 ) + ε gt. We choose ρ g = ρ = 0.90 as in Benhabib and Wen (2004). Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 38 / 44

To highlight the effect of indeterminacy on the propagation mechanism of RBC models, we graph the impulse responses to a persistent government spending shock with and without indeterminacy in Figure 4. Figure 5 graphs the impulse response of the model to a persistent preference shock. For the model without indeterminacy we set f = 0 and reset ξ = 0.88 such that the model with and without indeterminacy have the same steady state. Several features of Figure 4 deserves particular mention. First, in the case f = 0, we have marginal cost φ t = ξ is a constant. Hence the impulse responses of our model with financial constraints resemble these of a standard RBC model. Figure 4 and Figure 5 show that some diffi culties of the standard RBC model in generating business cycle fluctuations. Figure 4 shows that consumption and investment move against each other after a positive government spending shock. An increase in government spending generates a negative wealth effect, which reduces both consumption and leisure. The decrease in leisure leads to an increase in output. An increase in output together with a decrease in consumption imply that investment has to increase. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 39 / 44

Second, even though the model generates comovement without indeterminacy under persistent preference shocks, the responses of output to such demand shocks is monotonic. Neither government spending shocks nor preference shocks can generate the hump-shaped output dynamics observed in the data. And this monotonic and persistent output responses to demand shocks mostly come from the persistence of shocks, not from an inner propagation mechanism. If one reduces the persistence of the shocks, the persistence of output responses will reduced accordingly. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 40 / 44

Third, when the model is indeterminate, the responses of output to both the government spending shocks and the preference shocks are dramatically changed. Figure 4 and Figure 5 clearly show persistent and hump-shaped responses of output to both shocks. In addition, this persistent response of output is not due to the persistence in shocks. As Figure 3 has already demonstrated, the model with indeterminacy can generate persistent fluctuations even under i.i.d shocks. Figure 4 and Figure 5 again highlight the similarity of our indeterminacy model with those based on increasing return to scale, so it has a similar ability to explain other puzzles. For example, Benhabib and Wen (2004) demonstrated that their indeterminacy model based on increasing returns to scale can explain the forcecastable-movement puzzle as pointed out by Rotemberg and Woodford (1996), namely that they are highly forecastable and comove. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 41 / 44

Figure 4. Impulse response to a government shock. Solid lines are responses under determinacy (f = 0) and dashed lines are responses under indeterminacy. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 42 / 44

Figure 5. Impulse responses to a preference shock. Solid lines are responses under determinacy (f = 0) and dashed lines are responses under indeterminacy. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 43 / 44

We conclude that borrowing or collateral constraints can be a source of self-fulfilling fluctuations in economies that have no increasing returns to scale in production. Expectations of higher output can relax borrowing constraints, and firms can expand their output by bidding up factor prices and eliciting a labor supply response that allows the initial expectation to be fulfilled. The parameter ranges and markups where self-fulfilling expectations can occur are within realistic ranges and compatible with the data. Simulating our data we obtain moments and impulse responses that can reasonably match the US macroeconomic data. Pengfei Wang (New York University) Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity April 17, 2013 44 / 44