Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Similar documents
Total state and local business taxes

Total state and local business taxes

Cyclical Variability In State Government Revenue: Can Tax Reform Reduce It?

STATE AND LOCAL TAXES A Comparison Across States

Forecasting State and Local Government Spending: Model Re-estimation. January Equation

Total State and Local Business Taxes

Total state and local business taxes

State Corporate Income Tax Collections Decline Sharply

TAX REVENUE VOLATILITY AND A STATE-WIDE EDUCATION SALES TAX

Undocumented Immigrants are:

State Individual Income Taxes: Personal Exemptions/Credits, 2011

Commonfund Higher Education Price Index Update

Taxes and Economic Competitiveness. Dale Craymer President, Texas Taxpayers and Research Association (512)

The Effect of the Federal Cigarette Tax Increase on State Revenue

Media Alert. First American CoreLogic Releases Q3 Negative Equity Data

Annual Costs Cost of Care. Home Health Care

Union Members in New York and New Jersey 2018

Income from U.S. Government Obligations

Kentucky , ,349 55,446 95,337 91,006 2,427 1, ,349, ,306,236 5,176,360 2,867,000 1,462

Nation s Uninsured Rate for Children Drops to Another Historic Low in 2016

NCSL FISCAL BRIEF: PROJECTED STATE TAX GROWTH IN FY 2012 AND BEYOND

Pay Frequency and Final Pay Provisions

American Economics Group Clear and Effective Economic Analysis. American Economics Group

Notice on Reallotment of Workforce Investment Act (WIA) Title I Formula Allotted Funds

FISCAL FACT Top Marginal Effective Tax Rates By State under Rival Tax Plans from Congressional Democrats and Republicans

Federal Registry. NMLS Federal Registry Quarterly Report Quarter I

Tax Recommendations and Actions in Other States. Joel Michael House Research Department June 9, 2011

State Postal Abbreviation Codes

Total state and local business taxes. State-by-state estimates for fiscal year 2011 July 2012

Minnesota s Economics & Demographics Looking To 2030 & Beyond. Tom Stinson, State Economist Tom Gillaspy, State Demographer July 2008

The impact of cigarette excise taxes on beer consumption

Introduction... 1 Survey Methodology... 1 Industry Breakouts... 2 Organization Size Breakouts... 3 Geographic Breakouts

Checkpoint Payroll Sources All Payroll Sources

Table 1 - Special Fund Disbursements for FY

Total state and local business taxes State-by-state estimates for

Revenue Forecasting Practices: Accuracy, Transparency and Political Acceptance

Metrics and Measurements for State Pension Plans. November 17, 2016 Greg Mennis

Motor Vehicle Sales/Use, Tax Reciprocity and Rate Chart-2005

2008 State Business Tax Burden Rankings

State, Local and Net Tuition Revenue Supporting General Operating Expenses of Higher Education, U.S., Fiscal Year 2010, Current (unadjusted) Dollars

ONLINE APPENDIX. Concentrated Powers: Unilateral Executive Authority and Fiscal Policymaking in the American States

Impacts of Prepayment Penalties and Balloon Loans on Foreclosure Starts, in Selected States: Supplemental Tables

kaiser medicaid and the uninsured commission on An Overview of Changes in the Federal Medical Assistance Percentages (FMAPs) for Medicaid July 2011

A Database on the Passage and Enactment of Recent State Minimum Wage Increases

Overview of Sales Tax Exemptions for Agricultural Producers in the United States

AIG Benefit Solutions Producer Licensing and Appointment Requirements by State

BY THE NUMBERS 2016: Another Lackluster Year for State Tax Revenue

CIRCLE The Center for Information & Research on Civic Learning & Engagement. Youth Volunteering in the States: 2002 and 2003

Chapter D State and Local Governments

FAPRI Analysis of Dairy Policy Options for the 2002 Farm Bill Conference

The 2017 CHP Salary Survey

Fiscal Fact. By Kail Padgitt and Alicia Hansen

How Much Would a State Earned Income Tax Credit Cost in Fiscal Year 2018?

Sales Tax Return Filing Thresholds by State

ATHENE Performance Elite Series of Fixed Index Annuities

State Government Indigent Defense Expenditures, FY Updated

Understanding Oregon s Throwback Rule for Apportioning Corporate Income

State Income Tax Tables

The table below reflects state minimum wages in effect for 2014, as well as future increases. State Wage Tied to Federal Minimum Wage *

Total state and local business taxes

medicaid a n d t h e How will the Medicaid Expansion for Adults Impact Eligibility and Coverage? Key Findings in Brief

Business Planning for the New Economic Era

Termination Final Pay Requirements

The NCCI Split Point Change What You Need to Know

Federal Rates and Limits


The Costs and Benefits of Half a Loaf: The Economic Effects of Recent Regulation of Debit Card Interchange Fees. Robert J. Shapiro

WHILE NOT THE MOST VISIBLE OF TAXES, THE

Macroeconomic Impact Analysis of Proposed Greenhouse Gas and Fuel Economy Standards for Medium- and Heavy-Duty Vehicles

DSH Reduction Allocation Process Flows. DRAFT Based on 5/15/13 NPRM

March Karen Cunnyngham Amang Sukasih Laura Castner

Papers presented at the ICES-III, June 18-21, 2007, Montreal, Quebec, Canada

WHAT A 25-CENT FEDERAL GAS TAX INCREASE WOULD LOOK LIKE IN EACH STATE

MINIMUM WAGE WORKERS IN HAWAII 2013

CAPITOL research. States Face Medicaid Match Loss After Recovery Act Expires. health

State Budget Update. Fall 2017 FEB 2018

STATE REVENUE REPORT. Sales Tax Decline in Late 2008 Was the Worst in 50 Years

ECONOMIC IMPACT OF LOCAL PARKS FULL REPORT

SURVEY OF STATE FUNDING FOR PUBLIC TRANSPORTATION

Ability-to-Repay Statutes

Update: 50-State Survey of Retiree Health Care Liabilities Most recent data show changes to benefits, funding policies could help manage rising costs

State-Level Estimates of Union Density, 1964 to Present

Aetna Individual Direct Pay Commissions Schedule

Population in the U.S. Floodplains

Mapping the geography of retirement savings

ADDITIONAL REQUIRED TRAINING before proceeding. Annuity Carrier Specific Product Training

1969. Median. Introduction

MEDICAID BUY-IN PROGRAMS

2014 STATE AND FEDERAL MINIMUM WAGES HR COMPLIANCE CENTER

Other States Models. House Select Committee on Strategic Transportation Planning and Long Term Funding Solutions.

PAY STATEMENT REQUIREMENTS

Consumer Returns in the Retail Industry

Q Homeowner Confidence Survey Results. May 20, 2010

TA X FACTS NORTHERN FUNDS 2O17

2002 Tax and Budget Review and 2003 Budget Preview. Fifteen states made significant tax increases totaling almost $6 billion.

Social Security: The Windfall Elimination Provision (WEP)

AUGUST MORTGAGE INSURANCE DATA AT A GLANCE

THE STATE OF THE STATES IN DEVELOPMENTAL DISABILITIES

American Economics Group Clear and Effective Economic Analysis. American Economics Group

The Starting Portfolio is divided into the following account types based on the proportions in your accounts. Cash accounts are considered taxable.

Transcription:

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Evaluating State Revenue Variability: A Portfolio Approach Thomas A. Garrett Working Paper 2006-008A http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2006/2006-008.pdf February 2006 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Research Division P.O. Box 442 St. Louis, MO 63166 The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors.

Evaluating State Revenue Variability: A Portfolio Approach Thomas A. Garrett Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Research Division PO Box 442 St. Louis, MO 63166 JEL Codes: H71, G11 Keywords: state revenue, variability, portfolio, taxes Abstract State revenue variability is evaluated using a volatility model rooted in portfolio theory. The model evaluates how closely a state s revenue portfolio is constructed to minimize variability in total state tax revenue. The model complements parametric methods of revenue variability. Corresponding Author: Thomas A. Garrett, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Research Division, PO Box 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166-0442 Phone: (314) 444-8601 Fax: (314) 444-8731 Email: garrett@stls.frb.org

Evaluating State Revenue Variability: A Portfolio Approach I. Introduction Each state has a portfolio of taxes from which revenues are obtained. Although personal income taxes, corporate income taxes, sales, and excise taxes are common to most states, the degree to which each state relies on each revenue source varies dramatically. 1 The tax mix of a state is influenced by economic conditions, voter preferences, political behavior and the incentives of state legislators, and industry mix (Besley and Case, 2003; Crain, 2003). Parametric estimation of tax revenue variability is traditionally done by regressing the percentage change in the tax base (or revenue) on the percentage change income (Williams et al., 1973; Holcombe and Sobel, 1996, 1997). Comparing the elasticity of each tax allows a determination of which tax exhibits greater variability over the business cycle. Generally, corporate income taxes experience the greatest short-run variability, followed by personal income taxes, sales taxes, and excise taxes. 2 This note suggests an alternative approach to examining state revenue variability through the use of a volatility model based on portfolio theory (Markowitz, 1952). 3 Unlike traditional parametric methods, the portfolio approach provides a unique avenue to determine a tax s share of total tax revenue that minimizes the overall variability in total state tax revenue given a state s portfolio of tax revenue sources. Furthermore, by 1 In 2000, for example, over 61 percent of tax revenue in Washington came from the state s sales tax compared to only 15 percent in Vermont. Nearly 70 percent of California s total tax revenue was obtained through the personal income tax, whereas Tennessee only generated 2.5 percent of its total tax revenue from the personal income tax (only interest and dividends are taxed). Excise taxes accounted for 32 percent of total tax revenue in New Hampshire, but California obtained only 7.5 percent of its total tax revenue from excise taxes. 2 The exemption of food from the sales tax increases the variability of sales tax revenue. 3 Szakmary and Szakmary (1995) use the volatility model to answer the question of whether lottery revenues stabilize or destabilize total state revenue. 2

comparing the actual revenue share of a tax with the variance minimizing share, the model provides an answer to the question of how well a state s portfolio is constructed to minimize the variance in total state tax revenue. This is an interesting exercise given that revenue minimization is not usually the goal of governments when they establish tax rates and tax bases. Economists and budget officials should find the model and its empirical applications useful, as both can be used in conjunction with parametric techniques for analyzing revenue variability. Employing both methods can provide a more complete picture of tax revenue variability. II. A Model of Revenue Variability A state has several taxes from which it generates total tax revenue. The following model, based on portfolio theory, assumes a single source of tax revenue is evaluated with the sum of all other tax revenue. The percentage change in total state tax revenue (R) is a weighted average of these two tax revenue sources and can be written as: Rt = wt 1 Tt + (1 wt 1) Ot (1) where T is the percentage change in revenue from the tax of interest, O is the percentage change in tax revenue from all other tax sources, and w t-1 is the tax s share of total state tax revenue in period t-1. The variance of R, denoted as V R, measures the variability in total state tax revenue. Using the standard formula for computing variance and assuming w is constant over time, V R can be expressed as: V 2 2 = w V + (1 w) V + 2 w(1 w) cov( T, O) R T O (2) 3

where V T and V O denote the variance in the percentage change in tax revenue from the specific tax and the variance in the percentage change in revenue from all other taxes, respectively. Differentiating equation (2) with respect to w gives: δvr δ w = wv T + ( w 1) VO + (1 2 w) cov( TO, ) (3) Let w * denote the tax s share of total tax revenue that minimizes the variance in total state tax revenue. Setting the derivative in (3) equal to zero and solving for w * yields: * VO cov( T, O) w = V + V 2cov( T, O) T O (4) Or, by convention * VO cov( T, O) w = VT ( O) (5) Second order conditions confirm w * is a minimum: 2 VR = V 2cov(, ) ( ) 0 2 T + VO T O V T O > w (6) The expression in (5) reveals that w * is a function of the variance of T and O and the covariance between T and O. Furthermore, the correlation between T and O also determines w * since cov( TO, ) = ρto, σt σo. A time series of state tax revenue data can be used to compute V T, V O, cov(t,o) and the variable of interest, w *. 4 4 Note that w * can fall outside the range 0 1. The conditions under which this will occur are discussed later in the paper. 4

III. Application Annual revenue data from personal income taxes, corporate income taxes, general sales taxes, and excise (selective sales) taxes were obtained over the period 1977 to 2000 for a sampling of U.S. states. 5 A fifth category of tax revenue, termed other tax revenue was computed by subtracting the summed revenue from the four taxes from actual total state tax revenue. 6 The value of w * for each tax is computed using equation (5). How closely the share of each tax minimizes the variance of total state tax revenue can be determined by comparing the variance minimizing value of w * with the actual value of w. Because w is not constant over time, w * is compared to both and to the mean value of w over the sample period. The results of this exercise appear in Table 1. [Table 1 about here] The data in Table 1 reveal that the actual tax revenue shares in some states are very close to the minimizing shares, but in some states there is a relatively large discrepancy between the actual shares and the variance minimizing shares. For example, the actual shares of tax revenue in Arkansas, Iowa, Louisiana and West Virginia are generally within several percentage points of the variance minimizing shares. On the other hand, the actual sales tax revenue share in Alabama is nearly 60 percentage points lower than the revenue minimizing share. Generalizing across the sample of states, actual shares of personal and corporate income tax revenue are closer to the variance minimizing shares than are actual shares of 5 State tax revenue data are available from the U.S. Census, State Government Finances. The excise tax category consists of taxes on alcohol, motor fuels, tobacco, amusements, pari-mutuels, public utilities, insurance premiums, and other select taxes. 6 On average, the revenue from the other category accounts for 10 percent of total state tax revenue. However, states such as Delaware, Montana, and New Hampshire have a significantly higher percentage of total tax revenue coming from other taxes (about 25 percent, on average). 5

sales and excise revenue. In fact, the actual shares of excise tax revenue and, to some degree sales tax revenue, are below their variance minimizing shares for many states. One possible reason for this finding is the changing tax mix that has occurred in many states over the past several decades. Specifically, the share of total tax revenue from sales and excise taxes has decreased over the past 25 years while the share of total tax revenue from personal income taxes has increased. Furthermore, sales and excise taxes tend to be less volatile in response to business cycle changes than income taxes (Holcombe and Sobel, 1996, 1997). Thus, states are becoming more reliant on more volatile tax revenues. This suggests that states should rely more heavily on excise and sales taxes (i.e. w for excise and sales taxes should be higher) in order to minimize the variance in total tax revenue. 7 In the case of California, the variance minimizing shares of personal income and corporate income tax revenue are negative since there is no inherent constraint on 0 1 in equation (5). It can be shown that, for a specific tax, <0 when the positive correlation between revenue from the specific tax and all other tax revenue is high and the standard deviation of the percentage change in revenue for the tax of interest is relatively large. 8 The fact that 0 w 1 suggests that specific revenue sources in some states, such as California, cannot not be structured to minimize tax total revenue variability given the existing tax mix and individual shares of tax revenue. 7 This may result in a tradeoff between growth and variability. Because excise taxes, unlike income and sales taxes, are not indexed to inflation, frequent rate increases would be required to maintain a real level of excise tax revenue. In addition, the trend from a goods producing economy to a service economy does not bode well for growing sales tax revenue since services are less likely to be taxed than durable and nondurables. Thus, while sales and excise taxes are less volatile, they may also have a lower growth potential than income taxes. See Holcombe and Sobel (1997) for a discussion on tax revenue growth and variability. 8 Consider the case of <0. This implies that V O < cov(t,0) in equation (5). Rewriting cov(t,o) as ρ T,O σ T σ O, it can be shown from V O < ρ T,O σ T σ O that <0 when σ T >σ O /ρ T,O and ρ T,O >0. Now consider the case of >1. This implies that V O - cov(t,0) > V(T-O) in equation (5). Rewriting V(T-O) as V T +V O - 2cov(T,O) and using cov(t,o) = ρ T,O σ T σ O, it can be shown that >1 when σ T <σ O ρ T,O and ρ T,O >0. 6

IV. Discussion This note has extended a model of portfolio theory to an analysis of state tax revenue variability. The model established the conditions in which the revenue share of a certain tax will minimize the variance in total state tax revenue. Applying actual tax revenue data for a sample of U.S. states revealed that some states have a tax mix that is relatively close to the mix that minimizes total tax revenue variability. The model also revealed that actual excise tax and sales tax revenue shares are below their revenue minimizing levels, thus reflecting states growing reliance on more volatile taxes. The model presented in this note serves as a useful complement to parametric techniques that have been used to estimate tax variability. The parametric approach provides evidence on how revenue from each tax responds to business cycle changes, and the portfolio approach can determine how the percentage change in revenue from a specific tax then affects the variability in total state tax revenue by examining how the variance minimizing share of each tax has changed. Furthermore, because the estimate of w * is a function of the sample period used, future work could examine the stability of w * over various periods of the business cycle. An extension of the model could allow for the analysis of multiple taxes rather than considering a specific tax and all other tax revenue. In this case, equation (1) would contain, say, percent changes in sales tax revenue, excise tax revenue, income tax revenue, and corporate income tax revenue. The covariance between each pair of tax sources would be obtained, thus providing disaggregated information on the relationship between individual tax sources. Such an extension would therefore provide a more detailed analysis of how changes in the tax mix influence total tax revenue variability. 7

Table 1 Actual and Variance Minimizing Shares Selected States Sales Excise Personal Income Corporate Income W 1999 Alabama Arkansas Arizona California Connecticut Iowa 0.2734 0.3477 0.4388 0.3134 0.3344 0.3381 0.2795 0.3626 0.4432 0.3296 0.3943 0.3024 0.8880 0.3523 0.0728 0.8573 0.6713 0.2377 0.2454 0.1358 0.1306 0.0779 0.1666 0.1484 0.2764 0.1860 0.1471 0.0926 0.2219 0.1539 0.2990 0.3865 0.1504 0.5619 0.5806 0.1844 0.3162 0.3111 0.2782 0.4246 0.3751 0.3523 0.2658 0.2905 0.2290 0.3609 0.1761 0.3643 0.0050 0.3173 0.4489-0.0422 0.0393 0.3868 0.0386 0.0460 0.0723 0.0754 0.0493 0.0482 0.0505 0.0630 0.0602 0.1130 0.1148 0.0590 0.0103 0.1060 0.0382-0.0131 0.0393 0.0423 Sales Excise Personal Income Corporate Income Illinois 0.2805 0.3159 0.5155 0.1908 0.1945 0.3908 0.3417 0.3094 0.2137 0.0992 0.0857 0.0550 Louisiana 0.3083 0.3095 0.2758 0.2600 0.1993 0.2469 0.2366 0.1623 0.1024 0.0441 0.0725 0.0023 New York 0.2059 0.2087 0.6930 0.1253 0.1359 0.2001 0.5317 0.4917 0.2822 0.0746 0.0875 0.1405 Ohio 0.3231 0.3166 0.1298 0.1547 0.2047 0.5371 0.3956 0.3170 0.1106 0.0413 0.0640 0.0788 Vermont 0.1481 0.1830 0.5878 0.1740 0.2850 0.9249 0.2762 0.3308 0.7076 0.0358 0.0594 0.2193 West Virginia 0.2717 0.3818 0.2255 0.2636 0.2135 0.2858 0.2786 0.2414 0.1251 0.0797 0.0609 0.0619 Note: is revenue as a share of total state tax revenue in 1999, the mean of w is the average share of total revenue over the sample period 1977-2000, and is the share of tax revenue that minimizes the variance of total state tax revenue based on equation (5). Per equation (1), each specific source of tax revenue is examined individually, with all remaining taxes summed into the other tax revenue category (not shown). 8

References Besley, T. and A. Case, 2003, Political Institutions and Policy Choices: Evidence from the United States, Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 7-73. Crain, M., 2003, Volatile States: Institutions, Policy, and the Performance of American State Economies, (University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor). Holcombe, R. and R. Sobel, 1996, Measuring the Growth and Variability of Bases over the Business Cycle, National Journal, 49, 535-552. Holcombe, R. and R. Sobel, 1997, Growth and Variability in State Revenue (Greenwood Press, Westport, Connecticut). Markowitz, H., 1952, Portfolio Selection, Journal of Finance, 7, 77-91. Szakmary, A. and C. Szakmary, 1995, State Lotteries as a Source of Revenue: A Re- Examination, Southern Economic Journal, 64, 1167-1181. Williams, W., R. Anderson, D. Froehle, and K. Lamb, 1973, The Stability, Growth, and Stabilizing Influence of State es, National Journal, 26, 267-274. 9