A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

Similar documents
Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

A No-Arbitrage Model Of Liquidity In Financial Markets Involving Stochastic Strings: Applications To High-Frequency Data

Hedging and Portfolio Optimization in Financial Markets with a Large Trader

Markets with convex transaction costs

Umut Çetin and L. C. G. Rogers Modelling liquidity effects in discrete time

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices. II: Continuous-time case

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Hedging under Arbitrage

Continuous time Asset Pricing

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

On Utility Based Pricing of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets

Hedging under arbitrage

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

Enlargement of filtration

Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Asset Price Bubbles in Complete Markets

An Explicit Example of a Shadow Price Process with Stochastic Investment Opportunity Set

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Information Aggregation in Dynamic Markets with Strategic Traders. Michael Ostrovsky

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

arxiv: v13 [q-fin.gn] 29 Jan 2016

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Numerical Solution of Stochastic Differential Equations with Jumps in Finance

Robust Portfolio Choice and Indifference Valuation

The value of foresight

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

On worst-case investment with applications in finance and insurance mathematics

Expected utility models. and optimal investments. Lecture III

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Asymmetric information in trading against disorderly liquidation of a large position.

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

On the pricing of emission allowances

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Pricing and Hedging of Credit Derivatives via Nonlinear Filtering

Asymptotic Maturity Behavior of the Term Structure

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

DOI: /s Springer. This version available at:

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

Martingale Measure TA

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Liquidity Risk and Classical Option Pricing Theory

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Financial Markets with a Large Trader: an Approach via Carmona-Nualart Integration

Characterization of the Optimum

Numerical Solution of Stochastic Differential Equations with Jumps in Finance

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Kim Weston (Carnegie Mellon University) Market Stability and Indifference Prices. 1st Eastern Conference on Mathematical Finance.

MARTINGALES AND LOCAL MARTINGALES

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term.

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Interest rate models in continuous time

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Transcription:

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices Dmitry Kramkov (joint work with Peter Bank) Carnegie Mellon University and University of Oxford 5th Oxford-Princeton Workshop on Financial Mathematics & Stochastic Analysis March 27-28, 2009 1 / 26

Outline Model for a small trader Features of a large trader model Literature (very incomplete!) Trading at market indifference prices Asymptotic analysis: summary of results Conclusion 2 / 26

Model for a small trader Input: price process S = (S t ) for traded stock. Key assumption: trader s actions do not affect S. For a simple strategy with a process of stock quantities: Q t = N θ n 1 (tn 1,t n], n=1 where 0 = t 0 < < t N = T and θ n L 0 (F tn 1 ), the terminal value N V T = V T (Q) = θ n (S tn S tn 1 ) n=1 Mathematical challenge: define terminal wealth V T for general predictable process Q = (Q t ). 3 / 26

Passage to continuous time trading Two steps: 1. Establish that S is a semimartingale 1.1 limit of discrete sums, when sequence (Q n ) of simple integrand converges uniformly (Bechteler-Dellacherie) 1.2 Absence of arbitrage for simple strategies (NFLBR) (Delbaen & Schachermayer (1994)). 2. If S is a semimartingale, then we can extend the map Q V T (Q) from simple to general (predictable) strategies Q arriving to stochastic integrals: V T (Q) = T 0 Q t ds t. 4 / 26

Basic results for the small trader model Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing: 1. Absence of arbitrage for general admissible strategies (NFLVR) S is a local martingale under an equivalent probability measure (Delbaen & Schachermayer (1994)). 2. Completeness Uniqueness of a martingale measure for S (Harrison & Pliska (1983), Jacod (1979)). Arbitrage-free pricing formula: in complete financial model the arbitrage-free price for a European option with maturity T and payoff ψ is given by p = E [ψ], where P is the unique martingale measure. 5 / 26

Desirable features of a large trader model Logical requirements: 1. Allow for general continuous-time trading strategies. 2. Obtain the small trader model in the limit: V T (ɛq) = ɛ T 0 Q t ds (0) t + o(ɛ), ɛ 0. Practical goal: computation of liquidity or price impact corrections to prices of derivatives: p(ɛ) = ɛe [ψ] + 1 2 ɛ2 C(ψ) +o(ɛ 2 ). }{{} liquidity correction Here p(ɛ) is a price for ɛ contingent claims ψ. Of course, we expect to have C(ψ) 0 for all ψ and < 0 for some ψ. 6 / 26

Literature (very incomplete!) Model is an input: Jarrow (1992), (1994); Frey and Stremme (1997); Platen and Schweizer (1998); Papanicolaou and Sircar (1998); Cuoco and Cvitanic (1998); Cvitanic and Ma (1996); Schonbucher and Wilmott (2000); Cetin, Jarrow and Protter (2002); Bank and Baum (2003); Cetin, Jarrow, Protter and Warachka (2006), Cetin, Touzi, and Soner (2008),... Model is an output (a result of equilibrium): Kyle (1985), Back (1990), Gârleanu, Pedersen, Poteshman (1997)... 7 / 26

Financial model 1. Uncertainty and the flow of information are modeled, as usual, by a filtered probability space (Ω, F, (F t ) 0 t T, P). 2. Traded securities are European contingent claims with maturity T and payments ψ = (ψ i ). 3. Prices are quoted by a finite number of market makers. 3.1 Utility functions (u m (x)) x R,m=1,...,M (defined on real line) are continuously differentiable, strictly increasing, strictly concave, and bounded above: u m ( ) = 0, m = 1,..., M. 3.2 Initial (random) endowments α 0 = (α m 0 ) 1 m M (F-measurable random variables) form a Pareto optimal allocation. 8 / 26

Pareto allocation Definition A vector of random variables α = (α m ) 1 m M is called a Pareto allocation if there is no other allocation β = (β m ) 1 m M of the same total endowment: M β m = m=1 M α m, m=1 which would leave all market makers not worse and at least one of them better off in the sense that E[u m (β m )] E[u m (α m )] for all 1 m M, and E[u m (β m )] > E[u m (α m )] for some 1 m M. 9 / 26

Pricing measure of Pareto allocation First-order condition: We have an equivalence between 1. α = (α m ) 1 m M is a Pareto allocation. 2. The ratios of the marginal utilities are non-random: u m(α m ) u n(α n ) = const(m, n). Pricing measure is defined by the marginal rate of substitution: dq dp = u m(α m ) E[u m(α m )], 1 m M. (Marginal) price process of the traded contingent claims ψ: S t = E Q [ψ F t ] 10 / 26

Simple strategy Strategy: a process of quantities Q = (Q t ) of ψ. Goal: specify the terminal value V T = V T (Q). Consider a simple strategy with the process of quantities: Q t = N θ n 1 (tn 1,t n], n=1 where θ n is F tn 1 -measurable. We shall define the corresponding cash balance process: X t = where ξ n is F tn 1 -measurable. N ξ n 1 (tn 1,t n], n=1 11 / 26

Trading at initial time 1. The market makers start with the initial Pareto allocation α 0 = (α m 0 ) 1 m M of the total (random) endowment: Σ 0 := M α0 m. m=1 2. After the trade in θ 1 shares at the cost ξ 1, the total endowment becomes Σ 1 = Σ 0 ξ 1 θ 1 ψ. 3. Σ 1 is redistributed as a Pareto allocation α 1 = (α m 1 ) 1 m M. 4. Key condition: the expected utilities of market makers do not change, that is, E[u m (α m 1 )] = E[u m (α m 0 )], 1 m M. 12 / 26

Trading at time t n 1. The market makers arrive to time t n with F tn 1 -Pareto allocation α n of the total endowment: Σ n = Σ 0 ξ n θ n ψ. 2. After the trade in θ n+1 θ n shares at the cost ξ n+1 ξ n, the total endowment becomes Σ n+1 =Σ n (ξ n+1 ξ n ) (θ n+1 θ n )ψ =Σ 0 ξ n+1 θ n+1 ψ. 3. Σ n+1 is redistributed as F tn -Pareto allocation α n+1. 4. Key condition: the conditional expected utilities of market makers do not change, that is, E[u m (α m n+1) F tn ] = E[u m (α m n ) F tn ], 1 m M. 13 / 26

Final step The large trader arrives at maturity t N = T with 1. quantity Q T = θ N of the traded contingent claims ψ. 2. cash amount X T = ξ N. Hence, finally, his terminal wealth is given by V T := X T + Q T ψ. Proposition For any simple strategy Q the cash balance process X = X (Q) and the terminal wealth V T = V T (Q) are well-defined. Mathematical challenge: define terminal wealth V T for general strategy Q. 14 / 26

More on economic assumptions The model is essentially based on two economic assumptions: Market efficiency After each trade the market makers form a complete Pareto optimal allocation. They can trade anything with each other (not only ψ)! Information The market makers do not anticipate (or can not predict the direction of) future trades of the large economic agent. Two strategies coinciding on [0, t] and different on [t, T ] will produce the same effect on the market up to time t. The agent can split any order in a sequence of very small trades at marginal prices. The expected utilities of market makers do not change. Remark From the investor s point of view this is the most friendly type of interaction with market makers. 15 / 26

Comparison with Arrow-Debreu equilibrium Economic assumptions behind a large trader model based on Arrow-Debreu equilibrium: Market efficiency (Same as above) After re-balance the market makers form a Pareto optimal allocation. They can trade anything between each other (not only ψ)! Information The market makers have perfect knowledge of strategy Q. Changes in Pareto allocations occur only at initial time. Expected utilities of market makers increase as the result of trade. 16 / 26

Model based on Arrow-Debreu equilibrium Given a strategy Q the market makers immediately change the initial Pareto allocation α 0 to another Pareto allocation α = α(q) with pricing measure P, the price process S t := E P[ψ F t ] and total endowment M Σ := α m such that Σ 0 Σ = m=1 T 0 Q t d S t, and the following clearing conditions hold true: E P[α 0 m ] = E P[ α m ], 1 m M. 17 / 26

Back to our model Mathematical challenge: define terminal wealth for general Q. Question Let Q and (Q n ) n 1 be simple strategies such that (Q n Q) T sup Qt n Q t 0, in probability. (1) 0 t T Do their terminal gains converge: V n T V T, in probability? (2) Question Let Q be a predictable process (with LCRL trajectories) and (Q n ) n 1 be simple strategies such that (1) holds. Is there a random variable V T such that (2) holds as well? 18 / 26

Process of Pareto allocations Consider a simple strategy Q t = N θ n 1 (tn 1,t n], n=1 where θ n is F tn 1 -measurable and denote by A t = N α n 1 (tn 1,t n] n=1 the corresponding (non-adapted!) process of Pareto allocations. Remark The Pareto allocation A t contains all information at time t but is not F t -measurable (infinite-dimensional sufficient statistic). 19 / 26

Process of indirect utilities The process of expected (indirect) utilities for market makers: U m t = E[u m (A m t ) F t ], 0 t T, 1 m M. Crucial observation: for a simple strategy Q at any time t knowledge of (U t, Q t ) knowledge of A t. (U, Q) is a finite-dimensional (!) sufficient statistic. 20 / 26

Technical assumptions Assumption The utility functions of market makers have bounded risk-aversion, risk-tolerance, and prudence coefficients: m(x) u u m(x) + u m(x) u m(x) + u m(x) u m(x) c <. Assumption The filtration is generated by a Brownian motion W = (W i ) and the Malliavin derivatives of the total initial endowment Σ 0 and the payoffs ψ = (ψ k ) are well-defined. 21 / 26

The key intermediate result Theorem Under the assumptions above there is a continuously differentiable stochastic vector field G = (G t (u, q)) satisfying the growth condition: T 0 sup u (,0) M, q x G t (u, q) 2 dt <, x > 0, (3) 1 + log u such that for any simple strategy Q the indirect utilities of the market makers solve the stochastic differential equation: du m t = U m t G m t (U t, Q t )dw t, U m 0 = E[u m (α m 0 )]. (4) Remark The role of (3) is to prevent the solution of (4) to hit 0. This is a linear growth solution for Z log( U). 22 / 26

Locally bounded strategies Theorem Assume the technical conditions above. Let (Q n ) be a sequence of simple processes and Q be a locally bounded predictable process such that 1. sup n 1 Q n is locally bounded 2. Q n Q in P[dω] dt. Then the terminal values V T (Q n ) converge in probability to V T (Q) = M α0 m m=1 M m=1 where U = U(Q) solves the following SDE: u 1 m (U m T ) du t = G t (U t, Q t )dw t, U m 0 = E[u m (α m 0 )]. 23 / 26

Remark on admissibility Contrary to classical small agent model the set of locally bounded strategies does not allow arbitrage. Indeed, U(Q) is a local martingale bounded above submartingale. It follows that Hence, V T (Q) = E[u m (A m T (Q))] E[u m(α m 0 )], 1 m M. M α0 m m=1 M A m T (Q) 0 V T (Q) = 0. m=1 24 / 26

Asymptotic analysis: summary of results For a strategy Q we have the following expansion for terminal wealth: T V T (ɛq) = ɛ Q u dsu 0 + 1 0 2 ɛ2 L T (Q), where L T (Q) can be computed by solving two auxiliary linear SDEs. We use above expansion to compute replication strategy and liquidity correction to the prices of derivatives in the next order (ɛ 2 ). (Good qualitative properties!) Liquidity correction to the prices of derivatives can also be computed using an expansion of market indifference prices. (Easier to do than hedging!). Key inputs: risk-tolerance wealth processes of market makers for initial Pareto equilibrium. 25 / 26

Conclusion We have developed a continuous-time model for large trader starting with economic primitives, namely, the preferences of market makers. In this model, the large investor trades smartly, not revealing herself to market makers and, hence, not increasing their expected utilities. We show that the computation of terminal wealth V T (Q) for a strategy Q comes through a solution of a non-linear SDE. The model allows us to compute rather explicitly liquidity corrections to the terminal capitals of trading strategies and to the prices of derivatives. The model has good qualitative properties. 26 / 26