Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Similar documents
Volatility. Roberto Renò. 2 March 2010 / Scuola Normale Superiore. Dipartimento di Economia Politica Università di Siena

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Torben G. Andersen

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Nicola Fusari

Short-Time Asymptotic Methods in Financial Mathematics

Optimum Thresholding for Semimartingales with Lévy Jumps under the mean-square error

I Preliminary Material 1

Testing for non-correlation between price and volatility jumps and ramifications

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Polynomial processes in stochastic portofolio theory

Asymptotic Theory for Renewal Based High-Frequency Volatility Estimation

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Asymptotic Methods in Financial Mathematics

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Economics 883: The Basic Diffusive Model, Jumps, Variance Measures. George Tauchen. Economics 883FS Spring 2015

Estimation of dynamic term structure models

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

Option Panels in Pure-Jump Settings. Torben G. Andersen, Nicola Fusari, Viktor Todorov and Rasmus T. Varneskov. CREATES Research Paper

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Modeling the dependence between a Poisson process and a continuous semimartingale

Recent Advances in Fractional Stochastic Volatility Models

Self-Exciting Corporate Defaults: Contagion or Frailty?

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Rough Heston models: Pricing, hedging and microstructural foundations

Short-time asymptotics for ATM option prices under tempered stable processes

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus With Applications

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Near-expiration behavior of implied volatility for exponential Lévy models

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations

Martingales & Strict Local Martingales PDE & Probability Methods INRIA, Sophia-Antipolis

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

Conditional Full Support and No Arbitrage

The stochastic calculus

Market Volatility and Risk Proxies

Economics 883: The Basic Diffusive Model, Jumps, Variance Measures, and Noise Corrections. George Tauchen. Economics 883FS Spring 2014

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Pricing and hedging with rough-heston models

Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels

Ultra High Frequency Volatility Estimation with Market Microstructure Noise. Yacine Aït-Sahalia. Per A. Mykland. Lan Zhang

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Beyond the Black-Scholes-Merton model

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2010, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay Solutions to Final Exam

Economics 201FS: Variance Measures and Jump Testing

Volatility Jumps. December 8, 2008

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Exact Sampling of Jump-Diffusion Processes

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Lecture 2: Rough Heston models: Pricing and hedging

Non-semimartingales in finance

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Modeling the extremes of temperature time series. Debbie J. Dupuis Department of Decision Sciences HEC Montréal

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

1 IEOR 4701: Notes on Brownian Motion

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

No-arbitrage and the decay of market impact and rough volatility: a theory inspired by Jim

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

King s College London

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Stochastic Volatility Models with Jumps

Short-Time Asymptotic Methods In Financial Mathematics

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Lecture 1: Lévy processes

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Short-Time Asymptotic Methods In Financial Mathematics

Option Pricing Modeling Overview

Financial Econometrics Notes. Kevin Sheppard University of Oxford

Risk Neutral Valuation

Pricing Variance Swaps on Time-Changed Lévy Processes

King s College London

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

Efficient multipowers

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

2 Control variates. λe λti λe e λt i where R(t) = t Y 1 Y N(t) is the time from the last event to t. L t = e λr(t) e e λt(t) Exercises

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Optimal Stopping for American Type Options

The Black-Scholes Model

Convergence Analysis of Monte Carlo Calibration of Financial Market Models

Econophysics V: Credit Risk

Option Pricing and Calibration with Time-changed Lévy processes

A Consistent Pricing Model for Index Options and Volatility Derivatives

Analytical formulas for local volatility model with stochastic. Mohammed Miri

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

On modelling of electricity spot price

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Université de Montréal. Rapport de recherche. Empirical Analysis of Jumps Contribution to Volatility Forecasting Using High Frequency Data

Transcription:

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies George Tauchen Duke University Viktor Todorov Northwestern University 2013

Motivation The standard model where dx t = α t dt + σ t dw t + dy t, α t is the drift, W t is Brownian motion, σ t is stochastic volatility, Y t is the jump component. 1

Motivation High-frequency data makes possible recovering functions of realized volatility path from discrete observations of X: integrated volatility T 0 σ2 s ds, integrated functions of volatility t 0 f(σ s)ds for some smooth f( ), spot volatility σ 2 t, volatility occupation times T 0 1 {σs A}ds. 2

Motivation The volatility high-frequency estimators are based on the local Gaussianity in X: 1 h (X t+sh X t ) L σ t (B t+s B s ), as h 0 and s [0, 1], where B t is a Brownian motion and the above convergence is for the Skorokhod topology. Local Gaussianity has two important features: the scaling factor of the increments is 1/ h, the limiting distribution of the increments is Gaussian. 3

Main Results The local Gaussianity critical for the statistical/econometric work. The goal of the paper is to make it testable. We estimate locally volatility. We scale the high-frequency increments by the local volatility estimates. We derive the limiting behavior of the empirical cdf of the scaled increments when X is jump-diffusion or when it is pure-jump. We apply the limit theory to propose Kolmogorov-Smirnov type tests for the jumpdiffusion Itô semimartingale class of models. 4

Outline Construction of the Empirical Distribution of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales Convergence in Probability Feasible CLT and testing Local Gaussianity Monte Carlo Empirical Illustration 5

Empirical CDF of Devolatilized Increments Setting: we observe X on the discrete grid 0, 1 n, 2 n,...1 with n, we split high-frequency observations into blocks containing k n k n such that k n /n 0. observations with To devolatilize increments we use a local jump-robust estimator of volatility: V n j = π 2 n k n jkn i=(j 1)kn+2 n i 1 X n i X, j = 1,..., n/k n, which is local Bipower Variation. Note: for the behavior of our statistic in the pure-jump case it is important to use Bipower Variation. 6

Empirical CDF of Devolatilized Increments To form the statistic we need to filter the big jumps. remaining high-frequency observations is The total number of the N n (α, ϖ) = n/kn j=1 (j 1)kn+mn i=(j 1)kn+1 1 ( n i X α V n j n ϖ ), where α > 0 an ϖ (0, 1/2) and 0 < m n < k n. Note: the truncation depends on the local volatility estimator. 7

Empirical CDF of Devolatilized Increments The empirical CDF of the devolatilized and truncated increments is F n (τ) = 1 N n (α, ϖ) n/kn j=1 (j 1)kn+mn i=(j 1)kn+1 1 n n i X 1 { V n n i X α V n j n ϖ} τ j. 8

Limit Behavior when X is Jump-Diffusion We have under some regularity conditions: F n (τ) P Φ(τ), as n, where the above convergence is uniform in τ over compact subsets of (, 0) (0, + ) and Φ(τ) is the cdf of a standard normal variable. 9

Limit Behavior when X is Pure-Jump A more general setting for X is the following model dx t = α t dt + σ t ds t + dy t, where α t, σ t and Y t are processes with càdlàg paths adapted to the filtration and Y t is of pure-jump type. S t is a stable process with a characteristic function given by log [ ] E(e iust ) = t cu β (1 iγsign(u)φ), Φ = { tan(πβ/2) if β 1, log u, if β = 1, 2 π where β (0, 2] and γ [ 1, 1]. 10

Limit Behavior when X is Pure-Jump When β = 2, above model is the standard jump-diffusion. When β < 2, the above model is of pure-jump type with locally stable jumps. Local Gaussianity generalizes to local Stability: h 1/β (X t+sh X t ) L σ t (S t+s S t ), as h 0 and s [0, 1], for every t and where S t is a Lévy process identically distributed to S t. Note: the different scaling factor, and the different limiting distribution. 11

Limit Behavior when X is Pure-Jump What happens with F n (τ) in the pure-jump setting? Recall the scaled devolatilized increments are n n i X V n j = n1/β n i X n 2/β 1 V n j, and n2/β 1 V n j is a consistent estimator for σ t in the pure-jump setting. 12

Limit Behavior when X is Pure-Jump Under some regularity conditions we have if β (1, 2] F n (τ) P F β (τ), as n, where the above convergence is uniform in τ over compact subsets of (, 0) (0, + ); 2 S F β (τ) is the cdf of 1 π E S 1 (S 1 is the value of the β-stable process S t at time 1) and F 2 (τ) equals the cdf of a standard normal variable Φ(τ). Note: 2 F β (τ) corresponds to the cdf of a random variable Z with E Z = π, = the difference between β < 2 and β = 2 will be in the relative probability assigned to big versus small values of τ. 13

Limit Behavior when X is Itô semimartingale + Noise What happens if X (either jump-diffusion or pure-jump) is contaminated with noise: where {ϵ in } i=1,...,n are i.i.d. X i n = X in + ϵ in, random variables defined on a product extension of the original probability space and independent from F and we further assume E ϵ in 1+ι < for some ι > 0. 14

Limit Behavior when X is Itô semimartingale + Noise What happens with F n (τ) in the noisy setting? Recall the scaled devolatilized increments are n n i X V n j = n i X n 1 V n j, and n 1 is the correct scaling factor that ensures V n j converges to a non-degenerate limit. 15

Limit Behavior when X is Itô semimartingale + Noise Under certain regularity conditions we have F n (τ) P F ϵ (τ), as n, where the above convergence is uniform in τ over compact subsets of (, 0) (0, + ) and we denote µ = π 2 F ϵ (τ) is the cdf of 1 µ ( E ϵ in ϵ i 1 ( ) ϵ in ϵ i 1. n ϵ i 1 n n ) ϵ i 2, n 16

Limit Behavior when X is Itô semimartingale + Noise If ϵ in is normally distributed then n n i X V n j N(0, σ 2 ), where σ 2 = 2 π 2 E ( ξ 1 + ξ 2 ξ 2 + ξ 3 ), with ξ 1, ξ 2 and ξ 3 independent standard normals. Note: σ 2 < 1. 17

CLT when X is jump-diffusion Theorem 1. Let X t be jump-diffusion satisfying some regularity conditions. Further, let the block size grow at the rate m n k n 0, k n n q, for some q (0, 1/2), when n. We then have locally uniformly in subsets of (, 0) (0, + ) F n (τ) Φ(τ) = Ẑn 1 (τ) + Ẑn 2 (τ) + 1 τ 2 Φ (τ) τφ (τ) k n 8 ( ) 1 + o p, k n ( (π ) 2 + π 3) 2 18

CLT when X is jump-diffusion with the pair (Ẑn 1 (τ), Ẑn 2 (τ)) having the following limit behavior ( n/k n m n Ẑ n1 (τ) n/k n k n Ẑ n2 (τ) ) L (Z 1 (τ) Z 2 (τ)), where Φ(τ) is the cdf of a standard normal variable and Z 1 (τ) and Z 2 (τ) are two independent Gaussian processes with covariance functions Cov (Z 1 (τ 1 ), Z 1 (τ 2 )) = Φ(τ 1 τ 2 ) Φ(τ 1 )Φ(τ 2 ), [ τ1 Φ (τ 1 ) τ 2 Φ ] (τ 2 ) ( ( ) π 2 Cov (Z 2 (τ 1 ), Z 2 (τ 2 )) = + π 3), τ 1, τ 2 R \ 0. 2 2 2 19

CLT when X is jump-diffusion Comments: Z 1 (τ) is the standard Brownian bridge appearing in the Donsker theorem for empirical processes Z 2 (τ) is due to the estimation of the local scale σ t via V n j the third component in F n (τ) Φ(τ) is asymptotic bias picking the rate of growth of m n and k n arbitrary close to n, we can make the rate of convergence of F n (τ) arbitrary close to n asymptotic bias and variances are constant = feasible inference is straightforward n rate is in general not possible because of the presence of the drift term in X 20

Kolmogorov Smirnov test The critical region of our proposed test is given by C n = { } sup N n (α, ϖ) F n (τ) Φ(τ) > q n (α, A) τ A where recall Φ(τ) denotes the cdf of a standard normal random variable, α (0, 1), A R \ 0 is a finite union of compact sets with positive Lebesgue measure, and q n (α, A) is the (1 α)-quantile of sup τ A Z 1(τ) + mn k n Z 2 (τ) + mn k n n τ 2 Φ (τ) τφ (τ) k n 8 ( (π ) 2 ) + π 3 2, with Z 1 (τ) and Z 2 (τ) being the Gaussian processes defined in the Theorem. 21

Kolmogorov Smirnov test We have lim n P (C n ) = α, if β = 2 and lim inf n P (C n ) = 1, if β (1, 2). 22

Monte Carlo We test performance on the following models: Jump-Diffusion Model dx t = V t dw t + R xµ(ds, dx), dv t = 0.03(1.0 V t )dt + 0.1 V t db t, where (W t, B t ) is a vector of Brownian motions with corr(w t, B t ) = 0.5 and µ is a homogenous Poisson measure with compensator ν(dt, dx) = dt 0.25e x /0.4472 0.4472 dx which corresponds to double exponential jump process with intensity of 0.5. Pure-Jump Model X t = S Tt, with T t = t 0 V s ds, where S t is a symmetric tempered stable martingale with Lévy measure 0.1089e x x 1+1.8 V t is the square-root diffusion given above. and 23

Monte Carlo Tuning parameters: time span: 252 days frequency: n = 100 and n = 200 corresponding to 5-min and 2-min sampling n/k n in the range 1 3 blocks per day m n /k n = 0.75 for n = 100 and m n /k n = 0.70 for n = 200 α = 3 and ϖ = 0.49 for jump cutoff 24

Monte Carlo Table 1: Monte Carlo Results for Jump-Diffusion Model Nominal Size Rejection Rate Sampling Frequency n = 100 k n = 33 k n = 50 k n = 100 α = 1% 4.1 0.4 2.2 α = 5% 15.4 3.6 10.6 Sampling Frequency n = 200 k n = 67 k n = 100 k n = 200 α = 1% 1.2 2.0 7.8 α = 5% 4.4 7.1 26.2 Note: For the cases with n = 100 we set m n /k n = 0.75 and for the cases with n = 200 we set m n /k n = 0.70. 25

Monte Carlo Table 2: Monte Carlo Results for Pure-Jump Model Nominal Size Rejection Rate Sampling Frequency n = 100 k n = 33 k n = 50 k n = 100 α = 1% 27.5 87.4 99.9 α = 5% 66.6 97.5 100.0 Sampling Frequency n = 200 k n = 67 k n = 100 k n = 200 α = 1% 100.0 100.0 100.0 α = 5% 100.0 100.0 100.0 Note: For the cases with n = 100 we set m n /k n = 0.75 and for the cases with n = 200 we set m n /k n = 0.70. 26

Empirical Application-I We use two data sets: IBM stock price and the VIX volatility index, sample period 2003-2008, test is performed for each of the years in the sample, we perform test at 5-minute and 2-minute frequencies, n/k n = 2 for the five-minute sampling frequency and n/k n = 3 for the two-minute frequency, the range for the KS test is A = [Q(0.01) : Q(0.40)] [Q(0.60) : Q(0.99)], where Q(α) is the α-quantile of standard normal. 27

IBM, 5 min VIX, 5 min 4 4 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 8 IBM, 2 min 8 VIX, 2 min 6 6 4 4 2 2 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Year 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Year 28

Empirical Application-II S&P index, 5-min 2007 2012 VIX futures prices also 2007 2012 Examine Q-Q plots before and after truncating large jumps. Examine Q-Q plots for stable-like prices 29

QQ-Plot S&P 500, raw and truncated for large jumps S&P 500 2 2 1 1 0 0 1 1 2 2 2 1 0 1 2 2 1 0 1 2 30

VIX Futures Things are not nearly as clear-cut with these data. 31

QQ-Plot VIX futures, raw and truncated for large jumps 8 6 4 2 0 2 4 6 8 10 4 2 0 2 4 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 4 2 0 2 4 32

VIX futures: Determination of the index β We need to know the activity index β in order to get a reference stable distribution. We minimize the mean squared difference of OBS-PRED for Q-Q plot data over a grid of β. 33

Objective Function 52.5 52 Integrated distance between quantiles 51.5 51 50.5 50 49.5 49 1.75 1.8 1.85 1.9 beta 34

Final Q-Q Plots We look at Q-Q plots using the Gaussian distribution as the reference and then using the stable( ˆβ = 1.82...) as the reference distribution. We now look at the left and right tails of Q-Q plots: 35

Left and right sides of QQ-Plots of unscaled and scaled VIX futures vs stable( ˆβ) 0 4 1 3 2 2 3 1 4 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2 0 4 1 3 2 2 3 1 4 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2 36

Conclude Can test the core distributional assumption of financial modeling Useful for examining risk premiums of jumps of different size. Potentially very relevant to regulators who monitor markets to identify unusual trading patterns. Other multivariate applications in progress, 37