Introduction Intuitive Gravity Structural Gravity Discrete Choice Gravity. The Gravity Model. James E. Anderson. Boston College and NBER.

Similar documents
International Trade Gravity Model

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE CHANGING INCIDENCE OF GEOGRAPHY. James E. Anderson Yoto V. Yotov. Working Paper

Gravity, Distance, and International Trade

Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries

The Changing Incidence of Geography

The Changing Incidence of Geography

CHAPTER 1: Partial equilibrium trade policy analysis with structural gravity 1

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

Lecture 3: New Trade Theory

International Trade and Income Differences

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle

An Advanced Guide to Trade Policy Analysis: The Structural Gravity Model. Yoto V. Yotov, Roberta Piermartini, José-Antonio Monteiro, and Mario Larch

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum. Topics in international Trade

Terms of Trade and Global Efficiency Effects of Free Trade Agreements,

Research at Intersection of Trade and IO. Interest in heterogeneous impact of trade policy (some firms win, others lose, perhaps in same industry)

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

Terms of Trade and Global Efficiency Effects of Free Trade Agreements,

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel

The Composition of Exports and Gravity

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices

Measurement of Protection

International Trade Lecture 1: Trade Facts and the Gravity Equation

Choice Probabilities. Logit Choice Probabilities Derivation. Choice Probabilities. Basic Econometrics in Transportation.

International Economics: Lecture 10 & 11

Eaton and Kortum, Econometrica 2002

International Trade Lecture 1: Trade Facts and the Gravity Equation

World Trade Organization Economic Research and Statistics Division

Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments

Foreign Direct Investment I

14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 12 and 13 Input-Output Linkages: Implications for Productivity and Volatility

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Econ 8401-T.Holmes. Lecture on Foreign Direct Investment. FDI is massive. As noted in Ramondo and Rodriquez-Clare, worldwide sales of multinationals

A gravity equation of bank loans

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 1: Ricardian Models (I)

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Homework Assignments

The effect of free trade agreements revisited: Does residual trade cost bias matter?

Do Customs Union Members Engage in More Bilateral Trade than Free-Trade Agreement Members?

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

Computing General Equilibrium Theories of Monopolistic Competition and Heterogeneous Firms

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

DETERMINANTS OF TRADE IN VALUE-ADDED:

Bilateral Trade in Textiles and Apparel in the U.S. under the Caribbean Basin Initiative: Gravity Model Approach

Institutional Distance and Foreign Direct Investment

DATA BASE AND METHODOLOGY

The Gravity Model: A workhorse model for empirical analysis of international trade

Offshoring and skill-upgrading in French manufacturing: a Heckscher-Ohlin-Melitz view

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model

An Analysis of the CSI Effect on the U.S. Trade (Draft)

Chapter 3: Predicting the Effects of NAFTA: Now We Can Do It Better!

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

Gravity Redux: Structural Estimation of Gravity Equations with Asymmetric Bilateral Trade Costs

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

INTERNATIONAL REAL ESTATE REVIEW 2002 Vol. 5 No. 1: pp Housing Demand with Random Group Effects

Introduction to the Maximum Likelihood Estimation Technique. September 24, 2015

Economic Determinants of Free Trade Agreements Revisited: Distinguishing Sources of Interdependence

Essays on Trade, Inequality, and Gravity

Poultry in Motion: A Study of International Trade Finance Practices

International Trade and Income Differences

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Bias in Reduced-Form Estimates of Pass-through

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright

International Trade: Lecture 4

Effects of WTO accession on Vietnam s trade:

Definition 9.1 A point estimate is any function T (X 1,..., X n ) of a random sample. We often write an estimator of the parameter θ as ˆθ.

International Development and Firm Distribution

The Effect of the Uruguay Round on the Intensive and Extensive Margins of Trade

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data

Trade Liberalization, Growth, and FDI: A Structural Estimation Framework

Disaggregated trade and disaggregated currency unions: a ranking of common currency effects

Small Sample Bias Using Maximum Likelihood versus. Moments: The Case of a Simple Search Model of the Labor. Market

Outward FDI and Total Factor Productivity: Evidence from Germany

Stock Price Sensitivity

Gravity Redux: Measuring International Trade Costs with Panel Data

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

Price Discrimination and Trade in Intermediate Goods (Preliminary Draft)

Modelling International Trade

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets

Week 7 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Simulation Methods

TWO ESSAYS ON THE ESTIMATION OF AGRICULTURAL TRADE FLOWS: MODEL SELECTION AND ENDOGENEITY OF TRADE AGREEMENTS. David R. Thibodeau

Firm-to-Firm Trade: Imports, Exports, and the Labor Market

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

Heterogeneous Firms. Notes for Graduate Trade Course. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. January 30, 2013

Transcription:

The Gravity Model James E. Anderson Boston College and NBER March 2011

Outline Introduction Intuitive Gravity Size Effects Structural Gravity Differentiated Demand Differentiated Productivity Discrete Choice Gravity Selection to Trade Migration Firms Choice of Destinations

Motivation Striking facts: enormous variation in economic interaction across space. Gravity flows increasing in size of markets, decreasing in distance, very good fit, stable coefficient estimates. Implication: unobservable trade costs are BIG. What makes a model successful or the facts it addresses interesting (to economists)? Gravity example. Intellectual orphan long ignored by mainstream economists e.g. Leamer and Levinsohn (1995) Handbook. Progress with theoretical foundations adoption by the family (Feenstra, 2004) and continuing refinements. Intuitive appeal empirically and theoretically popularity.

History Analogy with Newton s Law of Gravity. X ij = Y i E j /d 2 ij gives the predicted movement of goods or labor between i and j, X ij as product of origin mass Y i, destination mass E j, divided by distance d 2 ij. Looser analogy with mass and distance exponents estimated to be around 1 for each. Better fit with more proxies for resistance to trade such as common language, borders, etc. First applied to migration in UK by Ravenstein (1884) First applied to trade by Tinbergen (1962).

More Recent History Bilateral frictions alone seem inadequate to explain X ij ; flow from i to j is influenced by resistance to i s shipments on its other possible destinations, resistance to shipments to j from j s other possible sources of supply; analogue to Newtonian gravity N-body problem. Remoteness: i d ij/y i captures intuition that each country j has distance from all others that matters. Index is atheoretic and fails to deal with simultaneity of N-body analogy. Multilateral resistance of structural gravity model is the solution.

Aggregate vs. Disaggregate Gravity applied mostly to aggregate flows of goods or populations. But theory applies to disaggregated goods (e.g., by sectors) and factors (e.g., by skill level of migrants). Serious downward aggregation bias (Anderson and Yotov, 2010). Gravity applied mostly to highly aggregated regions (e.g., nations). But theory applies to disaggregated regions. Which aggregates? Usual gravity mass variables are GDP s for Y s and national incomes for Es. But gravity logic applies to gross flows, not value added or expenditure on final goods.

Frictionless Gravity Action via mass variables: clear intuition, some not quite obvious results. Implications from frictionless gravity point toward a structural theory. Benchmark trade pattern of frictionless world helps draw inference of trade frictions. Smooth world: agents purchase goods in same proportions everywhere. Then X ij = Y i E j i Y i = Y i Y. Multiply both sides by E j, yielding frictionless gravity: where b j = E j /Y and s i = Y i /Y. X ij = Y ie j Y = s ib j Y, (1)

Size Effects in Frictionless Gravity 1. Big producers have big market shares everywhere, 2. small sellers are more open in the sense of trading more with the rest of the world, 3. the world is more open the more similar in size and the more specialized the countries are, 4. the world is more open the greater the number of countries, and 5. world openness rises with convergence under the simplifying assumption of balanced trade.

Size Effects Formally Implication 1: big producers have big market shares everywhere because the frictionless gravity prediction is that : X ij /E j = s i. Implication 2, small sellers are more open in the sense of trading more with the rest of the world follows from X ij /E j = 1 Y j /Y = 1 s j i j using j E j = i Y i, balanced trade for the world.

World Openness Define world openness as the ratio of international shipments to total shipments, j i j X ij/y. Dividing (1) through by Y, world openness is given by X ij /Y = b j (1 s j ) = 1 b j s j. j i j j j Using standard properties of covariance and j s j = j b j = 1: X ij /Y = 1 1/N Nr bs Var(s)Var(b) (2) j i j Variance Var(s), Var(b) measures size dis-similarity while the correlation of s and b, r bs, is an inverse measure of specialization. Implication 3 follows from equation (2).

More on Size Effects More novel implication 4, world openness is ordinarily increasing in the number of countries: smaller countries are more open; division makes for more and smaller countries. Differentiate j i j X ij/y = 1 j b js j, yielding j (b j ds j + s j db j ). The differential expression above should ordinarily be positive.

More on Size Effects On aggregate trade data, gravity implication 5, world openness rises with convergence under balanced trade, b j = s j, j. The right hand side of equation (2) NVar(s) + 1/N while per capita income convergence lowers Var(s) toward Var(population). Baier and Bergstrand (2001) find relatively little action from convergence in postwar growth. Recent rise of China and India might give more action. But size interacts with frictions and their incidence...

Basic Elements Detail, high variation of bilateral shipments infer trade costs. Economize on other details of economic interaction to preserve bilateral detail. Solution: Modularity, consistent with many g, e. superstructures. Focus on distribution for given levels of supply at each origin and given demand at each destination. Requires separability restrictions on preferences and/or technology Requires separability of distribution costs. Iceberg melting distribution uses resources in same proportion as production.

Three Structural Frameworks of Distribution The same structural gravity model 3 frameworks: Differentiated Products in Demand, given supply and expenditure Differentiated Productivity in Supply, homogeneous demand Discrete Choice Aggregation (3rd lecture) General equilibrium of distribution (conditional on upper level supply and demand variables).

Differentiated Demand CES demand structure (final or intermediate) X k ij = ( β k i p k i t k ij P k j ) 1 σk E k j (3) where ( ) 1/(1 σk ) P k j = i (β k i p k i t k ij )1 σ k (4) Market clearance at end user prices: Y k i = j X k ij. Use (3) in market clearance eqn., then factor out (β k i p k i ) 1 σ k.

Substitute for (β k i p k i ) 1 σ k : Distribution Equilibrium X k ij = E k j Yi k Y k ( t k ij P k j Π k i ) 1 σk (5) (Π k i )1 σ k = j (P k j ) 1 σ k = i ( t k ij P k j ( t k ij Π k i ) 1 σk E k j Y k (6) ) 1 σk Y k i Y k. (7) (5)-(7) is the structural gravity model. (5) is the trade flow equation. Π k i denotes outward multilateral resistance (OMR), while Pj k denotes inward multilateral resistance (IMR).

Empirical Orientation YX ij /Y i E j is ratio of actual trade to frictionless trade; related to proxies for unobservable trade frictions: t ij = exp(γ 0 + γ 1 ln d ij + γ z z + φ i + µ j + ln ɛ ij ) (8) where d ij is bilateral distance, z is other controls such as common language, φ i is an exporter fixed effect and µ j is an importer fixed effect. Could also use full information methods to replace φs and µs. More risky estimation (but Anderson-Yotov 2010b suggested structural gravity comes very close). My take: gravity is about estimating (8). Agnosticism about upper level linkage. Size effects controlled for by origin and destination fixed effects.

Disaggregation Again Appropriate disaggregation should be used to estimate (8). Trade costs probably differ by firm. If data permits... Distinction between arms-length and various degrees of affiliation probably matters. Appropriate proxies, direct data where possible (but endogeneity).

Normalization (8) can only identify relative trade costs from perturbations of relative trade flows from frictionless trade flows. Levels of t ij implied by regression are due to implicit normalization. In practice, normalize {t ij } by min i t ii = 1. Given ts, (6)-(7) can be solved for Πs and Ps up to a normalization. Full g.e. consistency restricts the normalization in each sector.

Incidence Πs and Ps are sellers and buyers incidence respectively. Replace actual tij ks by Πk i Pk j in equations (6)-(7): they continue to hold given Es and Y s. Structural gravity also implies (β k i p k i Π k i )1 σ k = Y k i /Y k, i, k (9) where βs are CES parameters and p s are factory gate prices. Because i (βk i pi k Π k i )1 σ k = 1, the left hand side of (9) is a CES expenditure share on world market. Effectively good k from i is sold at uniform sellers incidence Π k i to a world market.

Incidence and TFP Multilateral resistance is interpreted as the incidence of TFP frictions in distribution. Sectoral TFP friction in distribution from i in good k: t i k = j tk ij y ij k/ j y ij k. Laspeyres index of trade frictions. Compare to Π k i. t k i gives the sellers incidence Π k i only under the p.e. and inconsistent assumption that all incidence falls on the seller i. Laspeyres TFP and incidence of TFP differ in magnitude and for IMR the correlation between them is low (Anderson and Yotov, 2010a,b).

Useful Structural Gravity Indexes CHB i ( tii Π i P i ) 1 σ. CHB varies substantially by country, product and time despite constant gravity coefficients (Anderson and Yotov; 2010a,b). Border Effects: inter-regional/international trade costs. For British Columbia s exports to adjacent Alberta and across the US border to adjacent Washington X BC,AB X BC,WA = ( ) tbc,wa P σ 1 AB. t BC,AB P WA Anderson and Yotov (2010a) decompose sellers incidence into domestic and international components for Canada s provinces.

Comparative Statics Structural gravity comparative statics of incidence. For given E and Y shares, calculate changes in incidence Π s and P s due to changes in t s. Trade flows in (5) are invariant to a uniform rise in trade costs (including costs of internal shipment). Π s and P s are HD(1/2) in t s. For given t s calculate changes in incidence due to change E, Y s. The empirical literature tends to indicate little change in gravity coefficients, but big changes in CHB (Anderson-Yotov 2010a,b). Full general equilibrium structure changes in Y, E s induced by change in ts or other exogenous variables.

Differential Productivity (5)-(7) also by Ricardian technology drawn from a Frechet probability distribution (Eaton and Kortum, 2002). CES demand for intermediates homogeneous across origins; substitution on intensive margin disappears in equilibrium. Productivity draws plus trade frictions equilibrium wages that assign to countries effectively CES proportions of the continuum of goods. Frechet dispersion parameter comparative advantage, substitutability on extensive margin like σ on intensive margin. Location parameter differs nationally, represents absolute advantage, acts like β k i s taste advantage on intensive margin. Absolute advantage and country size explain the Y s and Es

Discrete Choice Gravity Three aspects of discrete choice over origin-destination flows 1. zeroes in trade flows some potential flows are equal to zero. may imply non-ces (with σ > 1), hence choke price. Translog promise here. but may imply fixed export cost, discrete choice by firms to enter. fixed export cost suggests a volume effect, selection of number of active firms. 2. migrant choice of destination 3. firm s choice over destinations

Zeroes HMR: CES/Armington preferences; zeroes fixed costs of export facing firms. High productivity firms choose to pay the fixed cost of exporting; if none do then zero trade from i. The gravity model becomes X k ij = E k j Yi k Y k V k ij ( t k ij P k j Π k i ) 1 σk (Π k i )1 σ k = j (P k j ) 1 σ k = i ( t k ij P k j ( t k ij Π k i ) 1 σk Vij ke j k Y k ) 1 σk Vij k. Y i k Y k. V k ij generated by selection equation separately estimated.

Econometrics of Zeroes HMR results suggest selection is potent: reduces variable trade cost coefficients. OLS alternative: drop the zeroes; disallow selection. In principle this is OK if no selection. Tobit is not OK. Santos-Silva and Tenreyro (2006) suggest that estimation the log of (8) is biased due to non-normal heteroskedastic ɛ ij. Alternative estimation is Poisson-Pseudo-Maximum-Likelihood (PPML). No treatment of selection. Anderson-Yotov (2010b) find that OLS, PPML and HMR give equivalent results on normalized ts, due to near perfect collinearity of gravity coefficients in the three methods.

Selection in HMR Selection mechanism: non-negative profits requirement selects upper tail of Pareto productivity distribution of potential trading firms. Pareto is consistent with observation that the largest and most productive firms export the most. Pareto allows estimation with industry trade data. Notice that zeroes do not arise if the support of the productivity distribution is not bounded above. Artificial restriction? Besedes and Prusa (2006 JIE, CJE): (US 10 digit HS bilateral) trade flickers on and off, tending to contradict fixed costs. Translog choke prices, combine with fixed costs: possibly discriminate between two explanations of zeroes.

Migration and Multinomial Logit Let w i denote the wage at location i, i. Migrant from j to i with iceberg cost factor δ ji > 1 receives net wage (w i /δ ji ). Assume logarithmic utility. Migrant s utility of migration is u ji = ln w i ln δ ji ln w j + ln ɛ jih, where the idiosyncratic utility of migration ln ɛ jih is not observable by the econometrician. Worker chooses the destination with the largest surplus. McFadden (1973) showed that if ln ɛ had the type-1 extreme value distribution, the probability that a randomly drawn individual would pick any particular migration destination has the multinomial logit form. Migrant proportions thus have the multinomial logit form, w i and w j are fixed effects and δ ji is proxied by gravity variables.

Structural Gravity Setup Make use of market clearance in the same way as for goods (thus model distribution of stocks of labor). With logarithmic utility, the migration equation is analogous to the CES demand M ji = w i /δ ji k w k /δ jk Nj. (10) Solve the market clearance equations for each destination of labor and substitute out in the bilateral flow equations.

Structural Gravity Model of Migration M ji = Li N j N 1/δ ji Ω i W j. (11) Ω i = j W j = k 1/δ ji W j 1/δ jk Ω k N j N. (12) L k N. (13) Can get the CES form if utility is the log of a CRRA function. Ω and W have buyers and sellers incidence interpretation.

Other Potential Applications Services trade (Head and Mayer) FDI Portfolio investment not very amenable to finding structural gravity so far.

Multinomial Logit and Trade One approach to trading firms choice of destinations follows the migration model and applies multinomial logit. In principle this could look exactly like (8), but attention to the detailed implications might suggest useful alternative trade proxies or direct evidence. An important objection to this simple procedure is that firms do not choose one destination out of many independent choices. Instead, the firm may realize that each choice affects the cost of reaching other destinations. Multinomial logit is no longer appropriate.

Sequencing Export Entry Morales (Harvard, 2010) has applied new techniques from applied IO to estimate how firms choose multiple markets over time. Cannot infer exact size of sunk costs from choices of firms, but the observed choices (coupled with weak assumptions on firm behavior) can be used to rule out certain regions of the parameter space. Averaging over different firms decisions in different markets yields a set (or interval) of parameter values consistent with firm behavior. Moment Inequality Estimation, first application in trade. No need to impose that firms have perfect foresight nor that they have rational expectations.