Price Discrimination and Trade in Intermediate Goods (Preliminary Draft)

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Price Discrimination and Trade in Intermediate Goods (Preliminary Draft)"

Transcription

1 Price Discrimination and Trade in Intermediate Goods (Preliminary Draft) Anna Ignatenko March 3, 2018 Abstract In this paper, I document the existence of price discrimination in firm-to-firm cross-border transactions. First, using firm-level Customs data from Chile, I find that larger buyers of the same inputs are charged lower input prices. To rationalize this finding, I build a novel model of trade in inputs featuring two-sided heterogeneity. Heterogeneous input suppliers compete in prices a la Bertrand and internalize the effect of their decisions on market aggregates. Final goods producers also differ in exogenous productivity, but can reduce the costs of production by integrating backwards into input production. In equilibrium, to discourage entry in the upstream market, input producers charge lower prices to larger final goods producers and thus engage in third-degree price discrimination. I also study the implications of price discrimination for entry and exit of firms, trade and consumer welfare. PhD Candidate at the University of California, Davis: aignatenko@ucdavis.edu 1

2 1 Introduction In the face of new and more granular firm-level data, a recurring finding is that firms charge different prices to different buyers: a violation of the Law of One Price. The existing trade literature has overwhelmingly explained this through a theory that different destination countries demand different qualities of goods, and that the price variation across buyers is accounted for by differences in qualities. In other words, the Law of One Price is not in fact violated because the goods being sold are different. However, another and perhaps even more natural explanation for the firm-to-firm price variation, is that the goods are in fact the same but firms discriminate across different buyers. This alternative explanation for the price patterns in trade has been demonstrated to be valid in the firmto-end-consumer context by Simonovska (2015), and has been studied extensively in an industrial organization literature that dates back as early as Robinson (1933). It would also seem natural then that discrimination could also occur in firm-to-firm transactions, which has been studied by industrial organization economists since at least Katz (1987). There are countless anecdotal examples of different firms obtaining different input prices from domestic suppliers: Wal-Mart, for example, is notorious for their lower input prices for identical goods. It would be surprising if firm-to-firm discrimination did not explain at least some of the variation in prices across buyers. In this paper, I first document price differences in firm-to-firm cross-border transactions that are consistent with third-degree price discrimination in inputs markets. In particular, using firm-level Customs data from Chile, I find that firms buying larger quantities of inputs face lower input prices. To rationalize this finding, I build a novel model of international trade of inputs, in which price discrimination arises as a result of strategic interaction of buyers and sellers of inputs. Building on the idea proposed in Katz (1987), in this model production of final goods requires inputs that heterogeneous final goods producers can either buy from upstream intermediate goods producers and/or produce themselves. Obtaining the upstream technology for downstream producers is costly, and thus only more productive firms find it worthwhile to produce inputs in-house. On the other hand, intermediate goods producers upstream compete in prices and are large enough to internalize the effect of their pricing decisions on market aggregates. This implies that intermediate goods producers have incentives to engage in price discrimination and set prices inversely proportional to downstream firms elasticity of demand. Larger buyers of inputs can partially rely on their own inputs and thus have higher elasticity of demand for inputs they do buy. As a result, in equilibrium, input producers charge lower prices to their larger buyers of inputs. Intu- 2

3 itively, the threat of losing larger buyers is what makes input producers lower their prices for larger firms, compared to those they charge to smaller firms. This is the first model of trade featuring endogenous third-degree price discrimination in inputs markets. Interestingly, in inputs markets price discrimination implies the opposite direction of price differences, compared to the price discrimination in the markets of consumer goods. In that literature (e.g. Simonovska (2015), Jung et al. (2015)), consumers with higher demand ( high type ) face higher prices relative to consumers with lower demand ( low type ). Such difference in the predictions arises because consumers, unlike, final goods producers, can not threaten the producers to leave the market. Studying price discrimination in inputs markets in the context of international trade brings several additional insights to both the industrial organization and international trade literatures. First, free entry condition, often evoked in trade models, allows to study the effect of price discrimination on firm s entry and exit decisions as well as other aggregate outcomes. In the industry equilibrium of the model, wider opportunities for price discrimination in inputs markets lead to higher expected profits of downstream firms and fewer active firms in the market. Since only the most productive firms remain on the market, it benefits the final goods consumers through lower price of a consumption basket. Secondly, firm s decisions to export and to produce inputs in-house are complementary: access to foreign markets provides an additional incentive to invest in in-house production of inputs. Thus, instances of trade liberalization in the downstream sector can be used to identify the relationship between firm productivity (or size) and the input prices the firm faces. Third, detailed firm-level data collected by Customs agencies allows to empirically study the existence of price discrimination in a wide range of industries. International trade data suggests that intermediate goods account for as much as twothirds of cross-border transactions of goods. These imported inputs are shown to have positive impact on firm productivity (e.g. Blaum et al. (2015), Halpern et al. (2015)) and imply lower consumer prices. Most studies in international trade, however, ignore the fact that most buyers and sellers of inputs are large multinational firms with significant market power. In absence of market power, input producers can not price discriminate across buyers. Thus, all results related to the input trade are obtained under the assumption of common prices conditional on quality. In this paper I show that this assumption is strictly violated in the data and then study how price discrimination our understanding of trade in inputs and its implications for productivity and the gains of trade liberalization. This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, I document price variation in firm-tofirm transactions that is consistent with the existence of price discrimination. In Section 3, I introduce a new model of trade that explains such variation, in Section 4, I conclude. 3

4 2 Suggestive Evidence 2.1 Data To collect evidence suggestive of the existence of price discrimination in inputs markets, I rely on firm-level Customs data from Chile over the period from 1993 to On the import side, in each year there are about firms importing goods from abroad, and firms are tracked across time with a unique identification number. This identification number is the same as the one used in the data on firm-level exports. In each year about 50% of firms that are engaged in imports also export goods abroad. I use the information about exporting activities of firms to identify their industry and as a proxy for the firm size. Each good in the data is defined as a 10-digit code in the HS industry classification. On average, each importer buys each product from two different countries. The statistics summarizing firms importing and exporting activities in one year (2005) is provided in Table 1. Although there is no direct measure of per unit price of goods, each shipment is characterized by the total value and the number of goods shipped. The total value is a free-onboard value (FOB), which means that it is not affected by insurance and transportation costs. It is denominated in current pesos. I proxy prices with unit values, calculated as FOB value divided by the number of goods in the shipment. Mean Median Total imports, 000s pesos # imported products/firm #sourcing countries/product % Exporters 49 Total exports, 000s pesos # exported products/firm Number of observations 254,158 Number of firms 18,481 Table 1: Summary Statistics, 2005 Next, I explore how thus obtained prices of goods vary across shipments of different size and across buyers. 4

5 2.2 Price Discrimination in International Trade Traditional models of international trade assume that firms obtain the same prices on the same intermediate goods they buy. To test this assumption, I estimate the following specification: ln(p ick ) = f s + f k + f c + f Σ + β 1 ln(q ick ) + β 2 ln(size i ) + ɛ ick, (1) where i, c and k denote the buyer, the product and the country of origin of the product, respectively. Apart from buyer s industry, product and country fixed effects (f s, f k and f c ), I also include the so called sourcing strategy fixed effect, f Σ. This fixed effect controls for the differences in the extensive margins of trade across firms and is motivated by the recent international trade literature (for example, Antras et al. (2017)). It shows that if there are complementarities across foreign varieties in the production function, the cost reduction from importing a particular input will depend on the entire set of countries a firms is importing from. Another firm characteristic included in specification (1) is the log of firm size, proxied with either total exports or total imports of firm i. Previous literature (for example, Kugler and Verhoogen (2011), Blaum et al. (2013)) has shown there firm size is positively correlated with the prices of inputs the firm pays. This correlation is often explained through complementarities between firm s productivity and quality of inputs. The main relationship of interest in equation (1) is the one between the price of an input paid by a buyer and the purchased quantity of that input. The law of one price would imply that coefficient β 1 is equal to zero. Table 2 reports estimation results for specification (1). In the first two columns, total imports and total exports are used as a proxy for firm s size, respectively. The results suggest that prices are not constant across buyers, but rather depend on the amount of inputs firms purchase. 5

6 (1) (2) (3) lprice lprice lprice ln(total imp) *** (0.007) ln(q ick ) *** *** *** (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) ln(total exp) *** (0.006) n.dest *** (0.003) Observations 121, , ,620 R-squared Std errors clustered at the firm level *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Table 2: The relationship between input prices and quantities In particular, the coefficient on log quantity is negative, which means that firms buying larger quantities of goods face lower per unit prices. Specification (1), however, suffers from the usual simultaneity bias that arises when one tries to estimate the relationship between price and quantities. In this case, simultaneity bias is positive, which implies that the obtained estimate of β 1 is biased upward. Overall, the documented negative relationship between input prices and quantities at the firm level makes standard trade models based on common prices (conditional on quality) counterfactual. At the same time, such a relationship is consistent with third-degree price discrimination in inputs markets, whereby larger buyers obtain lower input prices. In the next section, I rationalize this relationship in an international trade model that features two-sided heterogeneity and allows to study the implications of price discrimination in inputs markets for international trade and welfare. 3 Theoretical Framework In this section, I incorporate third-degree price discrimination by input producers in the general equilibrium international trade model in order to rationalize the documented empirical findings. I further use the proposed theoretical framework to study the impact of trade liberalization on firm s productivity and consumer welfare. 6

7 3.1 Environment Consider the world consisting of N countries indexed by i and j. Each country i is populated by L i consumers that inelastically supply one unit of labor each and consume a continuum of final goods varieties. These varieties are produced by heterogeneous final goods producers, which differ in their productivity φ. Production of final goods requires intermediate goods, which firms can either produce themselves or purchase from independent input producers upstream. Final goods production technology features increasing returns to scale with fixed costs depending on firm s decision to engage in in-house production of inputs. There is free entry in the final goods market, and the market structure is monopolistic competition. Fixed number of intermediate goods producers in each country j produce substitutable inputs using labor as the only input in their linear production function. They compete in prices and are large enough relative to the market to internalize the effects of their decisions on aggregate market outcomes. This departure from traditional international trade literature that assume atomistic firms with no market power, brings several new insights. First, it implies that firms charge variable mark-ups of price over marginal costs: input producers with larger market share face lower perceived elasticity of demand and thus can charge higher mark-ups. Second, market power allows same input producers to charge different prices to different buyers for the same good. For third-degree price discrimination to arise in equilibrium, the following assumptions need to be satisfied. Firstly, intermediate goods producers can observe individual characteristics of their downstream buyers, and, secondly, intermediate goods can only be purchased from their respective producers (in other words, re-selling is not possible). The sequence of moves in this environment is as follows. First, each potential entrant into the final goods market pay entry costs in terms of labor and learn their productivity. Second, those firms that decide to stay on the market, consider investing additional fixed costs in inputs production technology and exporting. Third, intermediate goods producers decide what prices to charge to their buyers downstream. And in the last stage, final goods producers make their input sourcing and pricing decisions. In the following sections I describe the details of the model and outline the industry equilibrium. 3.2 Preferences Consumers in country i have identical preferences represented by the standard CES utility function over a set Ω i of final goods varieties ω: 7

8 U i = ( ω Ω i q i (ω) σ dω) σ These utility function gives rise to the following demand system in country i: q i (ω) = E i P i p i (ω) σ, where p i (ω) is the price of variety ω, P i ( ω Ω i p i (ω) 1 σ i dω ) 1 1 σ i is the standard CES price index of final goods, and E i is country i s aggregate spending on manufacturing goods. 3.3 Technology and market structure The production side of the economy consists two sectors - upstream sector producing inputs and downstream sector producing final goods. Below I describe the market structures in downstream and upstream sectors. Downstream sector. Each final goods variety is sold by a single firm in a monopolistically competitive environment with free entry. Firms are heterogeneous in their productivity φ, with which they transform one unit of a composite input X into a final good. The cummulative distribution of productivities across downstream firms is denoted by G(φ). To enter the downstream sector in country i, firms pay fixed entry costs f e in terms of country i s labor units. In every period, there is an exogenous probability of exit, β. After learning their productivity downstream firms decide whether to stay or exit the market. Firms that stay in the market produce final goods using the production function: Y (φ) = φ ( ) (α d Q d ) ρ 1 ρ + (α f Q f ) ρ 1 ρ ρ ρ 1, where Q d is domestic intermediate input and Q f is the aggregate imported input bundle. The imported composite input Q f is itself a CES aggregate over all inputs imported by the firm, either produced in-house with marginal costs c v, x v, or by specialized input producers, x k, k Σ: Q f = ( (δ v x v ) η 1 η + (δ k x k ) η 1 η k Σ ) η η 1 There is fixed costs of production f denominated in units of labor. In-house production of inputs, x v requires additional investment in fixed costs f(n 1). At the same time, inhouse production of inputs lowers firm s marginal costs through the love-for-variety effect of the CES production function. Thus, when deciding whether to produce any inputs inhouse, the firms chooses between two different technologies - O (for outsourcing) and BI (for backward integration) with the corresponding total cost functions: T C O (q, φ) = f + q P O x φ 8

9 T C BI (q, φ) = nf + q P BI x φ, where Px O and Px BI are the CES aggregate prices of composite inputs in case of full outsourcing and in-house production of inputs, respectively. These price are part of the solution of cost minimization problem of the firm and are described below. Thus, in this set up, a part of firm productivity (φ) is the result of luck, while another part (P x ) is driven by the decisions of firms in both upstream and downstream sectors. Downstream firms can reduce their marginal costs by producing some inputs in-house, while upstream firms decide on prices of inputs final goods producers pay. A final goods producer s problem is to choose the price p(φ), quantities of inputs x v, {x k } k Σ in order to maximize firm s profits. To make the decisions of whether to enter the export market and whether to invest in in-house production of inputs, firms compare the total profits of each of the four possible choices. Upstream sector. Each country i has a fixed (exogenous) number of heterogeneous input producers, M U i. They employ labor one-to-one in production and face iceberg trade costs τ ij 1 when selling inputs internationally. Firms in each country faced the derived demand on their inputs from downstream firm and compete by choosing prices. Firms in the upstream sector internalize the effects of their decisions on the market outcomes of their country. In doing so, they observe the individual characteristics of the downstream buyers and thus can charge different prices for the same good. An input producer s problem is to choose individual prices for each of the downstream buyers of its inputs to maximize the profits. Next I describe firms optimal behavior conditional on entry and keeping wages fixed. 3.4 Equilibrium with Trade in Intermediate Goods First, consider the case when final goods are not tradeable, while intermediate goods can be sourced from all over the world. Then, conditional on the choice of inputs and consumer preferences, downstream firm φ maximizes it profits from serving the domestic market: π(φ) = EP p(φ) σ ( p(φ) P S x φ ) f I BI (n 1)f, where Px S is the price index of intermediate inputs that depends on firm s sourcing technology, S = {O, BI} and I BI is an indicator variable equal to one when firm φ backward integrates. Under CES preferences and monopolistic competition, the profit maximizing price is a constant mark-up over marginal costs: 9

10 p(φ) = σ P S x φ Given this price, the demand for final goods variety φ, firm s revenue and operational profits (gross of fixed costs) are, respectively: where m = σ q(φ) = EP m σ (P S x ) σ φ σ r(φ) = E(P/m) (P S x ) 1 σ φ π(φ) = r(φ) σ, is the final goods producer s markup. From cost minimization problem it follows that to produce Y units of final goods, a downstream firm purchases domestic and imported inputs: Q d = (P d/α d ) ρ (P S x ) ρ Y Q f = (P S f /α f ) ρ (P S x ) ρ Y, where P d, P f are CES price indexes of domestic and imported inputs, respectively, and Px S = ( (P d /α d ) 1 ρ + (Pf S/α f) 1 ρ) 1 1 ρ is a price of a composite input used in production. The demand for an input produced by supplier k is: x k = ( p k /δ k P S f ) η ( P S f /α f P S x ) ρy Also, if this firm decides to backward integrate in input production, the in-house production of inputs is x v = ( c v/δ v P S f ) η ( P S f /α f P S x ) ρy When making the decision of whether to backward integrate in input production or not, the firm compares the total profits from both options, π O (φ) and π BI (φ). Downstream firm with productivity φ will choose to backward integrate if π BI (φ) π O (φ). This condition determines the cut-off productivity above which firms find it profitable to invest in the upstream technology: φ I = ( ) 1 σf(n 1) E(γ 1) P O x P/m, (2) ( ) where γ P BI 1 σ x P > 1 is related to the per-unit cost advantage of firms with in-house x O production of inputs. 10

11 Since the production technology features increasing returns to scale, some firms with productivity draws below a certain level, φ, will exit. This cut-off productivity level is determined from the zero profit condition as: φ = ( ) 1 fσ E P O x P/m (3) In order to have firms that outsource their inputs and those that produce them in-house active in the downstream market, the fixed costs of backward integration should be sufficiently large compared to the savings in marginal costs it brings: n > γ. If this is true, then firms with productivity draws φ < φ exit the market, those with productivity draws φ [φ, φ I ) outsource all their inputs, and those with productivity draws φ φ I engage in in-house production of inputs. Turning to the upstream sector, the producer of input k faces the following derived demand: x S k = ( p k /δ k P S f ) η ( P S f /α f P S x ) ρ (P ) S σ x (φ/m) σ EP, S = {O, BI} (4) Apart from being more productive, firms that produce inputs in-house also have more elastic demand for inputs they purchase from the upstream sector. If upstream producers have a non-negligible market shares, downstream firm s demand elasticity for input k can be expressed as ε S k = η + (η ρ)s S k, (5) where s S k = (p k/δ k ) 1 η is the share of expenditures on input k in total expenditures on (Pf S)1 η imported inputs. Note that, all else equal, this share is lower for firms that also produce some inputs in-house. Hence, the firms that backward integrate into the input production are more productive and more elastic to changes in input price, p k. So long as input producers can tell the firms that can backward integrate from those that can not, they will engage in price discrimination, if arbitrage is not possible. Since firms with in-house production of inputs have more elastic demand, they are expected to obtained a lower input price from the same supplier. To see this, note that in equilibrium, input producer k from country d sets input prices according to the Lerner index: p S kd c kd p S kd = 1 ε S kd (6) Since ε BI kd > εo kd, pbi kd < po kd, as upstream suppliers charge higher mark-ups to firms 11

12 without in-house production of inputs. Downstream firms with better initial (exogenous) productivity draws, φ, obtain (endogenous) cost advantages through several channels. First, they find it profitable to produce some inputs in-house and thus benefit through love-for-variety effects of the CES production function. Second, since they can produce inputs in-house, they rely less on purchase intermediate goods and thus benefit through lower input prices. This model thus rationalizes third-degree price discrimination by intermediate goods producers: they charge higher prices to the small buyers, and lower prices - to the large buyers of inputs. 1 This prediction is at odds with the one obtained for the final goods markets, where larger buyers (richer consumers) of final goods are charged higher prices. The reason is that, unlike consumers, producers often can take actions to influence the price of inputs they face. In case of this paper, larger final goods producers can organize in-house production of inputs and, by threatening input producers with competition, obtain lower input prices. When testing this prediction in the data, the challenge is to find an empirical equivalent for the exogenous, raw, productivity draw, φ. In the next section I discuss how the model can be used to guide the choice of firm productivity measures. 3.5 Firm size and Input Prices Consider the expression for the quantity of input k purchased by a firm with sourcing strategy S = {BI, O} from equation (4): ( ) x S k (φ) = p S η ( k /δ k P S ) f /α ρ f ( ) Pf S P P S σ x S x (φ/m) σ EP, S = {O, BI} And consider a downstream firm with productivity draw φ I, which is exactly indifferent between backward integration in the input production and not. It can be shown that if such a firm decides to integrate backwards, it will purchase more inputs than the amount it would buy if it did not integrate backwards: x BI k (φ I) > x O k (φ I) It is easy to see that in equilibrium the demand for inputs from firms with productivities below or above the backward integration cut-off, φ I, increases in firm productivity, φ. Since the equilibrium quantity of inputs is positively correlated with the productivity draws, it can be used to test for the negative relationship between firm productivity and the input price. The drawback of quantities as a measure of firm productivity is that it gives rise to the simultaneity bias. 1 In Melitz (2003)-type models firm productivity is perfectly positively correlated with firm size. 12

13 The alternative method is to use downstream firm output or total sales as a measure of productivity. Recall that in equilibrium, output and total sales can be expressed the function of firm productivity φ as, respectively: q(φ) = EP m σ ( P S x r(φ) = E (P/m) ( P S x ) σ φ σ ) 1 σ φ Not only firms that backward integrate are more productive than the ones that do not, but they also face lower input prices precisely by threatening to backward integrate. The last part implies that firms that backward integrate have lower average costs of inputs: Px BI < Px O. As a result, total output and total sales are positively correlated with productivity draws φ: q(φ 1 ) > q(φ 0 ) if φ 1 > φ 0 r(φ 1 ) > r(φ 0 ) if φ 1 > φ 0 Thus, both total output and total sales can be used to study the relationship between firm productivity and the input price. Next I discuss how the instances of trade liberalization in the downstream sector can become a source of exogenous variation in market access. 3.6 Trade Liberalization Downstream Now I relax the assumption that only intermediate goods are traded internationally and allow for exports of final goods. I introduce the following notation: a domestic country is denoted with subscript d and any foreign country with subscript i. Before any downstream firm exports its final output to any country i, it has to pay the fixed costs of exporting f x. Then, downstream firms decide whether to export and backwards integrate, by comparing the total profits of the four possible options, described below. Profits if only serving the domestic market and outsourcing all inputs: π O d = 1 σ E d(p d /m) (P O x ) 1 σ φ f Profits if only serving the domestic market with in-house production of inputs: π BI d = 1 E σ d(p d /m) (Px BI ) 1 σ φ nf Profits if exporting to country i and outsourcing all inputs: 13

14 π O x = 1 (P O σ x ) 1 σ φ (E d (P d /m) + τ 1 σ di E i (P i /m) ) f f x Profits if exporting to country i with in-house production of inputs: π BI x = 1 σ (P BI x ) 1 σ φ (E d (P d /m) + τ 1 σ di E i (P i /m) ) nf f x Exporting and input sourcing choices are illustrated in Figure 1, where the four profit functions are plotted against firm s exogenous productivity φ. In equilibrium depicted in Figure 1, downstream firms self-select into four groups: the least productive firms (φ < φ ) exit the market, the low productivity firms (φ φ φ x ) outsource all their inputs and only serve the domestic final goods consumers, the medium productivity firms (φ x φ φ I ) still outsource all their inputs but ) both also export their final goods, and finally, the most productive firms (φ > φ I export and produce some of their inputs in-house. Figure 1: Exporting and Input sourcing modes Note that in Figure 1, the parameters are such that the strategy of serving only domestic consumers and producing some inputs in-house is always dominated by other strategies.it implies that there are no firms that invest in in-house production of inputs and do not export, which reflects the complementarity between exporting and in-house production. 14

15 In equilibrium, the demand for input k by downstream firms that outsource their input production and those that produce some inputs in-house is: x O k x BI k = ( p O k /δ k P O f = ( p BI k /δ k Pf BI ) η ( P O f /α f P O x ) η ( P BI f P BI x /α f ) ρ(p O x ) σ (φ/m) σ (E d P d ) ρ(p BI x ) σ (φ/m) σ (E d P d + I x τ σ di E i P i ) + τ σ di E i P i ) where I x is an indicator function, which is equal to one if the firm is an exporter and is equal to zero otherwise. To study how trade liberalization (i.e. reduction in bilateral iceberg trade costs τ di ) affects firms incentives to backward integrate and export, it is useful to write down the cut-off productivities, φ, φ x and φ I. The exit productivity cut-off φ is determined from the zero-profit condition: π O d (φ ) = 0 1 σ E d(p d /m) (P O x ) 1 σ φ f = 0 (7) Since the marginal exporter from d to i outsources all its inputs, the exporting productivity cut-off φ x can be expressed as a function of φ using π O d (φ x) = π O x (φ x ) as: i ) d ) ( fx /(E i P φ x = φ f/(e d P ) 1 τdi (8) Hence, as long as fx/(e ip i ) f/(e d P d ) > 1, φ x > φ, as illustrated in Figure 1. Finally, the least productive firm that can produce inputs in-house is an exporter. The productivity of this firm, φ I, is found from πx BI (φ I ) = πx O (φ I ) as: φ I = φ ( n 1 γ 1 E d P d E d P d + τ 1 σ di E i P i ) 1 (9) From the expressions (8) - (9) it follows that both exporting and backward integration productivity cut-offs are increasing in iceberg trade costs τ di. In other words, the reduction in trade costs due to trade liberalization with country i allows firms that previously did not export to start exporting. Moreover, some firms that found it profitable to export even before trade liberalization, now find it also profitable to invest in the upstream technology. This is because trade liberalization works as a (arguably exogenous) shock to the demand for goods produced by exporters, which makes backward integration more profitable. The described effects of trade liberalization in the downstream sector are illustrated in Figure 2. 15

16 Figure 2: The effects of trade liberalization Figure 2 makes it clear that gains from trade liberalization are heterogeneous across different downstream firms. For example, firms that were large exporters of final goods even before trade liberalization are not expected to gain through lower input prices, as they already obtain low input prices due to their size. On the other hand, very small domestic producers of final goods still can not export even after the decrease in transportation costs. It is only the more productive new exporters and less productive old exporters that are predicted to gain through lower input prices. After the reduction in trade costs, those firms experience a positive demand shock, which makes in-house production of inputs more profitable and allows them to obtain lower input prices from the upstream producers. Being positively correlated with firm sales, reductions in tariffs on final goods can be used as an instrumental variable for firm size when studying its effect on input prices faced by final goods producers. In what follows I explore the implications of third-degree price discrimination in inputs markets for the downstream industry equilibrium. 3.7 Industry Equilibrium Downstream industry equilibrium in country d consists of the price of final goods (P d ), (endogenous) number of firms (M d ) and the average profits of active firms. Free entry to the downstream sector requires that the sunk entry cost f e equals the present value of expected profits: f e = (1 G(φ )) 1 π, (10) β where 1 G(φ ) is the share of potential entrant that stay active after learning their 16

17 productivity, and π is an expected per-period profits of active firms. The expected perperiod profits can be expressed as the sum of expected profits from domestic sales and expected profits from exporting: π = π d + p x π x, (11) where p x = 1 G(φx) 1 G(φ ) is the share of exporting firms in the downstream sector. For the ease of derivations, I will further assume that G(φ) is a Pareto cummulative distribution function with the shape parameter κ 2 : G(φ) = 1 φ κ Under this distributional assumption, the expected profits become 3 : ( = 1+ ) κ+ f x f ( A d A i ) where A j = E j (P j /m). κ π = σ 1 f (12) κ σ + 1 ( τ κ +(γ 1) κ σ κ 1 (n 1) A d A d +τ 1 σ di ) κ A i (1+ κ A i τ κ f xa d ), As is increasing in the marginal cost advantage of in-house production γ, so is the average profits in the downstream sector. Using the solution for expected profits (12) in the free entry condition (10), one can find the exit productivity cut-off as a function of parameters, including : ( σ 1 f φ = κ σ + 1 βf e ) 1 κ (13) This cut-off allows to solve for the number of active firms in the downstream sector of country d: M d = 1 G(φ ) = κ σ + 1 βf e σ 1 f Therefore, larger cost reductions due to in-house production implies fewer firms in the downstream sector in equilibrium. This is because price discrimination in inputs markets leads to higher expected profits in the downstream sector. Under free entry and constant mark-ups, higher expected profits can only be sustained with fewer firms on the market, hence - smaller M d. 2 Standard assumption that found empirical support in international trade literature 3 For expected profits to be positive, the following restriction on the parameters should be satisfied: κ > σ 1 (14) 17

18 Two other important productivity cut-offs, φ x and φ I can be easily obtained from (8) and (9): ( σ 1 f φ x = κ σ + 1 βf e ( σ 1 f φ I = κ σ + 1 βf e ) 1 ( κ f x /τ 1 σ di f/a d ) 1 ( κ n 1 γ 1 A i A d A d + τ 1 σ di A i ) 1 τdi (15) ) 1 Finally, the price index in the downstream sector can be solved for using the solution for φ and the zero-profit condition for the least productive active firm on the market (7): ( σ 1 f P d = κ σ + 1 βf e ) 1 κ ( fσ E d (16) ) 1 mp O x (17) Thus, final goods consumers gain from price discrimination, as it reduces the price of the consumer goods: as γ increases, the final goods price index P d falls. 4 Conclusion The existence of price discrimination has been long documented and studied in industrial organization, yet the international trade literature neglects the possibility of different firms getting different price for exact same product. I this paper, using firm-level Customs data, I showed that the assumption of common prices does not seem to hold in the data. When purchasing the same input, buyers with larger quantities obtain lower input prices. To rationalize this observation, I build a model of trade in intermediate goods, in which there are differences in endogenous demand elasticity across buyers of inputs. In this model, heterogeneous downstream firms can decide to produce inputs in-house and export their goods. Both exporting and in-house production are associated with larger fixed costs. As a result, only initially more productive firms sort into in-house production of inputs and exporting. As more productive firms can substitute inputs produced in-house for the one they buy from upstream suppliers, their demand on inputs is more elastic. Since input prices are inversely proportional to the demand elasticity, upstream suppliers charge lower prices to larger (more productive) downstream firms. Incorporating price discrimination into the general equilibrium trade model allows to study its implications for market aggregates. For instance, wider possibility for price discrimination in the upstream sector increases the expected profit of the downstream sectors and reduces the number of active firms in that sector. This, in turn, implies that consumers benefit from price discrimination through lower production costs of the final 18

19 goods producers as well as the selection of more productive firms. This paper also showed that firms decisions to export and engage in in-house production of inputs are complementary. On the one hand, by reducing firm s production costs and thus increasing operational profits, in-house production of inputs allows firms to overcome the fixed costs of exporting. On the other hand, by offering larger economies of scale, exporting itself encourages firms to set-up the production of inputs. Thus, instances of trade liberalization in the downstream sectors can be used as exogenous shocks to identify the causal effect of firm s productivity of the prices of inputs it faces. The proposed framework with price discrimination in the inputs markets can be further used to empirically study the role of imported intermediates in firms productivity. When firms face different prices on same inputs, it results in heterogeneity in productivity gains from trade liberalization in the upstream sectors. 19

20 References Antras, P., Fort, T. C., and Tintelnot, F. (2017). The margins of global sourcing: theory and evidence from us firms. American Economic Review, 107(9): Blaum, J., Lelarge, C., and Peters, M. (2013). Non-homothetic import demand: Firm productivity and quality bias. Unpublished paper. Blaum, J., Lelarge, C., and Peters, M. (2015). The gains from input trade in firm-based models of importing. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research. Halpern, L., Koren, M., and Szeidl, A. (2015). Imported inputs and productivity. American Economic Review, 105(12): Jung, J. W., Simonovska, I., and Weinberger, A. (2015). Exporter heterogeneity and price discrimination: a quantitative view. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research. Katz, M. L. (1987). The welfare effects of third-degree price discrimination in intermediate good markets. The American Economic Review, pages Kugler, M. and Verhoogen, E. (2011). Prices, plant size, and product quality. The Review of Economic Studies, 79(1): Melitz, M. J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6): Simonovska, I. (2015). Income differences and prices of tradables: Insights from an online retailer. The Review of Economic Studies, 82(4):

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003) 14.581 Week 8 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 1 / 42 Firm-Level Heterogeneity and Trade What s wrong

More information

Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data

Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data Appendix For Online Publication Jose L. Groizard, Priya Ranjan, and Antonio Rodriguez-Lopez March 2014 A A Model of Input Trade and Firm-Level

More information

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Class Notes on Chaney (2008) Class Notes on Chaney (2008) (With Krugman and Melitz along the Way) Econ 840-T.Holmes Model of Chaney AER (2008) As a first step, let s write down the elements of the Chaney model. asymmetric countries

More information

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot Online Theory Appendix Not for Publication) Equilibrium in the Complements-Pareto Case

More information

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices Haichao Fan Amber Li Sichuang Xu Stephen Yeaple Fudan, HKUST, HKUST, Penn State and NBER May 2018 Mark-Ups

More information

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model Firms in International Trade Lecture 2: The Melitz Model Stephen Redding London School of Economics 1 / 33 Essential Reading Melitz, M. J. (2003) The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and

More information

Location, Productivity, and Trade

Location, Productivity, and Trade May 10, 2010 Motivation Outline Motivation - Trade and Location Major issue in trade: How does trade liberalization affect competition? Competition has more than one dimension price competition similarity

More information

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

Economics 689 Texas A&M University Horizontal FDI Economics 689 Texas A&M University Horizontal FDI Foreign direct investments are investments in which a firm acquires a controlling interest in a foreign firm. called portfolio investments

More information

ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model

ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model Xiaodong Zhu University of Toronto October 15, 2010 1 / 22 Dynamic Industry Model with heterogeneous firms where opening to trade leads to reallocations of resources

More information

Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments

Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments Alessandra Peter, Cian Ruane Stanford University November 3, 2017 Question Selling manufactured goods involves costs of distribution:

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

Heterogeneous Firms. Notes for Graduate Trade Course. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. January 30, 2013

Heterogeneous Firms. Notes for Graduate Trade Course. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. January 30, 2013 Heterogeneous Firms Notes for Graduate Trade Course J. Peter Neary University of Oxford January 30, 2013 J.P. Neary (University of Oxford) Heterogeneous Firms January 30, 2013 1 / 29 Plan of Lectures 1

More information

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity .. International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity Akihiko Yanase (Graduate School of Economics) January 13, 2017 1 / 28 Introduction Krugman (1979, 1980)

More information

Trade and Technology Asian Miracles and WTO Anti-Miracles

Trade and Technology Asian Miracles and WTO Anti-Miracles Trade and Technology Asian Miracles and WTO Anti-Miracles Guillermo Ordoñez UCLA March 6, 2007 Motivation Trade is considered an important source of technology diffusion...but trade also shapes the incentives

More information

Foreign Direct Investment I

Foreign Direct Investment I FD Foreign Direct nvestment [My notes are in beta. f you see something that doesn t look right, would greatly appreciate a heads-up.] 1 FD background Foreign direct investment FD) occurs when an enterprise

More information

Entry, Trade Costs and International Business Cycles

Entry, Trade Costs and International Business Cycles Entry, Trade Costs and International Business Cycles Roberto Fattal and Jose Lopez UCLA SED Meetings July 10th 2010 Entry, Trade Costs and International Business Cycles SED Meetings July 10th 2010 1 /

More information

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry Lin, Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 7(2), December 2014, 17-31 17 Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically

More information

Estimating the Productivity Gains from Importing [Preliminary - Comments welcome]

Estimating the Productivity Gains from Importing [Preliminary - Comments welcome] Estimating the Productivity Gains from Importing [Preliminary - Comments welcome] Joaquin Blaum, Claire Lelarge, Michael Peters September 2014 Abstract Trade in intermediate inputs raises firm productivity

More information

Productivity, Fair Wage and Offshoring Domestic Jobs

Productivity, Fair Wage and Offshoring Domestic Jobs Productivity, Fair Wage and Offshoring Domestic Jobs Xi Chen July 7, 2017 Preliminary draft Abstract This paper develops a general equilibrium model with monopolistic competition that incorporates: (i)

More information

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment Chapter 6 Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment In Romer s IS/MP/IA model, we assume prices/inflation adjust imperfectly when output changes. Empirically, there is a negative relationship

More information

Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel

Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel Anca Cristea University of Oregon December 2010 Abstract This appendix

More information

Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr, Prat, Schmerer (2011)

Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr, Prat, Schmerer (2011) Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr, Prat, Schmerer (2011) Davide Suverato 1 1 LMU University of Munich Topics in International Trade, 16 June 2015 Davide Suverato, LMU Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr,

More information

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices : Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices (2008, AER) December 5 th, 2008 Empirical motivation US PPI-based RER is highly volatile Under PPP, this should induce a high volatility

More information

Entry on Export Markets and Firm-Level Performance Growth: Intra-Industrial Convergence or Divergence?

Entry on Export Markets and Firm-Level Performance Growth: Intra-Industrial Convergence or Divergence? Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Papers -7-20 Entry on Export Markets and Firm-Level Performance Growth: Intra-Industrial Convergence or Divergence? Florian Mayneris CORE, florian.mayneris@uclouvain.be

More information

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013 Comprehensive Exam August 19, 2013 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question. Good luck! 1 1 Menu

More information

Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity

Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity ERASMUS UNIVERSITY ROTTERDAM Erasmus School of Economics Department of Economics Supervisor: Dr. J. Emami Namini

More information

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS Bielefeld University phemelo.tamasiga@uni-bielefeld.de 01-July-2013 Agenda 1 Motivation 2 3 4 5 6 Motivation Samuelson (1939);there are gains from trade, consequently

More information

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography Increasing Returns and Economic Geography Department of Economics HKUST April 25, 2018 Increasing Returns and Economic Geography 1 / 31 Introduction: From Krugman (1979) to Krugman (1991) The award of

More information

International Trade Gravity Model

International Trade Gravity Model International Trade Gravity Model Yiqing Xie School of Economics Fudan University Dec. 20, 2013 Yiqing Xie (Fudan University) Int l Trade - Gravity (Chaney and HMR) Dec. 20, 2013 1 / 23 Outline Chaney

More information

Firm-to-Firm Trade: Imports, Exports, and the Labor Market

Firm-to-Firm Trade: Imports, Exports, and the Labor Market Firm-to-Firm Trade: Imports, Exports, and the Labor Market Jonathan Eaton, Samuel Kortum, Francis Kramarz, and Raul Sampognaro CREST, June 2013 Cowles Conference Agenda I Most firms do not export, and

More information

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies Lecture 14 Multinational Firms 1. Review of empirical evidence 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies 3. A model with endogenous multinationals 4. Pattern of trade in goods

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 07/05 Firm heterogeneity, foreign direct investment and the hostcountry welfare: Trade costs vs. cheap labor By Arijit Mukherjee

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Welfare Consequences of Globalization

Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Welfare Consequences of Globalization Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Welfare Consequences of Globalization Andrés Rodríguez-Clare (UC Berkeley and NBER) September 29, 2012 The Armington Model The Armington Model CES preferences:

More information

Lecture 3: New Trade Theory

Lecture 3: New Trade Theory Lecture 3: New Trade Theory Isabelle Méjean isabelle.mejean@polytechnique.edu http://mejean.isabelle.googlepages.com/ Master Economics and Public Policy, International Macroeconomics October 30 th, 2008

More information

Transfer Pricing by Multinational Firms: New Evidence from Foreign Firm Ownership

Transfer Pricing by Multinational Firms: New Evidence from Foreign Firm Ownership Transfer Pricing by Multinational Firms: New Evidence from Foreign Firm Ownership Anca Cristea University of Oregon Daniel X. Nguyen University of Copenhagen Rocky Mountain Empirical Trade 16-18 May, 2014

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location This Version: 9 May 006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location Nathaniel P.S. Cook Abstract This paper examines

More information

The Composition of Knowledge and Long-Run Growth

The Composition of Knowledge and Long-Run Growth The Composition of Knowledge and Long-Run Growth Jie Cai Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Nan Li International Monetary Fund 4th Joint WTO-IMF-WB trade workshop, 2015 Jie Cai & Nan Li 1/25

More information

Monopolistic competition models

Monopolistic competition models models Robert Stehrer Version: May 22, 213 Introduction Classical models Explanations for trade based on differences in Technology Factor endowments Predicts complete trade specialization i.e. no intra-industry

More information

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies Lecture 14 Multinational Firms 1. Review of empirical evidence 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies 3. A model with endogenous multinationals 4. Pattern of trade in goods

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam MACROECONOMICS Prelim Exam Austin, June 1, 2012 Instructions This is a closed book exam. If you get stuck in one section move to the next one. Do not waste time on sections that you find hard to solve.

More information

The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade

The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade Katsufumi Fukuda 1 August 3, 214 Abstract This paper shows that globalization

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum. Topics in international Trade

Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum. Topics in international Trade Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum Topics in international Trade 1 Overview 1. Motivation 2. Framework of the model 3. Technology, Prices and Trade Flows 4. Trade Flows and Price Differences

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

International Trade: Lecture 4

International Trade: Lecture 4 International Trade: Lecture 4 Alexander Tarasov Higher School of Economics Fall 2016 Alexander Tarasov (Higher School of Economics) International Trade (Lecture 4) Fall 2016 1 / 34 Motivation Chapter

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Transport Costs and North-South Trade Transport Costs and North-South Trade Didier Laussel a and Raymond Riezman b a GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II b Department of Economics, University of Iowa Abstract We develop a simple two country

More information

The Gains From Input Trade in Firm-Based Models of Importing [Preliminary - Comments welcome]

The Gains From Input Trade in Firm-Based Models of Importing [Preliminary - Comments welcome] The Gains From Input Trade in Firm-Based Models of Importing [Preliminary - Comments welcome] Joaquin Blaum, Claire Lelarge, Michael Peters March 2015 Abstract Trade in intermediate inputs allows firms

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Cúrdia FRB New York Michael Woodford Columbia University Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial Frictions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions

More information

International Development and Firm Distribution

International Development and Firm Distribution International Development and Firm Distribution Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis February 2016 1 A. Introduction Conventional macroeconomic models employ aggregate production

More information

International Banks and the Cross-Border Transmission of Business Cycles 1

International Banks and the Cross-Border Transmission of Business Cycles 1 International Banks and the Cross-Border Transmission of Business Cycles 1 Ricardo Correa Horacio Sapriza Andrei Zlate Federal Reserve Board Global Systemic Risk Conference November 17, 2011 1 These slides

More information

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. 1 Market Demand Assume that there are only two goods (x and y)

More information

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics June. - 2011 Trade, Development and Growth For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option Instructions

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

Federico Esposito. 41 Trumbull Street, Third floor Dept. of Economics, Yale University

Federico Esposito. 41 Trumbull Street, Third floor Dept. of Economics, Yale University Federico Esposito Home Address: Office Address: 41 Trumbull Street, Third floor Dept. of Economics, New Haven, CT 06510 37 Hillhouse Avenue Telephone: 203-772-9529 E-mail: mailto:federico.esposito@yale.edu

More information

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through Gita Gopinath Harvard and NBER Oleg Itskhoki Harvard CEFIR/NES March 11, 2009 1 / 39 Motivation Micro-level studies document significant heterogeneity in

More information

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters A. Kerem Coşar Davide Suverato kerem.cosar@chicagobooth.edu davide.suverato@econ.lmu.de University of Chicago Booth School of Business

More information

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Shutao Cao 1 Yahong Zhang 2 1 Bank of Canada 2 Western University October 21, 2014 Motivation The US experience suggests that the collapse

More information

Renegotiation of Trade Agreements and Firm Exporting Decisions: Evidence from the Impact of Brexit on UK Exports

Renegotiation of Trade Agreements and Firm Exporting Decisions: Evidence from the Impact of Brexit on UK Exports Renegotiation of Trade Agreements and Firm Exporting Decisions: Evidence from the Impact of Brexit on UK Exports Meredith A. Crowley Oliver Exton Lu Han University of Cambridge July 2018 Disclaimer This

More information

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities 14.452. Topic 7. Nominal rigidities Olivier Blanchard April 2007 Nr. 1 1. Motivation, and organization Why introduce nominal rigidities, and what do they imply? In monetary models, the price level (the

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 12 and 13 Input-Output Linkages: Implications for Productivity and Volatility

14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 12 and 13 Input-Output Linkages: Implications for Productivity and Volatility 14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 12 and 13 Input-Output Linkages: Implications for Productivity and Volatility Daron Acemoglu MIT October 17 and 22, 2013. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Input-Output Linkages

More information

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model Wisarut Suwanprasert Vanderbilt University December 206 Abstract I study the impact of the Most Favored Nation (MFN)

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON QUALITY BIAS AND INFLATION TARGETS. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON QUALITY BIAS AND INFLATION TARGETS. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON QUALITY BIAS AND INFLATION TARGETS Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe Working Paper 1555 http://www.nber.org/papers/w1555 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 15 Massachusetts

More information

Introducing Firm Heterogeneity Theory into CGEBox

Introducing Firm Heterogeneity Theory into CGEBox Introducing Firm Heterogeneity Theory into CGEBox Wolfgang Britz and Yaghoob Jafari Institute for Food and Resource Economics, University of Bonn, Germany Abstract Computable general equilibrium models

More information

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION A10282W1 FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION Preliminary Examination for Philosophy, Politics and Economics Preliminary Examination for Economics and Management Preliminary Examination for History and Economics SECOND

More information

What does consumer heterogeneity mean for measuring changes in the cost of living?

What does consumer heterogeneity mean for measuring changes in the cost of living? What does consumer heterogeneity mean for measuring changes in the cost of living? Robert S. Martin Office of Prices and Living Conditions FCSM Conference 3/9/2018 1 / 25 Disclaimer The views expressed

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

Trade and the Environment with Heterogeneous Firms

Trade and the Environment with Heterogeneous Firms Trade and the Environment with Heterogeneous Firms Claustre Bajona Ryerson University Paul Missios Ryerson University Andrea Pierce Industry Canada VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE. Please do not quote

More information

Lecture 3: International trade under imperfect competition

Lecture 3: International trade under imperfect competition Lecture 3: International trade under imperfect competition Agnès Bénassy-Quéré (agnes.benassy@cepii.fr) Isabelle Méjean (isabelle.mejean@polytechnique.edu) www.isabellemejean.com Eco 572, International

More information

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction Philippe Aghion Antonin Bergeaud Timo Boppart Peter J Klenow Huiyu Li January 17, 2017 A1 Heterogeneous elasticities and varying markups In

More information

The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence

The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence Shon Ferguson and Rikard Forslid September 2011, Work in progress Abstract The purpose of this study is to test what type of firms start

More information

Factor price overshooting with trade liberalization: theory and evidence

Factor price overshooting with trade liberalization: theory and evidence Factor price overshooting with trade liberalization: theory and evidence Julian EMAMI NAMINI and Ricardo A. ÓPEZ February 15, 2012 Abstract We develop an intra industry trade model with human capital and

More information

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out Kiyoshi Matsubara August 2005 Abstract This article addresses the decision of plant location by a home firm and its impact on the home economy, especially through

More information

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis S. Gilchrist 1 1 Boston University and NBER MFM Summer Camp June 12, 2016 DISCLAIMER: The views expressed are solely the responsibility of the authors and

More information

The science of monetary policy

The science of monetary policy Macroeconomic dynamics PhD School of Economics, Lectures 2018/19 The science of monetary policy Giovanni Di Bartolomeo giovanni.dibartolomeo@uniroma1.it Doctoral School of Economics Sapienza University

More information

Inflation & Welfare 1

Inflation & Welfare 1 1 INFLATION & WELFARE ROBERT E. LUCAS 2 Introduction In a monetary economy, private interest is to hold not non-interest bearing cash. Individual efforts due to this incentive must cancel out, because

More information

New Trade Theory I. Part A: Simple monopolistic competition model. Robert Stehrer. The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw

New Trade Theory I. Part A: Simple monopolistic competition model. Robert Stehrer. The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw Part A: Simple monopolistic competition model The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw May 15, 217 Introduction 1 Classical models 1 Explanations based on technology and/or factor

More information

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model NOT FOR PUBLICATION Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome Small Open Economy Model In this appendix, we develop a general equilibrium model of how increased import competition from China affects employment

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Human Capital, Technology Diffusion and Interdependencies

Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Human Capital, Technology Diffusion and Interdependencies 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Human Capital, Technology Diffusion and Interdependencies Daron Acemoglu MIT December 1, 2009. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 11 December 1, 2009. 1 /

More information

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model. Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model. Olivier Blanchard May 25 14.452. Spring 25. Topic 7. 1 Why introduce nominal rigidities, and what do they imply? An informal walk-through. In the model we

More information

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis Answer each question in three or four sentences and perhaps one equation or graph. Remember that the explanation determines the grade. 1. Question

More information

Effects of Rules of Origin on FTA Utilization Rates and Country Welfare

Effects of Rules of Origin on FTA Utilization Rates and Country Welfare Effects of Rules of Origin on FTA Utilization Rates and Country Welfare Nan Xu This Draft: August 2016 Abstract Free trade agreements are generally under-utilized. Assuming full utilization overstates

More information

Demand uncertainty and the Joint Dynamics of Exporters and Multinational Firms

Demand uncertainty and the Joint Dynamics of Exporters and Multinational Firms Demand uncertainty and the Joint Dynamics of Exporters and Multinational Firms Cheng Chen (University of Hong Kong) Tatsuro Senga (Queen Mary University of London) Chang Sun (Princeton University) Hongyong

More information

Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade

Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade Klaus Desmet November 2010. Economic () Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade November 2010 1 / 35 Outline 1 The seminal model of economic

More information

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017] Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017] 1. A tax is to be levied on a commodity bought and sold in a competitive market. Two possible forms of tax may be used: In one case, a per unit tax

More information

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-05 Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI The

More information

International Trade: Lecture 3

International Trade: Lecture 3 International Trade: Lecture 3 Alexander Tarasov Higher School of Economics Fall 2016 Alexander Tarasov (Higher School of Economics) International Trade (Lecture 3) Fall 2016 1 / 36 The Krugman model (Krugman

More information

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics Spring - 2005 Trade and Development Instructions (For students electing Macro (8701) & New Trade Theory (8702) option) Identify yourself

More information

Global Production with Export Platforms

Global Production with Export Platforms Global Production with Export Platforms Felix Tintelnot University of Chicago and Princeton University (IES) ECO 552 February 19, 2014 Standard trade models Most trade models you have seen fix the location

More information

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence Loyola University Chicago Loyola ecommons Topics in Middle Eastern and orth African Economies Quinlan School of Business 1999 Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MEA Countries: Theory

More information

The Costs of Environmental Regulation in a Concentrated Industry

The Costs of Environmental Regulation in a Concentrated Industry The Costs of Environmental Regulation in a Concentrated Industry Stephen P. Ryan MIT Department of Economics Research Motivation Question: How do we measure the costs of a regulation in an oligopolistic

More information

Computing General Equilibrium Theories of Monopolistic Competition and Heterogeneous Firms

Computing General Equilibrium Theories of Monopolistic Competition and Heterogeneous Firms Computing General Equilibrium Theories of Monopolistic Competition and Heterogeneous Firms Edward J. Balistreri Colorado School of Mines Thomas F. Rutherford ETH-Zürich March 2011 Draft Chapter for the

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen March 15, 2013 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations March 15, 2013 1 / 60 Introduction The

More information

International Trade Lecture 5: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition

International Trade Lecture 5: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition International Trade Lecture 5: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition Yiqing Xie School of Economics Fudan University Nov. 22, 2013 Yiqing Xie (Fudan University) Int l Trade - IRTS-MC

More information

A simple equilibrium model for commodity markets

A simple equilibrium model for commodity markets A simple equilibrium model for commodity markets Ivar Ekeland, Delphine Lautier, Bertrand Villeneuve Chair Finance and Sustainable Development Fime Lab University Paris-Dauphine Commodity market Commodity

More information

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014 External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ali Shourideh Wharton Ariel Zetlin-Jones CMU - Tepper November 7, 2014 Introduction Question: How

More information