International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

Similar documents
International Trade Lecture 5: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model

Heterogeneous Firms. Notes for Graduate Trade Course. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. January 30, 2013

Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model

THE IMPACT OF TRADE ON INTRA-INDUSTRY REALLOCATIONS AND AGGREGATE INDUSTRY PRODUCTIVITY

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity

Trade and the Environment with Heterogeneous Firms

Productivity, Fair Wage and Offshoring Domestic Jobs

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I)

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

An easier to understand version of Melitz (2003)

Monopolistic competition models

Lecture 3: International trade under imperfect competition

International Trade

Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr, Prat, Schmerer (2011)

International Trade: Lecture 3

Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

Innovation, Firm Dynamics, and International Trade

International Trade

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Price Discrimination and Trade in Intermediate Goods (Preliminary Draft)

Lecture 12: New Economic Geography

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

International Economics: Lecture 10 & 11

The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices

Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Welfare Consequences of Globalization

ESSAYS ON TRADE LIBERALIZATION WITH FIRM HETEROGENEITY. Aleksandr Vashchilko. Dissertation. Submitted to the faculty of the

The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade

Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data

A Model of Trade Liberalization and Technology Adoption with Heterogeneous Firms

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 19: Trade and Labor Markets (Theory)

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

Labor Market Rigidities, Trade and Unemployment

Computing General Equilibrium Theories of Monopolistic Competition and Heterogeneous Firms

Trade and Technology Asian Miracles and WTO Anti-Miracles

International Trade Gravity Model

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

Inequality, Costly Redistribution and Welfare in an Open Economy

Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with. Heterogeneous Firms

Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments

Macro (8701) & Micro (8703) option

Monopolistic competition: the Dixit-Stiglitz-Spence model

Location, Productivity, and Trade

New Trade Theory I. Part A: Simple monopolistic competition model. Robert Stehrer. The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw

Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade

Problem Set # Public Economics

Econ 8401-T.Holmes. Lecture on Foreign Direct Investment. FDI is massive. As noted in Ramondo and Rodriquez-Clare, worldwide sales of multinationals

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 5: The Ricardo-Viner and Heckscher-Ohlin Models (Theory I)

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

General Equilibrium and Economic Welfare

Reallocation Effects in the Specific Factors and Heckscher-Ohlin. Models under Firm Heterogeneity

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

14.54 International Trade Lecture 4: Exchange Economies

Micro to Macro: Optimal Trade Policy with Firm Heterogeneity

Entry, Trade Costs and International Business Cycles

U(x 1. ; x 2 ) = 4 ln x 1

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

1 Dynamic programming

The Dixit-Stiglitz-Krugman Trade Model: A Geometric Note

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SKILL BIASED HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS, TRADE LIBERALIZATION, AND THE SKILL PREMIUM. James Harrigan Ariell Reshef

Simple e ciency-wage model

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

EconS Oligopoly - Part 3

The Margins of Export: An Integrated approach

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Principles of Optimal Taxation

14.54 International Trade Lecture 5: Exchange Economies (II) Welfare, Inequality, and Trade Imbalances

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

Trade and Capital Flows: A Financial Frictions Perspective

A Model of Trade with Ricardian Comparative Advantage and Intra-sectoral Firm Heterogeneity

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

Productivity: Theory and Evidence

ECO 445/545: International Trade. Jack Rossbach Spring 2016

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Trade and the Internal Labor Markets of Multiproduct Firms

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy

UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

Multinational Firms, Trade, and the Trade-Comovement Puzzle

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Reallocation Effects in the Specific Factors and Heckscher-Ohlin. Models under Firm Heterogeneity

Problem Set # Public Economics

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 1: Ricardian Models (I)

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

Outward FDI and domestic input distortions: evidence from Chinese Firms

Transcription:

14.581 International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003) 14.581 Week 8 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 1 / 42

Firm-Level Heterogeneity and Trade What s wrong with previous theories? Nineties have seen a boom in the availability of micro-level data Problem: previous theories are at odds with (or cannot account for) many micro-level facts: 1 Within a given industry, there is rm-level heterogeneity 2 Fixed costs matter in export related decisions 3 Within a given industry, more productive rms are more likely to export 4 Trade liberalization leads to intra-industry reallocation across rms 5 These reallocations are correlated with productivity and export status 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 2 / 42

Firm-Level Heterogeneity and Trade What does Melitz (2003) do about it? Melitz (2003) will develop a model featuring facts 1 and 2 that can explain facts 3, 4, and 5 This is by far the most in uential trade paper in the last 10 years Two building blocks: 1 Krugman (1980): CES, IRS technology, monopolistic competition 2 Hopenhayn (1992): equilibrium model of entry and exit From a normative point of view, Melitz (2003) may also provide new source of gains from trade if trade induces reallocation of labor from least to most productive rms (more on that later) 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 3 / 42

Today s Plan 1 A Refresher on Monopolistic Competition 1 Krugman (1979) 2 An Important Special Case: CES Utility 2 Melitz (2003) 1 Krugman (1980) meets Hopenhayn (1992) 2 Selection into Exports and the Impact of Trade 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 4 / 42

Monopolistic Competition Basic idea Monopoly pricing: Each rm faces a downward-sloping demand curve No strategic interaction: Each demand curve depends on the prices charged by other rms but since the number of rms is large, each rm ignores its impact on the demand faced by other rms Free entry: Firms enter the industry until pro ts are driven to zero for all rms 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 5 / 42

Monopolistic Competition Graphical analysis p AC MC MR D q 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 6 / 42

Krugman (1979) Endowments, preferences, and technology Endowments: All agents are endowed with 1 unit of labor Preferences: All agents have the same utility function given by where: U = R n 0 u (c i ) di u (0) = 0, u 0 > 0, and u 00 < 0 (love of variety) σ (c) cu u0 00 > 0 is such that σ 0 0 (why?) IRS Technology: Labor used in the production of each variety is l i = f + q i /ϕ where ϕ common productivity parameter 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 7 / 42

Krugman (1979) Equilibrium conditions 1 Consumer maximization: 2 Pro t maximization: p i = 3 Free entry: p i p i = λ 1 u 0 (c i ) 4 Good and labor market clearing: σ (ci ) w σ (c i ) 1 ϕ w q i = wf ϕ q i = Lc i L = nf + R n q i 0 ϕ di 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 8 / 42

Krugman (1979) Equilibrium conditions rearranged Symmetry ) p i = p, q i = q, and c i = c for all i 2 [0, n] c and p/w are simultaneously characterized by (PP): p σ (c) 1 w = σ (c) 1 ϕ (ZP): p w = f q + 1 ϕ = f Lc + 1 ϕ n can then be computed using market clearing conditions n = 1 f /L + c/ϕ 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 9 / 42

Krugman (1979) Graphical analysis p/w Z P (p/w) 0 P Z c 0 c 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 10 / 42

Krugman (1979) Gains from trade revisited p/w Z Z P (p/w)0 (p/w)1 P Z Z c1 c0 c Suppose that two identical countries open up to trade This is equivalent to a doubling of country size (which would have no e ect in a neoclassical trade model) Because of IRS, opening up to trade now leads to: Increased product variety: c 1 < c 0 ) 1 f /2L+c 1 /ϕ > 1 f /L+c 0 /ϕ Pro-competitive/e ciency e ects: (p/w) 1 < (p/w) 0 ) q 1 > q 0 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 11 / 42

CES Utility Trade economists most preferred demand system Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) utility corresponds to the case where: U = R n 0 (c i ) σ 1 σ di, where σ > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between pair of varieties This is the case considered in Krugman (1980) What is it to like about CES utility? Homotheticity (u (c) (c) σ σ 1 is actually the only functional form such that U is homothetic) Can be derived from discrete choice model with i.i.d extreme value shocks (See Feenstra Appendix B) Is it empirically reasonable? 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 12 / 42

CES Utility Special properties of the equilibrium Because of monopoly pricing, CES ) constant markups: p σ 1 w = σ 1 ϕ Because of zero pro t, constant markups ) constant output per rm: p w = f q + 1 ϕ Because of market clearing, constant output per rm ) constant number of varieties per country: n = L f + q/ϕ So, gains from trade only come from access to Foreign varieties IRS provide an intuitive reason why Foreign varieties are di erent But consequences of trade would now be the same if we had maintained CRS with di erent countries producing di erent goods 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 13 / 42

CES Utility Special properties of the equilibrium Decentralized equilibrium is e cient Decentralized equilibrium solves: R n max q i,n subject to : nf + R n 0 A central planner would solve: subject to: Under CES, p i (q i ) q i q 1 0 p i (q i ) q i di q i di L. ϕ R n max q i,n 0 (q i ) σ 1 σ di nf + R n 0 q i di L. ϕ 1 σ i ) Two solutions coincide This is unique to CES (in general, entry is distorted) This implies that many properties of perfectly competitive models will carry over to this environment 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 14 / 42

Demand Like in Krugman (1980), representative agent has CES preferences: Z σ U = q (ω) σ σ 1 σ 1 dω ω2ω where σ > 1 is the elasticity of substitution Consumption and expenditures for each variety are given by p (ω) σ q (ω) = Q (1) P p (ω) 1 σ r (ω) = R (2) P where: Z P p (ω) 1 ω2ω 1 Z σ 1 σ dω, R r (ω), and Q R/P ω2ω 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 15 / 42

Production Like in Krugman (1980), labor is the only factor of production L total endowment, w = 1 wage Like in Krugman (1980), there are IRS in production l = f + q/ϕ (3) Like in Krugman (1980), monopolistic competition implies p (ϕ) = 1 ρϕ CES preferences with monopoly pricing, (2) and (4), imply (4) r (ϕ) = R (Pρϕ) σ 1 (5) These two assumptions, (3) and (4), further imply π (ϕ) r (ϕ) l (ϕ) = r (ϕ) σ 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 16 / 42 f

Production Comments: 1 Higher productivity ϕ in the model implies higher measured productivity r(ϕ) l (ϕ) = 1 1 ρ f l (ϕ) 2 More productive rms produce more and earn higher revenues q (ϕ 1 ) q (ϕ 2 ) = ϕ1 ϕ 2 σ and r (ϕ 1 ) r (ϕ 2 ) = σ 1 ϕ1 3 ϕ can also be interpreted in terms of quality. This is isomorphic to a change in units of account, which would a ect prices, but nothing else ϕ 2 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 17 / 42

Aggregation By de nition, the CES price index is given by Z P = p (ω) 1 ω2ω 1 σ 1 σ dω Since all rms with productivity ϕ charge the same price p (ϕ), we can rearrange CES price index as Z + P = p (ϕ) 1 0 1 σ 1 σ Mµ (ϕ) d ϕ where: M mass of (surviving) rms in equilibrium µ (ϕ) (conditional) pdf of rm-productivity levels in equilibrium 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 18 / 42

Aggregation Combining the previous expression with monopoly pricing (4), we get where Z + eϕ P = M 1 1 σ /ρeϕ 0 ϕ σ 1 1 σ 1 µ (ϕ) d ϕ One can do the same for all aggregate variables Comments: R = Mr (eϕ), Π = Mπ (eϕ), Q = M σ σ 1 q (eϕ) 1 These are the same aggregate variables we would get in a Krugman (1980) model with a mass M of identical rms with productivity eϕ 2 But productivity eϕ now is an endogenous variable which may respond to changes in trade cost, leading to aggregate productivity changes 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 19 / 42

Entry and exit In order to determine how µ (ϕ) and eϕ get determine in equilibrium, one needs to specify the entry and exit of rms Timing is similar to Hopenhayn (1992): 1 There is a large pool of identical potential entrants deciding whether to become active or not 2 Firms deciding to become active pay a xed cost of entry f e > 0 and get a productivity draw ϕ from a cdf G 3 After observing their productivity draws, rms decide whether to remain active or not 4 Firms deciding to remain active exit with a constant probability δ 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 20 / 42

Aside: Pareto distributions In variations and extensions of Melitz (2003), most common assumption on the productivity distribution G is Pareto: G (ϕ) 1 ϕ ϕ θ for ϕ ϕ g (ϕ) θϕ θ ϕ θ 1 for ϕ ϕ Pareto distributions have two advantages: 1 Combined with CES, it delivers closed form solutions 2 Distribution of rm sizes remains Pareto, which is not a bad approximation empirically (at least for the upper tail) But like CES, Pareto distributions will have very strong implications for equilibrium properties (more on this later) 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 21 / 42

Productivity cuto In a stationary equilibrium, a rm either exits immediately or produces and earns the same pro ts π (ϕ) in each period In the absence of time discounting, expected value of a rm with productivity ϕ is v (ϕ) = max 0, t=0 + (1 δ)t π (ϕ) = max 0, π (ϕ) δ n o There exists a unique productivity level ϕ inf ϕ 0 : π(ϕ) δ > 0 Productivity cuto ϕ can also be written as: π (ϕ ) = 0 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 22 / 42

Aggregate productivity Once we know ϕ, we can compute the pdf of rm-productivity levels ( g (ϕ) if ϕ ϕ µ (ϕ) = 1 G (ϕ ) 0 if ϕ < ϕ Accordingly, the measure of aggregate productivity is given by Z eϕ (ϕ 1 + ) = 1 G (ϕ ϕ σ 1 g (ϕ) d ϕ ) ϕ 1 σ 1 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 23 / 42

Free entry condition Let π Π/M denote average pro ts per period for surviving rms Free entry requires the total expected value of pro ts to be equal to the xed cost of entry Free Entry Condition (FE): 0 G (ϕ ) + π δ [1 G (ϕ )] = f e π = δf e 1 G (ϕ ) (6) Holding constant the xed costs of entry, if rms are less likely to survive, they need to be compensated by higher average pro ts 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 24 / 42

Zero cuto pro t condition De nition of ϕ can be rearranged to obtain a second relationship between ϕ and π By de nition of π, we know that r π = Π/M = π [eϕ (ϕ [eϕ (ϕ )], π = )] f σf By de nition of ϕ, we know that π (ϕ ) = 0, r (ϕ ) = σf 1 Two previous expressions imply ZCP condition: r [eϕ (ϕ π = " )] eϕ (ϕ f r (ϕ 1 = ) σ 1 f 1# ) ϕ (7) 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 25 / 42

Closed economy equilibrium 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 26 / 42

Aside: the shape of the ZCP schedule FE and ZCP, (6) and (7), determine a unique (π, ϕ ), and therefore eϕ, independently of country size L the only variable left to compute is M, which can be done using free entry and labor market clearing as in Krugman (1980) However, ZCP is not necessarily downward sloping: it depends on whether eϕ or ϕ increases relatively faster ZCP is downward sloping for most common distributions In the Pareto case, it is easy to check that eϕ/ϕ is constant: So ZCP is at and average pro ts are independent of ϕ 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 27 / 42

Number of varieties and welfare Free entry and labor market clearing imply L = R = rm We can rearrange the previous expression M = L r = L σ (π + f ) Like in Krugman (1980), welfare of a representative worker is given by U = 1/P = M σ 1 1 ρeϕ Since eϕ and π are independent of L, growth in country size and costless trade will also have the same impact as in Krugman (1980): welfare % because of % in total number of varieties in each country 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 28 / 42

Open economy model In the absence of trade costs, we have seen trade integration does not lead to any intra-industry reallocation (eϕ is xed) In order to move away from such (counterfactual) predictions, Melitz (2003) introduces two types of trade costs: 1 Iceberg trade costs: in order to sell 1 unit abroad, rms need to ship τ 1 units 2 Fixed exporting costs: in order to export abroad, rms must incur an additional xed cost f ex (information, distribution, or regulation costs) after learning their productivity ϕ In addition, Melitz (2003) assumes that c = 1,..., n countries are symmetric so that w c = 1 in all countries 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 29 / 42

Production Monopoly pricing now implies p d (ϕ) = 1 ρϕ, p x (ϕ) = τ ρϕ Revenues in the domestic and export markets are r d (ϕ) = R d [P d ρϕ] σ 1, r x (ϕ) = τ 1 σ R x [P x ρϕ] σ 1 Note that by symmetry, we must have P d = P x = P and R d = R x = R Let f x δf ex. Pro ts in the domestic and export markets are π d (ϕ) = r d (ϕ) σ f, π x (ϕ) = r x (ϕ) σ f x 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 30 / 42

Productivity cuto s Expected value of a rm with productivity ϕ is v (ϕ) = max 0, + t=0 (1 δ)t π (ϕ) = max But total pro ts of are now given by 0, π (ϕ) δ π (ϕ) = π d (ϕ) + max f0, π x (ϕ)g n o Like in the closed economy, we let ϕ inf ϕ 0 : π(ϕ) δ > 0 n o In addition, we let ϕx inf ϕ ϕ : π x (ϕ) δ > 0 be the export cuto In order to have both exporters and non-exporters in equilibrium, ϕx > ϕ, we assume that: τ σ 1 f x > f 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 31 / 42

Selection into exports π Exit Don t Export Export π D π X 0 (ϕ * ) σ 1 (ϕ* x )σ 1 (ϕ) σ 1 -f D -f X Image by MIT OpenCourseWare. 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 32 / 42

Are exporters more productive than non-exporters? In the model, more productive rms (higher ϕ) select into exports Empirically, this directly implies larger rms (higher r (ϕ)) Question: Does that also mean that rms with higher measured productivity select into exports? Answer: Yes. For this to be true, we need which always holds if τ σ r d (ϕ) + nr x (ϕ) l d (ϕ) + nl x (ϕ) > r d (ϕ) l d (ϕ), 1 f x > f Comment: Like in the closed economy, this crucially relies on the fact that xed labor costs enter the denominator 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 33 / 42

Aggregation In the open economy, aggregate productivity is now given by where: eϕ t = 1 h M eϕ σ 1 + nm x (eϕ M x /τ) σ 1i σ 1 1 t M t M + nm x is the total number of varieties Z + 1 eϕ = 1 1 G (ϕ ϕ ) σ 1 σ 1 g (ϕ) d ϕ is the average productivity ϕ across all rms 1 eϕ x = 1 ϕ σ 1 σ 1 g (ϕ) d ϕ is the average productivity 1 G (ϕ x ) Z + ϕ x across all exporters 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 34 / 42

Aggregation Once we know eϕ t, we can still compute all aggregate variables as: Comment: P = M 1 1 σ t /ρeϕ t, R = M t r (eϕ t ), Π = M t π (eϕ t ), Q = M σ σ 1 t q (eϕ t ) Like in the closed economy, there is a tight connection between welfare (1/P) and average productivity (eϕ t ) But in the open economy, this connection heavily relies on symmetry: welfare depends on the productivity of foreign, not domestic exporters 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 35 / 42

Free entry condition The condition for free entry is unchanged Free Entry Condition (FE): π = δf e 1 G (ϕ ) (8) The only di erence is that average pro ts now depend on export pro ts as well π = π d (eϕ) + np x π x (eϕ x ) where: p x = 1 G (ϕ x ) 1 G (ϕ is probability of exporting conditional on successful entry ) 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 36 / 42

Zero cuto pro t condition By de nition of the cut o productivity levels, we know that This implies π d (ϕ ) = 0, r d (ϕ ) = σf π x (ϕ x ) = 0, r x (ϕ x ) = σf x r x (ϕx ) r d (ϕ ) = f x f 1, ϕ x = fx σ 1 ϕ τ f By rearranging π as a function of ϕ, we new ZCP condition: " eϕ (ϕ π = " ) σ 1 eϕx (ϕ f 1# ) σ 1 ϕ + np x f x 1# ϕx (ϕ ) 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 37 / 42

The Impact of Trade π Free entry π π a δf a Trade Zero cutoff profit Autarky ϕ a ϕ ϕ Image by MIT OpenCourseWare. 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 38 / 42

The Impact of Trade In line with empirical evidence, exposure to trade forces the least productive rms to exit: ϕ > ϕ a Intuition: For exporters: Pro ts % due to export opportunities, but & due to the entry of foreign rms in the domestic market (P &) For non-exporters: only the negative second e ect is active Comments: The % in ϕ is not a new source of gains from trade. It s because there are gains from trade (P &) that ϕ %increases Welfare unambiguously % though number of domestic varieties & M = R r = L σ (π + f + p x nf x ) < M a 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 39 / 42

The Impact of Trade π π π D π X 0 (ϕ * ) σ 1 (ϕ * x ) σ 1 (ϕ) σ 1 -f D -f X Image by MIT OpenCourseWare. 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 40 / 42

The Impact of Trade Lose Market Share Gain Market Share π π π a π D π X (ϕ* a ) σ 1 0 (ϕ ) σ 1 (ϕ (ϕ) σ 1 x ) σ 1 -f D -f X Image by MIT OpenCourseWare. 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 41 / 42

Other comparative static exercises Starting from autarky and moving to trade is theoretically standard, but not empirically appealing Melitz (2003) also considers: 1 Increase in the number of trading partners n 2 Decrease in iceberg trade costs τ 3 Decrease in xed exporting costs f x Same qualitative insights in all scenarios: Exit of least e cient rms Reallocation of market shares from less from more productive rms Welfare gains 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 42 / 42

MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 14.581 International Economics I Spring 2013 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms.