Revenue optimization in AdExchange against strategic advertisers

Similar documents
Optimal Regret Minimization in Posted-Price Auctions with Strategic Buyers

arxiv: v1 [cs.lg] 23 Nov 2014

Regret Minimization against Strategic Buyers

Learning for Revenue Optimization. Andrés Muñoz Medina Renato Paes Leme

An algorithm with nearly optimal pseudo-regret for both stochastic and adversarial bandits

Horizon-Independent Optimal Pricing in Repeated Auctions with Truthful and Strategic Buyers

Monte-Carlo Planning: Introduction and Bandit Basics. Alan Fern

Monte-Carlo Planning: Introduction and Bandit Basics. Alan Fern

CS364A: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture #3: Myerson s Lemma

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments

Multi-armed bandit problems

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

Lecture 5. 1 Online Learning. 1.1 Learning Setup (Perspective of Universe) CSCI699: Topics in Learning & Game Theory

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Pricing a Low-regret Seller

Lecture 11: Bandits with Knapsacks

Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding October 24, Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

Budget Management In GSP (2018)

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome.

Sublinear Time Algorithms Oct 19, Lecture 1

Preference Networks in Matching Markets

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Outline. Objective. Previous Results Our Results Discussion Current Research. 1 Motivation. 2 Model. 3 Results

Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk

The efficiency of fair division

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

Lecture l(x) 1. (1) x X

Lecture 5: Iterative Combinatorial Auctions

Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective

Single Price Mechanisms for Revenue Maximization in Unlimited Supply Combinatorial Auctions

The Duo-Item Bisection Auction

CS269I: Incentives in Computer Science Lecture #14: More on Auctions

Bandit Learning with switching costs

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

All Equilibrium Revenues in Buy Price Auctions

2 Comparison Between Truthful and Nash Auction Games

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Single Price Mechanisms for Revenue Maximization in Unlimited Supply Combinatorial Auctions

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

Dynamics of the Second Price

Socially-Optimal Design of Crowdsourcing Platforms with Reputation Update Errors

TTIC An Introduction to the Theory of Machine Learning. The Adversarial Multi-armed Bandit Problem Avrim Blum.

Decentralized supply chain formation using an incentive compatible mechanism

Tug of War Game. William Gasarch and Nick Sovich and Paul Zimand. October 6, Abstract

On the Optimality of a Family of Binary Trees Techical Report TR

Adaptive Experiments for Policy Choice. March 8, 2019

Regret Minimization and Correlated Equilibria

Revenue Equivalence and Mechanism Design

Best response cycles in perfect information games

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

A lower bound on seller revenue in single buyer monopoly auctions

1 Overview. 2 The Gradient Descent Algorithm. AM 221: Advanced Optimization Spring 2016

Bernoulli Bandits An Empirical Comparison

Recalling that private values are a special case of the Milgrom-Weber setup, we ve now found that

Matching Markets and Google s Sponsored Search

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

On the Efficiency of Sequential Auctions for Spectrum Sharing

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

Mechanism Design For Set Cover Games When Elements Are Agents

Essays on Some Combinatorial Optimization Problems with Interval Data

6.896 Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory February 10, Lecture 3

Posted-Price Mechanisms and Prophet Inequalities

Random Search Techniques for Optimal Bidding in Auction Markets

A Theory of Value Distribution in Social Exchange Networks

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

A Theory of Value Distribution in Social Exchange Networks

Commitment in First-price Auctions

Game Theory Lecture #16

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Yao s Minimax Principle

Lower Bounds on Revenue of Approximately Optimal Auctions

Networks: Fall 2010 Homework 3 David Easley and Jon Kleinberg Due in Class September 29, 2010

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

Price Setting with Interdependent Values

COS 511: Theoretical Machine Learning. Lecturer: Rob Schapire Lecture #24 Scribe: Jordan Ash May 1, 2014

Attracting Intra-marginal Traders across Multiple Markets

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing

Mechanisms for House Allocation with Existing Tenants under Dichotomous Preferences

Auction Prices and Asset Allocations of the Electronic Security Trading System Xetra

Regret Minimization and the Price of Total Anarchy

Mechanisms for Matching Markets with Budgets

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

D I S C O N T I N U O U S DEMAND FUNCTIONS: ESTIMATION AND PRICING. Rotterdam May 24, 2018

The Value of Temptation

Laws of probabilities in efficient markets

Information Aggregation in Dynamic Markets with Strategic Traders. Michael Ostrovsky

Blind Portfolio Auctions via Intermediaries

An Approximation Algorithm for Capacity Allocation over a Single Flight Leg with Fare-Locking

,,, be any other strategy for selling items. It yields no more revenue than, based on the

Smoothed Analysis of Binary Search Trees

CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #18: Multi-Parameter Revenue-Maximization

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

CS 573: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture date: 22 February Combinatorial Auctions 1. 2 The Vickrey-Clarke-Groves (VCG) Mechanism 3

Finding Equilibria in Games of No Chance

Sequential Auctions and Auction Revenue

Transcription:

000 001 002 003 004 005 006 007 008 009 010 011 012 013 014 015 016 017 018 019 020 021 022 023 024 025 026 027 028 029 030 031 032 033 034 035 036 037 038 039 040 041 042 043 044 045 046 047 048 049 050 051 052 053 054 Revenue optimization in AdExchange against strategic advertisers Abstract In recent years, AdExchanges have become a popular tool for selling online advertisement space. This platform, has been beneficial not only to publishers, who have drastically increased their revenue by adopting it, but also to advertisers, who can design better marketing campaigns; and, ultimately to the user, who obtains a broader selection of ads relevant to his interests. Recently, some revenue optimization algorithms for AdExchanges have been proposed. However, none of these algorithms considers the possibility of facing a strategic advertiser. In this paper, the complications arising from these interactions are studied and a new revenue optimization algorithm is proposed and analyzed. In particular, we present tight bounds on the regret of an online learner attempting to optimize his revenue. 1. Introduction Over the past decade, online advertisement has become one of the fastest growing industries in the world. In fact, in 2013, this industry experienced a growth of 32% over the previous year (Nielsen, 2013). More recently, a new ad space selling platform has gained momentum amidst advertising companies: AdExchanges, similar to a financial exchange, sell displaying rights to advertisers by conducting real-time auctions. Several advantages over traditional online advertising are offered by AdExchanges; first of all, due to the absence of contracts, publishers are not obliged to display a minimal amount of impressions from an advertiser. Consequently, a more diverse collection of ads is seen by the user. In addition, more control on the time and location of ads is given to the advertiser, resulting in a better targeted marketing campaign. Finally, because the publishers inventory is sold using a second-price auction with reserve, fairness in the pricing scheme is guaranteed (Vickrey, 2012; Milgrom & Weber, 1982). The main objective of a publisher selling advertise- Preliminary work. Under review by the International Conference on Machine Learning (ICML). Do not distribute. ment space is to optimize his revenue. Due to the nature of AdExchanges, this may only be done by setting an appropriate reserve price. If set too low, the optimal revenue may not be attained by the publisher. However, when set too high, the bidder will not have any incentive to bid, resulting in no revenue for the publisher. Leveraging the transaction history collected by AdExchanges, some revenue optimization algorithms have been proposed in the literature (Cesa-Bianchi et al., 2013; Ostrovsky & Schwarz, 2011). More recently, a learning theory motivated algorithm was proposed by Mohri & Medina (2014) for optimizing revenue in second-price auctions with reserve. The aforementioned algorithms heavily rely on the assumption that the outcomes of repeated auctions are i.i.d. realizations of a random variable. However, one cannot expect the outcome of repeated auctions not to depend on the past. Indeed, with the knowledge of the fact that the publisher is using a revenue optimization algorithm, an advertiser might try to mislead the publisher by under-bidding. In fact, empirical evidence of strategic behavior by advertisers has been found by Edelman and Ostrovsky Edelman & Ostrovsky (2007). Our objective will thus be to analyze the interactions between strategic advertisers and publishers. In practice, several auctions in AdExchanges consist of a single bidder. In this setting, second-price auctions with reserve are equivalent to posted-price auctions: a seller sets a price for a good and the buyer decides whether or not to accept it (bid higher than the reserve price). In view of this fact and in order to capture the strategic behavior of a buyer, we will analyze online-algorithms for repeated posted-price auctions. At every time t, a price p t is offered by the seller and the buyer must decide to accept it or leave it. This scenario may be modeled as a two player repeated nonzero sum game with incomplete information where the seller s objective is to maximize his revenue while the advertiser seeks to maximize her surplus (see Section 2 for a complete explanation of the setup). The literature on non-zero sum games is very rich, however, much of the work on this subject has focused on characterizing different types of equilibria. Moreover, our problem has a particular structure that can be exploited to design efficient revenue optimization 055 056 057 058 059 060 061 062 063 064 065 066 067 068 069 070 071 072 073 074 075 076 077 078 079 080 081 082 083 084 085 086 087 088 089 090 091 092 093 094 095 096 097 098 099 100 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109

110 111 112 113 114 115 116 117 118 119 120 121 122 123 124 125 126 127 128 129 130 131 132 133 134 135 136 137 138 139 140 141 142 143 144 145 146 147 148 149 150 151 152 153 154 155 156 157 158 159 160 161 162 163 164 algorithms. From the seller s perspective, this game can also be seen as a bandit problem since only the revenue (reward) of the prices offered is accessible to the seller. Kleinberg & Leighton (2003) precisely study this continuous bandit setting under the assumption of an oblivious buyer (more precisely, the authors assume that at each round the seller interacts with a different buyer). The authors present a tight Θ(log log T ) regret bound for the scenario of a buyer having a fixed valuation and a regret bound of O(T 2/3 ) when facing an adversarial buyer by using an elegant reduction to a discrete bandit problem. However, when dealing with a strategic buyer, the usual definition of regret is no longer meaningful. Indeed, consider the following example: let the valuation of the buyer be given by v [0, 1] and assume an algorithm with sub-linear regret is used for T by the seller. A possible strategy for the buyer, knowing the seller s algorithm, would be to accept prices only if they are smaller than some small value ɛ, certain that the seller will eventually learn to offer only prices less than ɛ. If ɛ v, the buyer would have considerably boosted its surplus while in theory the buyer would have not incurred a large regret since in hindsight, the best fixed strategy would have been to offer price ɛ for all rounds. This, however does not seem optimal for the seller. In view of this, we use the definition of strategic-regret introduced by Amin et al. (Amin et al., 2013) to study precisely this problem. The authors give upper and lower bounds for the regret of a seller facing a strategic buyer and show that the surplus of the buyer must be discounted over time in order to be able to achieve sublinear regret (see Section 2). However, the gap between the authors upper and lower bound is in O( T ). Our main contribution is to give an upper bound on the strategic regret that is only a factor of O(log T ) away from the lower bound given in (Amin et al., 2013). In order to do this, we present a reduction of this problem to a truthful scenario. The proposed algorithm not only outperforms that of Amin et al. but also admits a much simpler analysis than the one given by the authors. 2. Setup The following game is to be played by a buyer and a seller. A good, for instance advertisement space, is repeatedly sold to the buyer who has a private valuation for it of v [0, 1]. At each round t 1,..., T, a price p t is offered by the seller and a decision a t {0, 1} is made by the buyer. a t takes value 1 when the buyer accepts to buy at that price and 0 otherwise. At the beginning of the game, the algorithm A used by the seller to set prices, is announced to the buyer and the buyer strategically plays against this algorithm. The knowledge of A is a standard assumption in mechanism design and also matches the practice in AdExchanges. For a value of γ < 1, define the discounted surplus of the buyer to be Sur(A, v) = T γ t 1 a t (v p t ). t=1 The discounting factor γ represents the preference of the buyer for acquiring the good now and not in the future. The revenue of the seller is given by Rev(A, v) = T a t p t. t=1 Finally, the performance of a seller s algorithm will be measured by the notion of strategic regret (Amin et al., 2013) Reg(A, v) = T v Rev(A, v). The buyer s objective will be to maximize his discounted surplus while the seller seeks to minimize his regret. Notice that because of the discounting factor γ, the buyer cannot be fully adversarial. We will be interested in designing algorithms that can attain a sub-linear regret o(t ). Before presenting the main results of this paper, let us study the complications that arise from dealing with a strategic buyer. Suppose the seller attempts to learn v by performing a binary search. This would be a natural algorithm when the buyer is truthful. However, since the algorithm is known to the buyer, for γ 0, it is in the best interest of the buyer to lie on the initial rounds, thereby quickly, in fact exponentially, decreasing the price offered by the seller. The seller would attain an Ω(T ) regret. The main issue with the previous approach is that a binary search algorithm is too aggressive. Indeed, an untruthful buyer can manipulate the seller into offering prices less than v/2 by lying about her value only once! The previous discussion suggests following a more conservative approach, In the next section, we discuss a natural family of conservative algorithms for this problem. 3. Monotone algorithms In the recent work of (Amin et al., 2013) the following conservative pricing strategy is introduced: let p 1 = 1 165 166 167 168 169 170 171 172 173 174 175 176 177 178 179 180 181 182 183 184 185 186 187 188 189 190 191 192 193 194 195 196 197 198 199 200 201 202 203 204 205 206 207 208 209 210 211 212 213 214 215 216 217 218 219

220 221 222 223 224 225 226 227 228 229 230 231 232 233 234 235 236 237 238 239 240 241 242 243 244 245 246 247 248 249 250 251 252 253 254 255 256 257 258 259 260 261 262 263 264 265 266 267 268 269 270 271 272 273 274 Algorithm 1 Family of monotone algorithms. Let p 1 = 1 and p t p t 1 for t = 2,... T. t = 1 p = p t while (Buyer rejects p) and (t < T ) do t = t + 1 p = p t while (t < T ) do t = t + 1 and β < 1. If price p t is rejected at round t, the lower price p t+1 = βp t is offered at the next round. If at any time price p t is accepted, then this price is offered for all the remaining rounds. We will denote this algorithm by monotone. The motivation behind this algorithm is clear: for an appropriate choice of β, the seller can slowly decrease the prices offered, thereby pressing the buyer to reject many prices (which is not convenient for her) before obtaining a favorable price. The authors present an O(T γ T ) regret bound for this algorithm, with T γ = 1/(1 γ). A more careful analysis shows that this bound can be further tightened to O( T γ T + T ) when the discounting factor γ is known to the seller. Despite its sublinear regret, the monotone algorithm remains suboptimal for certain choices of γ. Indeed, consider a scenario with γ 1. For this setting, the buyer would no longer have an incentive to lie, thus, an algorithm such as binary search would achieve logarithmic regret, while the regret achieved by the monotone algorithm is only guaranteed to be in O( T ). One may argue that the monotone algorithm is too specific since it admits a single parameter β and that perhaps a more complex algorithm with the same monotonic idea could achieve a more favorable regret. Let us therefore analyze a generic monotone algorithm A m defined by Algorithm 1. It can be shown that any monotone algorithm achieves regret Ω( T ) against truthful buyers and under a mild condition on the prices offered it is also true that against a strategic buyer all monotone algorithms have regret in Ω( T γ T + T ). Therefore, monotone is in fact optimal for this class of algorithms. 4. An optimal algorithm We will now define an algorithm that forces a buyer to be almost truthful, while keeping an aggressive search 1/2 1/4 3/4 1/16 5/16 9/16 13/16 Figure 1. Tree T (3) associated to the algorithm proposed in (Kleinberg & Leighton, 2003). strategy. The main idea of our algorithm is to press the buyer to stop lying by continuing to offer the price she rejects multiple times. Let à be an algorithm for revenue optimization used against a truthful buyer. Denote by T (T ) the tree associated to à after T rounds. That is, T (T ) is a complete tree of height T with nodes n T (T ) labeled with prices p n offered by Ã. The right and left children of n are denoted by r(n) and l(n) respectively. The price offered when p n is accepted by the buyer is the label of r(n) while the price offered by à if p n is rejected is the label of l(n). Figure 1 depicts the tree generated by the algorithm proposed in (Kleinberg & Leighton, 2003), which is described later on. Let S N and let A be defined by Algorithm 2. This algorithm mimics the behavior of Ã, however, when a price is rejected by the buyer, she must actually reject it for S rounds. In view of the discounting factor γ, it is not in the best interest of the buyer to lie for several rounds. Thus, if S is large enough, the buyer has a strong incentive to be truthful. Let us properly analyze Algorithm A. The prices offered by this algorithm define a path in T (T ). For each node in this path, we may define time t(n) to be the number of rounds it takes for A to reach this node. Notice that since S may be greater than 1, the path chosen by A might not necessarily reach the leaves of T (T ). We can also define the function U : T (T ) R +, whose value is the utility the buyer can get by playing an optimal strategy against A after node n is first reached. Lemma 1. The function U(n) satisfies the following recursive relation U(n) = max(γ t(n) 1 (v p n ) + U(r(n)), U(l(n))). (1) The previous lemma immediately gives us conditions under which a buyer will reject a price. Proposition 1. For any reachable node n, if price p n 275 276 277 278 279 280 281 282 283 284 285 286 287 288 289 290 291 292 293 294 295 296 297 298 299 300 301 302 303 304 305 306 307 308 309 310 311 312 313 314 315 316 317 318 319 320 321 322 323 324 325 326 327 328 329

330 331 332 333 334 335 336 337 338 339 340 341 342 343 344 345 346 347 348 349 350 351 352 353 354 355 356 357 358 359 360 361 362 363 364 365 366 367 368 369 370 371 372 373 374 375 376 377 378 379 380 381 382 383 384 Algorithm 2 Definition of algorithm A n = the root of T (T ) while Number of offered prices less than T do n if Accepted then n = r(n) else n for S times n = l(n) end if is rejected by the buyer, then v p n < γ S (1 γ)(1 γ S ). Let us consider the following algorithm à introduced in (Kleinberg & Leighton, 2003). The algorithm keeps track of a feasible interval [a,b] initialized to [0,1] and an increment parameter ɛ initialized to 1/2. The algorithm works in phases. In each phase, it offers prices a + ɛ, a + 2ɛ,... until a price is rejected. If price a + kɛ is rejected, then a new phase starts with the feasible interval set to [a + (k 1)ɛ, a + kɛ] and the increment parameter set to ɛ 2. This process continues until b a < 1/T at which point the price a is offered for the remaining rounds. It is evident that the number of phases needed by the algorithm is less than log 2 log 2 T, a more surprising fact is that this algorithm has been shown to achieve regret O(log log T ) when the seller faces a truthful buyer. Let us analyze the regret of our modified algorithm A when using the tree induced by Ã. Proposition 2. For any value of v [0, 1] and any γ (0, 1), the regret of algorithm A admits the following upper bound: Reg(A, v) (vs+1)( log 2 log 2 T +1)+ (1 + γ)γs T 2(1 γ)(1 γ S ). (2) It is worth noting that for S = 1 and γ 0 the upper bound coincides with that of (Kleinberg & Leighton, 2003). When an upper bound on the discounting factor γ is known to the seller, he can leverage this information and optimize upper bound (2) with respect to the parameter S. Theorem 1. Let 1/2 < γ < γ 0 < 1 and S = γ argmin S 1 + S 0 T (1 γ 0)(1 γ. 0 S) For any v [0, 1], if T > 4, the regret of A satisfies Reg(A, v) (2vγ 0 T γ0 log ct +1+v)(log 2 log 2 T +1)+4T γ0, where c = 4 log 2. The theorem helps us define conditions under which logarithmic regret can be achieved. Indeed, if γ 0 = e 1/ log T = O(1 1 log T ), using the inequality e x 1 x + x 2 /2 valid for all x > 0 we obtain 1 log2 T log T. 1 γ 0 2 log T 1 It then follows from Theorem 1 that Reg(A, v) (2v log T log ct + 1 + v)(log 2 log 2 T + 1) + 4 log T. (3) Let us compare the regret bound given by Theorem 1 with the one given in (Amin et al., 2013). The above discussion shows that for certain values of γ, an exponentially better regret can be achieved by our algorithm. It can be argued that the knowledge of an upper bound on γ is required, whereas this is not needed for the monotone algorithm. However, if γ > 1 1 T the regret bound on monotone is super-linear, and therefore uninformative. Thus, in order to properly compare both algorithms, we may assume that γ < 1 1 T in which case, by Theorem 1 the regret of our algorithm is O( T log T ) whereas only linear regret can be guaranteed by the monotone algorithm. Even under the more favorable bound of O( T γ T + T ), for any α < 1 and γ < 1 1/T α, the monotone algorithm will achieve regret O(T α+1 2 ) while a strictly better regret O(T α log T log log T ) is attained by ours. 5. Lower bound The following lower bounds have been given independently by Amin et. al (Amin et al., 2013) and Kleinberg and Leighton (Kleinberg & Leighton, 2003). Theorem 2. (Amin et al., 2013) Let γ > 0 be fixed. For any algorithm A, there exists a valuation v for the buyer such that Reg(A, v) 1 12 T γ. The above theorem is in fact given for the stochastic setting where the buyer s valuation is a random variable taken from some fixed distribution D. Nevertheless, the proof of this theorem selects D to be a point mass, therefore reducing the scenario to a fixed priced setting. Theorem 3. (Kleinberg & Leighton, 2003) Given any algorithm A to be played against a truthful buyer, there exists a value v [0, 1] such that Reg(A, v) C log log T for some universal constant C. Combining these results lead immediately to the following. 385 386 387 388 389 390 391 392 393 394 395 396 397 398 399 400 401 402 403 404 405 406 407 408 409 410 411 412 413 414 415 416 417 418 419 420 421 422 423 424 425 426 427 428 429 430 431 432 433 434 435 436 437 438 439

440 441 442 443 444 445 446 447 448 449 450 451 452 453 454 455 456 457 458 459 460 461 462 463 464 465 466 467 468 469 470 471 472 473 474 475 476 477 478 479 480 481 482 483 484 485 486 487 488 489 490 491 492 493 494 Corollary 1. Given any algorithm A, there exists a buyer s ( valuation v ) [0, 1] such that Reg(A, v) 1 max 12 T γ, C log log T, for a universal constant C. We now compare the upper bounds given in the previous section with the bound of Corollary 1. For γ > 1/2, we have Reg(A, v) = O(T γ log T log log T ). On the other hand, for γ 1/2, we may choose r = 1, in which case, by Proposition 2, Reg(A, v) = O(log log T ). Therefore, our upper and lower bounds match up to an O(log T ) term. 6. Conclusion and further research We have presented an analysis of revenue optimization algorithms against strategic buyers. In doing so, we have closed the gap between upper and lower bounds on strategic regret to a logarithmic factor. Furthermore, the algorithm presented here is simple to analyze and reduces to the truthful scenario when γ 0. This is an important property that previous algorithms did not admit. We believe that our analysis can be extended to the case of random valuations and, in fact, to general bandit problems with strategic opponents. References Amin, Kareem, Rostamizadeh, Afshin, and Syed, Umar. Learning prices for repeated auctions with strategic buyers. In NIPS, pp. 1169 1177, 2013. Cesa-Bianchi, Nicolò, Gentile, Claudio, and Mansour, Yishay. Regret minimization for reserve prices in second-price auctions. In SODA, pp. 1190 1204, 2013. Edelman, Benjamin and Ostrovsky, Michael. Strategic bidder behavior in sponsored search auctions. Decision Support Systems, 43(1), 2007. Kleinberg, Robert D. and Leighton, Frank Thomson. The value of knowing a demand curve: Bounds on regret for online posted-price auctions. In FOCS, pp. 594 605, 2003. Milgrom, P.R. and Weber, R.J. A theory of auctions and competitive bidding. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, pp. 1089 1122, 1982. Mohri, Mehryar and Medina, Andres Muñoz. Learning theory and algorithms for revenue optimization in second-price auctions with reserve. In Proceedings of The 31st International Conference on Machine Learning. JMLR Workshop and Conference Proceedings, 2014. Nielsen. Global adview pulse, quarter 3. Technical report, The Nielsen Company, 2013. Ostrovsky, Michael and Schwarz, Michael. Reserve prices in internet advertising auctions: A field experiment. In Proceedings of the 12th ACM conference on Electronic commerce, pp. 59 60. ACM, 2011. Vickrey, William. Counterspeculation, auctions, and competitive sealed tenders. The Journal of finance, 16(1):8 37, 2012. 495 496 497 498 499 500 501 502 503 504 505 506 507 508 509 510 511 512 513 514 515 516 517 518 519 520 521 522 523 524 525 526 527 528 529 530 531 532 533 534 535 536 537 538 539 540 541 542 543 544 545 546 547 548 549