Working Group on IMF Programs and Health Expenditures Background Paper March 2007

Similar documents
Working Group on IMF Programs and Health Expenditures Background Paper April 2007

Background Note on Prospects for IDA to Become Financially Self-Sustaining

Working Paper Number 116 April 2007

MDRI HIPC MULTILATERAL DEBT RELIEF INITIATIVE HEAVILY INDEBTED POOR COUNTRIES INITIATIVE GOAL GOAL

HIPC HEAVILY INDEBTED POOR COUNTRIES INITIATIVE MDRI MULTILATERAL DEBT RELIEF INITIATIVE

Report on Countries That Are Candidates for Millennium Challenge Account Eligibility in Fiscal

HIPC DEBT INITIATIVE FOR HEAVILY INDEBTED POOR COUNTRIES ELIGIBILITY GOAL

MDRI HIPC. heavily indebted poor countries initiative. To provide additional support to HIPCs to reach the MDGs.

Working Party on Export Credits and Credit Guarantees

ShockwatchBulletin: Monitoring the impact of the euro zone crisis, China/India slow-down, and energy price shocks on lower-income countries

ALLOCATING IDA FUNDS BASED ON PERFORMANCE. Fourth Annual Report on IDA s Country Assessment and Allocation Process

PARIS CLUB RECENT ACTIVITY

Lessons learnt from 20 years of debt relief

Small States - Performance in Public Debt Management

PROGRESS REPORT NATIONAL STRATEGIES FOR THE DEVELOPMENT OF STATISTICS. May 2010 NSDS SUMMARY TABLE FOR IDA AND LOWER MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES

INTERNATIONAL BANK FOR RECONSTRUCTION AND DEVELOPMENT BOARD OF GOVERNORS. Resolution No. 612

Education for All Fast Track Initiative (EFA-FTI) FTI) FASID Tokyo August 10, Desmond BERMINGHAM Head, FTI Secretariat

IBRD/IDA and Blend Countries: Per Capita Incomes, Lending Eligibility, and Repayment Terms

Building resilience and reducing vulnerability in small states

Fiscal Policy Responses in African Countries to the Global Financial Crisis

TRENDS AND MARKERS Signatories to the United Nations Convention against Transnational Organised Crime

GEF Evaluation Office MID-TERM REVIEW OF THE GEF RESOURCE ALLOCATION FRAMEWORK. Portfolio Analysis and Historical Allocations

Senior Leadership Programme (SLP) CATA Commonwealth Association of Tax Administrators

NSDS STATUS IN IDA AND LOWER MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES

Report to Donors Sponsored Delegates to the 12th Conference of the Parties Punta del Este, Uruguay 1-9 June 2015

IBRD/IDA and Blend Countries: Per Capita Incomes, Lending Eligibility, IDA Repayment Terms

Argentina Bahamas Barbados Bermuda Bolivia Brazil British Virgin Islands Canada Cayman Islands Chile

2019 Daily Prayer for Peace Country Cycle

Supplementary Table S1 National mitigation objectives included in INDCs from Jan to Jul. 2017

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND AND INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENT ASSOCIATION

IDA16 Mid-Term Review. Capping MDRI Netting Out: Implementation Experience

WILLIAMS MULLEN. U.S. Trade Preference Programs & Trade Agreements

CLEAN TECHNOLOGY FUND ELIGIBILITY OF GUARANTEES FINANCED FROM THE CLEAN TECHNOLOGY FUND FOR SCORING AS OFFICIAL DEVELOPMENT ASSISTANCE

The State of the World s Macroeconomy

Figure 1. Exposed Countries

The world of CARE. 2 CARE Facts & Figures

Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2011

H. R. To provide for the cancellation of debts owed to international financial institutions by poor countries, and for other purposes.

An Introduction to DeMPA

Re-Evaluating the Effectiveness of Trade Conditions in Fund-Supported Programs

These notes are circulated for the information of Members with the approval of the Member in charge of the Bill, the Hon W.E. Teare, MHK.

2 Albania Algeria , Andorra

WGI Ranking for SA8000 System

Building Resilience in Fragile States: Experiences from Sub Saharan Africa. Mumtaz Hussain International Monetary Fund October 2017

Africa: An Emerging World Region

Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide Out-of-sample results based on IMF s new Global Debt Database

ANNEX 2. The following 2016 per capita income guidelines apply for operational purposes:

to Debt Management Capacity Building in LICs

SURVEY TO DETERMINE THE PERCENTAGE OF NATIONAL REVENUE REPRESENTED BY CUSTOMS DUTIES INTRODUCTION

World Bank Lending to Borrowers in Africa by Theme and Sector Fiscal

Annex Supporting international mobility: calculating salaries

Sustainability Framework (DSF) for LICs: An Overview

An Introduction to Subnational DeMPA

Enabling long term. finance in local currency. Enabling Long Term. Local Currency

TABLe A.1 Countries and Their Financial System Characteristics, Averages, Accounts per thousand adults, commercial banks

Appendix 3 Official Debt Restructuring

w w w. k u w a i t - f u n d. o r g

EMBARGOED UNTIL GMT 1 AUGUST

Compliance Report Okinawa 2000 Development. Commitments 1. Debt

IDA13. Measuring Outputs and Outcomes in IDA Countries

The Little Data Book on External Debt

ANNEX 2. The applicable maturity premiums for pricing groups A, B, C and D are set forth in Tables 2, 3, 4 and 5 below, respectively

Annex A to DP/2017/39 17 October 2017 Annex A to the UNDP integrated resources plan and integrated budget estimates for

INTERNATIONAL BANK FOR RECONSTRUCTION AND DEVELOPMENT BOARD OF GOVERNORS. Resolution No General Capital Increase

Why Corrupt Governments May Receive More Foreign Aid

( Euro) Annual & Monthly Premium Rates. International Healthcare Plan. Geographic Areas. (effective 1st July 2007) Premium Discount

United Nations Environment Programme

The cost of closing national social protection gaps

African Financial Markets Initiative

IMPENDING CHANGES. Subsistence Allowances

Appendix II. Financial Operations and Transactions Appendix II.1. Arrangements approved during financial years ended April 30,

The Changing Wealth of Nations 2018

Debt Management: The Alphabet Soup

The world of CARE. CARE International Member Countries A Australia B Austria C Canada D Denmark. E France F Germany G Japan H Netherlands

Improving the Investment Climate in Sub-Saharan Africa

COUNTRY DSA(US$) MAX RES RATE MAX TRV RATE EFFECTIVE DATE OF %

1.1 LIST OF DAILY MAXIMUM AMOUNT PER COUNTRY WHICH IS DEEMED TO BEEN EXPENDED

OP 3.10 Annex D - IBRD/IDA and Blend Countries: Per Capita. Incomes, Lending Eligibility, and Repayment Terms, July 2016, updated December 2016

COUNTRY DSA(US$) MAX RES RATE MAX TRV RATE EFFECTIVE DATE OF %

Afghanistan $135 $608 $911 1 March Albania $144 $2,268 $3,402 1 January Angola $286 $5,148 $7,722 1 January 2003

Resolution adopted by the General Assembly on 24 December [on the report of the Fifth Committee (A/67/502/Add.1)]

Afghanistan $135 $608 $911 1 March Albania $144 $2,268 $3,402 1 January Algeria $208 $624 $936 1 March 1990

COUNTRY DSA(US$) MAX RES RATE MAX TRV RATE EFFECTIVE DATE OF %

Country Documentation Finder

Monitoring the impact of the financial crisis on national education financing: A cross country study

Appendix II. Appendix Table II.1. Arrangements approved during financial years ended April 30, Amounts committed under arrangements 1

COUNTRY DSA(US$) MAX RES RATE MAX TRV RATE EFFECTIVE DATE OF %

ANNEX 2: Methodology and data of the Starting a Foreign Investment indicators

IBRD/IDA and Blend Countries: Per Capita Incomes, Lending Eligibility, and Repayment Terms

The world of CARE. CARE International Member Countries A Australia B Austria C Canada D Denmark. E France F Germany/Luxemburg G Japan H Netherlands

Established in July 1989, extended, current closing date July 31, 2017.

International Monetary Fund-World Bank Group Technical Assistance Activities on Public Debt Management in Low Income Countries 1

Memoranda of Understanding

OP 3.10 Annex D - IBRD/IDA and Blend Countries: Per Capita Incomes, Lending Eligibility, and Repayment Terms, July 2016

Hundred and Seventy-fifth Session. Rome, March Status of Current Assessments and Arrears as at 31 December 2018

World Meteorological Organization

Finexpo s action focuses on financing conditions for credits granted for the supply of equipment and services.

IFAD s participation in the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries Debt Initiative. Proposal for the Comoros and the 2010 progress report

To forecast demand for HCV medication under several scenarios (over a 10-year period)

Premium rates ($) Aetna International Healthcare Plan

Transcription:

Working Group on IMF Programs and Health Expenditures Background Paper March 2007 Inflation Targets in IMF-Supported Programs By David Goldsbrough, Ehui Adovor, and Ben Elberger Abstract In this paper, the authors summarize the evidence on the links between inflation and growth as well as IMF targets for inflation. They find that the weight of the theoretical and empirical evidence suggests that programs should generally avoid pushing inflation, say, 5 percent in low-income countries because of the risks of an unintended contractionary stance in the event of shocks. A number of IMF programs may have gone beyond the available evidence in targeting very low inflation. Nevertheless, the authors conclude that this is not the central issue in the debate over the appropriateness of macroeconomic frameworks in IMF program design. This is largely because there is no stable, permanent tradeoff through which a more expansionary monetary policy can buy higher growth. Eventually, price and wage expectations adjust. The speed at which such adjustments occur is an important influence on the monetary stance and those requiring nominal price and wage declines can be slow to take place. For this reason, targeting very low inflation, when there is a significant risk that temporary adverse shocks may require significant shifts in relative prices, can be costly in terms of lost output. But once expectations have already adjusted to a low-inflation environment, a monetary stance that is flexible enough to accommodate such shocks would be sufficient. Beyond that, there is no strong evidence that deliberately targeting higher inflation can yield faster growth. This paper informed the deliberations of the Center for Global Development s Working Group on IMF Programs and Health Expenditures. This is one of a series of background papers prepared for the Working Group on IMF Programs and Health Expenditures. The views expressed are those of the author(s) and should not be attributed to members of the Working Group, or to the directors or funders of the Center for Global Development. Use and dissemination of this paper is encouraged; however, reproduced copies may not be used for commercial purposes. Further usage is permitted under the terms of the Creative Commons License. www.cgdev.org/section/initiatives/_active/ghprn/workinggroups/imf 1

This note briefly summarizes the evidence on the links between inflation and growth and then investigates what IMF programs have actually targeted for inflation. We then draw a number of conclusions. 1. The Nature of the Debate 1 The nature of the debate about the appropriate targets for inflation rates in low-income countries revolves around two sets of arguments: (i) (ii) More expansionary monetary policy, reflected in less conservative inflation targets, would generate faster real growth. Although the channels through which higher demand-driven growth would be achieved and sustained are often not well explained, the strongest argument is that a greater susceptibility by low income countries to exogenous shocks makes it harder to accommodate the short-term effects on prices within very low inflation targets. With lower average inflation, more nominal prices (and wages) need to decline in absolute terms to restore equilibrium in the event of such shocks. Since nominal prices are often sticky downwards, short-term monetary management may involve greater output volatility and a lower trend growth rate when it is guided by very low inflation targets. Higher inflation than is typical in IMF programs would make available additional fiscal space, via additional monetary financing of the fiscal deficit. Additional monetary expansion leading to higher inflation involves a redistribution of resources toward the government (via the inflation tax on those holding currency) and, like most other taxes, imposes a further cost on the economy by distorting decisionmaking. Whether it is worth bearing those costs depends on how high they are in comparison with the costs of raising other taxes or forgoing expenditures, which is an empirical question. 2 The evidence on the association between inflation and growth from a large number of crosscountry studies (see IMF, 2005 and Chowdhury, 2005 for reviews) indicates that the relationship is non-linear: at low initial rates, higher inflation may have no effect on growth or the effect may even be positive, but after some threshold higher inflation is typically associated with poorer growth outcomes. There is considerable debate as to exactly where this threshold lies; some results suggest a threshold around 5-10 percent while some suggest 10-20 percent or even higher. The precise magnitudes estimated in the various cross-country studies should be taken with a grain of salt because the benefits of more stable prices for an economy are likely to depend considerably on people s expectations of whether they will last, which could vary enormously from country to country depending on the credibility of institutions and each country s past 1 This section draws upon the discussion in the earlier background note on The Nature of the Debate between the IMF and its Critics. 2 The revenue generated by money creation called seigniorage comes from the fact that those who hold currency or similar domestic claims on the central bank are giving an interest-free loan to the bank. This is transferred to the government as central bank profits or -market loans. The discussion in ActionAid (2004 and 2005) makes clear that their criticism of IMF inflation targets relies primarily on the first argument i.e. that more expansionary monetary policy would generate faster real growth. 2

history with inflation. However, there is probably a broad measure of consensus on at least the first three of the following: Inflation targets should be set to avoid the risk of an unintended contractionary stance. Since such risks can be greater in low income countries because they typically suffer from larger shocks, programs in low income countries should avoid pushing inflation to very low levels-- say, 5 percent. An exception to this lower threshold may be necessary in countries that are part of a common currency area, where the inflation rate is determined by the exchange rate arrangements. For example, the West African Economic and Monetary Union (WAEMU) has a target of no more than 3 percent average annual inflation, based on the objective of keeping the inflation differential with the Euro, to which it is pegged, small. Inflation rates above about 30 percent are likely to be harmful for growth. There is much less consensus on the middle range. IMF policy papers have taken the position that the evidence supports the use of single-digit ranges for inflation targets in low-income countries while a number of critics argue that higher ranges say, 15-20 percent or even higher would be acceptable. 3 However, there is no evidence that targeting substantially higher inflation is actually good for growth. Indeed, one of the difficulties with applying the cross-country results to individual country cases is that the cross-country evidence ignores the path by which a country arrived at a particular inflation rate. But this inflation history can be critical for how expectations of future inflation respond to changes in monetary policy. For example, even if it is true that a country has foregone some output by attempting to reduce inflation too rapidly (perhaps because inflation expectations were slow to adapt downwards), it does not necessarily follow that targeting higher inflation thereafter would increase growth. The outcome will depend substantially on how quickly expectations of future inflation respond to the adoption of higher inflation targets; in practice, they are likely to respond quickly, so countries get the higher inflation but no significant output gains. 4 Going from a 5 to a 15-20 percent inflation rate would not generate very large additional resources for the budget from seigniorage because the initial stocks of money in relation to GDP are small in low-income countries and higher inflation would have some disincentive effect on currency holdings. Typical estimates suggest that the additional revenue could be around ½ percent of GDP. 5 While such additional resources could have an impact if devoted to high-priority activities, the magnitude is relatively small. Thus, while there is undoubtedly a grey area in which it is not possible to say what the precise relationship is between growth and inflation, these remaining differences, although not negligible, do not seem large enough to be the central issue in the debate on the appropriateness 3 The inflation rate is one of 16 indicators considered by the U.S. Millennium Challenge Corporation in determining eligibility for the Millennium Challenge Account. To pass the indicator, a country s inflation rate needs to be under a ceiling of 15 percent. 4 This is similar to the analysis of why there is no stable relationship between inflation and unemployment, for which Edmund Phelps recently received the Nobel Prize. See Swedish Academy of Sciences (2006). 5. Total seigniorage earnings have typically been in the range of 1-1 ½ percent of GDP for low-income countries not experiencing very rapid inflation. Adam and Bevan (2005) identify a threshold effect, beyond which higher seigniorage tends to have a negative effect on growth, at about 1 ¼ percent of GDP, but note that these effects depend on how the resources are used. 3

of IMF-supported macroeconomic frameworks. The discussion suggests that the most significant question is whether IMF-supported programs have inappropriately targeted very low inflation and thereby incurred risks of an overly contractionary demand management stance in the event of unexpected shocks. We turn to this issue next. 2. What have IMF programs actually targeted for inflation? The IMF s own general policy conclusion on appropriate targets for inflation, summarized in its 2006 paper, Designing Monetary Policy in Low-Income Countries, is as follows: On balance, these considerations support the use of single digit inflation targets.however, pushing inflation too low say, 5 percent may entail a loss of output and seigniorage revenue, suggesting a need for caution in setting very low inflation targets in low-income countries. These countries tend to be subject to larger output volatility and more pronounced price shocks, and program design should take these attributes properly into account. In particular, inflation targets should be set so as to help avoid risks of an unintended contractionary policy stance. IMF (2006), page 17 It is useful to investigate whether IMF-supported programs have in practice gone beyond the generally accepted evidence (and IMF policy pronouncements) to target very low inflation rates. To address this question, we reviewed initial program targets for inflation under all arrangements in the PRGF and its predecessor, the ESAF, between 1995 and early 2007. 6 The results indicate the following: Of the 32 arrangements approved under the PRGF between 2003 and February 2007 (referred to here as the late PRGF period), two thirds (22 cases) targeted inflation to be at or under 5 percent by the second year and over one third ( 12 cases) targeted inflation to be under 3 percent (Table 1; see Appendix 1 for the country details). 7 However, most of the programs with very low inflation targets (i.e. 3 percent or under) were with countries in currency unions. Apart from such cases, only two programs (Armenia and Albania) targeted inflation to remain 3 percent. However, almost one third (10 out of 32 cases) targeted inflation in the 3-5 percent range. At the other end of the range, only one case (Zambia) had inflation targeted to remain in double digits. To a considerable extent, these low targets reflected a starting position of low inflation as a result of earlier successes with macroeconomic stabilization. No major shift in the pattern of inflation targets seems to have occurred between the ESAF and the PRGF, apart from that reflected in the generally better starting position under the PRGF (see Appendix 1). 6 Timing and country coverage are important because two earlier investigations came to somewhat different conclusions. Oxfam (2003) reported that 16 of the 20 3-year programs they examined had inflation targets 5 percent at the end of the period whereas the IEO (2004, see Box 4.7) reported that when initial inflation was above 10 percent, programs always targeted a decline but that when initial inflation was 5 percent, the majority of programs projected inflation would rise; in those cases where inflation was between 5 and 10 percent, about two thirds of programs targeted lower inflation. 7 The focus is on targeted inflation in the second year (t +1 ) because many programs did not include inflation targets for the third year (t +2 ). 4

Table 1. Inflation Targets in PRGF-Supported Programs, 2003-Feb 2007 (Number of IMF Arrangements) Targeted inflation in t +1 Initial inflation rate in t -1 (percent) (percent) 3-5- 10- Above Total 5% 10% 20% 20% 8 (6) 8(6) 3-5% 2 (2) 3 5(2) 5-10% 2 (2) 5 4 11(2) 10-20% 2 5 7 Above 20% 1 1 Total 12 (10) 10 9 1 0 32 Source: Calculated from the tables in Appendix 1. # Numbers in brackets are the number of countries in currency unions (CFA franc or East Caribbean Currency Union) 3. Conclusions. If, as discussed earlier, the weight of the theoretical and empirical evidence suggests that programs should generally avoid pushing inflation, say, 5 percent in low-income countries because of the risks of an unintended contractionary stance in the event of shocks, then a number of programs may have gone beyond the available evidence in targeting very low inflation. Setting aside programs with countries in currency unions where the choice of exchange rate arrangement compels a low inflation rate about half of countries with PRGF arrangements since 2003 have involved programs that target inflation at 5 percent or lower; in all these cases, inflation was already very low at the start of the program. Nevertheless, we do not believe that this is the central issue in the debate over the appropriateness of macroeconomic frameworks in IMF program design. This is largely because there is no stable, permanent tradeoff through which a more expansionary monetary policy can buy higher growth. Eventually, price and wage expectations adjust. The speed at which such adjustments occur is an important influence on the monetary stance and those requiring nominal price and wage declines can be slow to take place. For this reason, targeting very low inflation, when there is a significant risk that temporary adverse shocks may require significant shifts in relative prices, can be costly in terms of lost output. But once expectations have already adjusted to a low-inflation environment, a monetary stance that is flexible enough to accommodate such shocks would be sufficient. Beyond that, there is no strong evidence that deliberately targeting higher inflation can yield faster growth. What this means in practice depends considerably on the inflation history and institutional arrangements of each country, so it is not possible to say from simple cross-country comparisons discussed in this paper whether monetary program design and implementation in particular cases was conducted appropriately. But whatever the answer to this question, we do not think it is the most critical issue in the debate about the appropriateness of IMF macroeconomic programs. 5

Appendix 1 Initial and Targeted Inflation Under ESAF-Supported Programs, 1995-1999 Initial inflation rate (at t -1 ) 3.1-5% 5.1-10% 10.1-20% Above 20% Targeted inflation (t +1 ) 3.1-5% 5.1-10% 10.1-20% Burkina Faso (1999), Central African Republic, Djibouti, Ethiopia, The Gambia, Macedonia, Mali (1999), Senegal Benin, Burkina Faso (1995), Niger Cameroon, Congo (Republic), Cote d Ivoire, Mali (1996) Mozambique (1999) Guinea, Guyana, Mauritania (1995) Kenya, Mauritania (1999) Cambodia, Ghana (1999), Haiti, Rwanda, Uganda Chad, Tanzania Azerbaijan, Bolivia, Nicaragua Guinea-Bissau, Honduras, Kyrgyz Republic, Pakistan Albania, Armenia, Ghana (1995), Madagascar, Malawi, Zambia (1995), Zambia (1999) Georgia, Mongolia, Mozambique (1996), Tajikistan, Yemen Totals 15 (11) 13 (2) 14 (1) 5 Above 20% Totals 9 (4) 6 (4) 9 (4) 9 (1) 14 (1) * Countries in bold are members of a currency union (CFA franc or East Caribbean Currency Union). Figures in brackets indicate number of countries that are members of a currency union. 6

Appendix 1 Initial and Targeted Inflation in Early PRGF-Supported Programs, 2000-2002 Initial inflation rate (at t -1 ) 3.1-5% 5.1-10% 10.1-20% Above 20% Benin, Cameroon, Macedonia, Niger, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Cape Verde Albania, Rwanda, Cote d Ivoire, The Gambia Guinea- Bissau, Sao Tome and Principe Targeted inflation (t +1 ) 3.1-5% 5.1-10% 10.1-20% Chad, Ethiopia, Sierra Leone, Guyana, Uganda, Vietnam Kenya, Tanzania, Guinea, Madagascar, Georgia Malawi Above 20% Totals 13 (3) Lao PR 5 (1) Lesotho, Mongolia, Nicaragua Moldova, Tajikistan Congo (DRC) Totals 13 (5) 12 (2) 5 1 0 8 (1) 2 (1) 4 (0) * Countries in bold are members of a currency union (CFA franc or East Caribbean Currency Union). Figures in brackets indicate number of countries that are members of a currency union. 7

Appendix 1 Initial and Targeted Inflation in Late PRGF-Supported Programs, 2003-2007 Initial Inflation Rate (at t -1 ) 3.1-5% 5.1-10% 10.1-20% Chad, Mali, Senegal, Dominica, Armenia, Cameroon, Benin, Albania Burkina Faso, Niger Central African Republic, Grenada Targeted Inflation (at t +1 ) 3.1-5% 5.1-10% 10.1-20% Kyrgyz Republic, Tanzania, Georgia Rwanda, Nepal, Mauritania 1, Burundi, Afghanistan Kenya, Malawi Mauritania 2, Honduras, Sri Lanka, Moldova Madagascar, Haiti, Mozambique, Sierra Leone, Ghana Above 20% Totals 8 (6) 5 (2) 11(2) Zambia 8 Above 20% 0 Totals 12 (10) 10 9 1 0 1 2003 PRGF Program 2 2006 PRGF Program * Countries in bold are members of a currency union (CFA franc or East Caribbean Currency Union). Figures in brackets indicate number of countries that are members of a currency union. 8

References ActionAid International USA (2004). Blocking Progress: How the Fight Against HIV/AIDS Is Being Undermined by the World Bank and International Monetary Fund. September 2004. ActionAid International USA (2005). Changing Course: Alternative Approaches to Achieve the Millennium Development Goals and Fight HIV/AIDS. September 2005. Chowdhury, A. and McKinley, T. (2006). Gearing Macroeconomic Policies to Manage Large Inflows of ODA: The Implications for HIV/AIDS Programmes. UNDP International Poverty Center, Working Paper No. 17, May 2006. Gupta, Sanjeev, Powell, R. and Yang, Y. (2006). Macroeconomic Challenges of Scaling Up Aid to Africa: a checklist for practitioners. Handbook prepared by the Policy Wing of the IMF s African Department. International Monetary Fund. International Monetary Fund (2004). A Response to ActionAid International and Other Organizations. By Thomas Dawson, Director, External Relations Department, IMF. September 30, 2004. Available at www.imf.org/external/np/vc/2004/093004.htm. International Monetary Fund (2005). Monetary and Fiscal Policy Design Issues in Low-Income Countries, August 2005. Available at www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2005/080805m.pdf. International Monetary Fund (2006). Designing Monetary and Fiscal Policy in Low-Income Countries. Occasional Paper 250. Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences (2006) The Prize in Economic Sciences 2006: Edmund Phelps. Available at http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/2006/info.pdf 9