Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain

Similar documents
Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy

Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden

CBO Projects More Severe Downturn

Will Fiscal Stimulus Packages Be Effective in Turning Around the European Economies?

The Ryan Medicare Plan: Winners and Losers

The Urgent Need for Job Creation

FINANCE & DEVELOPMENT

The Gains from Trade in a New Model from the IMF: Still Very Small

APPENDIX: Country analyses

1 World Economy. Value of Finnish Forest Industry Exports Fell by Almost a Quarter in 2009

Usable Productivity Growth in the United States

Leading Economic indicators

Finland falling further behind euro area growth

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Winter edition December 2012

Eurozone 2016 Economic and Capital Market Outlook

OECD Economic Outlook. Randall S. Jones Head, Japan/Korea Desk 25 November 2014

The American Debt Burden

Table 1.1. A comparison between the present forecast and the previous forecast in selected areas.

Maneuvering Past Stagflation: Prospects for the U.S. Economy In

What The New CBO Report Shows Budget And Economic Outlook Has Not Improved by James Horney and Richard Kogan

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

The Case for Money Finance:

Cutting debt and deficits

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast June 2014

CRS Report for Congress

Global Macroeconomic Monthly Review

Getting Mexico to Grow With NAFTA: The World Bank's Analysis. October 13, 2004

The euro area economy: an update Euro Challenge November 2016

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast December 2014

FISCAL POLICY* Chapt er. Key Concepts

International Monetary and Financial Committee

ECONOMIC RECOVERY AT CRUISE SPEED

Debt and Austerity in Europe: Who Will Pay for Growth?

cepr Briefing Paper Paying the Bills in Brazil: Does the IMF s Math Add Up? CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH By Mark Weisbrot and Dean Baker 1

Chapter 16: FISCAL POLICY

Economic Projections :2

Economic Activity, Prices, and Monetary Policy in Japan

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (October 2014)

Fund Management Diary

Summary and Economic Outlook

Separating European Austerity Fact from Fiction A Lesson for the U.S. on Why Budget Cutting Works

Research US The outlook for US government debt

GENERAL FUND REVENUE REPORT & ECONOMIC OUTLOOK. January 2010 Barry Boardman, Ph.D. Fiscal Research Division North Carolina General Assembly

Cutting debt and deficits

Part VIII: Short-Run Fluctuations and. 26. Short-Run Fluctuations 27. Countercyclical Macroeconomic Policy

WHY THE EUROPEAN COMMISSION IS WRONG: THE CASE OF SPAIN. By Vicente Navarro 19/08/2013. The Vice President of the European Commission, Olli Rehn, in

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Spring edition March 2012

Speaking Points for the Gaidar Forum Economic Perspective for Europe and Russia

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001

Report Documentation Page Form Approved OMB No Public reporting burden for the collection of information is estimated to average 1 hour per re

Macro Focus. From austerity to growth? 30 May Group Economics Macro Research

The sharp accumulation in government debt can t go on forever

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

Economic Activity, Prices, and Monetary Policy in Japan

Estimating a Fiscal Reaction Function for Greece

BALANCING THE FEDERAL BUDGET: ECONOMIC RATIONALE AND ISSUES

Euro area fundamentals #1 Potential growth important for bond yields

Reflections on Secular Stagnation. Dr. Lawrence H. Summers February 19, 2015

Global Macroeconomic Monthly Review

Analysis of Congressional Budget Office s August 2012 Updateof the Budget and Economic Outlook

RECENT ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTS IN SOUTH AFRICA

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast June 2014

JOBS, GROWTH, EQUALITY: (SURPRISE! THE IMF IS IN FAVOR OF ALL THREE)

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (April 2017) Summary

Project Link Meeting, New York

Data Brief. Dangerous Trends: The Growth of Debt in the U.S. Economy

FISCAL COUNCIL OPINION ON THE SUMMER FORECAST 2018 OF THE MINISTRY OF FINANCE

CBPP S UPDATED LONG-TERM FISCAL DEFICIT AND DEBT PROJECTIONS

The structural decline in the Eurozone s growth potential

Keeping you informed matters

OBSERVATION. TD Economics PERSISTENT FEDERAL DEFICITS ON THE HORIZON

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Spring edition March 2013

What Governance for the Eurozone? Paul De Grauwe London School of Economics

Past, Present and Future: The Macroeconomy and Federal Reserve Actions

Economic and Fiscal Assessment Update. Ottawa, Canada November 2,

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

BELARUSIAN MACROECONOMIC FORECAST No. 2(13), November 2016

QUARTERLY REPORT ON THE SPANISH ECONOMY OVERVIEW

Economic and financial outlook

Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy

Jobs Held by Former Welfare Recipients Hit Hard by Economic Downturn

Global Business Cycles

MCCI ECONOMIC OUTLOOK. Novembre 2017

Current Economic Conditions and Selected Forecasts

WHAT THE EURO CRISIS MEANS FOR TAXPAYERS AND THE U.S. ECONOMY, PART 1 DECEMBER 15, 2011

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on October 30 and 31, 2017

Briefing Note Budget 2009 Economic and Fiscal Outlook Key Issues

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

PIMCO Cyclical Outlook for Europe: Near-Term Recovery, Long-Term Risks

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on September 20 and 21, 2017

Financial Market Outlook: Stocks Rebounding from July Correction, Further Gains Likely. Bond Yields Range Bound

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast March 2015

Governor's Statement No. 33 October 10, Statement by the Hon. MAREK BELKA, Governor of the Bank for THE REPUBLIC OF POLAND

Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy

Outlook & Perspective

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (October 2017)

Productivity and Sustainable Consumption in OECD Countries:

The Federal Budget: Sources of the Movement from Surplus to Deficit

The Congressional Budget Office s 2012 Long-Term Budget Outlook: An Analysis

Transcription:

November 2013 Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain By David Rosnick and Mark Weisbrot * Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Ave. NW Suite 400 Washington, DC 20009 tel: 202-293-5380 fax: 202-588-1356 www.cepr.net David Rosnick is an Economist at the Center for Economic and Policy Research in Washington, DC. Mark Weisbrot is co-director of CEPR.

Contents Introduction... 1 Options for restoring full employment in Spain... 5 Conclusion... 8 References... 10 Acknowledgements The authors thank Dan Beeton and Eileen O Grady for editorial assistance.

Introduction With Spain s official unemployment rate at 26 percent, and the economy projected to contract by 1.3 percent this year, it is difficult to make the case for continued austerity that could push a barely growing economy back into recession. Yet the government is committed to further fiscal tightening, on the grounds that it has no choice. In defending the austerity last April, Prime Minister Mariano Rajoy said: These are tough budgets, painful. We are doing things that nobody likes. But this is what needs to be done to correct the mistakes and failures of the past. 1 And on numerous occasions he has added, There is no other alternative. 2 This paper will show that there are various feasible alternatives that can restore full employment to Spain by 2018, as well as other possibilities that could accomplish this goal even sooner. According to the International Monetary Fund (IMF), Spain s economy in 2014 will run 3.6 percent below its potential. This represents a loss of income of 1,700 ($2,300) per person in the labor force. However, this almost certainly understates the degree to which the Spanish economy is currently underperforming. In April 2011, the IMF estimated that Spain s potential output for 2014 was 1.13 trillion while today estimating Spain s actual output to be 1.03 trillion a shortfall of 8.6 percent. In other words, in the last two years, the IMF has erased more than half of Spain s underperformance by revising down potential output. This matters a great deal in guiding economic policy. If output is well below potential, this means that the economy is full of qualified workers left unemployed because business does not foresee sufficient sales to make the hiring of these workers profitable. Only increasing demand for goods and services will return the unemployed to work. Generally, this means that the government itself must step up by purchasing domestic goods and hiring the unemployed. Another source of demand is the foreign sector. Devaluing a country s currency relative to that of its trading partners makes domestic goods and services more desirable than foreign. In the case of Spain and other depressed European economies where much capital has left the country, the economy would also get a significant boost from capital inflows when a devaluation cheapens the foreign currency price of domestic assets. If, however, the country shares a common currency with its main trading partners as is the case with Spain then a nominal devaluation is not possible, making government spending even more important. 1 Carlos Cué and Francesco Manetto Rajoy defiende el ajuste como único antídoto contra la intervención. El País, April 2, 2012. 2 See e.g., http://www.europapress.es/nacional/noticia-rajoy-admite-hay-ajustes-no-le-gustan-no-hay-alternativa- 20120718095509.html ; and http://www.europapress.es/nacional/noticia-rajoy-admite-hay-ajustes-no-le-gustan-no-hay-alternativa- 20120718095509.html Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain 1

On the other hand if there is considerable unemployment while output is near potential, then unemployment is considered structural. In such a case, even if businesses have opportunity to expand profitably they fail to find qualified workers among the unemployed. The solution to structural unemployment, as opposed to demand-driven cyclical unemployment, generally involves weakening workers bargaining position to make production more profitable. If one kind of unemployment is wrongly identified as the other, the consequences can be disastrous. As an economy founders in a deep recession and operates below capacity, there is little incentive for businesses to expand capacity by investing. Thus, the potential of the economy to produce in the future is damaged. Likewise, the longer workers remain unemployed, the less likely they are to fulfill their own potential. In this way, untreated cyclical unemployment may turn into structural unemployment. At first glance, IMF data suggests that the transformation from cyclical to structural is well underway in Spain, as evidenced by the downward revisions to potential output. However, recent downward revisions to potential output presented seem especially large. In comparison to the IMF s estimate that Spain s economy is running 3.6 percent short of potential, the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) estimates the 2014 output gap to be -9.4 percent. 3 Furthermore, revenues naturally fall when an economy is depressed, so the fiscal stance of the government is adjusted to the business cycle. This means that if a fall in output is deemed structural rather than cyclical, the government will appear to be less austere than it would if the downturn were cyclical. Thus, it is no surprise that in the IMF s recent Article IV consultation, the focus was on structural issues and debt reduction rather than boosting demand since by the IMF s analysis, the economy is not so far from its potential. In this paper, we describe a simple economic model and based almost entirely on IMF data show how Spain s economy may be improved. With some modest assistance from the European Central Bank (ECB), Spain s debt levels may even be reduced relative to the size of the economy, even while pursuing a fiscal stimulus. Forecasts for Spain 2014-18 Figure 1 shows the historical and projected GDP for Spain, along with estimates for potential GDP. The right panel shows projections by the OECD, while the left panel shows those made by the IMF. 3 The output gap is defined as the percent of GDP above potential, so a negative output gap means that the economy is depressed. Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain 2

FIGURE 1 Real GDP and Potential Output (Billions of 2008 Euros) WEO OECD 1200 1200 1100 1100 1000 1000 900 900 800 2000 800 2000 Sources: IMF World Economic Outlook October 2013, OECD Economic Outlook 93, and authors calculations In both sets of projections, the economy is expected to recover over the next several years. The major difference between the two is that the IMF expects Spain s potential GDP to stagnate, while the OECD expects more rapid growth in potential GDP. 4 The IMF s pessimism is so extreme that even if Spain returns to full employment in 2018, they forecast an economy that will be less productive than it was back in 2007 a truly lost decade. If the Spanish economy does continue to stagnate, the IMF s assumptions for potential growth will become a self-fulfilling prophecy, due to low rates of investment and low participation in the labor force. Furthermore, it may be noted that the OECD also projects larger government deficits than does the IMF. In each year from 2013-18, every dollar of additional borrowing in the OECD forecast relative to the IMF forecast is associated with 1.5-2.9 dollars of additional GDP This suggests a relatively large effective fiscal multiplier. In this paper, we will use more conservative estimates. A recent paper summarizing more than 100 studies of fiscal multipliers suggests that tax and transfer multipliers are somewhat less than 1.0, with larger 4 It is inevitable that the IMF will show little growth in potential GDP as Spain s economy continues to stagnate, as its estimates are based on filtering actual GDP to remove cyclical effects. By contrast, the OECD projects capital stocks and effective labor to estimate potential output. For this reason, we will use OECD estimates for potential output rather than those produced by the IMF. Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain 3

multiplier effects for direct government spending on consumption and investment the latter about 1.0 percentage point greater than the tax multiplier. 5 The Model Suppose that every dollar of taxes reduces GDP by 50 cents. Suppose further that every dollar of primary (non-interest 6 ) transfers from the government to the public increases GDP by 50 cents, but every dollar of direct expenditures increases GDP by $1.50. Given baseline GDP (Y), an increase in direct expenditures (dg), primary transfers (dt) and revenues (dr), results in an alternative path for GDP (Y ) where Y = Y + (3dG + dt dr)/2. As the World Economic Outlook (WEO) does not distinguish between direct expenditures and transfers, we may distinguish an increase in direct spending from an increase in transfers by adjusting the multiplier accordingly. 7 Figure 2 shows the effect of raising direct expenditures by 1 percent of potential GDP, and alternatively, the effect of cutting taxes by 1 percentage point of GDP. 8 By construction, each alternative lowers the cyclically-adjusted primary budget balance 9 by 1 percent of potential GDP. As seen in Figure 2, the baseline cyclically-adjusted primary fiscal balance is expected to move into surplus this year. Officially, the IMF reports a structural fiscal deficit amounting to 4.9 percent of potential GDP, but this figure relies on their very low estimates of potential GDP. Regardless, an increase in government expenditures has a much larger effect on output than does a tax cut of (cyclically-adjusted) equivalent size. 10 5 Table 5, http://www.boeckler.de/pdf/p_imk_wp_117_2013 6 Interest payment recipients are assumed here to be all foreigners. Thus, any increase in interest payments has no effect on output. In practice, some interest payments are domestic, and therefore likely to be recycled in part into the economy. This assumption makes larger deficits appear less beneficial than would otherwise by the case. 7 That is, an increase in spending which consists entirely of transfers will have a multiplier of 0.5, while an increase in spending which consists entirely of direct expenditures will have a multiplier of 1.5. A 50-50 mix of transfers and direct expenditures will have a multiplier of 1.0. 8 Note that because the increase in spending (tax cut) raises GDP, the amount of the increase (tax cut) in euros is more than 1 percent of baseline GDP. If baseline revenues and spending are 40 percent of GDP, raising it to 41 percent would require an increase in government expenditures equal to about 2 percent of baseline GDP, thereby raising GDP by nearly 2.5 percent. 9 Here, we define the cyclically-adjusted primary balance as potential GDP times the revenue share of GDP, less primary expenditures, as described in http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/tnm/2009/tnm0905.pdf. The cyclically- adjusted primary balance as a share of potential GDP is therefore given by the revenue share of GDP, less the primary expenditure share of potential GDP. 10 Note that these results are built in to the model, and do not serve as independent evidence of large fiscal multipliers. Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain 4

Adjusted Balance (% of Potential GDP) Output Gap (% of Potential GDP) Revenues (% of GDP) Primary Expenditures (% of GDP) FIGURE 2 Effects of Alternative Types of Fiscal Stimulus 46 46 44 44 42 42 40 40 38 38 36 36 34 34 5 5 0 0-5 -5-10 -10-15 Sources: IMF World Economic Outlook October 2013, OECD Economic Outlook 93, and authors calculations Options for Restoring Full Employment in Spain Based on this model, we now investigate policies to help the Spanish economy return to its potential. These options fulfill the modest goal of narrowing the output gap to zero by 2018. There are innumerable paths by which this goal may be achieved, but here we consider two possibilities. The first path returns the cyclically-adjusted primary balance to a path that reaches -1 percent of potential GDP by 2018. The second path more slowly improves the output gap but more slowly increases the cyclically-adjusted primary deficit to -2 percent of potential GDP by 2018. These alternatives are illustrated in Figure 3. Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain 5

Adjusted Balance (% of Potential GDP) Output Gap (% of Potential GDP) Revenues (% of GDP) Primary Expenditures (% of GDP) FIGURE 3 Alternatives for Reaching Full Employment by 2018 46 46 44 44 42 42 40 40 38 38 36 36 34 34 2005 2010 2015 5 5 0 0-5 -5-10 -10-15 Sources: IMF World Economic Outlook October 2013, OECD Economic Outlook 93, and authors calculations As Figure 3 shows, both alternatives require higher revenues and expenditures than does the baseline scenario, and the first alternative employs generally higher revenues and expenditures than does the second. However, the first alternative results in higher GDP in the medium-run with generally less debt as a share of the economy than even the baseline, as seen in Figure 4. Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain 6

Net Lending (Billions of Euros) Net Debt (% of GDP) The second alternative path to full employment involves higher levels of debt both absolute and relative to the size of the economy. As we assumed this debt to be foreign, the interest payments represent a real cost to the domestic economy. In this model the cost is reflected in the need for higher revenues, which then slows growth. Spain, having a shared currency, has no ability to monetize its debt. Rather, the ECB holds that power. If the ECB bought significant amounts of debt with the intent of rebating (or forgoing) interest payments, this would in effect lower Spain s debt levels, which would then permit an increase in primary deficits. FIGURE 4 Deficits and Debt Under Alternative Policies 50 100 0 80-50 60-100 40-150 20 Sources: IMF World Economic Outlook October 2013, OECD Economic Outlook 93, and authors calculations Suppose that the ECB committed to financing half of any proposed stimulus that is, purchasing Spanish debt of value equivalent to 50 percent of primary net lending in excess of baseline. As a money-creating central bank, there is no true cost to the ECB to make this commitment. Nevertheless, the size of the commitment may be described by the cumulative interest payments that the ECB would forgo. In the first alternative path, the ECB would forgo about 1 billion euros per year less than 0.1 percent of Spain s GDP. Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain 7

Cumulative ECB Refunds (Billions of Euros) Net Debt (% of GDP) As seen in Figure 5, such a commitment by the ECB would leave Spain s net debt as a share of GDP below that of the baseline path. FIGURE 5 Debt Path net of ECB Purchases and Refunds 4 100 80 2 60 40 0 20 Sources: IMF World Economic Outlook October 2013, OECD Economic Outlook 93, and authors calculations To be sure, the model used in these forecasts is a simple one, and the timing of any stimulus is unlikely to be so immediate. However, these examples suggest that if the goal is economic recovery, then Spain s options are wider than generally recognized. This is true even while maintaining a preoccupation with debt levels, and particularly true if the ECB is willing to provide very modest assistance to the government. A goal of reaching full employment by 2018 appears to be in reach, even without the IMF s pessimistic forecast for potential output. Indeed, a much faster economic recovery than is currently forecast will be necessary to prevent a self-fulfilling prophecy of depressed capacity. Conclusion Contrary to the common assertions that Spain has no alternative to its current policies of austerity and prolonged high unemployment, this paper shows that full employment can be achieved by 2018 without accumulating an unsustainable debt burden. However, the Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain 8

scenarios illustrated here are modest proposals with either limited or no co-operation at all from the European Central Bank (ECB). In reality, Spain s economy is depressed, and there is no threat of excessive increases in inflation; it is currently running at negative 0.1 percent over the past year. In this situation, if Spain had its own its own currency and central bank, it could replace some or all of the tax increases with money borrowed from the central bank created through quantitative easing, as in the U.S. or Japan. Of course it cannot do this while it is part of the eurozone, but it is worth emphasizing that the ECB, if it wanted to play the role that the U.S. or Japanese central banks have done for their own economies, could make Spain s return to full employment vastly easier politically. It could also make the recovery much faster than the scenarios described in this paper, and lower the country s net debt burden. Nonetheless, these scenarios also illustrate that Spain has feasible options to return to full employment, even without co-operation from the ECB. Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain 9

References Cué, Carlos and Francesco Manetto. Rajoy defiende el ajuste como único antídoto contra la intervención. El País, April 2, 2012. http://politica.elpais.com/politica/2012/04/02/actualidad/1333353051_934446.htm l Fedelino, Annalisa, Mark Horton, and Anna Ivanova. Computing Cyclically Adjusted Balances and Automatic Stabilizers. International Monetary Fund. November 2009. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/tnm/2009/tnm0905.pdf International Monetary Fund. World Economic Outlook October 2013: Transitions and Tensions. Washington, D.C., 2013. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2013/02/ Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Economic Outlook No 93. June 2013. http://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?datasetcode=eo93_flashfile_eo93 Rajoy admite que hay ajustes que no le gustan pero no hay alternativa. Europa Press. July 18, 2013. http://www.europapress.es/nacional/noticia-rajoy-admite-hay-ajustes-nole-gustan-no-hay-alternativa-20120718095509.html Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain 10