Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Similar documents
M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

RENÉ CARMONA AND SERGEY NADTOCHIY BENDHEIM CENTER FOR FINANCE, ORFE PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRINCETON, NJ 08544

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

A Consistent Pricing Model for Index Options and Volatility Derivatives

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Regression estimation in continuous time with a view towards pricing Bermudan options

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Arbitrage-free market models for interest rate options and future options: the multi-strike case

Arbitrage-free market models for option prices: The multi-strike case

Polynomial processes in stochastic portofolio theory

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Weak Reflection Principle and Static Hedging of Barrier Options

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Option Pricing and Calibration with Time-changed Lévy processes

IMPA Commodities Course : Forward Price Models

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

D MATH Departement of Mathematics Finite dimensional realizations for the CNKK-volatility surface model

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

The stochastic calculus

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

On modelling of electricity spot price

DYNAMIC CDO TERM STRUCTURE MODELLING

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Implementing the HJM model by Monte Carlo Simulation

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

Analytical formulas for local volatility model with stochastic. Mohammed Miri

Large Deviations and Stochastic Volatility with Jumps: Asymptotic Implied Volatility for Affine Models

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Linear-Rational Term-Structure Models

Information, Interest Rates and Geometry

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Hedging of swaptions in a Lévy driven Heath-Jarrow-Morton framework

LOGNORMAL MIXTURE SMILE CONSISTENT OPTION PRICING

European call option with inflation-linked strike

Hedging under Arbitrage

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging

The Term Structure of Interest Rates under Regime Shifts and Jumps

Normal Inverse Gaussian (NIG) Process

Logarithmic derivatives of densities for jump processes

A Brief Introduction to Stochastic Volatility Modeling

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Generalized Affine Transform Formulae and Exact Simulation of the WMSV Model

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Hedging Basket Credit Derivatives with CDS

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

The British Russian Option

Managing the Newest Derivatives Risks

A Closed-form Solution for Outperfomance Options with Stochastic Correlation and Stochastic Volatility

Spot and forward dynamic utilities. and their associated pricing systems. Thaleia Zariphopoulou. UT, Austin

Valuing volatility and variance swaps for a non-gaussian Ornstein-Uhlenbeck stochastic volatility model

Path Dependent British Options

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Interest rate models in continuous time

Short-time asymptotics for ATM option prices under tempered stable processes

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Developments in Volatility Derivatives Pricing

Pricing Variance Swaps on Time-Changed Lévy Processes

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Stochastic volatility modeling in energy markets

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

Prospect Theory, Partial Liquidation and the Disposition Effect

MLEMVD: A R Package for Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Multivariate Diffusion Models

COMBINING FAIR PRICING AND CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS

From Implied to Spot Volatilities

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

Sato Processes in Finance

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Saddlepoint Approximation Methods for Pricing. Financial Options on Discrete Realized Variance

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Exact Sampling of Jump-Diffusion Processes

A Robust Option Pricing Problem

Arbitrageurs, bubbles and credit conditions

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Financial Engineering. Craig Pirrong Spring, 2006

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Unified Credit-Equity Modeling

"Pricing Exotic Options using Strong Convergence Properties

Transcription:

Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 1 / 22

Problem Formulation Introduction Problem Formulation Consider a liquid market consisting of an underlying price process (S t ) t 0 and prices of European Call options of all strikes K and maturities T : ({C t (T, K)} T,K>0 ) t 0 Want to describe a large class of market models: arbitrage-free stochastic models (say, given by SDE s) for time-evolution of the market, S and {C(T, K)} T,K>0, such that 1 one can start the model from almost any initial condition, which is the set of currently observed market prices; 2 one can prescribe almost any dynamics for the model provided it doesn t contradict the no-arbitrage property. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 2 / 22

Motivation Introduction Problem Formulation Many Call Options have become liquid need for financial models consistent with the observed option prices. Common stochastic volatility models (BS, Hull-White, Heston, etc.) are unable to reproduce the observed call prices of all strikes and maturities (fit the implied volatility surface). Local volatility models can fit option prices better. However, the above models have to be recalibrated to fit option prices at different times they cannot be used to describe time evolution of call price surface. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 3 / 22

Motivation Introduction Problem Formulation Many Call Options have become liquid need for financial models consistent with the observed option prices. Common stochastic volatility models (BS, Hull-White, Heston, etc.) are unable to reproduce the observed call prices of all strikes and maturities (fit the implied volatility surface). Local volatility models can fit option prices better. However, the above models have to be recalibrated to fit option prices at different times they cannot be used to describe time evolution of call price surface. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 3 / 22

Preceding Results Introduction Literature Review E. Derman, I. Kani (1997): idea of dynamic local volatility for continuum of options. P. Schönbucher, M. Schweizer, J. Wissel (1998-2008): consider fixed maturity and all strikes, fixed strike and all maturities, finitely many strikes and maturities (using mixture of Implied and Local Volatilities). J. Jacod, P. Protter, R. Cont, J. da Fonseca, V. Durrleman (2002-2009): study dynamics of Implied Volatility or option prices directly. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 4 / 22

General methodology Direct approach First, need a reasonable notion of price in the model: let s agree that pricing is linear, that is, prices of all contingent claims are given by discounted conditional expectations of their payoffs under some measure (assume discount rate is one). It seems natural to model observables directly under pricing measure: choose a driving Brownian motion B and a Poisson random measure N (which represent the background stochastic factors) and prescribe dynamics of (infinite-dimensional) process of option prices through its semimartingale characteristics dc t = α t dt + β t db t + γ t (x) [N(dx, dt) ν(dx, dt)] Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 5 / 22

General methodology Direct approach First, need a reasonable notion of price in the model: let s agree that pricing is linear, that is, prices of all contingent claims are given by discounted conditional expectations of their payoffs under some measure (assume discount rate is one). It seems natural to model observables directly under pricing measure: choose a driving Brownian motion B and a Poisson random measure N (which represent the background stochastic factors) and prescribe dynamics of (infinite-dimensional) process of option prices through its semimartingale characteristics dc t = α t dt + β t db t + γ t (x) [N(dx, dt) ν(dx, dt)] Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 5 / 22

General methodology Consistency conditions Need to make sure these dynamics, indeed, produce option prices: each resulting C t (T, K) should coincide with corresponding conditional expectation. Consistency conditions on {α, β, γ} These conditions should be explicit! A perfect example is F (α t, β t, γ t ) = 0, where F is known explicitly, and the above equation can be solved for some of the arguments. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 6 / 22

General methodology Consistency conditions Need to make sure these dynamics, indeed, produce option prices: each resulting C t (T, K) should coincide with corresponding conditional expectation. Consistency conditions on {α, β, γ} These conditions should be explicit! A perfect example is F (α t, β t, γ t ) = 0, where F is known explicitly, and the above equation can be solved for some of the arguments. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 6 / 22

General methodology Direct approach: difficulties Turns out, the above direct approach (prescribing dc t directly) results in way too complicated consistency conditions... Why does it happen? Recall that the definition of call prices as expectations implies certain static no-arbitrage properties : C t (T, K) has to be nonnegative, convex in K, converge to payoff, etc. These properties have to be preserved by the dynamics, which is reflected in the consistency conditions - hence the complexity. Static no-arbitrage conditions define a manifold in space of functions of two variables. Therefore, the consistent set of parameters can only be of the form α(c t, t, ω), β(c t, t, ω), γ(c t, t, ω) Need to analyze resulting SDE in an infinite-dimensional manifold... Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 7 / 22

General methodology Direct approach: difficulties Turns out, the above direct approach (prescribing dc t directly) results in way too complicated consistency conditions... Why does it happen? Recall that the definition of call prices as expectations implies certain static no-arbitrage properties : C t (T, K) has to be nonnegative, convex in K, converge to payoff, etc. These properties have to be preserved by the dynamics, which is reflected in the consistency conditions - hence the complexity. Static no-arbitrage conditions define a manifold in space of functions of two variables. Therefore, the consistent set of parameters can only be of the form α(c t, t, ω), β(c t, t, ω), γ(c t, t, ω) Need to analyze resulting SDE in an infinite-dimensional manifold... Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 7 / 22

General methodology Direct approach: difficulties Turns out, the above direct approach (prescribing dc t directly) results in way too complicated consistency conditions... Why does it happen? Recall that the definition of call prices as expectations implies certain static no-arbitrage properties : C t (T, K) has to be nonnegative, convex in K, converge to payoff, etc. These properties have to be preserved by the dynamics, which is reflected in the consistency conditions - hence the complexity. Static no-arbitrage conditions define a manifold in space of functions of two variables. Therefore, the consistent set of parameters can only be of the form α(c t, t, ω), β(c t, t, ω), γ(c t, t, ω) Need to analyze resulting SDE in an infinite-dimensional manifold... Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 7 / 22

Code-books General methodology Let s linearize this manifold: find a one-to-one mapping of the set of feasible Call price surfaces (or its large enough subset) into some open set in a linear space. And consider dynamics in this linear space instead. In general, code-book for a given set of derivatives is a one-to-one mapping defined on a family of their feasible price sets. Examples of code-books include: Yield curve for Treasury Bonds market. Implied correlation for CDO tranches. Implied volatility for Call options Recall that we require certain properties from the code-book. In particular, implied vol will not work. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 8 / 22

Code-books General methodology Let s linearize this manifold: find a one-to-one mapping of the set of feasible Call price surfaces (or its large enough subset) into some open set in a linear space. And consider dynamics in this linear space instead. In general, code-book for a given set of derivatives is a one-to-one mapping defined on a family of their feasible price sets. Examples of code-books include: Yield curve for Treasury Bonds market. Implied correlation for CDO tranches. Implied volatility for Call options Recall that we require certain properties from the code-book. In particular, implied vol will not work. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 8 / 22

Code-books General methodology Let s linearize this manifold: find a one-to-one mapping of the set of feasible Call price surfaces (or its large enough subset) into some open set in a linear space. And consider dynamics in this linear space instead. In general, code-book for a given set of derivatives is a one-to-one mapping defined on a family of their feasible price sets. Examples of code-books include: Yield curve for Treasury Bonds market. Implied correlation for CDO tranches. Implied volatility for Call options Recall that we require certain properties from the code-book. In particular, implied vol will not work. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 8 / 22

General methodology Local Volatility as a code-book B.Dupire (1994) deduced that, if d S T = S T a(t, S T )dw T, S0 = S t, (1) then a 2 (T, K) := 2 T C(T, K) K 2 2 C(T, K) K 2 (2) We can use (2) to recover Local Volatility a from market prices of Call options, and we can use (1) to generate a (feasible!) Call price surface from a given Local Vol (and current level of underlying S t ). Only some regularity and nonnegativity is required from surface a(.,.)! Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 9 / 22

General methodology Local Volatility as a code-book B.Dupire (1994) deduced that, if d S T = S T a(t, S T )dw T, S0 = S t, (1) then a 2 (T, K) := 2 T C(T, K) K 2 2 C(T, K) K 2 (2) We can use (2) to recover Local Volatility a from market prices of Call options, and we can use (1) to generate a (feasible!) Call price surface from a given Local Vol (and current level of underlying S t ). Only some regularity and nonnegativity is required from surface a(.,.)! Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 9 / 22

Other code-books Tangent models When can we use Local Vol as a (static) code-book for Call prices? I. Gyongy: it is possible if underlying follows regular enough Ito process. Can we develop a general approach to construction of code-books? Local Volatility code-book can be interpreted as follows: we choose a model from the class of diffusion models, such that it produces the correct (market-given) call prices, and the corresponding Local Vol gives the code-book value. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 10 / 22

Other code-books Tangent models When can we use Local Vol as a (static) code-book for Call prices? I. Gyongy: it is possible if underlying follows regular enough Ito process. Can we develop a general approach to construction of code-books? Local Volatility code-book can be interpreted as follows: we choose a model from the class of diffusion models, such that it produces the correct (market-given) call prices, and the corresponding Local Vol gives the code-book value. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 10 / 22

Other code-books Tangent models When can we use Local Vol as a (static) code-book for Call prices? I. Gyongy: it is possible if underlying follows regular enough Ito process. Can we develop a general approach to construction of code-books? Local Volatility code-book can be interpreted as follows: we choose a model from the class of diffusion models, such that it produces the correct (market-given) call prices, and the corresponding Local Vol gives the code-book value. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 10 / 22

Tangent models Constructing convenient code-books Consider a class of simple financial models for the underlying, parameterized by θ Θ M = {M(θ)} θ Θ For example, M can be a class of diffusion) models parameterized by Local Vol and initial value: θ = (a(.,.), S 0 Each model M(θ) produces Call prices C θ (T, K). If the mapping θ C θ is invertible, we obtain a code-book associated with M. Of course, Θ needs to be an open set in a linear space - but usually this can be achieved. We have rediscovered calibration, but with a proper meaning now! Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 11 / 22

Tangent models Tangent models Construct market model by prescribing time-evolution of θ t, and obtain C t as an inverse of the code-book transform. Recall that feasibility of call prices means there is a true (but unknown) martingale model for underlying process S in the background. If at time t there exists θ t Θ, such that C θt coincides with true Call price surface C t, we say that the true model admits a tangent model from class M at time t. In the above notation, process (θ t ) t 0 is consistent with a true model for S if M(θ t ) is tangent to this true model at any time t. Note the analogy with tangent vector field in differential geometry. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 12 / 22

Tangent models Tangent models Construct market model by prescribing time-evolution of θ t, and obtain C t as an inverse of the code-book transform. Recall that feasibility of call prices means there is a true (but unknown) martingale model for underlying process S in the background. If at time t there exists θ t Θ, such that C θt coincides with true Call price surface C t, we say that the true model admits a tangent model from class M at time t. In the above notation, process (θ t ) t 0 is consistent with a true model for S if M(θ t ) is tangent to this true model at any time t. Note the analogy with tangent vector field in differential geometry. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 12 / 22

Tangent models Tangent models Construct market model by prescribing time-evolution of θ t, and obtain C t as an inverse of the code-book transform. Recall that feasibility of call prices means there is a true (but unknown) martingale model for underlying process S in the background. If at time t there exists θ t Θ, such that C θt coincides with true Call price surface C t, we say that the true model admits a tangent model from class M at time t. In the above notation, process (θ t ) t 0 is consistent with a true model for S if M(θ t ) is tangent to this true model at any time t. Note the analogy with tangent vector field in differential geometry. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 12 / 22

Tangent Lévy Models Lévy-based code-book Consider a model M(κ, s), given by Exponential of a pure jump additive (time-inhomogeneous Lévy) process T S T = s + S u (e x 1) [N(dx, du) ν(dx, du)], t R where N(dx, du) is a Poisson random measure associated with jumps of log( S), given by its compensator ν(dx, du) = κ(u, x)dxdu equipped with its natural filtration. Thus, we obtain the set of simple models M = {M(κ, s)}, with κ changing in a space of (time-dependent) Lévy densities. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 13 / 22

Tangent Lévy Models Lévy density as a code-book Notice that C κ,s (T, e x ) satisfies a PIDE analogous to the Dupire s equation. Introduce κ,s (T, x) = x C κ,s (T, e x ), and deduce an initial-value problem for κ,s from the PIDE for call prices. Take Fourier transform in x to obtain ˆ κ,s (T, ξ). The initial-value problem in Fourier domain can be solved in closed form, which gives us an explicit expression for ˆ κ,s in terms of κ and s. This expression can be inverted to obtain κ from ˆ κ,s and s. Thus, given s (= S t ), we have a bijection: C κ,s κ,s ˆ κ,s κ. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 14 / 22

Tangent Lévy Models Tangent Lévy Models We say that (S t ) t [0, T ] and (κ t ) t [0, T ] form a tangent Lévy model if the following holds under the pricing measure: 1 C κt,st = C t at each t. 2 Process S is a martingale, and κ t 0. 3 S and κ evolve according to S t = S 0 + t 0 R S u (exp (γ(ω, u, x)) 1)(N(dx, du) ρ(x)dxdu), κ t = κ 0 + t 0 α udu + m t n=1 0 βn udbu n, where B = ( B 1,..., B m) is a m-dimensional Brownian motion, N is a Poisson random measure with compensator ρ(x)dxdu, γ(ω, t, x) is a predictable random function, processes α and {β n } m n=1 take values in a corresponding function space. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 15 / 22

Tangent Lévy Models Consistency conditions Given that 2 and 3 hold, 1 is equivalent to the following pair of conditions: 1 Drift restriction: α t (T, x) = Q(β t ; T, x) := m T e x y 2 ψ 2 βn t (u; y) du n=1 R ] (1 y x ) ψ βn t (T ; x) t [ ψ βn t (T ; x y) T ψ βn t (u; y) du ψ βn t (T ; x y) dy t 2 Compensator specification: κ t (t, x)dxdt = (ρ (x) dxdt) γ 1 (t,.) where ψ βn t (T, x) = e x sign(x) x βt n (T, y)dy Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 16 / 22

Existence of Tangent Lévy Models Specifications Choose ρ(x) := e λ x ( x 1 2δ 1 ), with some fixed λ > 1 and δ (0, 1). Consider κ of the form: κ(t, x) = ρ(x) κ(t, x), where κ is an element of the space of continuous functions, equipped with usual sup norm. Then α t = α t /ρ and β t = β t /ρ, and we have d κ t = α t dt + β t db t, { } stopped at τ 0 = inf t 0 : inf T [t, T ],x R κ t (T, x) 0. Then, κ t := ρ κ t τ0 is nonnegative and changes on an open set in a linear space! There exists a (tractable) specification γ(t, x) := Γ( κ t ; x) which fulfills the compensator specification automatically. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 17 / 22

Existence of Tangent Lévy Models Specifications Choose ρ(x) := e λ x ( x 1 2δ 1 ), with some fixed λ > 1 and δ (0, 1). Consider κ of the form: κ(t, x) = ρ(x) κ(t, x), where κ is an element of the space of continuous functions, equipped with usual sup norm. Then α t = α t /ρ and β t = β t /ρ, and we have d κ t = α t dt + β t db t, { } stopped at τ 0 = inf t 0 : inf T [t, T ],x R κ t (T, x) 0. Then, κ t := ρ κ t τ0 is nonnegative and changes on an open set in a linear space! There exists a (tractable) specification γ(t, x) := Γ( κ t ; x) which fulfills the compensator specification automatically. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 17 / 22

Existence of Tangent Lévy Models Specifications Choose ρ(x) := e λ x ( x 1 2δ 1 ), with some fixed λ > 1 and δ (0, 1). Consider κ of the form: κ(t, x) = ρ(x) κ(t, x), where κ is an element of the space of continuous functions, equipped with usual sup norm. Then α t = α t /ρ and β t = β t /ρ, and we have d κ t = α t dt + β t db t, { } stopped at τ 0 = inf t 0 : inf T [t, T ],x R κ t (T, x) 0. Then, κ t := ρ κ t τ0 is nonnegative and changes on an open set in a linear space! There exists a (tractable) specification γ(t, x) := Γ( κ t ; x) which fulfills the compensator specification automatically. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 17 / 22

Existence of Tangent Lévy Models Local existence S t = S 0 + t 0 R S u (exp (Γ( κ u ; x)) 1)(N(dx, du) ρ(x)dxdu) κ t = κ 0 + t τ 0 0 Q(ρ β u )du + m t τ0 n=1 0 β udb n u n (3) For any given Poisson random measure N, with compensator ρ(x)dxdt, any Brownian motion B = ( B 1,..., B m) independent of N, and any { } m progressively measurable square integrable stochastic processes β n (with values in corresponding function space) independent of N, there exists a unique pair (S t, κ t ) t [0, T ] of processes satisfying (3). The pair (S t, ρ κ t τ0 ) t [0, T ] forms a tangent Lévy model. n=1 Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 18 / 22

Existence of Tangent Lévy Models Example of a tangent Lévy model Choose m = 1, and β t (T, x) = ξ t C(x), where C(x) is some fixed function (satisfying some technical conditions), and ξ t = ξ( κ t ) = σ ( ) inf κ t (T, x) ɛ ɛ T [t, T ],x R Then drift restriction simplifies to T Q(ρ β t ; T, x) = e x y ψ ρ β t (u, y) du x ψ ρ β t (T, x y) ρ(x) R t T ψ ρ β t (u, y) du ψ ρ β t (T, x y) dy = ξ 2 ( κ t ) (T t T ) A(x) t and κ t (T, x) = κ 0 (T, x) + (T t T ) A(x) t 0 t ξ 2 ( κ u )du + C(x) ξ 2 ( κ u )db u 0 Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 19 / 22

Existence of Tangent Lévy Models Conclusions We have described a general approach to constructing market models for Call options: find the right code-book by choosing a space of tangent models, prescribe time-evolution of the code-book value via its semimartingale characteristics and analyze consistency of resulting dynamics. This approach was illustrated by Tangent Lévy Models - a large class of market models, explicitly constructed and parameterized by β! Proposed market models allow one to start with observed call price surface and model explicitly its future values under the risk-neutral measure. For example, they provide a flexible framework for simulating the (arbitrage-free) evolution of implied volatility surface. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 20 / 22

Existence of Tangent Lévy Models Further extensions One needs to consider β t = β( κ t ) and solve the resulting SDE for κ t, as shown in the example, in order to ensure that κ stays positive. There exists an extension of the Lévy-based code-book, the pair ( Lévy density, instantaneous volatility ), which allows the true underlying to have a non-trivial continuous martingale component. Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 21 / 22

Estimation of TL Model Estimated coefficients C 1 and C 2, as functions of x = log(k/s). Sergey Nadtochiy (University of Oxford) Tangent Lévy Models Bachelier Congress 22 / 22