Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Similar documents
RATING BASED LÉVY LIBOR MODEL

The Lévy Libor model with default risk

A new approach to LIBOR modeling

DYNAMIC CDO TERM STRUCTURE MODELLING

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Enlargement of filtration

No arbitrage conditions in HJM multiple curve term structure models

Lévy Processes. Antonis Papapantoleon. TU Berlin. Computational Methods in Finance MSc course, NTUA, Winter semester 2011/2012

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Hedging of swaptions in a Lévy driven Heath-Jarrow-Morton framework

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

Hedging under Arbitrage

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

1.1 Implied probability of default and credit yield curves

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Contagion models with interacting default intensity processes

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

DISCRETE TENOR MODELS FOR CREDIT RISKY PORTFOLIOS DRIVEN BY TIME-INHOMOGENEOUS LÉVY PROCESSES

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES

Hedging Basket Credit Derivatives with CDS

Efficient valuation of exotic derivatives in Lévy models

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

L 2 -theoretical study of the relation between the LIBOR market model and the HJM model Takashi Yasuoka

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

ABOUT THE PRICING EQUATION IN FINANCE

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Pricing and Hedging of Credit Derivatives via Nonlinear Filtering

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

Credit derivatives pricing using the Cox process with shot noise intensity. Jang, Jiwook

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

7 th General AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference 2015

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

Discrete time interest rate models

Interest rate models in continuous time

Valuing power options under a regime-switching model

Hedging under arbitrage

LOGNORMAL MIXTURE SMILE CONSISTENT OPTION PRICING

Risk Neutral Measures

Modeling Credit Risk with Partial Information

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

Lecture 5: Review of interest rate models

Analysis of Fourier Transform Valuation Formulas and Applications

Jump-type Lévy processes

On the pricing of emission allowances

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

Risk Neutral Valuation

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

The stochastic calculus

Optional semimartingale decomposition and no arbitrage condition in enlarged ltration

Modern Methods of Option Pricing

Unified Credit-Equity Modeling

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

Control Improvement for Jump-Diffusion Processes with Applications to Finance

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term.

SÉMINAIRE DE PROBABILITÉS (STRASBOURG)

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

arxiv: v13 [q-fin.gn] 29 Jan 2016

Option Pricing with Delayed Information

Numerical Solution of Stochastic Differential Equations with Jumps in Finance

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

Toward a coherent Monte Carlo simulation of CVA

Transcription:

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Zorana Grbac Department of Math. Stochastics, University of Freiburg Joint work with Ernst Eberlein Croatian Quants Day University of Zagreb, 9th April 2010 () 1 / 36

Libor market models introduction Discrete tenor structure: 0 = T 0 < T 1 <... < T n = T, with δ k = T k+1 T k T 0 T 1 T 2 T 3 T n 1 T n = T () 2 / 36

Libor market models introduction Discrete tenor structure: 0 = T 0 < T 1 <... < T n = T, with δ k = T k+1 T k T 0 T 1 T 2 T 3 T n 1 T n = T Default-free zero coupon bonds: B(, T 1),..., B(, T n) () 2 / 36

Libor market models introduction Discrete tenor structure: 0 = T 0 < T 1 <... < T n = T, with δ k = T k+1 T k T 0 T 1 T 2 T 3 T n 1 T n = T Default-free zero coupon bonds: B(, T 1),..., B(, T n) Forward Libor rate at time t T k for the accrual period [T k, T k+1 ] L(t, T k ) = 1 ( ) B(t, Tk ) δ k B(t, T k+1 ) 1 () 2 / 36

Libor market models introduction Discrete tenor structure: 0 = T 0 < T 1 <... < T n = T, with δ k = T k+1 T k T 0 T 1 T 2 t T 3 T k T k+1 T n 1 T n = T Default-free zero coupon bonds: B(, T 1),..., B(, T n) Forward Libor rate at time t T k for the accrual period [T k, T k+1 ] L(t, T k ) = 1 ( ) B(t, Tk ) δ k B(t, T k+1 ) 1 () 3 / 36

Libor market models introduction Discrete tenor structure: 0 = T 0 < T 1 <... < T n = T, with δ k = T k+1 T k T 0 T 1 T 2 t T 3 T k T k+1 T n 1 T n = T Defaultable zero coupon bonds with credit ratings: B C(, T 1),..., B C(, T n) Defaultable forward Libor rate at time t T k for the accrual period [T k, T k+1 ] L C(t, T k ) = 1 ( ) BC(t, T k ) δ k B C(t, T k+1 ) 1 () 4 / 36

Libor modeling modeling under forward martingale measures, i.e. risk-neutral measures that use zero-coupon bonds as numeraires on a given stochastic basis, construct a family of Libor rates L(, T k ) and a collection of mutually equivalent probability measures P Tk such that ( ) B(t, Tj) B(t, T k ) are P Tk -local martingales 0 t T k T j () 5 / 36

Libor modeling modeling under forward martingale measures, i.e. risk-neutral measures that use zero-coupon bonds as numeraires on a given stochastic basis, construct a family of Libor rates L(, T k ) and a collection of mutually equivalent probability measures P Tk such that ( ) B(t, Tj) B(t, T k ) are P Tk -local martingales 0 t T k T j model additionally defaultable Libor rates L C(, T k ) such that ( ) BC(t, T j) B(t, T k ) are P Tk -local martingales 0 t T k T j () 5 / 36

Credit risk with ratings Credit risk: risk associated to any kind of credit-linked events (default, changes in the credit quality etc.) Credit rating: measure of the credit quality (i.e. tendency to default) of a company () 6 / 36

Credit risk with ratings Credit risk: risk associated to any kind of credit-linked events (default, changes in the credit quality etc.) Credit rating: measure of the credit quality (i.e. tendency to default) of a company Credit ratings identified with elements of a finite set K = {1, 2,..., K}, where 1 is the best possible rating and K is the default event Credit migration is modeled by a conditional Markov chain C with state space K, where K is the absorbing state Default time τ: the first time when C reaches state K, i.e. τ = inf{t > 0 : C t = K} () 6 / 36

Defaultable bonds with ratings Consider defaultable bonds with credit migration process C and fractional recovery of Treasury value q = (q 1,..., q K 1) upon default Payoff of such a bond at maturity equals B C(T k, T k ) = 1 {τ>tk } + q Cτ 1 {τ Tk } K 1 = 1 {CTk =i} + q Cτ 1 {CTk =K}, i=1 where C τ denotes the pre-default rating. () 7 / 36

Defaultable bonds with ratings Consider defaultable bonds with credit migration process C and fractional recovery of Treasury value q = (q 1,..., q K 1) upon default Payoff of such a bond at maturity equals B C(T k, T k ) = 1 {τ>tk } + q Cτ 1 {τ Tk } K 1 = 1 {CTk =i} + q Cτ 1 {CTk =K}, i=1 where C τ denotes the pre-default rating. time-t price of such a defaultable bond can be expressed as K 1 B C(t, T k ) = B i(t, T k )1 {Ct=i} + q Cτ B(t, T k )1 {Ct=K}, i=1 where B i(t, T k ) represents the bond price at time t provided that the bond has rating i during the time interval [0, t]. We have B i(t k, T k ) = 1, for all i. () 7 / 36

Canonical construction of C Let (Ω, F T, F = (F t) 0 t T, P T ) be a given complete stochastic basis. Let Λ = (Λ t) 0 t T be a matrix-valued F-adapted stochastic process λ 11(t) λ 12(t)... λ 1K(t) λ 21(t) λ 22(t)... λ 2K(t) Λ(t) =........ 0 0... 0 which is the stochastic infinitesimal generator of C. () 8 / 36

Canonical construction of C Let (Ω, F T, F = (F t) 0 t T, P T ) be a given complete stochastic basis. Let Λ = (Λ t) 0 t T be a matrix-valued F-adapted stochastic process λ 11(t) λ 12(t)... λ 1K(t) λ 21(t) λ 22(t)... λ 2K(t) Λ(t) =........ 0 0... 0 which is the stochastic infinitesimal generator of C. Enlarge probability space (Ω, F T, P T ) ( Ω, G T, Q T ) and use canonical construction to construct C (Bielecki and Rutkowski, 2002) () 8 / 36

Canonical construction of C Let (Ω, F T, F = (F t) 0 t T, P T ) be a given complete stochastic basis. Let Λ = (Λ t) 0 t T be a matrix-valued F-adapted stochastic process λ 11(t) λ 12(t)... λ 1K(t) λ 21(t) λ 22(t)... λ 2K(t) Λ(t) =........ 0 0... 0 which is the stochastic infinitesimal generator of C. Enlarge probability space (Ω, F T, P T ) ( Ω, G T, Q T ) and use canonical construction to construct C (Bielecki and Rutkowski, 2002) The process C is a conditional Markov chain relative to F if for every 0 t s and any function h : K R E QT [h(c s) F t F C t ] = E QT [h(c s) F t σ(c t)], where F C = (F C t ) denotes the filtration generated by C. (skip details) () 8 / 36

Canonical construction - details Let Λ = (Λ t) 0 t T be a matrix-valued F-adapted stochastic process on (Ω, F T, P T ) λ 11(t) λ 12(t)... λ 1K(t) λ 21(t) λ 22(t)... λ 2K(t) Λ(t) =........ 0 0... 0 where λ ij are nonnegative processes, integrable on every [0, t] and λ ii(t) = j K\{i} λij(t). Let µ = (δ ij, j K) be a probability distribution on Ω = K. Define ( Ω, G T, Q T ) = (Ω Ω U Ω, F T F U 2 Ω, P T P U µ), On (Ω U, F U, P U ) a sequence (U i,j), i, j N, of mutually independent random variables, uniformly distributed on [0, 1]. () 9 / 36

The jump times τ k are constructed recursively as { ( ) } τk 1 +t τ k := τ k 1 + inf t 0 : exp λ Ck 1 C k 1 (u)du U 1,k, with τ 0 := 0. τ k 1 The new state at the jump time τ k is defined as C k := C(U 2,k, C k 1, τ k ), with C 0(ω, ω U, ω) = ω and where C : [0, 1] K R + Ω K is any mapping such that for any i, j K, i j, it holds if λ ii(t) < 0 and 0, if λ ii(t) = 0. Finally, for every t 0 Leb ({u [0, 1] : C(u, i, t) = j}) = λij(t) λ ii(t), C t := C k 1, for t [τ k 1, τ k ), k 1. () 10 / 36

Definition The process C is a conditional Markov chain relative to F, i.e. for every 0 t s and any function h : K R it holds E QT [h(c s) F t F C t ] = E QT [h(c s) F t σ(c t)], where F C = (F C t ) denotes the filtration generated by C. Proposition The conditional expectations with respect to enlarged σ-algebras can be expressed in terms of F t-conditional expectations. It holds E QT [Y F t σ(c t)] = K i=1 E QT [Y1 {Ct=i} F t] 1 {Ct=i} E QT [1, {Ct=i} F t] for any G-measurable random variable Y. () 11 / 36

Properties of C (a) for every t s u and any function h : K R a stronger version of conditional Markov property holds: E QT [h(c s) F u F C t ] = E QT [h(c s) F u σ(c t)] (b) for every t s and B F C t : E QT [1 B F s] = E QT [1 B F t] (c) F-conditional Chapman-Kolmogorov equation where P(t, s) = [p ij(t, s)] i,j K and p ij(t, s) := P(t, s) = P(t, u)p(u, s), QT (Cs = j, Ct = i Fs) Q T (C t = i F s) (d) F-conditional forward Kolmogorov equation dp(t, s) ds = P(t, s)λ(s) () 12 / 36

The progressive enlargement of filtration G = (G t) 0 t T, where satisfies the (H)-hypothesis: G t := F t F C t, (H) Every local F-martingale is a local G-martingale. () 13 / 36

The progressive enlargement of filtration G = (G t) 0 t T, where satisfies the (H)-hypothesis: G t := F t F C t, (H) Every local F-martingale is a local G-martingale. It is well-known that (H) is equivalent to (H1) E QT [Y F T ] = E QT [Y F t], for any bounded, F C t -measurable random variable Y. () 13 / 36

The progressive enlargement of filtration G = (G t) 0 t T, where satisfies the (H)-hypothesis: G t := F t F C t, (H) Every local F-martingale is a local G-martingale. It is well-known that (H) is equivalent to (H1) E QT [Y F T ] = E QT [Y F t], for any bounded, F C t -measurable random variable Y. But this follows easily from property E QT [1 B F s] = E QT [1 B F t], t s, B F C t, which is proved as a consequence of the canonical construction. () 13 / 36

Risk-free Lévy Libor model (Eberlein and Özkan, 2005) Let (Ω, F T, F = (F t) 0 t T, P T ) be a complete stochastic basis. as driving process take a time-inhomogeneous Lévy process X = (X 1,..., X d ) whose Lévy measure satisfies certain integrability conditions, i.e. () 14 / 36

Risk-free Lévy Libor model (Eberlein and Özkan, 2005) Let (Ω, F T, F = (F t) 0 t T, P T ) be a complete stochastic basis. as driving process take a time-inhomogeneous Lévy process X = (X 1,..., X d ) whose Lévy measure satisfies certain integrability conditions, i.e. an adapted, cádlág process with X 0 = 0 and such that (1) X has independent increments (2) the law of X t is given by its characteristic function ( t ) E[exp(i u, X t )] = exp θ s(iu)ds with θ s(iu) = i u, b s 1 2 u, csu + R d 0 ) (e i u,x 1 i u, x Fs T (dx). () 14 / 36

X is a special semimartingale with canonical decomposition t t t X t = b sds + csdws T + x(µ ν T )(ds, dx), 0 0 0 R d where W T denotes a P T -standard Brownian motion and µ is the random measure of jumps of X with P T -compensator ν T. We assume that b = 0. () 15 / 36

Construction of Libor rates Begin by specifying the dynamics of the most distant Libor rate under P T (regarded as the forward measure associated with date T ) ( t t L(t, T n 1) = L(0, T n 1) exp b L (s, T n 1)ds + σ(s, T n 1)dX s ), 0 where the drift is chosen in such a way that L(, T n 1) becomes a P T -martingale: b L (s, T n 1) = 1 σ(s, Tn 1), csσ(s, Tn 1) 2 ( ) e σ(s,tn 1),x 1 σ(s, T n 1), x F T (dx). R d 0 s () 16 / 36

Construction of Libor rates Begin by specifying the dynamics of the most distant Libor rate under P T (regarded as the forward measure associated with date T ) ( t t L(t, T n 1) = L(0, T n 1) exp b L (s, T n 1)ds + σ(s, T n 1)dX s ), 0 where the drift is chosen in such a way that L(, T n 1) becomes a P T -martingale: b L (s, T n 1) = 1 σ(s, Tn 1), csσ(s, Tn 1) 2 ( ) e σ(s,tn 1),x 1 σ(s, T n 1), x F T (dx). R d 0 s Next, define the forward measure P Tn 1 associated with date T n 1 via dp Tn 1 1 + δn 1L(t, Tn 1) = dp T 1 + δ n 1L(0, T n 1) Ft and proceed with modeling of L(, T n 2)... () 16 / 36

General step: for each T k (i) define the forward measure P Tk+1 via dp Tk+1 n 1 1 + δ l L(t, T l ) = dp T 1 + δ l L(0, T l ) = B(0, T ) B(t, T k+1 ) B(0, T k+1 ) B(t, T ). Ft l=k+1 (ii) the dynamics of the Libor rate L(, T k ) under this measure ( t t L(t, T k ) = L(0, T k ) exp b L (s, T k )ds + where X T k+1 t = t 0 0 csdw T k+1 s + t 0 0 σ(s, T k )dx T k+1 s R d x(µ ν T k+1 )(ds, dx) ), (1) () 17 / 36

General step: for each T k (i) define the forward measure P Tk+1 via dp Tk+1 n 1 1 + δ l L(t, T l ) = dp T 1 + δ l L(0, T l ) = B(0, T ) B(t, T k+1 ) B(0, T k+1 ) B(t, T ). Ft l=k+1 (ii) the dynamics of the Libor rate L(, T k ) under this measure ( t t L(t, T k ) = L(0, T k ) exp b L (s, T k )ds + where X T k+1 t = t 0 0 csdw T k+1 s + with P Tk+1 -Brownian motion W T k+1 and ν T k+1 (ds, dx) = n 1 l=k+1 t 0 0 σ(s, T k )dx T k+1 s R d x(µ ν T k+1 )(ds, dx) ), (1) ( ) δl L(s, T l ) 1 + δ l L(s, T l ) (e σ(s,t l),x 1) + 1 ν T (ds, dx). The drift term b L (s, T k ) is chosen such that L(, T k ) becomes a P Tk+1 -martingale. () 17 / 36

This construction guarantees that the forward bond price processes ( ) B(t, Tj) B(t, T k ) 0 t T j T k are martingales for all j = 1,..., n under the forward measure P Tk associated with the date T k (k = 1,..., n). The arbitrage-free price at time t of a contingent claim with payoff X at maturity T k is given by = B(t, T k )E PTk [X F t]. π X t () 18 / 36

How to include credit risk with ratings in the Lévy Libor model? () 19 / 36

How to include credit risk with ratings in the Lévy Libor model? (1) Use defaultable bonds with ratings to introduce a concept of defaultable Libor rates () 19 / 36

How to include credit risk with ratings in the Lévy Libor model? (1) Use defaultable bonds with ratings to introduce a concept of defaultable Libor rates (2) Adopt the backward construction of Eberlein and Özkan (2005) to model default-free Libor rates () 19 / 36

How to include credit risk with ratings in the Lévy Libor model? (1) Use defaultable bonds with ratings to introduce a concept of defaultable Libor rates (2) Adopt the backward construction of Eberlein and Özkan (2005) to model default-free Libor rates (3) Define and model the pre-default term structure of rating-dependent Libor rates () 19 / 36

How to include credit risk with ratings in the Lévy Libor model? (1) Use defaultable bonds with ratings to introduce a concept of defaultable Libor rates (2) Adopt the backward construction of Eberlein and Özkan (2005) to model default-free Libor rates (3) Define and model the pre-default term structure of rating-dependent Libor rates To include credit migration between different rating classes: () 19 / 36

How to include credit risk with ratings in the Lévy Libor model? (1) Use defaultable bonds with ratings to introduce a concept of defaultable Libor rates (2) Adopt the backward construction of Eberlein and Özkan (2005) to model default-free Libor rates (3) Define and model the pre-default term structure of rating-dependent Libor rates To include credit migration between different rating classes: (4) Enlarge probability space: (Ω, F, F, P T ) ( Ω, G, G, Q T ) and construct the migration process C () 19 / 36

How to include credit risk with ratings in the Lévy Libor model? (1) Use defaultable bonds with ratings to introduce a concept of defaultable Libor rates (2) Adopt the backward construction of Eberlein and Özkan (2005) to model default-free Libor rates (3) Define and model the pre-default term structure of rating-dependent Libor rates To include credit migration between different rating classes: (4) Enlarge probability space: (Ω, F, F, P T ) ( Ω, G, G, Q T ) and construct the migration process C (5) The (H)-hypothesis X remains a time-inhomogeneous Lévy process with respect to Q T and G with the same characteristics () 19 / 36

How to include credit risk with ratings in the Lévy Libor model? (1) Use defaultable bonds with ratings to introduce a concept of defaultable Libor rates (2) Adopt the backward construction of Eberlein and Özkan (2005) to model default-free Libor rates (3) Define and model the pre-default term structure of rating-dependent Libor rates To include credit migration between different rating classes: (4) Enlarge probability space: (Ω, F, F, P T ) ( Ω, G, G, Q T ) and construct the migration process C (5) The (H)-hypothesis X remains a time-inhomogeneous Lévy process with respect to Q T and G with the same characteristics (6) Define on this space the forward measures Q Tk by: for each tenor date T k Q Tk is obtained from Q T in the same way as P Tk from P T (k = 1,..., n 1) () 19 / 36

Conditional Markov chain C under forward measures Note that dq Tk dq T = ψ k, where ψ k is an F Tk -measurable random variable with expectation 1. () 20 / 36

Conditional Markov chain C under forward measures Note that dq Tk dq T = ψ k, where ψ k is an F Tk -measurable random variable with expectation 1. Theorem Let C be a canonically constructed conditional Markov chain with respect to Q T. Then C is a conditional Markov chain with respect to every forward measure Q Tk and p Q T k ij (t, s) = p Q T ij (t, s) i.e. the matrices of transition probabilities under Q T and Q Tk are the same. () 20 / 36

Conditional Markov chain C under forward measures Note that dq Tk dq T = ψ k, where ψ k is an F Tk -measurable random variable with expectation 1. Theorem Let C be a canonically constructed conditional Markov chain with respect to Q T. Then C is a conditional Markov chain with respect to every forward measure Q Tk and p Q T k ij (t, s) = p Q T ij (t, s) i.e. the matrices of transition probabilities under Q T and Q Tk are the same. Theorem The (H)-hypothesis holds under all Q Tk, i.e. every (F, Q Tk )-local martingale is a (G, Q Tk )-local martingale. () 20 / 36

Rating-dependent Libor rates The forward Libor rate for credit rating class i L i(t, T k ) := 1 ( ) Bi(t, T k ) δ k B i(t, T k+1 ) 1, i = 1, 2,..., K 1 We put L 0(t, T k ) := L(t, T k ) (default-free Libor rates). () 21 / 36

Rating-dependent Libor rates The forward Libor rate for credit rating class i L i(t, T k ) := 1 ( ) Bi(t, T k ) δ k B i(t, T k+1 ) 1, i = 1, 2,..., K 1 We put L 0(t, T k ) := L(t, T k ) (default-free Libor rates). The corresponding discrete-tenor forward inter-rating spreads H i(t, T k ) := Li(t, T k) L i 1(t, T k ) 1 + δ k L i 1(t, T k ) () 21 / 36

Observe that the Libor rate for the rating i can be expressed as 1 + δ k L i(t, T k ) = (1 + δ k L i 1(t, T k ))(1 + δ k H i(t, T k )) i = (1 + δ k L(t, T k )) (1 + δ k H j(t, T k )) }{{}}{{} j=1 default-free Libor spread j 1 j () 22 / 36

Observe that the Libor rate for the rating i can be expressed as 1 + δ k L i(t, T k ) = (1 + δ k L i 1(t, T k ))(1 + δ k H i(t, T k )) i = (1 + δ k L(t, T k )) (1 + δ k H j(t, T k )) }{{}}{{} j=1 default-free Libor spread j 1 j Idea: model H j(, T k ) as exponential semimartingales and thus ensure automatically the monotonicity of Libor rates w.r.t. the credit rating: L(t, T k ) L 1(t, T k ) L K 1(t, T k ) = worse credit rating, higher interest rate () 22 / 36

Pre-default term structure of rating-dependent Libor rates For each rating i and tenor date T k we model H i(, T k ) as ( t H i(t, T k ) = H i(0, T k ) exp b H i (s, T k )ds + with initial condition 0 t 0 γ i(s, T k )dx T k+1 s H i(0, T k ) = 1 ( ) Bi(0, T k )B i 1(0, T k+1 ) δ k B i 1(0, T k )B i(0, T k+1 ) 1. X T k+1 is defined as earlier and b H i (s, T k ) is the drift term (we assume b H i (s, T k ) = 0, for s > T k H i(t, T k ) = H i(t k, T k ), for t T k ). ) (2) () 23 / 36

Pre-default term structure of rating-dependent Libor rates For each rating i and tenor date T k we model H i(, T k ) as ( t H i(t, T k ) = H i(0, T k ) exp b H i (s, T k )ds + with initial condition 0 t 0 γ i(s, T k )dx T k+1 s H i(0, T k ) = 1 ( ) Bi(0, T k )B i 1(0, T k+1 ) δ k B i 1(0, T k )B i(0, T k+1 ) 1. X T k+1 is defined as earlier and b H i (s, T k ) is the drift term (we assume b H i (s, T k ) = 0, for s > T k H i(t, T k ) = H i(t k, T k ), for t T k ). the forward Libor rate L i(, T k ) is obtained from relation 1 + δ k L i(t, T k ) = (1 + δ k L(t, T k )) i (1 + δ k H j(t, T k )). j=1 ) (2) () 23 / 36

Theorem Assume that L(, T k ) and H i(, T k ) are given by (1) and (2). Then: (a) The rating-dependent forward Libor rates satisfy for every T k and t T k L(t, T k ) L 1(t, T k ) L K 1(t, T k ), i.e. Libor rates are monotone with respect to credit ratings. (b) The dynamics of the Libor rate L i(, T k ) under P Tk+1 is given by where ( t L i(t, T k ) = L i(0, T k ) exp b L i (s, T k )ds + + 0 t 0 t 0 csσ i(s, T k )dw T k+1 s ), R d S i(s, x, T k )(µ ν T k+1 )(ds, dx) () 24 / 36

σ i(s, T k ) := l i(s, T k ) 1( ) l i 1(s, T k )σ i 1(s, T k ) + h i(s, T k )γ i(s, T k ) = l i(s, T k ) 1[ l(s, T k )σ(s, T k ) + i j=1 ] h j(s, T k )γ j(s, T k ) represents the volatility of the Brownian part and ( ) S i(s, x, T k ) := ln 1 + l i(s, T k ) 1 (β i(s, x, T k ) 1) controls the jump size. Here we set and h i(s, T k ) := δ kh i(s, T k ) 1 + δ k H i(s, T k ), l i(s, T k ) := δ kl i(s, T k ) 1 + δ k L i(s, T k ), ( ) β i(s, x, T k ) := β i 1(s, x, T k ) 1 + h i(s, T k )(e γ i(s,t k ),x 1) ( ) = 1 + l(s, T k )(e σ(s,tk),x 1) i j=1 ( ) 1 + h j(s, T k )(e γ j(s,t k ),x 1). () 25 / 36

L(t, T n 1) L i 1(t, T n 1) H i (t,t n 1 ) L i(t, T n 1) L(t, T k ) L i 1(t, T k ) H i (t,t k ) L i(t, T k ) L(t, T k 1 ) L i 1(t, T k 1 ) H i (t,t k 1 ) L i(t, T k 1 ) L(t, T 1) L i 1(t, T 1) H i (t,t 1 ) L i(t, T 1) Default-free Rating i 1 Rating i Figure: Connection between subsequent Libor rates () 26 / 36

No-arbitrage condition for the rating based model Recall the defaultable bond price process with fractional recovery of Treasury value q K 1 B C(t, T k ) = B i(t, T k )1 {Ct=i} + q Cτ B(t, T k )1 {Ct=K}. i=1 () 27 / 36

No-arbitrage condition for the rating based model Recall the defaultable bond price process with fractional recovery of Treasury value q K 1 B C(t, T k ) = B i(t, T k )1 {Ct=i} + q Cτ B(t, T k )1 {Ct=K}. i=1 No-arbitrage: the forward bond price process B C(, T k ) B(, T j) must be a Q Tj -local martingale for every k, j = 1,..., n 1. () 27 / 36

No-arbitrage condition for the rating based model Recall the defaultable bond price process with fractional recovery of Treasury value q K 1 B C(t, T k ) = B i(t, T k )1 {Ct=i} + q Cτ B(t, T k )1 {Ct=K}. i=1 Or equivalently: the forward bond price process B C(, T k ) B(, T = BC(, T k) B(, T j) j) B(, T k ) B(, T k ) }{{} dq Tk dq Tj must be a Q Tk -local martingale for every k = 1,..., n 1. () 28 / 36

We postulate that the forward bond price process is given by B C(t, T k ) B(t, T k ) := = K 1 i k 1 i=1 j=1 l=0 i=1 1 1 + δ l H j(t, T l ) } {{ } :=H(t,T k,i) t e 0 λ i (s)ds 1 {Ct=i} + q Cτ 1 {Ct=K} K 1 t H(t, T k, i)e 0 λ i (s)ds 1 {Ct=i} + q Cτ 1 {Ct=K}, (3) where λ i is some F-adapted process that is integrable on [0, T ]. (go to DFM) () 29 / 36

We postulate that the forward bond price process is given by B C(t, T k ) B(t, T k ) := = K 1 i k 1 i=1 j=1 l=0 i=1 1 1 + δ l H j(t, T l ) } {{ } :=H(t,T k,i) t e 0 λ i (s)ds 1 {Ct=i} + q Cτ 1 {Ct=K} K 1 t H(t, T k, i)e 0 λ i (s)ds 1 {Ct=i} + q Cτ 1 {Ct=K}, (3) where λ i is some F-adapted process that is integrable on [0, T ]. (go to DFM) Note that this specification is consistent with the definition of H i which implies the following connection of bond prices and inter-rating spreads: B j(t, T k ) B j 1(t, T k ) = Bj(t, T k 1) 1 B j 1(t, T k 1 ) 1 + δ k 1 H j(t, T k 1 ) and relation B i(t, T k ) B(t, T k ) = B1(t, T k) B(t, T k ) i j=2 B j(t, T k ) B j 1(t, T k ). () 29 / 36

Lemma Let T k be a tenor date and assume that H j(, T k ) are given by (2). The process H(, T k, i) has the following dynamics under P Tk H(t, T k, i) = H(0, T k, i) ( E t b H (s, T k, i)ds 0 + 0 R d j=1 l=1 cs 0 i k 1 h j(s, T l )γ j(s, T l )dw T k s j=1 l=1 ( i ) k 1 ( ) 1 1 + h j(s, T l )(e γ j(s,t l ),x 1) 1 (µ ν T k )(ds, dx) ), where b H (s, T k, i) is the drift term. () 30 / 36

No-arbitrage condition Theorem Let T k be a tenor date. Assume that the processes H j(, T k ), j = 1,..., K 1, are given by (2). Then the process B C(,T k ) B(,T k defined in (3) is a local martingale with respect to the ) forward measure Q Tk and filtration G iff: for almost all t T k on the set {C t K} ( b H e t ) 0 λ C t (s)ds (t, T k, C t) + λ Ct (t) = 1 q Ct λ CtK(t) (4) H(t, T k, C t) K 1 (1 H(t, T k, j)e ) t 0 λ j (s)ds + j=1,j C t H(t, T k, C t)e t 0 λ C t (s)ds λ Ctj(t). () 31 / 36

No-arbitrage condition Theorem Let T k be a tenor date. Assume that the processes H j(, T k ), j = 1,..., K 1, are given by (2). Then the process B C(,T k ) B(,T k defined in (3) is a local martingale with respect to the ) forward measure Q Tk and filtration G iff: for almost all t T k on the set {C t K} ( b H e t ) 0 λ C t (s)ds (t, T k, C t) + λ Ct (t) = 1 q Ct λ CtK(t) (4) H(t, T k, C t) K 1 (1 H(t, T k, j)e ) t 0 λ j (s)ds + j=1,j C t H(t, T k, C t)e t 0 λ C t (s)ds λ Ctj(t). Sketch of the proof: Use the fact that the jump times of the conditional Markov chain C do not coincide with the jumps of any F-adapted semimartingale, use some martingales related to the indicator processes 1 {Ct=i}, i K, and stochastic calculus for semimartingales. () 31 / 36

Defaultable forward measures Assume that B C(,T k ) is a true martingale w.r.t. forward measure B(,T k ) QT k. (back to DFP) () 32 / 36

Defaultable forward measures Assume that B C(,T k ) is a true martingale w.r.t. forward measure B(,T k ) QT k. (back to DFP) The defaultable forward measure Q C,Tk for the date T k is defined on (Ω, G Tk ) by dq C,Tk := B(0, T k) B C(t, T k ) dq Tk B C(0, T k ) B(t, T k ). Gt This corresponds to the choice of B C(, T k ) as a numeraire. () 32 / 36

Defaultable forward measures Assume that B C(,T k ) is a true martingale w.r.t. forward measure B(,T k ) QT k. (back to DFP) The defaultable forward measure Q C,Tk for the date T k is defined on (Ω, G Tk ) by dq C,Tk := B(0, T k) B C(t, T k ) dq Tk B C(0, T k ) B(t, T k ). Gt This corresponds to the choice of B C(, T k ) as a numeraire. Proposition The defaultable Libor rate L C(, T k ) is a martingale with respect to Q C,Tk+1 and dq C,Tk = BC(0, T k+1) B C(0, T k ) (1 + δ kl C(t, T k )). Gt dq C,Tk+1 () 32 / 36

Pricing problems I: Defaultable bond Proposition The price of a defaultable bond with maturity T k and fractional recovery of Treasury value q at time t T k is given by [ K 1 B C(t, T k )1 {Ct K} = B(t, T k ) E QTk [1 p ik(t, T k ) F t] i=1 1 {Ct=i} K 1 + j=1 ] E QTk [1 {t<τ Tk }1 {Ct=i}1 {Cτ =j}q j F t]. E QTk [1 {Ct=i} F t] () 33 / 36

Pricing problems II: Credit default swap consider a maturity date T m and a defaultable bond with fractional recovery of Treasury value q as the underlying asset protection buyer pays a fixed amount S periodically at tenor dates T 1,..., T m 1 until default protection seller promises to make a payment that covers the loss if default happens: 1 q Cτ has to paid at T k+1 if default occurs in (T k, T k+1 ] () 34 / 36

Pricing problems II: Credit default swap consider a maturity date T m and a defaultable bond with fractional recovery of Treasury value q as the underlying asset protection buyer pays a fixed amount S periodically at tenor dates T 1,..., T m 1 until default protection seller promises to make a payment that covers the loss if default happens: 1 q Cτ has to paid at T k+1 if default occurs in (T k, T k+1 ] Proposition The swap rate S at time 0 is equal to m k=2 B(0, T k) K 1 j=1 E Q Tk [(1 q j)1 {Tk 1 <τ T k,c τ =j} ] S = m 1 k=1 B(0, T, k)e QTk [1 p ik(0, T k )] if the observed class at time zero is i. () 34 / 36

Pricing problems III: use of defaultable measures Proposition Let Y be a promised G Tk -measurable payoff at maturity T k of a defaultable contingent claim with fractional recovery q upon default and assume that Y is integrable with respect to Q Tk. The time-t value of such a claim is given by π t (Y) = B C(t, T k )E QC,Tk [Y G t]. () 35 / 36

Pricing problems III: use of defaultable measures Proposition Let Y be a promised G Tk -measurable payoff at maturity T k of a defaultable contingent claim with fractional recovery q upon default and assume that Y is integrable with respect to Q Tk. The time-t value of such a claim is given by π t (Y) = B C(t, T k )E QC,Tk [Y G t]. Example: a cap on the defaultable forward Libor rate () 35 / 36

Pricing problems III: use of defaultable measures Proposition Let Y be a promised G Tk -measurable payoff at maturity T k of a defaultable contingent claim with fractional recovery q upon default and assume that Y is integrable with respect to Q Tk. The time-t value of such a claim is given by π t (Y) = B C(t, T k )E QC,Tk [Y G t]. Example: a cap on the defaultable forward Libor rate The time-t price of a caplet with strike K and maturity T k on the defaultable Libor rate is given by C t(t k, K) = δ k B C(t, T k+1 )E QC,Tk+1 [(L C(T k, T k ) K) + G t] and the price of the defaultable forward Libor rate cap at time t T 1 is given as a sum C t(k) = n δ k 1 B C(t, T k )E QC,Tk [(L C(T k 1, T k 1 ) K) + G t]. k=1 () 35 / 36

T. Bielecki and M. Rutkowski, Credit Risk: Modeling, Valuation and Hedging, Springer, 2002. E. Eberlein, W. Kluge, and P. J. Schönbucher, The Lévy Libor model with default risk, Journal of Credit Risk 2, 3-42, 2006. E. Eberlein and F. Özkan, The Lévy LIBOR model. Finance and Stochastics 9, 327-348, 2005. R. Elliott, M. Jeanblanc, and M. Yor, On models of default risk, Mathematical Finance 10, 179-195, 2000. Z. Grbac, Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach, Ph.D. Thesis, University of Freiburg, 2009 J. Jacod and A.N. Shiryaev, Limit theorems for stochastic processes, Springer, 2003. P. Protter, Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations, Springer, 2005. K.-I. Sato, Lévy Processes and Infinitely Divisible Distributions, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1999. () 36 / 36