A1: American Options in the Binomial Model

Similar documents
On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

European Contingent Claims

Optimal Stopping. Nick Hay (presentation follows Thomas Ferguson s Optimal Stopping and Applications) November 6, 2008

δ j 1 (S j S j 1 ) (2.3) j=1

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

MORE REALISTIC FOR STOCKS, FOR EXAMPLE

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Lecture l(x) 1. (1) x X

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

Option Pricing Models for European Options

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

X i = 124 MARTINGALES

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 11 10/9/2013. Martingales and stopping times II

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

Hedging under Arbitrage

Option Pricing Models. c 2013 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 205

2 The binomial pricing model

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

Arbitrage-Free Pricing of XVA for Options in Discrete Time

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Non-semimartingales in finance

Risk Neutral Measures

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 9

Game Theory: Normal Form Games

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

CHAPTER 14: REPEATED PRISONER S DILEMMA

Lecture 16: Delta Hedging

Lecture 16. Options and option pricing. Lecture 16 1 / 22

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

Term Structure Lattice Models

Lecture 14: Examples of Martingales and Azuma s Inequality. Concentration

6.896 Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory February 10, Lecture 3

10.1 Elimination of strictly dominated strategies

Optimal Stopping Rules of Discrete-Time Callable Financial Commodities with Two Stopping Boundaries

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

ECON 815. Uncertainty and Asset Prices

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Homework Assignments

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Competitive Market Model

Online Supplement: Price Commitments with Strategic Consumers: Why it can be Optimal to Discount More Frequently...Than Optimal

B. Online Appendix. where ɛ may be arbitrarily chosen to satisfy 0 < ɛ < s 1 and s 1 is defined in (B1). This can be rewritten as

Modern Methods of Option Pricing

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

In chapter 5, we approximated the Black-Scholes model

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Class Notes on Financial Mathematics. No-Arbitrage Pricing Model

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

sample-bookchapter 2015/7/7 9:44 page 1 #1 THE BINOMIAL MODEL

King s College London

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

Lecture 6. 1 Polynomial-time algorithms for the global min-cut problem

American options and early exercise

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin , CHINA

Some Computational Aspects of Martingale Processes in ruling the Arbitrage from Binomial asset Pricing Model

Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model

Put-Call Parity. Put-Call Parity. P = S + V p V c. P = S + max{e S, 0} max{s E, 0} P = S + E S = E P = S S + E = E P = E. S + V p V c = (1/(1+r) t )E

Chapter 6: Risky Securities and Utility Theory

Review of Derivatives I. Matti Suominen, Aalto

Financial Mathematics. Christel Geiss Department of Mathematics University of Innsbruck

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

MARTINGALES AND LOCAL MARTINGALES

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

CS364A: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture #14: Robust Price-of-Anarchy Bounds in Smooth Games

Pricing and hedging in the presence of extraneous risks

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

Properties of American option prices

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 10: Options pricing in binomial lattices

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

Homework 2: Dynamic Moral Hazard

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Help Session 4. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

The Probabilistic Method - Probabilistic Techniques. Lecture 7: Martingales

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure

MATH 425: BINOMIAL TREES

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

The Real Numbers. Here we show one way to explicitly construct the real numbers R. First we need a definition.

Online Appendix for Debt Contracts with Partial Commitment by Natalia Kovrijnykh

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Stochastic Finance - A Numeraire Approach

MATH 121 GAME THEORY REVIEW

Risk Neutral Valuation, the Black-

Transcription:

Appendix 1 A1: American Options in the Binomial Model So far we were dealing with options which can be excercised only at a fixed time, at their maturity date T. These are european options. In a complete model, lie the Binomial or the Blac-Scholes model, these options can be replicated exactly. Now we are considering options which can be excercised at an arbitrary time t [0, T. These are called american options. Thus, if a ban is selling an american option, it has to be prepared to pay the payoff to the customer not only at t = T, but at an arbitrary t [0, T. Therefore it would be desirable to replicate the option for all t [0, T, not only at t = T. However, this is not possible. But it is possible to set up a selffinancing strategy whose portfolio value is always greater or equal to the option s payoff and this leads to an arbitrage free fair price for the american option contract. We first consider the situation in discrete time, in the Binomial model. Let Π S = S 0 X j (1.1 be the price process for the Binomial model. That is, the X j are identically independently distributed with { U = 1 + u with probability p X j = (1.2 D = 1 + d with probability q = 1 p The discounted price process s = R S, R = 1 + r, is given by where the x j = X j /R have the distribution Π s = s 0 x j (1.3 db({x j } = N Π db(x j (1.4 db(x = { p δ(x U/R + (1 p δ(x D/R } dx (1.5 191

192 A1 Let C be the payoff of some (exotic or not american option. That is, excercising the option at time {1, 2,..., N} gives a payment of C = C ( S 0,..., S (1.6 For a simple call or put (1.6 reduces to C = C(S. Let c = R C(S 0,..., S (1.7 be the discounted payoff at time. We are looing for some selffinancing strategy (δ whose discounted portfolio value v = R V at time is always bigger than c, v = v 0 + δ j 1 (s j s j 1! c (1.8 At time = N, we should have v N = c N. At time = N 1, v N 1 should be such that we can guarantie v N = c N at = N and it must be at least c N 1. In the first lecture on the Binomial model and in lecture 5 we saw that we can guarantie v N = c N at = N if we define v N 1 = p v N (s 0,..., s N 1, s N 1 U/R + (1 p v N (s 0,..., s N 1, s N 1 D/R = E B[v N s N 1 (1.9 where p = R D U D is the probability of the equivalent martingale measure d B. That is, if we define a sequence of discounted portfolio values (u 0 N inductively by then we must have u N = c N (1.10 u 1 = max { c 1, E B[u s 1 }, = N, N 1,..., 1 (1.11 v u = 0,..., N (1.12 Observe that we cannot write equal in (1.12 since it is not clear that the portfolio values u defined in (1.10,1.11 can be generated by some selffinancing strategy. In fact, in general they cannot. Thus we have to find the smallest selffinancing strategy, which has the lowest price v 0 and satisfies (1.12. It is obtained as follows. Theorem 8.1: Let (u 0 N be the Snell envelope of the discounted american claim (c 0 N defined by (1.10,1.11. For = 1,..., N, let δ 1 (s 0,..., s 1 = u (s 0,..., s 1, s 1 U/R u (s 0,..., s 1, s 1 D/R s 1 U/R s 1 D/R (1.13

A1 193 and let v = u 0 + δ j 1 (s j s j 1 (1.14 be the discounted portfolio value of the selffinancing strategy defined by (1.13 with initial price u 0. Then any selffinancing strategy ṽ = ṽ 0 + δ j 1 (s j s j 1 with ṽ c for all satisfies ṽ u for all. In particular, each such strategy has a larger price than (1.14, ṽ 0 u 0. The relation between (u and (v is given by v = u + (max { } u (1.15 where ũ 1 := E B[u s 1. Proof: We first show (1.15. Recall from Theorem 1.1 that if δ 1 is given by (1.13 and if ũ 1 is given by ũ 1 = p u (s 0,..., s 1, s 1 U/R + (1 p u (s 0,..., s 1, s 1 D/R then there is the relation Hence, = E B[u s 1 (1.16 ũ 1 + δ 1 (s s 1 = u (1.17 v = u 0 + (1.17 = u 0 + = u + (1.11 = u + δ j 1 (s j s j 1 ( uj ũ j 1 ( uj 1 ũ j 1 (max { } c j 1, ũ 1 ũ 1 (1.18 which proves (1.15. The inequalities ṽ u for all can be obtained by induction. For = N, ṽ N c N = u N. Suppose ṽ u holds for. Then ṽ 1 = E B[ṽ s 1 E B[u s 1 = ũ 1 (1.19

194 A1 Since also by assumption ṽ 1 c 1 we have ṽ 1 max { } c 1, ũ 1 = u 1 which completes the induction. Theorem 8.1 solves the hedging problem for american options in the Binomial model and, by approximation with small t, also for the Blac-Scholes model. One has to compute the Snell envelope (u which can be easily done on an excel-sheet using the definition (1.10,1.11 and then the delta s for a selffinancing strategy are given by (1.13. Another characterization of the sequence (u, which is probably of more theoretical interest, can be given in terms of stopping times. It reads as follows. Theorem 8.2: Let T = { τ : {s j } 0 j N τ({s j } {, + 1,..., N}, τ stopping time } be the set of all stopping times bigger or equal than. Let c = R C(S 0,..., S be the discounted payoff of some american option and let (u be the Snell envelope defined by (1.10,1.11. Then where τ u=c is the stopping time defined by u = sup E B[ c τ s (1.20 τ T = E B[ cτ s u=c (1.21 τ u=c = min{j u j = c j } (1.22 Proof: From (1.15 we have and for m u = v (max { } (1.23 In particular, u m = u + (u m u = u + v m v u τ u=c = u + v τ u=c v = u + v τ u=c v m (max { } τ u=c τ u=c (max { c j 1, ũ j 1 } ũj 1 (ũ j 1 ũ j 1 (1.24 = u + v τ u=c v (1.25

A1 195 Thus, E B[ cτ s u=c = E B[ uτ s u=c = u + E B[ vτ s u=c v Lemma 8.3 = u (1.26 which proves (1.21. Furthermore, for every stopping time τ T, c τ u τ τ = u + v τ v (max { } (1.27 and therefore, using Lemma 8.3 below again, E B[ c τ s u + E B[ v τ v s }{{} =0 u E B [ (max { cj 1, ũ j 1 } ũj 1 χ(j τ s } {{ } 0 (1.28 This implies also sup τ T E B[ c τ s u and, because of (1.26, the equal sign follows. Lemma 8.3 (Stopping Theorem: Let v = v 0 + δ j 1(s j s j 1 be a selffinancing strategy and let τ be a stopping time. Let Ẽ denote the expectation with respect to the martingale measure. Then Ẽ[v τ = v 0, and, for τ, Ẽ[v τ s = v (1.29 Proof: For τ we have Ẽ[v τ s = v + = v + = v Ẽ [ δ j 1 (s j s j 1 χ(j τ s Ẽ [ δ j 1 (s j s j 1 s N Ẽ [ δ j 1 (s j s j 1 χ(j > τ s Ẽ [ δ j 1 (s j s j 1 χ(j > τ s (1.30 Since τ is a stopping time, we have τ = τ({s m } 0 m τ. Thus, for τ < j, τ is a function of at most s 0, s 1,..., s j 1. But then we can move the integrals over s n,..., s j directly to the

196 A1 s j in the last line of (1.30 to obtain Ẽ[v τ s = v Ẽ [ (Ẽ[sj δ j 1 s j 1 s j 1 χ(j > τ s }{{} =0 = v (1.31 since (s j is a martingale with respect to Ẽ. The next lemma states that if the option value of some european option is always bigger than the option s payoff, V (S C(S, then the Snell envelope coincides with the discounted V. Lemma 8.4: Let V be the portfolio value of a replicating strategy for some european option with payoff C(S 0,..., S N, that is, V is the option value at time. Then, if V (S 0,..., S C(S 0,..., S = N, N 1,..., m (1.32 the undiscounted Snell envelope U = R u satisfies In particular, if for c = R C(S then v c and u = v for all. U = V = N, N 1,..., m. (1.33 E B[c s 1 c 1 (1.34 Proof: We prove (1.33 by induction on. For = N, u N = c N = v N. Suppose (1.33 holds for. Observe that since v = v 1 + δ 1 (s s 1 we have v 1 = E B[v s 1. Then u 1 = max { c 1, E B[u s 1 } = max { c 1, E B[v s 1 } = max { c 1, v 1 } = v 1 (1.35 if v 1 c 1. This proves (1.33. (1.34 follows similar. By induction, starting at = N with v N = c N, v 1 = E B[v s 1 E B[c s 1 c 1 (1.36

A1 197 and the lemma is proven Condition (1.34 holds for a call option, but not for a put. Namely, for a call c = R (S K + = (s K/R + = (s 1 x K/R + (1.37 Since f(x = (s 1 x K/R + is a convex function, we can apply Jensen s inequality, f(x dp (x f ( x dp (x for any probability measure dp and convex function f, to obtain E B[c s 1 = (s 1x K/R d b(x + ( s 1 x d b(x K/R + = (s 1 K/R + R 1 (s 1 K/R 1 + = c 1 (1.38 If one tries the same computation for a put, one ends up with (K/R E B[c s 1 = s 1x d b(x + ( K/R s 1 x d b(x + = (K/R s 1 + (1.39 but this cannot be estimated against (K/R 1 s 1 + for R 1. Thus we can summarize Corollary 8.5: Let the discounting factor R 1. Then the values of american and european calls coincide but the values of american and european puts differ. The value of an american put at time is given by the undiscounted Snell envelope U = R u defined by (1.10,1.11.