CHARACTERIZATION OF CLOSED CONVEX SUBSETS OF R n

Similar documents
MAT25 LECTURE 10 NOTES. = a b. > 0, there exists N N such that if n N, then a n a < ɛ

The Real Numbers. Here we show one way to explicitly construct the real numbers R. First we need a definition.

Game Theory: Normal Form Games

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Laurence Boxer and Ismet KARACA

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Laurence Boxer and Ismet KARACA

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

Outline of Lecture 1. Martin-Löf tests and martingales

( ) = R + ª. Similarly, for any set endowed with a preference relation º, we can think of the upper contour set as a correspondance  : defined as

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

Lecture l(x) 1. (1) x X

25 Increasing and Decreasing Functions

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015

Lecture Notes 1

Lecture 14: Basic Fixpoint Theorems (cont.)

A Property Equivalent to n-permutability for Infinite Groups

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

CATEGORICAL SKEW LATTICES

Equivalence Nucleolus for Partition Function Games

Chair of Communications Theory, Prof. Dr.-Ing. E. Jorswieck. Übung 5: Supermodular Games

Strategies and Nash Equilibrium. A Whirlwind Tour of Game Theory

ECE 586GT: Problem Set 1: Problems and Solutions Analysis of static games

Sy D. Friedman. August 28, 2001

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Online Shopping Intermediaries: The Strategic Design of Search Environments

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Finite Additivity in Dubins-Savage Gambling and Stochastic Games. Bill Sudderth University of Minnesota

Applied Mathematics Letters

An Optimal Odd Unimodular Lattice in Dimension 72

TEST 1 SOLUTIONS MATH 1002

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

A Core Concept for Partition Function Games *

Chapter 1 Additional Questions

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

THE NUMBER OF UNARY CLONES CONTAINING THE PERMUTATIONS ON AN INFINITE SET

CONGRUENCES AND IDEALS IN A DISTRIBUTIVE LATTICE WITH RESPECT TO A DERIVATION

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

The Minimal Dominant Set is a Non-Empty Core-Extension

2 Deduction in Sentential Logic

Equilibrium selection and consistency Norde, Henk; Potters, J.A.M.; Reijnierse, Hans; Vermeulen, D.

INTERIM CORRELATED RATIONALIZABILITY IN INFINITE GAMES

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

Term Structure of Interest Rates

7. Infinite Games. II 1

1. Introduction. As part of his study of functions defined on product spaces, M. Hušek introduced a family of diagonal conditions in a topological

Non replication of options

Permutation Factorizations and Prime Parking Functions

SF2972 GAME THEORY Infinite games

Lindner, Szimayer: A Limit Theorem for Copulas

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

Building Infinite Processes from Regular Conditional Probability Distributions

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

ECON Micro Foundations

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

PURITY IN IDEAL LATTICES. Abstract.

Sublinear Time Algorithms Oct 19, Lecture 1

Yao s Minimax Principle

Optimal Auctions with Ambiguity

A1: American Options in the Binomial Model

EconS Micro Theory I Recitation #8b - Uncertainty II

Tug of War Game. William Gasarch and Nick Sovich and Paul Zimand. October 6, Abstract

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

LARGE CARDINALS AND L-LIKE UNIVERSES

PARTITIONS OF 2 ω AND COMPLETELY ULTRAMETRIZABLE SPACES

THE TRAVELING SALESMAN PROBLEM FOR MOVING POINTS ON A LINE

Separation axioms on enlargements of generalized topologies

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion

ELEMENTS OF MONTE CARLO SIMULATION

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Outline. 1 Introduction. 2 Algorithms. 3 Examples. Algorithm 1 General coordinate minimization framework. 1: Choose x 0 R n and set k 0.

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

GUESSING MODELS IMPLY THE SINGULAR CARDINAL HYPOTHESIS arxiv: v1 [math.lo] 25 Mar 2019

On Toponogov s Theorem

Epimorphisms and Ideals of Distributive Nearlattices

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

Part 3: Trust-region methods for unconstrained optimization. Nick Gould (RAL)

Approximating the Transitive Closure of a Boolean Affine Relation

Portfolio Choice. := δi j, the basis is orthonormal. Expressed in terms of the natural basis, x = j. x j x j,

The Binomial Theorem and Consequences

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Hints on Some of the Exercises

A Combinatorial Proof for the Circular Chromatic Number of Kneser Graphs

Stability in geometric & functional inequalities

INTERVAL DISMANTLABLE LATTICES

ON A PROBLEM BY SCHWEIZER AND SKLAR

1 Overview. 2 The Gradient Descent Algorithm. AM 221: Advanced Optimization Spring 2016

Interpolation. 1 What is interpolation? 2 Why are we interested in this?

Essays on Some Combinatorial Optimization Problems with Interval Data

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS

3 The Model Existence Theorem

Collinear Triple Hypergraphs and the Finite Plane Kakeya Problem

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

ON THE QUOTIENT SHAPES OF VECTORIAL SPACES. Nikica Uglešić

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Transcription:

CHARACTERIZATION OF CLOSED CONVEX SUBSETS OF R n Chebyshev Sets A subset S of a metric space X is said to be a Chebyshev set if, for every x 2 X; there is a unique point in S that is closest to x: Put di erently, S is Chebyshev i jf! 2 S : d(x;!) = d(x; S)gj = 1 for every x 2 X: For example, the one-dimensional unit sphere S 1 is not a Chebyshev subset of R 2 ; for f! 2 S 1 : d 2 (0;!) = d 2 (0; S 1 )g = S 1 : Similarly, N 1;R 2(0) is not Chebyshev. (If x lies outside of N 1;R 2(0); then there is no point in N 1;R 2(0) that is closest to x:) On the other hand, we have seen in Example D.5 that, given any positive integer n; every nonempty closed and convex subset of R n is, in fact, a Chebyshev subset of R n : It is remarkable that the converse of this also holds, that is, any Chebyshev set in R n is a nonempty closed and convex subset of R n : It is this result that we wish to prove in this section. Let s rst warm up with a few execises. Exercise 1. A subset S of a metric space X is said to be proximinal if, for every x 2 X; there is at least one point in S that is closest to x: (a) Show that every proximinal set is closed; (b) A closed set need not be proximinal (although this is the case in a Euclidean space). Let X := f(x m ) 2 `2 : x m = 0 for all but nitely many mg: Consider X as a metric subspace of `2, and show that S := f(x m ) 2 X : P 1 1 2 x i i = 0g is a closed subset of X which is not proximinal. (c) Every convex proximinal subset of R n is Chebyshev. Exercise 2. (E mov-stechkin) Let S be a subset of a metric space X and x 2 X. A sequence (y m ) 2 S 1 is said to be a minimizing sequence for x in S; if d(x; y m )! d(x; S): In turn, S is said to be approximately compact if, for every x 2 X; every minimizing sequence for x in S has a subsequence that converges in S: (a) Show that every approximately compact set is proximinal. (b) Show that f(x m ) 2 `2 : P1 jx i j = 1g is a proximinal subset of `2 which is not approximately compact. Projection Operators First, let us note that the projection operator p S onto any Chebyshev subset S of R n is well-de ned via the equation d 2 (x; p S (x)) = d 2 (x; S); x 2 X: Remark G.4 shows that this operator is nonexpansive, provided that S is convex. It is not readily clear if the same is true for any Chebyshev subset S of R n ; but we can at least say the following right away. 1

Lemma 1. The projection operator onto any Chebyshev subset of R n is continuous. Proof. Take any Chebyshev subset S of R n ; and let (x m ) be a convergent sequence in R n with x := lim x m : Note rst that d 2 (0; p S (x m )) d 2 (0; x) + d 2 (x; x m ) + d 2 (x m ; S); m = 1; 2; ::: It follows that fp S (x 1 ); p S (x 2 ); :::g is a bounded set in R n : (Right?) Now, to derive a contradiction, suppose lim p S (x m ) = p S (x) is false. Then, since fp S (x 1 ); p S (x 2 ); :::g is bounded, there must exist a convergent subsequence (x m k ) of (x m ) such that y := lim p S (x m k ) 6= ps (x): 1 But, by continuity of the maps d 2 (; S) and d 2 ; d 2 (x; p S (x)) = d 2 (x; S) = lim k!1 d 2 (x m k ; S) = lim k!1 d 2 (x m k ; p S (x m k )) = d 2 (x; y): Since S is Chebyshev, this implies p S (x) = y; a contradiction. As another preliminary, we would like to make note of the following observation: If S is a Chebyshev subset of R n and x is any point in R n ; then the nearest point p S (x) in S to x is also the nearest point in S to any point on the line segment between p S (x) and x: We prove this next. Lemma 2. Let S be a Chebyshev subset of R n and x 2 R n : Then, p S (x + (1 )p S (x)) = p S (x); 0 1: Proof. Suppose the claim is false, that is, there exists a (; y) 2 (0; 1) S with d 2 (x + (1 )p S (x); y) < d 2 (x + (1 )p S (x); p S (x)): Then, by the triangle inequality, d 2 (x; y) < d 2 (x; x + (1 )p S (x)) + d 2 (x + (1 )p S (x); p S (x)) = (1 )d 2 (x; p S (x)) + d 2 (x; p S (x)) = d 2 (x; p S (x)) = d 2 (x; S) which is impossible. 1 Wait, why? Because the closure of fp S (x 1 ); p S (x 2 ); :::g is closed and bounded, and hence, it is compact by the Heine-Borel Theorem. Conclusion: Every subsequence of (p S (x m )) has a convergent subsequence. Therefore, if every convergent subsequence of (p S (x m )) converged to p S (x); it would follow that every subsequence of (p S (x m )) has a subsequence that converges to p S (x); which is just another way of saying lim p S (x m ) = p S (x): 2

Motzkin s Characterization of Convex Sets We are now prepared to prove that every Chebyshev subset of R n is convex. Originally proved by Theodore Motzkin in 1935, this is one of the gems of convex analysis. Motzkin s Theorem. For any positive integer n; a nonempty closed subset S of R n is Chebyshev if, and only if, it is convex. 2 Combining this result with Exercise 1 yields the characterization we promised above. Corollary. A subset S of R n is Chebyshev if, and only if, it is nonempty, closed and convex. Thanks to Motzkin s Theorem, we can also strengthen Lemma 1 to the following: Corollary. The projection operator onto any Chebyshev subset of R n is nonexpansive. Proof. Apply Motzkin s Theorem and Remark G.4. Exercise 3. Give an example of a metric d such that a convex set in (R 2 ; d) is not Chebyshev. Exercise 4. Give an example of a metric d such that a non-convex set in (R 2 ; d) is Chebyshev. The rest of this handout is devoted to the proof of Motzkin s Theorem. Given Example D.5, all we need to do here is, then, to show that a Chebyshev set S in R n is convex. The crux of the argument is contained in the following fact: For any point x in R n ; the nearest point p S (x) in S to x is also the nearest point in S to any point on the ray that begins at p S (x) and passes through x: Lemma 3. Let S be a Chebyshev subset of R n and x 2 R n : Then, p S (x + (1 )p S (x)) = p S (x); 1: (1) Motzkin s Theorem is easily proved by using Lemma 3. Let s see this rst. Take any Chebyshev subset S of R n, and pick any two vectors x and y in S: For any given 2 A major open problem in approximation theory is if the role of R n can be replaced with an arbitrary Hilbert space in this statement. (This is Klee s problem.) While there are many partial answers to this query for instance, it is known that an arbitrary pre-hilbert space would not do the status of the problem is open at present. (See Deutsch (2002) for more on this.) 3

0 < < 1; we wish to show that z := x + (1 )y belongs to S: To this end, x an arbitrary positive real number ; and notice that (1 + )z p S (z) = z + (z p S (z)): Since x 2 S; then, Lemma 3 maintains that that is, d 2 (z + (z p S (z)); p S (z)) d 2 (z + (z p S (z)); x) (1 + ) 2 (z i p S (z) i ) 2 (z i x i + (z i p S (z) i )) 2 where we denote that ith component of p S (z) as p S (z) i : Let s open this up: (1+) 2 that is, (z i p S (z) i ) 2 (1 + 2) (z i x i ) 2 +2 (z i p S (z) i ) 2 (z i x i )(z i p S (z) i )+ 2 (z i p S (z) i ) 2 (z i x i ) 2 + 2 Now divide both sides by and let! 1 to get (z i x i )(z i p S (z) i ): (d 2 (z p S (z); 0)) 2 (z x)(z p S (z)): We can obviously replace x in this inequality by y (or by any element of S for that matter), so we also have (d 2 (z p S (z); 0)) 2 (z y)(z p S (z)): Aha! If we multiply the former inequality with and the latter with 1 them up, we get ; and add (d 2 (z p S (z); 0)) 2 (z (x + (1 )y))(z p S (z)) = (z z)(z p S (z)) = 0: But this means that z = p S (z); that is, z 2 S, as we sought. It remains to establish Lemma 3, which is a far more delicate matter. We shall attack the problem by rst transforming it into a xed point problem. 3 Here is the argument. Proof of Lemma 3. Let us suppose that the assertion of Lemma 3 is false. Then, there exists an x 0 in R n ns such that I := f 1 : p S (x 0 + (1 )p S (x 0 )) = p S (x 0 )g 6= [1; 1): 3 To the best of my knowledge, this proof is due to Roger Webster. 4

But, by Lemma 2, I has to be an interval with left-end point 1: (Yes?) By continuity of p S (Lemma 1), in turn, I must contain its supremum. It follows that I = [1; ] for some real number 1: De ne x := x 0 + (1 )p S (x 0 ): Then, p S (x) = p S (x 0 ) and p S (x + (1 )p S (x)) 6= p S (x) for any > 1: (2) (This just shows that if Lemma 3 is false, then there is a point x in R n ns such that, on the line that starts at p S (x) and passes through x; every point that is not on the line segment between x and p S (x) has a projection onto S di erent than p S (x).) The rest is magic! Let := d 2 (x; S); which is a positive number (as S is closed (being proximinal) and x lies outside S): Also de ne K :=! 2 R n : d 2 (x;!) ; 2 which is a nonempty, closed, bounded and convex set in R n that is disjoint from S: Now consider the function : K! R n de ned by (!) := x + 2 x p S (!) d 2 (x; p S (!)) : Since x =2 S; this function is well-de ned, and, by Lemma 1, it is continuous. (Yes?) Furthermore, for any! 2 K; we have x p S (!) d 2 (x; (!)) = d 2 2 d 2 (x; p S (!)) ; 0 = 2d 2 (x; p S (!)) d 2 (x; p S (!)) = 2 so that (!) 2 K: Conclusion: (K) K: It then follows from the Brouwer Fixed Point Theorem that z = (z) for some z 2 K: But this means that z = x + (x p S (z)); where := =2d 2 (x; p S (z)) > 0. Then x = 1 1 + z + 1 + p S(z); that is, x lies on the line segment that joins z and p S (z): So, by Lemma 2, p S (z) = p S (x); and hence z = (1 + )x + p S (x): Since > 0; this contradicts (2). Exercise 5. Let S be a Chebyshev subset of R n and x 2 R n ns: Prove that the following are equivalent without invoking Motzkin s Theorem: (i) S is convex; (ii) p S is nonexpansive; and (iii) (1) holds for all x 2 R n ns: Exercise 6. (Motzkin-Straus-Valentine) Let S be a subset of R n such that for every x 2 X there is a unique point in S that is farthest away from x: Prove that S is a singleton. 5

References Deutsch, F. 2001. Best Approximation in Inner Product Spaces. Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg. E mov, N. and S. Stechkin. 1961. Approximate Compactness and Chebyshev Sets. Sov. Math. Dokl., 2: 1226-1228. Motzkin, T., E. Straus and F. Valentine. 1953. The Number of Farthest Points. Paci c Journal of Mathemaics, 3: 221-232. 6