CHAPTER 9 FUNCTIONAL FORMS OF REGRESSION MODELS

Similar documents
MgtOp 215 Chapter 13 Dr. Ahn

ECONOMETRICS - FINAL EXAM, 3rd YEAR (GECO & GADE)

Which of the following provides the most reasonable approximation to the least squares regression line? (a) y=50+10x (b) Y=50+x (d) Y=1+50x

σ may be counterbalanced by a larger

Tests for Two Correlations

Microeconomics: BSc Year One Extending Choice Theory

Graphical Methods for Survival Distribution Fitting

Evaluating Performance

Notes are not permitted in this examination. Do not turn over until you are told to do so by the Invigilator.

Calibration Methods: Regression & Correlation. Calibration Methods: Regression & Correlation

II. Random Variables. Variable Types. Variables Map Outcomes to Numbers

Sampling Distributions of OLS Estimators of β 0 and β 1. Monte Carlo Simulations

Mode is the value which occurs most frequency. The mode may not exist, and even if it does, it may not be unique.

>1 indicates country i has a comparative advantage in production of j; the greater the index, the stronger the advantage. RCA 1 ij

Raising Food Prices and Welfare Change: A Simple Calibration. Xiaohua Yu

Quiz on Deterministic part of course October 22, 2002

Module Contact: Dr P Moffatt, ECO Copyright of the University of East Anglia Version 2

3/3/2014. CDS M Phil Econometrics. Vijayamohanan Pillai N. Truncated standard normal distribution for a = 0.5, 0, and 0.5. CDS Mphil Econometrics

Economics 1410 Fall Section 7 Notes 1. Define the tax in a flexible way using T (z), where z is the income reported by the agent.

4. Greek Letters, Value-at-Risk

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture VI: Industry Supply

occurrence of a larger storm than our culvert or bridge is barely capable of handling? (what is The main question is: What is the possibility of

Solutions to Odd-Numbered End-of-Chapter Exercises: Chapter 12

Consumption Based Asset Pricing

Linear Combinations of Random Variables and Sampling (100 points)

Tests for Two Ordered Categorical Variables

/ Computational Genomics. Normalization

2) In the medium-run/long-run, a decrease in the budget deficit will produce:

Survey of Math Test #3 Practice Questions Page 1 of 5

Measures of Spread IQR and Deviation. For exam X, calculate the mean, median and mode. For exam Y, calculate the mean, median and mode.

3: Central Limit Theorem, Systematic Errors

Multifactor Term Structure Models

Data Mining Linear and Logistic Regression

EDC Introduction

- contrast so-called first-best outcome of Lindahl equilibrium with case of private provision through voluntary contributions of households

EXAMINATIONS OF THE HONG KONG STATISTICAL SOCIETY

y\ 1 Target E-2 Extra Practice r i r Date: Name: 1. a) What is the approximate value of d when t = 3? Explain the method you used.

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Feb 2018

Answers to exercises in Macroeconomics by Nils Gottfries 2013

Random Variables. b 2.

ISyE 512 Chapter 9. CUSUM and EWMA Control Charts. Instructor: Prof. Kaibo Liu. Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering UW-Madison

THE VOLATILITY OF EQUITY MUTUAL FUND RETURNS

Chapter 3 Student Lecture Notes 3-1

Capability Analysis. Chapter 255. Introduction. Capability Analysis

A Comparison of Statistical Methods in Interrupted Time Series Analysis to Estimate an Intervention Effect

Applications of Myerson s Lemma

Finance 402: Problem Set 1 Solutions

PASS Sample Size Software. :log

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy

Taxation and Externalities. - Much recent discussion of policy towards externalities, e.g., global warming debate/kyoto

Simple Regression Theory II 2010 Samuel L. Baker

Analysis of Variance and Design of Experiments-II

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy

Explaining Movements of the Labor Share in the Korean Economy: Factor Substitution, Markups and Bargaining Power

SIMPLE FIXED-POINT ITERATION

Transformation and Weighted Least Squares

UNIVERSITY OF VICTORIA Midterm June 6, 2018 Solutions

15-451/651: Design & Analysis of Algorithms January 22, 2019 Lecture #3: Amortized Analysis last changed: January 18, 2019

Spurious Seasonal Patterns and Excess Smoothness in the BLS Local Area Unemployment Statistics

Interval Estimation for a Linear Function of. Variances of Nonnormal Distributions. that Utilize the Kurtosis

Chapter 3 Descriptive Statistics: Numerical Measures Part B

INTRODUCTION TO MACROECONOMICS FOR THE SHORT RUN (CHAPTER 1) WHY STUDY BUSINESS CYCLES? The intellectual challenge: Why is economic growth irregular?

Elton, Gruber, Brown, and Goetzmann. Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis, 7th Edition. Solutions to Text Problems: Chapter 9

Basket options and implied correlations: a closed form approach

Risk and Return: The Security Markets Line

OCR Statistics 1 Working with data. Section 2: Measures of location

Comparing Changes in Operational Productivity and Financial Productivity of Electric Utilities in a Competitive Environment

Quiz 2 Answers PART I

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY LECTURE 8: THE OPEN ECONOMY WITH FIXED EXCHANGE RATES

Bilateral Trade Flows and Nontraded Goods

Economic Design of Short-Run CSP-1 Plan Under Linear Inspection Cost

Domestic Savings and International Capital Flows

An Application of Alternative Weighting Matrix Collapsing Approaches for Improving Sample Estimates

Introduction. Why One-Pass Statistics?

Price and Quantity Competition Revisited. Abstract

University of Toronto November 9, 2006 ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #1 L0101 L0201 L0401 L5101 MW MW 1-2 MW 2-3 W 6-8

University of Toronto November 9, 2006 ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #1 L0101 L0201 L0401 L5101 MW MW 1-2 MW 2-3 W 6-8

Underemployment Intensity, its Cost, and their Consequences on the Value of Time.

Macroeconomic equilibrium in the short run: the Money market

Part I Modelling Money in General Equilibrium: a Primer Lecture 3 Welfare Cost of Inflation in the Basic MIU model

The Effects of Industrial Structure Change on Economic Growth in China Based on LMDI Decomposition Approach

Introduction. Chapter 7 - An Introduction to Portfolio Management

Spatial Variations in Covariates on Marriage and Marital Fertility: Geographically Weighted Regression Analyses in Japan

Scribe: Chris Berlind Date: Feb 1, 2010

Information Flow and Recovering the. Estimating the Moments of. Normality of Asset Returns

Midterm Exam. Use the end of month price data for the S&P 500 index in the table below to answer the following questions.

EPPE6024: Macroeconomics Lecture 2: Aggregate Demand (AD), Aggregate Supply (AS), and Business Cycle

Note on Cubic Spline Valuation Methodology

Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations, Wage Stickiness and Markup Adjustments

ISyE 2030 Summer Semester 2004 June 30, 2004

IND E 250 Final Exam Solutions June 8, Section A. Multiple choice and simple computation. [5 points each] (Version A)

Alternatives to Shewhart Charts

Ch Rival Pure private goods (most retail goods) Non-Rival Impure public goods (internet service)

CrimeStat Version 3.3 Update Notes:

FORD MOTOR CREDIT COMPANY SUGGESTED ANSWERS. Richard M. Levich. New York University Stern School of Business. Revised, February 1999

Fall 2017 Social Sciences 7418 University of Wisconsin-Madison Problem Set 3 Answers

Political Economy and Trade Policy

Prospect Theory and Asset Prices

MULTIPLE CURVE CONSTRUCTION

Uniform Output Subsidies in Economic Unions versus Profit-shifting Export Subsidies

Transcription:

CHAPTER 9 FUNCTIONAL FORMS OF REGRESSION MODELS QUESTIONS 9.1. (a) In a log-log model the dependent and all explanatory varables are n the logarthmc form. (b) In the log-ln model the dependent varable s n the logarthmc form but the explanatory varables are n the lnear form. (c) In the ln-log model the dependent varable s n the lnear form, whereas the explanatory varables are n the logarthmc form. (d) It s the percentage change n the value of one varable for a (small) percentage change n the value of another varable. For the log-log model, the slope coeffcent of an explanatory varable gves a drect estmate of the elastcty coeffcent of the dependent varable wth respect to the gven explanatory varable. (e) For the ln-ln model, elastcty = slope Y. Therefore the elastcty wll depend on the values of and Y. But f we choose and Y, the mean values of and Y, at whch to measure the elastcty, the elastcty at mean values wll be: slope. Y 9.. The slope coeffcent gves the rate of change n (mean) Y wth respect to, whereas the elastcty coeffcent s the percentage change n (mean) Y for a (small) percentage change n. The relatonshp between two s: Elastcty = slope. For the log-lnear, or log-log, model only, the elastcty and Y slope coeffcents are dentcal. 9.3. Model 1: ln Y = B + 1 B ln : If the scattergram of ln Y on ln shows a lnear relatonshp, then ths model s approprate. In practce, such models 66

are used to estmate the elastctes, for the slope coeffcent gves a drect estmate of the elastcty coeffcent. Model : ln Y = B + 1 B : Such a model s generally used f the objectve of the study s to measure the rate of growth of Y wth respect to. Often, the varable represents tme n such models. Model 3: : If the objectve s to fnd out the absolute change n Y for a relatve or percentage change n, ths model s often chosen. Model 4: Y = B + 1 B ln ) : If the relatonshp between Y and s curvlnear, as n the case of the Phllps curve, ths model generally gves a good ft. 9.4. (a) Elastcty. Y (1/ = B + B 1 (b) The absolute change n the mean value of the dependent varable for a proportonal change n the explanatory varable. (c) The growth rate. (d) dy d Y (e) The percentage change n the quantty demanded for a (small) percentage change n the prce. (f) Greater than 1; less than 1. 9.5. (a) True. d ln Y dy =, whch, by defnton, s elastcty. d ln d Y (b) True. For the two-varable lnear model, the slope equals and the elastcty = slope = B Y the log-lnear model, slope = whle the elastcty equals regresson model. B Y B B, whch vares from pont to pont. For Y, whch vares from pont to pont. Ths can be generalzed to a multple 67

(c) True. To compare two or more same. R s (d) True. The same reasonng as n (c). (e) False. The two, the dependent varable must be the r values are not drectly comparable. 9.6. The elastcty coeffcents for the varous models are: (a) B ( / Y ) (b) - (1 / Y ) (c) B B (d) - B (1 / ) (e) B (1 / Y ) (f) B (1 / ) Model (a) assumes that the ncome elastcty s dependent on the levels of both ncome and consumpton expendture. If B > 0, Models (b) and (d) gve negatve ncome elastctes. Hence, these models may be sutable for "nferor" goods. Model (c) gves constant elastcty at all levels of ncome, whch may not be realstc for all consumpton goods. Model (e) suggests that the ncome elastcty s ndependent of ncome,, but s dependent on the level of consumpton expendture, Y. Fnally, Model (f) suggests that the ncome elastcty s ndependent of consumpton expendture, Y, but s dependent on the level of ncome,. 9.7 (a) Instantaneous growth: 3.0%; 5.30%; 4.56%; 1.14%. (b) Compound growth: 3.07%; 5.44%; 4.67%; 1.15%. (c) The dfference s more apparent than real, for n one case we have annual data and n the other we have quarterly data. A quarterly growth rate of 1.14% s about equal to an annual growth rate of 4.56%. PROBLEMS 9.8. (a) MC = (b) AVC = B + + B3 3B4 B + B + B 3 4 1 (c) AC = B 1 + B + B3 + B4 By way of an example based on actual numbers, the MC, AVC, and AC from Equaton (9.33) are as follows: 68

MC = 63.4776 5.930 +.8188 AVC = 63.4776 1.9615 + 0.9396 1 AC = 141.7667 + 63.4776 1.9615 + 0.9396 (d) The plot wll show that they do ndeed resemble the textbook U-shaped cost curves. 1 9.9. (a) = B1 + B Y (b) Y = B + B 1 9.10. (a) In Model A, the slope coeffcent of -0.4795 suggests that f the prce of coffee per pound goes up by a dollar, the average consumpton of coffee per day goes down by about half a cup. In Model B, the slope coeffcent of -0.530 suggests that f the prce of coffee per pound goes up by 1%, the average consumpton of coffee per day goes down by about 0.5%. 1.11 (b) Elastcty = -0.4795 = -0.190.43 (c) -0.530 (d) The demand for coffee s prce nelastc, snce the absolute value of the two elastcty coeffcents s less than 1. (e) Antlog (0.7774) =.1758. In Model B, f the prce of coffee were $1, on average, people would drnk approxmately. cups of coffee per day. [Note: Keep n mnd that ln(1) = 0]. (f) We cannot compare the two r values drectly, snce the dependent varables n the two models are dfferent. 9.11. (a) Ceters parbus, f the labor nput ncreases by 1%, output, on average, ncreases by about 0.34%. The computed elastcty s dfferent from 1, for t = 0.3397 1 = -3.5557 0.1857 For 17 d.f., ths t value s statstcally sgnfcant at the 1% level of sgnfcance (two-tal test). 69

(b) Ceters parbus, f the captal nput ncreases by 1%, on average, output ncreases by about 0.85 %. Ths elastcty coeffcent s statstcally dfferent from zero, but not from 1, because under the respectve hypothess, the computed t values are about 9.06 and -1.65, respectvely. (c) The antlog of -1.654 = 0.1916. Thus, f the values of = 1, 3 = then Y = 0.1916 or (0.1916)(1,000,000) = 191,600 pesos. Of course, ths does not have much economc meanng [Note: ln(1) = 0]. (d) Usng the R varant of the F test, the computed F value s: 0.995 / F = = 1,691.50 (1 0.995) / 17 Ths F value s obvously hghly sgnfcant. So, we can reject the null hypothess that B = B 0. The crtcal F value s F = 6.11 for α = 1%. 3 = Note: The slght dfference between the calculated F value here and the one shown n the text s due to roundng. 9.1. (a) A pror, the coeffcents of ln(y / P) and lnσ BP,17 should be postve and the coeffcent of lnσ should be negatve. The results meet the pror E expectatons. (b) Each partal slope coeffcent s a partal elastcty, snce t s a log-lnear model. (c) As the 1,10 observatons are qute a large number, we can use the normal dstrbuton to test the null hypothess. At the 5% level of sgnfcance, the crtcal (standardzed normal) Z value s 1.96. Snce, n absolute value, each estmated t coeffcent exceeds 1.96, each estmated coeffcent s statstcally dfferent from zero. (d) Use the F test. The author gves the F value as 1,151, whch s hghly statstcally sgnfcant. So, reject the null hypothess. 9.13. (a) If (1 / ) goes up by a unt, the average value of Y goes up by 8.743. 8.743 (b) Under the null hypothess, t = = 3.0635, whch s statstcally.8478 sgnfcant at the 5% level. Hence reject the null hypothess. 70

(c) Under the null hypothess, F = 1,15 t15, whch s the case here, save the roundng errors. 1 (d) For ths model: slope = - 1 B = -8.743 t.5 = -3.8775. 1 (e) Elastcty = - 1 B = -8.743 = -1.117 t Y t (1.5)(4.8) Note: The slope and elastcty are evaluated at the mean values of and Y. (f) The computed F value s 9.39, whch s sgnfcant at the 1% level, snce for 1 and 15 d.f. the crtcal F value s 8.68. Hence reject the null hypothess that r = 0. 9.14. (a) The results of the four regressons are as follows: Dependent Varable Intercept Independent Varable Goodness of Ft 1 Ŷ t = 38.9690 + 0.609 t r = 0.943 t 3 t t = (10.105) (15.655) l ˆ n Y = 1.4041 + 0.5890 ln t t = (8.954) (0.090) r = 0.964 l ˆ n Y = 3.9316 + 0.008 t r = 0.984 t = (84.678) (13.950) 4 Ŷ t = -19.9661 + 54.16 ln t r = 0.9543 t = (-11.781) (17.703) (b) In Model (1), the slope coeffcent gves the absolute change n the mean value of Y per unt change n. In Model (), the slope gves the elastcty coeffcent. In Model (3) the slope gves the (nstantaneous) rate of growth n (mean) Y per unt change n. In Model (4), the slope gves the absolute change n mean Y for a relatve change n. (c) 0.609; 0.5890(Y / ); 0.008(Y); 54.16(1 / ). (d) 0.609( / Y); 0.5890; 0.008(); 54.16(1 / Y). 71

For the frst, thrd and the fourth model, the elastctes at the mean values are, respectvely, 0.5959, 0.6165, and 0.563. (e) The choce among the models ultmately depends on the end use of the model. Keep n mnd that n comparng the the dependent varable must be n the same form. r values of the varous models, 9.15. (a) ˆ1 = 0.0130 + 0.0000833 Y t = (17.06) (5.683) r = 0.8015 The slope coeffcent gves the rate of change n mean (1 / Y) per unt change n. dy B (b) = d B + B ) ( 1 At the mean value of, = 38.9, ths dervatve s -0.3146. (c) Elastcty = coeffcent s -0.1915. 1 (d) Ŷ = 55.4871 + 11.1797 t = (17.409) (4.45) dy. At = 38.9 and Y = 63.9, ths elastcty d Y r = 0.695 (e) No, because the dependent varables n the two models are dfferent. (f) Unless we know what Y and stand for, t s dffcult to say whch model s better. 9.16. For the lnear model, r = 0.99879, and for the log-ln model, r = 0.99965. Followng the procedure descrbed n the problem, r = 0.99968, whch s comparable wth the r = 0.99879. 9.17. (a) Log-lnear model: The slope and elastcty coeffcents are the same. Log-ln model: The slope coeffcent gves the growth rate. Ln-log model: The slope coeffcent gves the absolute change n GNP for a percentage n the money supply. 7

Lnear-n-varable model: The slope coeffcent gves the (absolute) rate of change n mean GNP for a unt change n the money supply. (b) The elastcty coeffcents for the four models are: Log-lnear: 0.988 Log-ln (Growth): 1.0007 (at = 1,755.667) Ln-log: 0.960 (at Y =,791.473) Lnear (LIV): 0.9637 (at = 1,755.667 and Y =,791.473). (c) The r s r s of the log-lnear and log-ln models are comparable, as are the of the ln-log and lnear (LIV) models. (d) Judged by the usual crtera of the t test, all the models more or less gve smlar results. r values, and the elastctes, (e) From the log-lnear model, we observe that for a 1% ncrease n the money supply, on the average, GNP ncreases by about 1%, the coeffcent 0.988 beng statstcally equal to 1. Perhaps ths model supports the monetarst vew. Snce the elastcty coeffcents of the other models are smlar, t seems all the models support the monetarsts. 9.18. (a) Ŷ t = 8.3407 + 0.9817 0.595 t se = (1.417) (0.0193) (0.015) t = (0.0617) (50.7754) (-17.0864) 3t R = 0.9940 p value = (0.0000)* (0.0000)* (0.0000)* R = 0.9934 * Denotes a very small value. (b) Per unt change n the real GDP ndex, on average, the energy demand ndex goes up by about 0.98 ponts, ceters parbus. Per unt change n the energy prce, the energy demand ndex goes down about 0.6 ponts, agan holdng all else constant. (c) From the p values gven n the above regresson, all the partal regresson coeffcents are ndvdually hghly statstcally sgnfcant. (d) The values requred to set up the ANOVA table are: TSS = 6,746.9887; ESS = 6,706.863, and RSS = 40.704. The computed F value s 1,647.638 wth a p value of almost zero. Therefore, we can reject the null hypothess 73

that there s no relatonshp between energy demand, real GDP, and energy prces (Note: These ANOVA numbers can easly be calculated wth the regresson optons n Excel). (e) Mean value of demand = 84.370; mean value of real GDP = 89.66, and the mean value of energy prce = 13.135, all n ndex form. Therefore, at the mean values, the elastcty of demand wth respect to real GDP s 1.048 and wth respect to energy prce, t s -0.3787. (f) Ths s straghtforward. (g) The normal probablty plot wll show that the resduals from the regresson model le approxmately on a straght lne, ndcatng that the error term n the regresson model seems to be normally dstrbuted. The Anderson-Darlng normalty test gves an s about 0.188, thereby supportng the normalty assumpton. A value of 0.50, whose p value (h) The normalty plot wll show that the resduals do not le on a straght lne, suggestng that the normalty assumpton for the error term may not be tenable for the log-lnear model. The computed Anderson-Darlng A s 1.00 wth a p value of about 0.009, whch s qute low. Note: Any mnor coeffcent dfferences between ths log-lnear regresson and the log-lnear regresson (9.1) are due to roundng. Regardng the Anderson-Darlng test, t s avalable n MINITAB. If you do not have access to MINITAB, you can use the normal probablty plots n EVews and Excel for a vsual nspecton, as descrbed above. EVews also has the Jarque-Bera normalty test, but you should avod usng t here because t s a large sample asymptotc test and the present data set has only 3 observatons. In fact, the Jarque-Bera test wll show that the resduals of both the lnear and the log-lnear regressons satsfy the normalty assumpton, whch s not the case based on the Anderson-Darlng A and the normal probablty plots. () Snce the lnear model seems to satsfy the normalty assumpton, ths model may be preferable to the log-lnear model. 9.19. (a) Ths wll make the model lnear n the parameters. 74

(b) The slope coeffcents n the two models are, respectvely: dy dt B 1 dy = and = B ( A + Bt) Y dt (c) In models (1) and () the slope coeffcents are negatve and are statstcally sgnfcant, snce the t values are so hgh. In both models the recprocal of the loan amount has been decreasng over tme. From the slope coeffcents already gven, we can compute the rate of change of loans over tme. (d) Dvde the estmated coeffcents by ther t values to obtan the standard errors. (e) Suppose for Model 1 we postulate that the true B coeffcent s -0.14. Then, usng the t test, we obtan: t = 0.0 ( 0.14) = -7.3171 0.008 Ths t value s statstcally sgnfcant at the 1% level. Hence, t seems there s a dfference n the loan actvty of New York and non-new York banks. [Note: s.e. = (-0.0)/(-4.5) = 0.008]. 9.0. (a) For the recprocal model, as Table 9-11 shows, the slope coeffcent (.e., the rate of change of Y wth respect to s B(1 / ). In the present nstance B = 0.0549. Therefore, the value of the slope wll depend on the value taken by the varable. (b) For ths model the elastcty coeffcent s B (1 / Y). Obvously, ths elastcty wll depend on the chosen values of and Y. Now, = 8.375 and Y = 0.433. Evaluatng the elastcty at these means, we fnd t to be equal to -0.0045. 9.1. We have the followng varable defntons: TOTAL PCE () = Total personal consumpton expendture; EP SERVICES ( Y 1 EP DURABLES ( ) = Expendture on servces; Y EP NONDURABLES ( ) = Expendture on durable goods; Y 3 ) = Expendture on nondurable goods. 75

Plottng the data, we obtan the followng scatter graphs: 3000 900 EP SERVICES (Y1) 800 700 600 500 400 400 4400 4600 4800 5000 500 TOTAL PCE () 750 EP DURABLES (Y) 700 650 600 550 500 400 4400 4600 4800 5000 500 TOTAL PCE () 76

1600 EP NONDURABLES (Y3) 1550 1500 1450 1400 1350 1300 400 4400 4600 4800 5000 500 TOTAL PCE () It seems that the relatonshp between the varous expendture categores and total personal consumpton expendture s approxmately lnear. Hence, as a frst step one could apply the lnear (n varables) model to the varous categores. The regresson results are as follows: (the ndependent varable s TOTAL PCE and fgures n the parentheses are the estmated t values). Dependent varable EP SERVICES EP DURABLES EP NONDURABLES ( Y 1 ) ( Y ) ( Y 3 ) Intercept.5759 (11.981) -554.5943 (-16.8744) 335.764 (4.7647) Slope (TOTAL PCE) 0.5164 (19.8600) 0.484 (35.468) 0.345 (81.1599) R 0.9988 0.9836 0.9968 Judged by the usual crtera, the results seem satsfactory. In each case the slope coeffcent represents the margnal propensty of expendture (MPE) that s the addtonal expendture for an addtonal dollar of TOTAL PCE. 77

Ths s hghest for servces, followed by durable and nondurable goods expendtures. By fttng a double-log model one can obtan the varous elastcty coeffcents. 9.. The EVews results for the frst model are as follows: Dependent Varable: Y Sample: 1971 1980 Varable Coeffcent Std. Error t-statstc Prob. C 1.79719 7.688560 0.166445 0.8719 1.069084 0.38315 4.486004 0.000 R-squared 0.715548 The output for the regresson-through-the-orgn model s: Dependent Varable: Y Sample: 1971 1980 Varable Coeffcent Std. Error t-statstc Prob. 1.08991 0.191551 5.6899 0.0003 R-squared 0.714563 Ths R may not be relable. Snce the ntercept n the frst model s not statstcally sgnfcant, we can choose the second model. 9.3. Usng the raw raw r formula, we obtan : = ( ) Y (11,344.8) r = = 0.785 Y (10,408.44)(15,801.41) You can compare ths wth the ntercept-present R value of 0.7155. 9.4. Computatons wll show that the raw r s 0.7318. The one n Equaton (9.40) s 0.7353. There s not much dfference between the two values. Any mnor dfferences between regressons (9.39) and (9.40) n the text and the same regressons based on Table 6-1 are due to roundng. 78