Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information

Similar documents
Exponential utility maximization under partial information

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Asymmetric information in trading against disorderly liquidation of a large position.

An example of indifference prices under exponential preferences

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property

Option Pricing with Delayed Information

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

Robust Portfolio Choice and Indifference Valuation

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Hedging under Arbitrage

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Risk Neutral Measures

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

Indifference fee rate 1

Quadratic Hedging of Basis Risk

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Citation: Dokuchaev, Nikolai Optimal gradual liquidation of equity from a risky asset. Applied Economic Letters. 17 (13): pp

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Indifference pricing and hedging for volatility. derivatives

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

Utility indifference valuation for non-smooth payoffs on a market with some non tradable assets

Conditional Certainty Equivalent

Hedging of swaptions in a Lévy driven Heath-Jarrow-Morton framework

ARBITRAGE-FREE PRICING DYNAMICS OF INTEREST-RATE GUARANTEES BASED ON THE UTILITY INDIFFERENCE METHOD

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Optional semimartingale decomposition and no arbitrage condition in enlarged ltration

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations

The minimal entropy martingale measure

On the pricing of emission allowances

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

Optimal asset allocation under forward performance criteria Oberwolfach, February 2007

Stochastic Integral Representation of One Stochastically Non-smooth Wiener Functional

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term.

Guarantee valuation in Notional Defined Contribution pension systems

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

The Self-financing Condition: Remembering the Limit Order Book

Enlargement of filtration

Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

Portfolio Selection with Randomly Time-Varying Moments: The Role of the Instantaneous Capital Market Line

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Spot and forward dynamic utilities. and their associated pricing systems. Thaleia Zariphopoulou. UT, Austin

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Mean-variance hedging when there are jumps

Hedging of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets

The Mathematics of Currency Hedging

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note

Kim Weston (Carnegie Mellon University) Market Stability and Indifference Prices. 1st Eastern Conference on Mathematical Finance.

Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels

Hedging under arbitrage

Interest rate models in continuous time

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

On worst-case investment with applications in finance and insurance mathematics

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Optimal investments under dynamic performance critria. Lecture IV

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

A Delayed Black and Scholes Formula II

Decomposition of life insurance liabilities into risk factors theory and application to annuity conversion options

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Time-Consistent and Market-Consistent Actuarial Valuations

Transcription:

Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information Marina Santacroce Politecnico di Torino Joint work with M. Mania WORKSHOP FINANCE and INSURANCE March 16-2, Jena 29

Outline Expected utility maximization under partial information: semimartingale setting Semimartingale model Expected utility and partial information Equivalent problem and solution Value process and BSDE Assumptions Equivalent problem Value process and BSDE F S G An example with explicit solution. Diffusion model with correlation Sufficiency of filtrations Sufficiency of filtrations

The model Let S = (S t, t [, T ]) be a continuous semimartingale which represents the price process of the traded asset. (Ω, A, A = (A t, t [, T ]), P), where A = A T and T < is a fixed time horizon. Assume the interest rate equal to zero. The price process S admits the decomposition S t = S + N t + λ ud N u, λ N T < a.s., where N is a continuous A -local martingale and λ is a A -predictable process (Structure condition).

Expected utility maximization and partial information Denote by G = (G t, t [, T ]) a filtration smaller than A G t A t, for every t [, T ]. G represents the information available to the hedger. We consider the exponential utility maximization problem with random payoff H at time T when G is the available information, to maximize E[ e α(x+ T π uds u H) ] over all π Π(G ). x represents the initial endowment (w.l.g. we take x = ) Π(G ) is a certain class of self-financing strategies (G -predictable and S-integrable processes). ( πudsu, t [, T ]) represents the wealth process related to the self-financing strategy π. This problem is equivalent to to minimize E[e α( T π uds u H) ] over all π Π(G ).

In most papers, under various setups, (see, e.g., Lakner (1998), Pham and Quenez (21), Zohar (21)) expected utility maximization problems have been considered for market models where only stock prices are observed, while the drift can not be directly observed. = under the hypothesis F S G. We consider the case when G does not necessarily contain all information on the prices of the traded asset i.e. S is not a G -semimartingale in general! = In this case, we solve the problem in 2 steps: Step 1: Prove that the expected exponential maximization problem is equivalent to another maximization problem of the filtered terminal net wealth (reduced problem) Step 2: Apply the dynamic programming method to the reduced problem. (In Mania et al. (28) a similar approach is used in the context of mean variance hedging).

Filtration F and decomposition of S w.r.t. F Let F = (F t, t [, T ]) be the augmented filtration generated by F S and G. S is a F -semimartingale: S t = S + λ (F) u d M u + M t, (Decomposition of S with respect to F ) M t = N t + (F) [λ u λ u ]d N u is F -local martingale where we denote by λ (F) the F -predictable projection of λ. Note that M = N are F S -predictable.

Assumptions In the sequel we will make the following assumptions: A) M is G -predictable and d M tdp a.e. λ F = λ G, hence for each t E(λ t F S t G t) = E(λ t G t), P a.s. B) any G -martingale is a F -local martingale, C) the filtration G is continuous, D) for any G -local martingale m(g) M, m(g) is G -predictable, E) H is an A T -measurable bounded random variable, such that P- a.s. E[e αh F T ] = E[e αh G T ],

Remarks Note that If F S G, then M is G -predictable. Besides, in this case G = F and conditions A), B), D) and the equality in E) are automatically satisfied. Condition B) is satisfied if and only if the σ-algebras Ft S G t and G T are conditionally independent given G t for all t [, T ] (Jacod 1978). The continuity of filtration G is weaker than the assumption that the filtration F is continuous. Filtration F continuous + condition B) Filtration G is continuous The converse is not true in general. The filtrations F S and F can be discontinuous.

G -projection processes Let Ŝt = E(St Gt) be the G -optional projection of St. Note that since λ F = λ G = λ, we have: Ŝ t = E(S t G t) = S + where M t is the G -local martingale E(M t G t). Under conditions A-D, M t = λ ud M u + M t d M, m(g) u dm u(g) + L t(g), d m(g) u where m(g) is any G -local martingale and L(g) is a G -local martingale orthogonal to m(g). Hence, M, m(g) t = M, m(g) t M, M t = M t. Using this decomposition and the Doléans equation, it is possible to show LEMMA Under conditions A)-D), Ê t(m) = E(E t(m) G t) = E t( M).

Equivalent problem We recall that our aim is to minimize E[e α( T π uds u H) ] over all π Π(G ). (1) where the class of strategies is defined as Π(G ) = {π : G predictable, π M BMO(F )} PROPOSITION Let conditions A)-E) be satisfied. Then the optimization problem (1) is equivalent to to minimize E[e α( T π udŝu H)+ α2 2 T π 2 u (1 κ2 u )d M u ], over all π Π(G ) (2) Moreover, for any π Π(G ) E[e α( T t H = 1 α ln E[eαH G T ], κ 2 t = d M t d M t. π uds u H) G t] = E[e α( T t π udŝu H)+ α2 2 T t πu 2 (1 κ2 u )d M u G t].

Sketch of the proof Let t =. Taking the conditional expectation with respect to F T and using condition E[e αh F T ] = E[e αh G T ], we have that ( E[e α( T π uds u H) ] = E e α ) T π uds u E[e αh F T ] Resorting to the F -decomposition of S, the previous lemma, the decomposition of Ŝ, we have that (3) is equal to E[E T ( απ M)e α2 2 = E[E(E T ( απ M) G T )e α2 2 = E[E T ( απ α2 M)e 2 T π 2 u d M u α T π u λud M u+α H] ( ) = E e α( T π uds u H). T π 2 u d M u α T π u λud M u+α H] T π 2 u d M u α T π u λud M u+α H] (3) = E[e α T π ud M u α2 2 T π 2 u d M u+ α2 2 T π 2 u d M u α T π u λud M u+α H] = E[e α( T π udŝu H)+ α2 2 T π 2 u (1 κ2 u )d M u ].

Remarks Let The previous proposition says that the optimization problems (1) and (2) are equivalent. It is sufficient to solve problem (2), which is formulated in terms of G -adapted processes. We can see (2) as an exponential hedging problem under complete information with a (multiplicative) correction term and we can solve it using methods for complete information. V t = ess inf π Π(G ) E[e α( T t π udŝu H)+ α2 2 T t πu 2 (1 κ2 u )d M u G t], be the value process related to the equivalent problem.

From now on let assume F) T λ 2 t d M t C, P a.s.. Note that: c V t C for two positive constants: H is bounded V t C. condition F) V t c for a positive c (by duality issues). Indeed, if V t(f ) = ess inf π Π(F) E[e α( T t π uds u H) F t], then it is well known that under condition F), V t(f ) c, (see e.g. Delbaen et al. (22)). Therefore [ ) ] V t = ess inf E E (e α( T t π uds u H) F t G t E(V t(f ) G t) c. π Π(G ) If H is G T -measurable, then H = H and problem (1) is equivalent to minimize E[e α( T π α2 T udŝu H)+ π 2 2 u (1 κ2 u )d M u ].

Main result THEOREM Under assumptions A)-F). Then, the value process V related to the equivalent problem (2) is the unique bounded strictly positive solution of the following BSDE Y t = Y + 1 2 Y T = E[e αh G T ] (ψ uκ 2 u + λ uy u) 2 Y u d M u + ψ ud M u + L t (4) Moreover the optimal strategy exists in the class Π(G ) and is equal to π t = 1 α ( λ t + ψtκ2 t Y t ). (5) The existence of a solution to the BSDE (4) is derived by using results in Tevzadze (28) (see also Morlais (28)). Unicity is proved by directly showing that the unique bounded solution of the BSDE is the value process of the problem.

F S G. What happens if F S t G t? G t = F t F S t G t The F decomposition of S is the G decomposition of S : S t = S + λ ud M u + M t, M M loc (G ) Note Mt = M t and κ 2 t = 1 for all t A), B), D) and E[e αh F T ] = E[e αh G T ] are satisfied = If G is continuous, the initial problem (1) is equivalent to to minimize E(e α( T π uds u H) ) over all π Π(G ).

COROLLARY Let F S G A. Assume G continuous, H to be a bounded A T -measurable random variable, T λ 2 t d M t C, P a.s.. Then, the value process V is the unique bounded positive solution of the BSDE Y t = Y + 1 2 (ψ u + λ uy u) 2 Y u d M u + Moreover, the optimal strategy is equal to π t = 1 α ( λ t + ψt Y t ). ψ udm u +L t, Y T = E(e αh G T ). (6) REMARK: In the case of full information G t = A t, we also have and Equation (6) takes on the form Y t = Y + 1 2 M t = M t = N t, λt = λ t, Y T = e αh (ψ u + λ uy u) 2 Y u d N u + ψ udn u + L t, Y T = e αh.

Diffusion model with correlation As an example we deal with a diffusion market model consisting of two correlated risky assets one of which has no liquid market. First we consider an agent who is finding the best strategy to hedge a contingent claim H, trading with the liquid asset but using just the information on the non tradable one (partial information). We solve the problem for full information when H is function only of the nontraded asset Then, we compare the results obtained in the cases of partial/full information.

Basis risk model The price of the two risky assets follow the dynamics subjected to initial conditions. d S t = S t(µ(t, η)dt + σ(t, η)dw 1 t ), dη t =b(t, η)dt + a(t, η)dw t, (7) W 1 and W are standard Brownian motions with constant correlation ρ, i.e. EdWt 1 dw t = ρdt, ρ ( 1, 1). W t = ρw 1 t + 1 ρ 2 W t, where W and W 1 are independent Brownian motions. η represents the price of a nontraded asset (e.g. an index); Besides, we denote ds t = d S t S t ds t = µ(t, η)dt + σ(t, η)dw 1 t S represents the process of returns of the tradable asset.

Assumptions Assume that the coefficients µ, σ, a and b are non anticipative functionals such that: 1) T µ 2 (t,η) dt is bounded, σ 2 (t,η) 2) σ 2 >, a 2 > 3) Eq. (7) admits a unique strong solution (η), 4) H is bounded and F η T σ(ξ)-measurable, where ξ is a random variable independent of S and η. Under conditions 2), 3) we have F S,η = F W 1,W and F η = F W.

Partial information Problem: An agent is hedging a contingent claim H trading with the liquid asset S using only observations coming from η. to minimize E[e α( T π uds u H) ] over all π Π(F η ), where π represents the dollar amount the agent invests in the stock which depends only on η. F t = F S,η t A t and G t = F η t. Under conditions 1) 4) (which imply that our assumptions A) F) are satisfied), = we give an explicit expression of the optimal amount of money that should be invested in the liquid asset.

In this model, M t = σ(u, η)dw 1 u, M t = σ 2 (u, η)du, λ t = µ(t, η) σ 2 (t, η). M t = ρ σ(u, η)dw u M t = ρ 2 M t and κ 2 t = ρ 2. Conditions 1) 4) imply that assumptions A) F) hold, indeed µ, σ, b, a are F η -measurable conditions A) and D); F W 1,W (resp. F W ) is the (augmented) filtration generated by W 1 and W (resp. W ) G = F η is continuous (condition C)); W is a Brownian motion (also) with respect to F W 1,W condition B); since F T = F S,η T, assumption 4) condition E); condition F) is here represented by 1).

We find that the value process related to the optimization problem is equal to V t = ( E Q[e (1 ρ2 )(α H 1 2 T ) t θu 2 1 du) F η 1 ρ t ] 2. (8) The optimal strategy π is identified by ( ) πt 1 ρh t = θ t + ασ(t, η) (1 ρ 2 )(c + hud W, (9) u) θ stands for the market price of risk θ t = µ σ h t is the integrand of the integral representation e (1 ρ2 )(α H 1 T T θ 2 2 t dt) = c + h td W t. Q, defined by d Q = E dp T ( ρ θ W ) is a new measure and W t = W t + ρ θudu is a Q-Brownian motion.

Full information Problem: An agent is trading with a portfolio of stocks S in order to solve the optimization problem ( to minimize E e α( T π t d S t H) ) over all π Π(F S,η ), (1) where π t represents the number of stocks held at time t and is adapted to the filtration F S,η t and H = f (η) is written on the non traded asset. the agent builds his strategy using all market information, and G t = F S,η t = A t; This problem was earlier studied in, e.g., Musiela and Zariphopoulou (24), Henderson and Hobson (25), Davis (26), for the basis risk model with constant µ and σ. Assuming the Markov structure of b and a, Musiela and Zariphopoulou gave an explicit expression for the related value function. Under suitable conditions on the coefficients of the model [i.e. 1) 3)] and assuming H = f (η) and bounded, we show that the value process related to (1) coincides with (8), and that the optimal amount of money depends only on the observation coming from the non traded asset.

Comparison Therefore, under conditions 1) 3) and assuming H = f (η) and bounded we recover the result of Musiela and Zariphopoulou in a non Markovian setting we find that the optimal amount of money depends only on the observation coming from the non traded asset. Indeed, the two optimization problems (partial/full information) are equivalent: the corresponding value processes coincide and the optimal strategies of these problems are related by the equality π partial t = π full t S t. = This means that, if H = f (η), the optimal dollar amount invested in the assets is the same in both problems and is based only on the information coming from the non traded asset η. = In other words, the information coming from η is sufficient for the full information problem...

Sufficiency of filtrations Let V t(a ) and V t(g ) be the value processes of the problems respectively in the cases of full and partial information, i.e. V t(a ) = ess inf E[e α( T t π uds u H ) A t], π Π(A ) V t(g ) = ess inf E[e α( T t π uds u H) G t]. π Π(G ) We express the optimization problem as the set OΠ = {(Ω, A, A, P), S, H} and we give the following definition of sufficient filtration. DEFINITION The filtration G is said to be sufficient for the optimization problem OΠ if V (G ) = V (A ), i.e., if T inf π Π(A ) E[e α( π uds u H) T ] = inf π Π(G ) E[e α( π uds u H) ]. (11) Our aim is to give sufficient conditions for (11).

Assumptions and G projections We recall the A -decomposition of S S t = S + N t + λ ud N u. We make the following assumptions, which are similar to the previous ones, but are written with respect to A instead of F (so they are stronger): A ) N is G -predictable, B ) any G -martingale is an A -local martingale, C ) the filtration G is continuous, D ) λ and N, m(g) (for any G -local martingale m(g)) are G -predictable, E ) H is a G T -measurable bounded random variable, F ) T λ2 t d N t C, P a.s.. Similarly to previously, we can prove that under conditions A ), B ), C ) Ŝ t = E(S t G t) = S + λ ud N u + N t, Nt = ( d N,m(g) u d m(g) u )dm u(g) + L t(g), for any G local martingale m(g). N, m(g) G = N, m(g) for any G local martingale m(g), where A G denotes the dual G -predictable projection of A.

Sufficient conditions Now, we give necessary and sufficient conditions for G to be sufficient. PROPOSITION Let conditions A ), B ), C ) and F ) be satisfied. Then the two value processes V t(a ) and V t(g ) coincide if and only if H is G T -measurable and bounded and the process V t(a ) satisfies the BSDE Y t = Y + 1 2 (ψ uk 2 u + λ uy u) 2 Y u d N u + ψ ud N u + Ñt, Y T = e αh, (12) where Ñ is a G -local martingale orthogonal to N and k 2 t = d N t/d N t. The necessity part relies essentially on the decomposition of N which enables to prove that, if V t(a ) = V t(g ), the BSDE satisfied by V t(a ) can be written as Eq. (12). Remark Note that we do not require condition D, which is needed to find the equivalent problem in the partial information case.

If F S G, we can reduce the necessary and sufficient conditions as follows. COROLLARY If F S G and C and F be satisfied. Then a) V t(a ) = V t(g ) if and only if H is G T -measurable and bounded and λ is G -predictable. b) If in addition condition B ) is satisfied and H is bounded and G T -measurable, then V (A ) = V (G ) if and only if λ is G -predictable. Relying on the previous results, we have THEOREM Let conditions A ) F ) be satisfied. Then V t(a ) = V t(g ) and the filtration G is sufficient. REMARK Note that under conditions A) F) the filtration G is sufficient for the auxiliary filtration F = Ft S G, i.e. for the optimization problem OΠ = {(Ω, F, F, P), S, H}.

Thank you.

Appendix References M.H.A. Davis, Optimal hedging with basis risk. From stochastic calculus to mathematical finance, Springer, Berlin, 26, 169 187. F. Delbaen, P. Grandits, T. Rheinländer, D. Samperi, M. Schweizer and C. Stricker, Exponential Hedging and Entropic Penalties. Mathematical Finance 12, N.2, 22, 99 123. V. Henderson and D.G. Hobson, Real options with constantrelative risk aversion, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 29, N.7, 25, 1237 1266 P. Lakner, Optimal trading strategy for an investor: the case of partial information. Stochastic Proccess. Appl. 76, 1998, 77 97. M. Mania, R. Tevzadze and T. Toronjadze, Mean-variance Hedging Under Partial Information. SIAM J.Control Optim. 47, N. 5, 28, pp. 2381-249. M. Musiela and T. Zariphopoulou, An example of indifference prices under exponential preferences, Finance Stochast. 8, 24, 229 239. H. Pham and M. C. Quenez, Optimal portfolio in partially observed stochastic volatility models. Ann. Appl. Probab. 11, N.1, 21, 21 238. R. Tevzadze, Solvability of backward stochastic differential equations with quadratic growth. Stochastic Proccess. Appl. 118, 28, 53 515. G. Zohar, A generalized Cameron-Martin formula with applications to partially observed dynamic portfolio optimization. Math. Finance 11, N.4, 21, 475 494.