working paper Fiscal Policy, Government Institutions, and Sovereign Creditworthiness By Bernardin Akitoby and Thomas Stratmann No.

Similar documents
IV. THE BENEFITS OF FURTHER FINANCIAL INTEGRATION IN ASIA

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Resource Windfalls and Emerging Market Sovereign Bond Spreads: The Role of Political Institutions

Macroeconomic policies and Business cycle: The Role of. Institutions in SAARC Countries. Samina Sabir and Khushbakht Zahid 1

What Firms Know. Mohammad Amin* World Bank. May 2008

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation. Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR

Does the Confidence Fairy Exist?

Managing Sudden Stops. Barry Eichengreen and Poonam Gupta

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Determinants and Effects of Fiscal Stabilization: New Evidence from Time-Varying Estimates *

"Inequality, Growth and Investment"

CORRELATION BETWEEN MALTESE AND EURO AREA SOVEREIGN BOND YIELDS

REGULATION, INVESTMENT, AND GROWTH ACROSS COUNTRIES

Macroeconomic Management in Emerging-Market Economies with Open Capital Accounts. Outline

FISCAL CONSOLIDATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN. Ahmed Waqar Qasim Muhammad Ali Kemal Omer Siddique

Chapter URL:

Unemployment in Australia What do existing models tell us?

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy

Discussion of Like a Good Neighbor: Monetary Policy, Financial Stability, and the Distribution of Risk

Estimating Trade Restrictiveness Indices

Response of Output Fluctuations in Costa Rica to Exchange Rate Movements and Global Economic Conditions and Policy Implications

Does money matter in the euro area?: Evidence from a new Divisia index 1. Introduction

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

International Journal of Advance Research in Computer Science and Management Studies

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Public Debt, Sovereign Default Risk and Shadow Economy

Cross-Country Studies of Unemployment in Australia *

Fiscal Policy and Financial Markets

Global Slack as a Determinant of US Inflation *

Discussion of Michael Klein s Capital Controls: Gates and Walls Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, September 2012

A formal look at the negative interbank rate

CONSERVATIVE CENTRAL BANKS: HOW CONSERVATIVE SHOULD A CENTRAL BANK BE?

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

Athens University of Economics and Business Department of Economics MSc in Economics INTERNATIONAL MACROECONOMICS

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

FINANCIAL INTEGRATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE OF PORTFOLIO EQUITY FLOWS TO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

PUBLIC DEBT AND INEQUALITY Alessandro Missale University of Milano. Winter School on Inequality and Social Welfare Theory Canazei 13 January 2014

Short-run effects of fiscal policy on GDP and employment in Sweden

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

A Regional Early Warning System Prototype for East Asia

International evidence of tax smoothing in a panel of industrial countries

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

Are Retailers More Sensitive to Changes in Business Conditions Compared to Wholesalers?

Output Volatility in Emerging Market and Developing Countries:

The Effects of Public Debt on Economic Growth and Gross Investment in India: An Empirical Evidence

DEVELOPMENT OF FINANCIAL SECTOR AN EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM SAARC COUNTRIES

REDUCTION OF EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION IN OECD COUNTRIES: ITS DRIVING FORCES

Pension Reform in Montana

Fiscal Policy: Ready for The Next Shock?

South Sudan, the EAC and East African Monetary Union

By! O Wog wja.l~j~j~j 9PHXS Y9PY'

Monetary Policy in Pakistan: The Role of Foreign Exchange and Credit Markets

Interest groups and investment: A further test of the Olson hypothesis

Financial Integration and Fiscal Policy ℵ

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Can Emerging Economies Decouple?

L-6 The Fiscal Multiplier debate and the eurozone response to the crisis. Carlos San Juan Mesonada Jean Monnet Professor University Carlos III Madrid

Cross Sectional Analysis of Financial Development on Economic Growth. Jeremy Carmack Hari Krishnam Haidan Zhou

GROWTH DETERMINANTS IN LOW-INCOME AND EMERGING ASIA: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS

Fiscal Transparency, Fiscal Performance and Credit Ratings

Supporting information for. Mainstream or niche? Vote-seeking incentives and the programmatic strategies of political parties

The Global Macroeconomy

Monetary Economics Semester 2, 2003

The impact of changing diversification on stability and growth in a regional economy

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

INDEPENDENT FISCAL COUNCILS & FISCAL POLITICS Comments on Beetsma, Debrun, and Sloof (2016)

Long-term uncertainty and social security systems

Financial market interdependence

Volume Author/Editor: Kenneth Singleton, editor. Volume URL:

NEW CONSENSUS MACROECONOMICS AND KEYNESIAN CRITIQUE. Philip Arestis Cambridge Centre for Economic and Public Policy University of Cambridge

Estimating a Fiscal Reaction Function for Greece

Analysing Inflation: Monetary and Real Theories

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Macroprudential Regulation and Economic Growth in Low-Income Countries: Lessons from ESRC-DFID Project ES/L012022/1

Does External Debt Lead to Growth in the Presence of Quality Institutions?

MONEY SUPPLY ROLE IN ECONOMIC AND INDUSTRIAL GROWTH: THE CASE OF JORDAN ( )

Ownership structure, regulation, and bank risk-taking: evidence from Korean banking industry

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

September 21, 2016 Bank of Japan

Stock Prices, Foreign Exchange Reserves, and Interest Rates in Emerging and Developing Economies in Asia

Monetary policy and the yield curve

Do We Need a New Conceptual Framework for Government Debt Management?

Political and Institutional Determinants of the Cyclicality of Fiscal Policy: Evidence from the OECD and Latin America

Commentary: Should the European Central Bank and the Federal Reserve Be Concerned about Fiscal Policy?

Politics of Fiscal Policy: A Global Perspective

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Rising public debt-to-gdp can harm economic growth

Macroeconomic Impact of the Subprime Crisis

DETERMINANTS OF EMERGING MARKET BOND SPREAD: EVIDENCE FROM TEN AFRICAN COUNTRIES ABSTRACT

Potential drivers of insurers equity investments

INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC STUDIES

Documento de Trabajo. ISSN (edición impresa) ISSN (edición electrónica)

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

Monetary Policy rule in the presence of persistent excess liquidity: the case of Trinidad and Tobago

Foreign Exchange Intervention and Central Bank Independence: The Latin American Experience

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

THRESHOLD EFFECT OF INFLATION ON MONEY DEMAND IN MALAYSIA

What Drives Fiscal Multipliers? The Role of Private Debt and Wealth

Transcription:

No. 10-41 July 2010 working paper Fiscal Policy, Government Institutions, and Sovereign Creditworthiness By Bernardin Akitoby and Thomas Stratmann The ideas presented in this research are the authors and do not represent official positions of the Mercatus Center at George Mason University. This paper is a chapter in the forthcoming book, Sovereign Debt: From Safety to Default, Robert W. Kolb, ed. (Hoboken, NJ: J. Wiley & Sons).

Fiscal Policy, Government Institutions, and Sovereign Creditworthiness Bernardin Akitoby Deputy Division Chief in the African Department of the International Monetary Fund Thomas Stratmann Professor of economics, George Mason University 1 I. Introduction The international financial crisis has brought to the forefront the role of fiscal policy and institutions in restoring confidence in financial markets. This raises a number of critical questions. First, how do financial markets react to fiscal policy shocks, such as changes in government spending or taxes? Second, do financial markets differentiate between currentexpenditure-based and revenue-based adjustments? Third, do financial markets discriminate between tax-financed and debt-financed spending? Fourth, to the extent that institutions shape fiscal outcomes, a critical question is whether fiscal variables interact with the political institutions to affect financial markets. Finally, do political institutions have some independent influence on financial markets beyond the fiscal and economic outcomes they shape? II. Analytical framework To investigate these questions, we use a conceptual framework that builds on the theory of sovereign risk pricing (Edwards, 1984) and the theoretical debate on whether the private sector s response to fiscal adjustment depends on the composition of fiscal adjustment (Alesina and Perotti, 1997) and institutions that shape the fiscal outcome (Persson and Tabellini, 2000). More specifically we introduce fiscal policy and institutions variables into the empirical model of sovereign risk pricing. We then derive a testable equation for spreads, which we estimate using panel data techniques (see Akitoby and Stratmann, 2008 and 2009). The data set for the dependent variable is the stripped spread obtained from the Emerging Markets Bond Index Global (EMBI Global). The EMBI Global tracks total returns for traded external debt instrument in emerging markets issued by sovereign and quasi-sovereign entities and covers 32 countries. For the choice of political institution variables, we consider the political system (presidential versus parliamentary); political constraints (Henisz, 2000); the Freedom House indexes of 1 This article is based on Akitoby and Stratmann (2008 and 2011).

2 political rights and civil liberties; the Kaufmann voice and accountability index; the democracy index (Polity) produced by the University of Maryland; the democratic accountability index of the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG); the ICRG political risk index; and whether there is an election in a particular year. Since many of these institutions are highly correlated, we will estimate separate regressions for each. For the fiscal variables, we include government revenues, current expenditures, and government investment. As for additional control variables, previous studies point to a large number of variables as possible determinants of sovereign risk. We aim for a parsimonious empirical model, capturing the key indicators of liquidity, solvency, and macroeconomic fundamentals. We therefore include the ratio of total debt outstanding to gross national income (GNI). This measure is a key indicator of a country s long-run solvency. Higher debt to GNI increases the default probability, and hence the sovereign risk. This variable is predicted to be positively associated with the spread. Other control variables include the ratio of foreign exchange reserves to GDP, the inflation rate, the output gap, default history, and the regional spread index. Foreign exchange reserves-to-gdp is expected to reduce spreads, because it is a measure of a country s capacity to service external debt. The inflation rate is a key indicator of economic stability. Monetization of fiscal deficits can lead to high inflation, which reduces growth by raising the cost of acquiring capital. For this reason, higher inflation will tend to increase sovereign risk. We include the output gap to control for the economic cycle and monetary conditions because recent work has shown that the timing and type of fiscal adjustment also depend on the economic cycle. We include a country s default history as one of the control variables and hypothesize that it has a positive coefficient because defaults increase risk. Another control variable is a regional spread index that controls for contagion effects; the regions are Africa, Asia, Europe, and Latin America. All regressions include country and year fixed effects. III. Key findings How do financial markets react to fiscal policy shocks, such as changes in government spending or taxes? We find that revenue increases and current spending cuts reduce spreads. The impact of government investment is not statistically significant. Thus the size of public investment may not matter to investors. Quality of public investments may matter, but our data do not speak to this issue. Overall, these findings support the hypothesis that government revenues and current spending decisions affect financial markets. Do financial markets differentiate between current-expenditure-based and revenue-based adjustments? Contrary to the established view, financial markets favor revenue-driven adjustments more than current-spending-driven adjustments. Deficit-reducing tax increases of 1 percentage point lower interest rates on sovereign bonds by 20 percent, while a similar reduction in current spending lower interest rates by only about 10 percent. Financial markets also react to the composition of spending, with cuts in current spending lowering spreads more than cuts in investment.

3 The result on the merits of spending-based versus revenue-based fiscal adjustments is consistent with the hypothesis that the three channels on which the success of spending-based fiscal adjustments rests labor markets, expectation, and credibility may not work well in emerging economies. First, in emerging economies, the transmission through labor markets may be hampered by labor-market segmentation, the dominant role of government employment and regulation, and the low degree of labor mobility across sectors. Moreover, wage earners in emerging economies represent a smaller proportion of total employment than in industrialized countries. Second, the expectation channel may be ineffective as liquidity constraints inhibit consumption smoothing. Finally, the credibility channel may not be effective if the social returns on government spending in developing countries are perceived to be higher than in developed countries. Do financial markets discriminate between tax-financed and debt-financed spending? Financial markets do prefer the former to the latter. A one percentage point increase in current spending lowers spreads by 9.5 percent if financed by taxes, but will raise spreads by about 8.5 percent if financed by debt. If a country finances current spending by raising revenue, the increase in revenue will reduce the spread, thereby offsetting the impact of increasing current spending on spreads; whereas, in the case of the debt-financed current spending, the increase in the country s indebtedness will further heighten the country risk. Put differently, tax-financed current spending is not equivalent to debt-financed current spending, as far as the impact on spreads is concerned. We find that a one percentage point increase in debt to GNI leads to about a 1 percent increase in spreads, which implies that countries with higher debt are penalized in international markets. Similarly, like Edwards (1986), we also find that financial markets are sensitive to changes in reserves, evidence that liquidity concerns are important in the international investor s decision. A one percentage point increase in reserves to GDP causes the spreads to fall by about 4.5 percent. The magnitudes of the estimated coefficients on the debt and reserves indicate that each percentage increase in reserves is four times as effective in reducing spreads as each percentage reduction in debt. Do fiscal variables interact with political institutions to affect financial markets? For example, for the same fiscal outcome, do market participants differentiate between right- and left-wing governments, or between majoritarian and proportional electoral systems? We find strong evidence that financial markets penalize left-wing regimes that undertake spendingdriven expansion. The penalty is estimated at about 3 percent higher interest rates. This may be because right-wing governments are often associated with fiscal conservatism and a smaller government size while left-wing governments are often associated with a larger government and broader social transfer programs. The findings also show that financial markets reward left-wing governments by more than right-wing governments when government revenues increase. Put differently, right-wing governments get lower benefits from a revenue-based consolidation. One reason for this could be that government spending is already low when the government is conservative; so that the marginal benefit from consolidation is less than if government spending is high. With regard to the differentiation between majoritarian and proportional electoral systems, the results show that financial markets penalize majoritarian regimes as opposed to

4 proportional regimes that undertake spending-driven expansion, presumably because these regimes are often associated with larger government and broader transfer programs. This finding is also consistent with the view that the majority-rule countries tend to have what is called in the United States pork barrel spending, which is spending targeted to electoral districts. Financial markets may believe that pork barrel spending increases when current expenditures and government investment rise. Much of what may be contained in the category of government investment (building roads and bridges) may have low returns under a majoritarian system when it is spending targeted to districts or swing states. Finally, do political institutions have some independent influence on financial markets beyond the fiscal and economic outcomes they shape? We find that political institutions matter for financial markets. The findings are robust to a wide range of indicators of institutional quality. First, democracy, regardless of how it is measured the Kaufmann voice and accountability index, the Freedom House index of political rights, the Polity index, or the ICRG democratic accountability index lowers spreads. The effects of democratic institutions are substantial. For example, a one standard deviation in the ICRG democratic accountability index decreases spreads by about 25 percent. More civil liberties also lower spreads because civil liberties foster democracy. A one-point reduction in political rights, as measured by the Freedom House index on a one to six scale, reduces spreads by 8.5 percent, and the same reduction in civil rights reduces spreads by 19 percent. These results forcefully suggest that financial markets are giving a premium to democratic regimes. Put differently, the markets tend to penalize nondemocratic regimes by charging them relatively higher interest rates. Because financial markets affect economic development through better resource allocation and risk diversification, our findings seem to suggest that democracy also matters for growth. Since we find that more government accountability, as measured by the ICRG index and the Kaufmann index, lowers spreads, our results lend support to the view that checks and balances increase creditworthiness. We find a negative and statistically significant sign on the ICRG political risk variable. This shows that lower political risk reduces spreads, which confirms the widely held view that financial markets dislike political risk. We also find some evidence that sovereign borrowing costs tend to be higher in election than in off-election years. This corroborates Block and Vaaler s (2004) finding that rating agencies and bondholders view elections negatively, presumably because elections are associated with uncertainty about the future. IV. Policy implications This study suggests a number of policy implications for countries seeking to lower their borrowing cost on international capital markets. First, a country can pursue either revenuebased or expenditure-based fiscal adjustments, when fiscal adjustment is required to reassure financial markets. However, a country would be better off pursuing revenue-driven fiscal adjustments, whenever the labor market, the expectation, and the credibility channels are not present. Second, a country would be better in cutting current spending instead of public investment, because financial markets pay attention to the composition of fiscal

5 consolidation. Third, since financial markets view high debt ratios negatively, reductions of debt through appropriate fiscal policy and debt management can lower spreads. Fourth, given the importance that the capital market attaches to the reserves-to-gdp ratio, government can aim at increasing their foreign reserves position through appropriate macroeconomic and structural policies. Finally, a country would be better off if it strengthened checks and balances and democratic accountability. References Akitoby, B. and T. Stratmann. 2008. Fiscal policy and financial markets. The Economic Journal 118 (November): 1971 1985. Akitoby, B. and T. Stratmann. 2011. The value of institutions for financial markets: evidence from emerging markets. Review of World Economics. Forthcoming. Alesina, A., and R. Perotti. 1997. Fiscal adjustments in OECD countries: composition and macroeconomic effects. IMF Staff Papers 44 (June): 210-248. Block, S. and P. Vaaler. 2004. The Price of Democracy: Sovereign Risk Ratings, Bond Spreads and Political Business Cycles in Developing Countries. Journal of International Money and Finance 23: 917 946. Edwards, S. 1984. LDC s foreign borrowing and default risk: an empirical investigation. The American Economic Review 74: 726-734. Edwards, S. 1986. The pricing of bonds and bank loans in international markets: an empirical analysis of developing countries foreign borrowing. European Economic Review 30: 565-589. Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 2000. Political Economics: explaining economic policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. About The Authors Bernardin Akitoby holds a PhD in economics from University of Montreal and degrees in business administration, finance, and accounting. He is currently deputy division chief in the African department of the International Monetary Fund. Prior to joining the IMF, he worked in the World Bank s Research Department. Akitoby s research has been published in academic journals, including The Economic Journal, European Journal of Political Economy, Review of World Economics, Economie Appliquée, and Revue Economique. His research interests include real business cycles, growth, exchange rate, hyperinflation, fiscal

6 policy, fiscal procyclicality, public investment and public-private partnerships, financial markets, economic institutions, and sovereign risk. Thomas Stratmann is University Professor of Economics and Law at George Mason University. He holds a PhD in economics from the University of Maryland. He held previous appointments at the Montana State University and is Research Professor at the ifo Institute at the University of Munich, Germany. Stratmann s research has been published in in many economics and political science journals including the American Economic Review, American Journal of Political Science, American Political Science Review, Journal of Political Economy, Journal of Law and Economics, and Public Choice. Thomas Stratmann s research interests include political economy, law and economics, public finance, financial markets, and fiscal policy.