How Do Producers Decide the Right Moment to Price Their Crop? An Investigation in the Canadian Wheat Market. by Fabio Mattos and Stefanie Fryza

Similar documents
2010 CAES Risk Management Workshop. Behavioural Dimensions of Decision Making in Grain Marketing. Fabio Mattos Stefanie Fryza

Farmer s Income Shifting Option in Post-harvest Forward Contracting

Development of a Market Benchmark Price for AgMAS Performance Evaluations. Darrel L. Good, Scott H. Irwin, and Thomas E. Jackson

Comparison of Hedging Cost with Other Variable Input Costs. John Michael Riley and John D. Anderson

The Preference for Round Number Prices. Joni M. Klumpp, B. Wade Brorsen, and Kim B. Anderson

Dynamic Decision Making in Agricultural Futures and Options Markets by Fabio Mattos, Philip Garcia and Joost M. E. Pennings

New Generation Grain Marketing Contracts

Cost of Forward Contracting Hard Red Winter Wheat

ACE 427 Spring Lecture 6. by Professor Scott H. Irwin

Advisory Service Marketing Profiles for Corn over

Effects of Price Volatility and Surging South American Soybean Production on Short-Run Soybean Basis Dynamics by. Rui Zhang and Jack Houston

Hedging Effectiveness around USDA Crop Reports by Andrew McKenzie and Navinderpal Singh

Advisory Service Marketing Profiles for Corn Over

Are New Crop Futures and Option Prices for Corn and Soybeans Biased? An Updated Appraisal. Katie King and Carl Zulauf

Forward Contracting Costs for Illinois Corn and Soybeans: Implications for Producer Pricing Strategies

Discussion: What Have We Learned from the New Suite of Risk Management Programs of the Food, Conservation, and Energy Act of 2008?

Portfolios of Agricultural Market Advisory Services: How Much Diversification is Enough?

Improving Your Crop Marketing Skills: Basis, Cost of Ownership, and Market Carry

Commodity Prices, Volatility and Risk: Is the Soybean Market Becoming Riskier?

The Pricing Performance of Market Advisory Services in Corn and Soybeans Over : A Non-Technical Summary

The Performance of Agricultural Market Advisory Services in Marketing Wheat

Testing the Effectiveness of Using a Corn Call or a Feeder Cattle Put for Feeder Cattle Price Protection. Hernan A. Tejeda and Dillon M.

factors that affect marketing

Have Commodity Index Funds Increased Price Linkages between Commodities? by Jeffrey H. Dorfman and Berna Karali

Innovative Hedging and Financial Services: Using Price Protection to Enhance the Availability of Agricultural Credit

1997 Pricing Performance of Market Advisory Services for Corn and Soybeans. Thomas E. Jackson, Scott H. Irwin, and Darrel L. Good

Saturday, January 5, Notes from Al

More on Commodity Prices, Volatility and Risk: Is the Corn Market Becoming Riskier?

Considerations When Using Grain Contracts

Understanding Markets and Marketing

IMPORTANT INFORMATION ABOUT THE FARMERS EQUITY TRUST AND THE G3 FARMERS EQUITY PLAN. Background

Wheat Basis Levels. Here is an example of basis calculated without an exchange rate adjustment to the futures price.

Performance of market advisory firms

Considerations When Using Grain Contracts

Relative Importance of Price vs. Yield variability in Crop Revenue Risk

Crops Marketing and Management Update

Crops Marketing and Management Update

Passive Investors and Managed Money in Commodity Futures. Part 3: Volatility. Prepared for: The CME Group. Prepared by:

Chart Pattern Secrets

Recent Convergence Performance of CBOT Corn, Soybean, and Wheat Futures Contracts

Contracts & Managing Risk

INPUT CAPITAL CORP. ANNOUNCES RECORD CANOLA SALES IN FY2018 Q1 RESULTS

HEDGING WITH FUTURES AND BASIS

Cash Ethanol Cross-Hedging Opportunities

Forward and Futures Contracts

Impacts of Linking Wheat Countercyclical Payments to Prices for Classes of Wheat

Agricultural FINANCE Monitor

Hedging Carcass Beef to Reduce the Short-Term Price Risk of Meat Packers

Econ 338c. April 12, 2007

Refined Oils Weekly Wire 05/25/2012

Journal of Cooperatives

The WTO and YOU. Crop Production Week CWB day January 15, Dustin Gosnell Director, Strategic Planning & Corporate Policy

Crops Marketing and Management Update

Forecasting Crop Prices using Leading Economic Indicators and Bayesian Model Selection. Yu Wang and Jeffrey H. Dorfman

Debt and Input Misallocation in Farm Supply and Marketing Cooperatives: A DEA Approach

Chart Pattern Secrets

Evidence of Farmer Forward Pricing Behavior. by Kevin McNew and Wesley Musser

Probability Distortion and Loss Aversion in Futures Hedging

Portfolios of Agricultural Market Advisory Services: How Much Diversification is Enough?

Non-Convergence of CME Hard Red Winter Wheat Futures and the Impact of Excessive Grain Inventories in Kansas

Information Content of USDA Rice Reports and Price Reactions of Rice Futures

Evaluation of Market Advisory Service Performance in Hogs. Rick L. Webber, Scott H. Irwin, Darrel L. Good and Joao Martines-Filho 1

Cost of Forward Contracting Wheat in Kansas

Bank Risk Ratings and the Pricing of Agricultural Loans

The Performance of Agricultural Market Advisory Services in Corn and Soybeans. Scott H. Irwin, Darrel L. Good and Joao Martines-Filho 1.

Evaluating the Hedging Potential of the Lean Hog Futures Contract

Return and Risk Performance of Basis Strategy: A Case Study of Illinois Corn and Soybeans, Crop Years

Has the Presence of the LDP Created Marketing Havoc in Missouri? Joe Parcell, Assistant Professor & Extension Economist

Basis Risk for Rice. Yoshie Saito Lord and Steven C. Turner Agricultural and Applied Economics The University of Georgia Athens Georgia

Informed Storage: Understanding the Risks and Opportunities

EC Grain Pricing Alternatives

The Value of USDA Outlook Information: An Investigation Using Event Study Analysis. Scott H. Irwin, Darrel L. Good and Jennifer K.

Farm/Ranch Management Decisions Under Drought

Crop Marketing 101. Prairie Oat Growers Association Annual meeting Banff, Alberta December 4, 2014

Provide a brief review of futures. Carefully review alternative market

Basis: The price difference between the cash price at a specific location and the price of a specific futures contract.

UK Grain Marketing Series January 19, Todd D. Davis Assistant Extension Professor. Economics

Performance of Statistical Arbitrage in Future Markets

Hedging Spot Corn: An Examination of the Minneapolis Grain Exchange s Cash Settled Corn Contract

Technical Report Coincident and Leading Economic Indicators Nebraska

MARKETING ALTERNATIVES

Farm Radio Connects. Research Conducted by Millennium Research

Understanding the Canola Futures Contract. Introduction. Background

AGBE 321. Problem Set 5 Solutions

The Common Crop (COMBO) Policy

ACE 427 Spring Lecture 11. Technical Analysis. by Professor Scott H. Irwin

Loan Deficiency Payments versus Countercyclical Payments: Do We Need Both for a Price Safety Net?

New Generation Grain Contracts Decision Contracts

Price Responses in Forward Contracting: Do We Limit The Upside And Expose The Downside?

Selected economic indicators of banking, agricultural and business conditions in the Eighth Federal Reserve District

2015 Market Outlook. DTN/The Progressive Farmer 2014 Ag Summit December 9, Darin Newsom DTN Senior Analyst

Influences on the Market. Common Marketing Terms. Types of Contracts. Terms of Contracts

BACK TO THE BASICS: WHAT DOES THE MARKET TELL US ABOUT HARVEST GRAIN BASIS

Commodity products. Grain and Oilseed Hedger's Guide

Do Roll Returns Really Exist? An Analysis of the S&P GSCI. Paul E. Peterson

Agricultural and Rural Finance Markets in Transition Proceedings of Regional Research Committee NC-1014 Minneapolis, Minnesota October 3-4, 2005

Measuring and Explaining Skewness in Pricing Distributions Implied from Livestock Options

GRAIN MARKETS SENSITIVE TO EXPORTS, SOUTH AMERICAN WEATHER

February 2018 Monthly Commodity Market Overview Newsletter. Stock Index Futures

Adam Pukalo Commodity Futures Advisor TECHNICALS & TRENDS. August 2016 Edition. Highlighted: Canola, Wheat, Soybeans & Cattle

Transcription:

How Do Producers Decide the Right Moment to Price Their Crop? An Investigation in the Canadian Wheat Market by Fabio Mattos and Stefanie Fryza Suggested citation format: Mattos, F., and S. Fryza. 213. How Do Producers Decide the Right Moment to Price Their Crop? An Investigation in the Canadian Wheat Market. Proceedings of the NCCC-134 Conference on Applied Commodity Price Analysis, Forecasting, and Market Risk Management. St. Louis, MO. [http://www.farmdoc.illinois.edu/nccc134].

How Do Producers Decide the Right Moment to Price Their Crop? An Investigation in the Canadian Wheat Market Fabio Mattos Stefanie Fryza * Paper presented at the NCCC-134 Conference on Applied Commodity Price Analysis, Forecasting, and Market Risk Management St. Louis, Missouri, April 22-23, 213 Copyright 213 by Fabio Mattos and Stefanie Fryza. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies. * Fabio Mattos (fmattos@unl.edu) is assistant professor in the Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Nebraska, and Stefanie Fryza (Stefanie.Fryza@ad.umanitoba.ca) is research associate in the Department of Agribusiness and Agricultural Economics, University of Manitoba.

How Do Producers Decide the Right Moment to Price Their Crop? An Investigation in the Canadian Wheat Market This research investigated the timing of marketing decisions in the Canadian wheat market. Cox proportional hazard models were estimated to explore how the timing of producers decisions were affected by market-based variable, which included an indicator showing whether current prices were above producers benchmark on a given day, 1-day average spread between current prices and producers benchmark, 1-day price trend and price volatility over 1 days. Marketing data for 17,338 producers who executed 59,184 transactions between 23/4 and 28/9 were used in the analysis. Overall results indicate that all variables affected timing decisions in producers marketing choices. However, the signs of the estimated coefficients tended to vary across contracts and years, suggesting that producers could change their pricing behavior over time and response to the covariates could also depend on characteristics of the contracts and how they relate to producers marketing strategies. Keywords: grain marketing, decision making, timing, wheat INTRODUCTION Agricultural economists have long been interested in how producers make marketing decisions and what variables influence their decision-making process. One of the main points in this field has been how producers choose the exact day to sell their crop. Previous studies have explored factors that explain how producers select marketing instruments (e.g. cash or futures contracts), such as price signals, farm size, past performance, education, among others (Isengildina and Hudson, 21; McNew and Musser, 22; Meulenberg and Pennings, 22; Dorfman and Karali, 21). However, little work has been done to investigate how producers choose the right moment to sell their crop. Two studies that have explored this point were Anderson and Brorsen (25) and Cabrini de Colonna (26). Anderson and Brorsen (25) obtained data on wheat purchases and prices paid from three Oklahoma elevators between 1992 and 21 and investigated whether producers followed any short-run pattern in selling their grain. They found evidence that producers would sell grain after price increases and hold it after price decreases, and that seasonality and day of the week would also play a role in their choices. Cabrini de Colonna (26) investigated how market advisory services developed marketing recommendations focusing on advisory programs tracked by the University of Illinois AgMAS project between 1995 and 24. Results suggested that programs tended to deliver sell (buy) recommendations after price increases (decreases), but this behavior was found to exhibit small magnitude. In addition, Cabrini de Colonna (26) explored the existence of loss realization aversion but found no evidence that the holding period of advisory programs futures positions was related to whether they represent a gain or a loss. 2

The objective of this research was to explore variables that affect producers marketing decisions related to the time when they price their crop. The grain marketing system in Canada offers a unique opportunity to explore how producers make decisions. During the period encompassed in this research, all wheat produced in Western Canada and sold for human consumption and export had to be marketed through the Canadian Wheat Board (CWB), which was the largest grain marketing agency in Canada and offered several pricing alternatives providing distinct combinations of return, risk and cash flow. The pool was the most traditional program and worked by pooling all wheat from producers to be traded by the CWB. Pool revenues were then distributed such that all producers received the same final price per unit regardless of when and to whom their grain was sold. During the crop year the CWB provided an expected price, which was its estimate of what the pool price would be at the end of the crop year and was often seen as a benchmark to alert producers as to whether to keep their wheat in the pool or to price their grain outside the pool. Marketing contracts (collectively known as Producer Payment Options PPO) were offered by the CWB in the 2/1 crop year, allowing producers to make their own marketing decisions in terms of when and how to price their grain. Producers could sell their wheat using any combination of these marketing contracts and the pool. Since all producers had to market their grain through the CWB, it was possible to follow exactly when they chose to market their grain, what market conditions were prevalent when they made their decisions, and what price they received. Data was made available by the CWB for the crop years 23/4 through 28/9 for all producers growing Canada Western Red Spring (CWRS) wheat. There were data on all producers with information indicating (i) type of contract used to market wheat, (ii) tonnes delivered, (iii) date when producer priced grain, (iv) final price received by each producer and (v) province. Another data set was also obtained with additional information on harvest pace showing how much of the crop was harvested on a weekly basis in each province and daily prices in the wheat market. This study uses a unique data set of wheat producers to perform a comprehensive analysis of marketing decisions. Results from this research can shed more light on the decision-making process in grain marketing, particularly on the importance of reference prices, trends and volatility in marketing decisions. As indicated by Hagedorn et al. (25), despite the importance of marketing in farm management it is alarming to realize that prevalent ideas about marketing decisions and performance still do not rely on a large body of evidence. This study aims to fill in these gaps and move us towards a more complete understanding of grain marketing. BACKGROUND The CWB has been the largest grain marketing agency in Canada and sole marketer for wheat produced in Western Canada. This region encompasses the provinces of Manitoba, Saskatchewan, Alberta and the Peace River area of British Columbia, accounting for approximately 9% of all wheat produced in the country. The CWB ceased to be the sole marketer of wheat following the 211/212 crop year 1, but during the time period encompassed by this study it centralized all wheat sales in Western Canada. The CWB offered different 1 The Canadian government introduced Bill C-18 on October 18, 211 to remove the CWB as the sole seller of wheat produced in Western Canada. The Marketing Freedom for Grain Farmers Act passed on November 28, 211 ratifying this change. 3

marketing alternatives allowing producers to choose a program that met their own needs and preferences regarding return, risk and cash flow. The oldest pricing alternative was pool pricing, which has been the main marketing program for Western Canada wheat since the 193s. The pool worked by pooling all wheat from producers in Western Canada to be traded by the CWB, giving the organization more market power to obtain higher prices. 2 Pool revenues were then distributed such that all producers received the same final price per unit regardless of when and to whom their grain was sold. With the pool, producers received an initial payment when deliveries were made to the grain handling facility, and additional payments as sales were completed throughout the crop year. The final pool price was known only after the end of the crop year, which goes from August 1 to July 31. However, during the crop year the CWB provided a projected price the Pool Return Outlook (PRO) which was its best estimate of what the pool price would be at the end of the crop year. 3 The PRO price was often seen as a benchmark that could be used to alert producers as to whether to keep their wheat in the pool or to price their grain outside the pool using marketing contracts. Marketing contracts collectively known as PPO were developed by the CWB to allow producers to price their own grain and provide them flexibility to manage their cash flow. These contracts were first offered in the 21/2 crop year and allowed producers to make their own marketing decisions. However, the execution of these contracts still had to go through the CWB. PPO contracts also differed from pool accounts in terms of payment schedule. Producers still received an initial payment when they delivered their wheat to the grain handling facility, but their final payment would come within 1 business days of delivery. Hence producers who used these marketing contracts could receive their full payment before the end of the crop year. PPO contracts encompassed five marketing contracts for wheat developed by the CWB: Early Payment Options (EPO), Fixed Price Contracts (FPC), Basis Price Contracts (BPC), Daily Price Contracts (DPC) and FlexPro. The EPO was mainly used for cash flow management and its price was just a fixed proportion of the expected pool price. The FPC offered a daily fixed price that was derived from the wheat futures contract traded at the Minneapolis Grain Exchange (MGE). In principle, the FPC resembled a forward contract by offering a fixed price for producers which already incorporated a futures price and basis. The BPC allowed producers to lock in a futures price (based on the MGE) and basis at different times during the marketing window, so their final price was only known after both components were determined. Thus the BPC was fundamentally a basis contract. The DPC and FlexPro offered producers a daily cash price based on wheat traded at the port of Vancouver. Note that the DPC was terminated after the 27/8 crop year and the FlexPro was offered in the 28/9 crop year. For the purpose of this paper, since the DPC and FlexPro were very similar in their functions and specifications; they are combined into one contract and generally referred to as DPC. Producers could sell their wheat using any combination of these marketing contracts and the pool. The marketing window during which producers could allocate their wheat to each marketing program varied across contracts. The marketing window for the FPC started about five 2 As a single agent selling Western Canadian wheat in the domestic and world markets, the CWB was able to consistently trade larger volumes than any individual producer in Canada. 3 A new PRO was usually released on the fourth Thursday of each month. 4

months before the beginning of the crop year and ended approximately three months into the crop year and it was essentially a pre-harvest contract. 4 The marketing window for the BPC also started several months before the beginning of the crop year and it would extend towards the end of the crop year. As for the DPC and FlexPro, the marketing window corresponded to the crop year. In addition, these two contracts had an extra characteristic: producers needed to indicate the total tonnage they wanted to price prior to the beginning of the crop year. RESEARCH METHOD The Cox proportional hazard model was used to estimate the effect of independent variables on producers selling decisions, following similar procedures by Coval and Shumway (25), Feng and Seasholes (25) and Seru et al. (21). This method provides a way to interpret the conditional probability of selling wheat and how this probability changes due to changes in the independent variables. The model describes how long producers wait until they decide to sell their grain assuming that the probability of selling wheat over the marketing window was not constant. The hazard rate was the conditional probability of selling grain on day t (conditional on not having sold it until day t-1). Hazard ratios obtained from the estimated model indicate the change in the hazard rate for a given change in the covariates, i.e. how much the conditional probability of selling wheat on day t changes as the values of covariates change. In this study the covariates include a gain/loss indicator showing whether the wheat price on day t was above or below the benchmark price adopted by producers, measures of price trend and price volatility in recent days, a price spread and dummies for days of the week. Thus the hazard ratio was modeled as in equation (1): h t 4 h t exp 1GIt 2Spreadt 3Trendt 3Volt jd jt (1) j 1 where h (t) represents the baseline hazard function, t the number of days the producer took to sell wheat since the beginning of the marketing window, GI the gain/loss indicator for producer i on day t, Spread was the difference on day t between current market price and the price expected to be paid in the pool, Trend represents the measure of price trend on day t, Vol the measure of price volatility on day t, and D represents dummy variables for days of the week. The gain/loss indicator was a binary variable that takes a value of 1 () when the current market price on day t was above (below) producer s benchmark. The benchmark adopted in this study was the expected CWB pool price (known as the PRO price). Thus it was assumed that producers compare current prices offered by marketing contracts with the price that the CWB expects to pay the pool. The price spread was calculated as the 1-day average of the difference between the current price and the PRO price. For example, the spread variable on day t was given by the average of the price spread in the previous 1 days. Positive (negative) values for this variable indicates current market prices were above (below) the expected pool price, and larger (smaller) values imply current prices increase (decrease) relative to the expected pool price. The measure of price trend was calculated as the difference between the current price on day t and the 4 The crop year goes from August 1 to July 31. 5

average price in the previous 1 days. Positive (negative) values of Trend i.e. price on day t above (below) the 1-day average price suggest recent uptrend (downtrend) in market prices. The measure of price volatility on day t was the standard deviation of current prices in the last 1 days, such that higher (lower) values of Vol indicate more (less) price volatility in the wheat market. The current market prices used in the analysis were different for each contract, reflecting their distinct characteristics. The FPC and DPC offer a specific price on any given day, i.e. there was a certain price that all producers who price with these contracts receive on day t, namely the fixed price for the FPC and the daily price for the DPC. Therefore, the fixed and daily prices were used to calculate the variables GI, spread, trend and volatility in the models for the FPC and DPC respectively. The BPC requires producers to lock in a futures price and a basis, which can be chosen from different maturities of the futures contract traded in the MGE. Since the data set provides no information on which maturity was chosen by producers, the nearby futures price was adopted as a reference and used to calculate all variables in the BPC model. Finally, there were four dummy variables for days of the week, ranging from Tuesday to Friday. When wheat was priced on a Tuesday (j=tuesday), D Tuesday =1 and D Wednesday = D Thursday = DFri day =. If wheat was priced on a Monday, all four dummy variables were equal to zero. The values of their estimated coefficients show the effect of each day of the week relative to Monday. DATA Data for this research were provided by the CWB and includes all producers who grew CWRS wheat from 23/4 through 28/9. 5 The dataset contains transactions made by each producer that indicates (i) what contracts they used to market their wheat, (ii) how many tonnes of wheat were allocated to each contract, (iii) dates when producers priced their wheat with contracts, and (iv) final price received by each producer for each marketing contract. Additional information on CWB pool prices for each crop year and daily prices for the PRO and MGE futures prices were also provided by the CWB. The sample used in the hazard model only includes producers who grew CWRS wheat in at least one of the six crop years and marketed their wheat using at least one of the three marketing contracts (FPC, BPC, DPC) considered in this study. The sample that meets these criteria contains 17,338 producers who executed 59,184 transactions. 6 The largest number of producers and transactions was concentrated in the FPC, followed by the BPC and DPC (Table 1). Note that, as opposed to the FPC and BPC, the DPC was developed in 25/6 and thus there was only four years of data for this contract. On average, producers made approximately three transactions when using these contracts to price their wheat. 5 Marketing contracts were first offered by the CWB in 2/1. However, very few producers used contracts in 2/1 and 21/2 and therefore these first two years were not included in the analysis. 6 The total number of producers who grew CWRS wheat between 23/4 and 28/9 was 67,798, thus the sample used in this study represents roughly 26% of all producers. 6

Table 1: Descriptive statistics of number of transactions, producers and quantity contracted All contracts FPC DPC BPC Transactions 59,184 36,826 8,324 14,34 Producers 17,338 15,556 2,761 4,981 Transaction/producer average 3.4 2.4 3.5 2.8 median 2. 2. 2. 2. maximum 88 28 69 39 The length of the marketing window varies across contracts and varied also within contracts during the sample period (Table 2). The FPC had the shortest marketing window at about eight months (except for 23/4). The DPC had a marketing window corresponding to the crop year and thus spanned for 12 months in all years of the sample. The BPC had the longest marketing window which ranged from approximately 16 to 22 months during the sample period. Table 2: Length of marketing window (number of days) a FPC DPC b BPC 23/4 158-492 24/5 248-489 25/6 246 365 487 26/7 247 365 487 27/8 248 366 666 28/9 25 365 665 (a) Numbers indicate total length of marketing window from the first to the last day contracts were available, but they could only be signed on business days during that period. (b) DPC was first offered in 25/6. Preliminary analysis of the data suggests that producers were more willing to price their wheat when current prices were going up and were above the PRO price (benchmark). Figure 1 shows charts with quantity of wheat contracted with the FPC during the marketing window (bars), along with the fixed price offered by the contract and the PRO price in each day (lines). An initial visualization of the charts suggests larger quantity of tonnes contracted during periods increasing prices and positive spreads between market price and PRO price. Figures 2 and 3 show similar charts for the BPC and DPC, respectively, and generally suggest the same type of response to prices. 7

8 Figure 1: PRO price (benchmark) and quantity contracted and price offered by Fixed Price Contracts (FPC) 2, 4, 6, 19 2 21 22 2/24/23 3/3/23 3/1/23 3/17/23 3/24/23 3/31/23 4/7/23 4/14/23 4/22/23 4/29/23 5/6/23 5/13/23 5/2/23 5/27/23 6/3/23 6/1/23 6/17/23 6/24/23 7/1/23 7/8/23 7/15/23 7/22/23 7/29/23 23/4 4, 8, 12, 19 2 21 22 23 2/27/24 3/5/24 3/12/24 3/19/24 3/26/24 4/2/24 4/9/24 4/16/24 4/23/24 4/3/24 5/7/24 5/14/24 5/21/24 5/28/24 6/4/24 6/11/24 6/18/24 6/25/24 7/2/24 7/9/24 7/16/24 7/23/24 7/3/24 8/6/24 8/13/24 8/2/24 8/27/24 9/3/24 9/13/24 9/2/24 9/27/24 1/4/24 1/11/24 1/18/24 1/25/24 24/5 1, 2, 3, 18 19 2 2/28/25 3/7/25 3/14/25 3/21/25 3/29/25 4/5/25 4/12/25 4/19/25 4/26/25 5/3/25 5/1/25 5/17/25 5/24/25 5/31/25 6/7/25 6/14/25 6/21/25 6/28/25 7/5/25 7/12/25 7/19/25 7/26/25 8/2/25 8/9/25 8/16/25 8/23/25 8/3/25 9/7/25 9/14/25 9/21/25 9/28/25 1/5/25 1/12/25 1/19/25 1/26/25 25/6 5, 1, 15, 2 21 22 23 2/27/26 3/6/26 3/13/26 3/2/26 3/27/26 4/3/26 4/1/26 4/17/26 4/24/26 5/1/26 5/8/26 5/15/26 5/22/26 5/29/26 6/5/26 6/12/26 6/19/26 6/26/26 7/3/26 7/1/26 7/17/26 7/24/26 7/31/26 8/7/26 8/14/26 8/21/26 8/28/26 9/4/26 9/11/26 9/18/26 9/25/26 1/2/26 1/9/26 1/16/26 1/23/26 1/3/26 26/7 4, 8, 12, 22 24 26 28 2/26/27 3/5/27 3/12/27 3/19/27 3/26/27 4/2/27 4/1/27 4/17/27 4/24/27 5/1/27 5/8/27 5/15/27 5/22/27 5/29/27 6/5/27 6/12/27 6/19/27 6/26/27 7/3/27 7/1/27 7/17/27 7/24/27 7/31/27 8/7/27 8/14/27 8/21/27 8/28/27 9/4/27 9/11/27 9/18/27 9/25/27 1/2/27 1/9/27 1/16/27 1/23/27 1/3/27 27/8 2, 4, 6, 3 35 4 2/25/28 3/3/28 3/1/28 3/17/28 3/25/28 4/1/28 4/8/28 4/15/28 4/22/28 4/29/28 5/6/28 5/13/28 5/2/28 5/27/28 6/3/28 6/1/28 6/17/28 6/24/28 7/1/28 7/8/28 7/15/28 7/22/28 7/29/28 8/5/28 8/12/28 8/19/28 8/26/28 9/3/28 9/1/28 9/17/28 9/24/28 1/1/28 1/8/28 1/15/28 1/22/28 1/29/28 TONNES FIXED_PRICE PRO 28/9 quantity contracted (tonnes) price (Cdn$/tonne)

Figure 2: PRO price (benchmark) and quantity contracted with Basis Price Contracts (BPC) and nearby futures price 23/4 24/5 22 22 2 4, 2 8, 3, 18 4, 18 2, 16 1, 23-2-24-1 23-3-1-1 23-3-24-1 23-4-7-1 23-4-22-1 23-5-6-1 23-5-2-1 23-6-3-1 23-6-17-1 23-7-1-1 23-7-15-1 23-7-29-1 23-8-12-1 23-8-26-1 23-9-1-1 23-9-24-1 23-1-8-1 23-1-22-1 23-11-5-1 23-11-19-1 23-12-3-1 23-12-17-1 24-1-2-1 24-1-16-1 24-1-3-1 24-2-13-1 24-2-27-1 24-3-12-1 24-3-26-1 24-4-9-1 24-4-23-1 24-5-7-1 24-5-21-1 24-6-4-1 24-6-18-1 24-2-27-2 24-3-12-2 24-3-26-2 24-4-9-2 24-4-23-2 24-5-7-2 24-5-21-2 24-6-4-2 24-6-18-2 24-7-2-1 24-7-16-1 24-7-3-1 24-8-13-1 24-8-27-1 24-9-13-1 24-9-27-1 24-1-11-1 24-1-25-1 24-11-8-1 24-11-22-1 24-12-6-1 24-12-2-1 25-1-3-1 25-1-17-1 25-1-31-1 25-2-14-1 25-2-28-1 25-3-14-1 25-3-29-1 25-4-12-1 25-4-26-1 25-5-1-1 25-5-24-1 25-6-7-1 25-6-21-1 25/6 26/7 quantity contracted (tonnes) 3, 2, 1, 2 18 16 6, 4, 2, 24 22 2 18 price (Cdn$tonne) 25-2-28-2 25-3-14-2 25-3-29-2 25-4-12-2 25-4-26-2 25-5-1-2 25-5-24-2 25-6-7-2 25-6-21-2 25-7-5-1 25-7-19-1 25-8-2-1 25-8-16-1 25-8-3-1 25-9-14-1 25-9-28-1 25-1-12-1 25-1-26-1 25-11-9-1 25-11-23-1 25-12-7-1 25-12-21-1 26-1-5-1 26-1-19-1 26-2-2-1 26-2-16-1 26-3-2-1 26-3-16-1 26-3-3-1 26-4-13-1 26-4-27-1 26-5-11-1 26-5-25-1 26-6-8-1 26-6-22-1 26-2-27-2 26-3-13-2 26-3-27-2 26-4-1-2 26-4-24-2 26-5-8-2 26-5-22-2 26-6-5-2 26-6-19-2 26-7-3-1 26-7-17-1 26-7-31-1 26-8-14-1 26-8-28-1 26-9-12-1 26-9-26-1 26-1-1-1 26-1-24-1 26-11-7-1 26-11-21-1 26-12-5-1 26-12-19-1 27-1-2-1 27-1-16-1 27-1-3-1 27-2-13-1 27-2-27-1 27-3-13-1 27-3-27-1 27-4-11-1 27-4-25-1 27-5-9-1 27-5-23-1 27-6-6-1 27-6-2-1 27/8 28/9 8 8 6 4 6, 2 4, 2, 6, 4, 2, 6 4 26-9-1-2 26-1-9-2 26-11-13-2 26-12-18-2 27-1-22-2 27-2-26-2 27-4-2-2 27-5-8-2 27-6-12-2 27-7-17-1 27-8-21-1 27-9-25-1 27-1-3-1 27-12-4-1 28-1-1-1 28-2-14-1 28-3-2-1 28-4-25-1 28-5-3-1 27-9-4-2 27-1-9-2 27-11-13-2 27-12-18-2 28-1-24-2 28-2-28-2 28-4-4-2 28-5-9-2 28-6-13-2 28-7-18-1 28-8-22-1 28-9-29-1 28-11-3-1 28-12-8-1 29-1-14-1 29-2-18-1 29-3-25-1 29-4-3-1 29-6-4-1 TONNES FUTURES PRO 9

Figure 3: PRO price (benchmark) and quantity contracted and price offered by Daily Price Contracts (DPC) 25/6 26/7 24 25 22 24 23 4, 2 22 6, 21 3, 2, 1, 18 4, 2, quantity contracted (tonnes) 8/1/25 8/15/25 8/29/25 9/13/25 9/27/25 1/11/25 1/25/25 11/8/25 11/22/25 12/6/25 12/2/25 1/4/26 1/18/26 2/1/26 2/15/26 3/1/26 3/15/26 3/29/26 4/12/26 4/26/26 5/1/26 5/24/26 6/7/26 6/21/26 7/5/26 7/19/26 27/8 7 6 5 4 3 6, 4, 8/1/26 8/15/26 8/29/26 9/12/26 9/26/26 1/1/26 1/24/26 11/7/26 11/21/26 12/5/26 12/19/26 1/2/27 1/16/27 1/3/27 2/13/27 2/27/27 3/13/27 3/27/27 4/1/27 4/24/27 5/8/27 5/22/27 6/5/27 6/19/27 7/3/27 7/17/27 7/31/27 28/9 32 28 price (Cdn$/tonne) 2, 1, 2, 24 8/1/27 8/15/27 8/29/27 9/12/27 9/26/27 1/1/27 1/24/27 11/7/27 11/21/27 12/5/27 12/19/27 1/4/28 1/18/28 2/1/28 2/15/28 2/29/28 3/14/28 3/31/28 4/14/28 4/28/28 5/12/28 5/26/28 6/9/28 6/23/28 7/7/28 7/21/28 8/1/28 8/15/28 8/29/28 9/15/28 9/29/28 1/13/28 1/27/28 11/1/28 11/24/28 12/8/28 12/22/28 1/7/29 1/21/29 2/4/29 2/18/29 3/4/29 3/18/29 4/1/29 4/16/29 4/3/29 5/14/29 5/28/29 6/11/29 6/25/29 7/9/29 7/23/29 TONNES DAILY_PRICE PRO RESULTS Cox proportional hazard models were estimated for each marketing contract in each crop year of the sample, thus six models were estimated for the FPC and BPC and four models were estimated for the DPC. In general all variables were statistically significant across contracts, suggesting that they all affected timing decisions in producers marketing choices. However, the signs of the estimated coefficients tended to vary across contracts and across years, suggesting that producers could change their pricing behavior over time and response to the covariates could also depend on characteristics of the contracts and how they relate to producers marketing strategies. The estimated coefficient for the gain indicator was generally positive for the FPC and DPC, suggesting that producers using these two contracts would be more likely to sell when prices were above the benchmark (Table 3 and 5). For the BPC results were mixed, with estimated coefficients exhibiting negative signs in three years and positive signs in two years 1

(Table 4). 7 The magnitude of the estimated coefficients was large compared to the other variables, suggesting an important role of this variable in marketing timing decisions. Findings that producers were more likely to sell with the FPC and DPC when current prices were above the benchmark may be related to the characteristics of the contracts. The FPC was essentially a pre-harvest contract, so producers who use it had not yet harvested and in some cases might not have finished planting. Thus they might be more tempted to quickly lock in a price above their benchmark if they want to sell in that period and reduce price uncertainty. In addition, the FPC had the shortest marketing window among the three contracts and producers might feel they cannot wait too long to use it. With respect to the DPC, this contract requires the quantity to be committed before the beginning of the marketing window, such that producers know they must price a certain quantity with this contract during the marketing window and if they failed to price the committed quantity a penalty fee was incurred. In this case, they might be interested in pricing as soon as the current price was above the benchmark, even though the marketing window lasts the entire crop year. On the other hand, the BPC had the longest marketing window among the three contracts, covering pre- and post-harvest periods. Hence producers might feel they had enough time to follow the market until they decide to price. In addition, there was no pre-commitment with respect to quantity to be priced with the BPC. 7 This variable was not used in the BPC model in 25/6 because the contract price was below the benchmark during the entire marketing window. 11

Table 3: Estimated Cox proportional hazard models Fixed Price Contracts (FPC) 23/4 24/5 25/6 26/7 27/8 28/9 coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) GI b 2.452 11.69 -.645.525 3.576 35.717 3.325 27.87 3.212 24.994 -.448.639 (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) Spread c -.377.686.927 2.527.55 1.56 -.26.974.13 1.19.76 1.79 (.) (.) (.284) (.) (.) (.) Trend d -.176.839.434 1.544.25 1.228 -.8.992.124 1.132.17 1.17 (.) Volatility e -.581 (.) Day dummies Tuesday -.676 (.22) Wednesday -2.522 (.) Thursday -3.647 (.) Friday -.737 (.225) (.).559-2.564 (.).58 -.9 (.846).8.633 (.).26.491 (.).478 -.55 (.) (.).77 1.553 (.).99 2.769 (.) 1.883 2.252 (.) 1.634 1.58 (.).577 1.239 (.) (.12) 4.725.577 (.) 15.951 -.211 (.) 9.58 -.161 (.) 4.857.26 (.483) 3.456.421 (.) (.) 1.78 -.9 (.142).89.165 (.).851 -.396 (.) 1.26 1.5 (.) 1.524.66 (.) (.).99.93 (.) 1.179 -.249 (.4).673 -.68 (.) 2.731-1.22 (.) 1.833-1.336 (.) Obs. f 136 4,98 923 11,297 16,999 2,491 R 2.772.915.832.43.765.756 LR test 21.2 12,251 1,645 5,821 24,637 3,518 Wald test 116.2 4,932 959.3 4,42 12,514 1,93 Score test 251.6 4,682 1,594 4,464 14,4 2,487 (a) p-values are presented in parentheses. (b) GI=gain indicator. Dummy variable equals 1 if current market price was above PRO price (benchmark) and otherwise. (c) Price spread was the average difference between futures price and PRO price (benchmark) during the 1-day period prior to the day when grain was priced. (d) Price trend was calculated as the difference between current market price on the day that grain was price and the average market price during the 1-day period prior to the day when grain was priced. (e) Volatility was calculated as the standard deviation of current market price during the 1-day period prior to the day when grain was priced. (f) Number of observations refers to quantity of transactions made during a marketing window, which is not equal to the number of producers who priced with marketing contracts. 1.98.779.544.295.263

Table 4: Estimated Cox proportional hazard models Basis Price Contracts (BPC) 23/4 24/5 25/6 26/7 27/8 28/9 coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) GI b -.293.746 -.788.455.712 2.39 -.62.538 1.775 5.898 (.77) (.) (.) (.) (.) Spread c -.18.898.97 1.12 -.265.767 -.231.793 -.6.994 -. 1. (.) (.) (.) (.) (.) (.9) Trend d.13 1.19.33 1.34.38 1.39 -.65.937.4 1.4.4 1.4 (.) Volatility e -.144 (.1) Day dummies Tuesday -1.1 (.) Wednesday.344 (.76) Thursday.284 (.78) Friday.619 (.) (.).866.422 (.).367 -.94 (.459) 1.411-2.25 (.) 1.328 -.48 (.724) 1.858 -.176 (.169) (.) 1.525 -.324 (.).91 -.22 (.13).11 -.23 (.16).954 -.219 (.9).839.97 (.225) (.).723 -.38 (.9).817.271 (.).816.358 (.).84 -.132 (.53) 1.12.361 (.) (.3).962 -.63 (.) 1.311.286 (.) 1.43.539 (.).876.321 (.) 1.434 -.214 (.4) (.).939 -.2 (.341) 1.331.45 (.382) 1.715.385 (.) 1.379.226 (.).88.469 (.) Obs. f 45 921 1,783 3,247 2,678 4,955 R 2.457.791.853.841.45.443 LR test 274.5 1,442 3,413 5,978 1,389 2,899 Wald test 254.7 736.4 1,827 4,18 1,75 2,325 Score test 271.1 1,717 2,487 4,788 1,116 2,747 (a) p-values are presented in parentheses. (b) GI=gain indicator. Dummy variable equals 1 if current market price was above PRO price (benchmark) and otherwise. (c) Price spread was the average difference between futures price and PRO price (benchmark) during the 1-day period prior to the day when grain was priced. (d) Price trend was calculated as the difference between current market price on the day that grain was price and the average market price during the 1-day period prior to the day when grain was priced. (e) Volatility was calculated as the standard deviation of current market price during the 1-day period prior to the day when grain was priced. (f) Number of observations refers to quantity of transactions made during a marketing window, which is not equal to the number of producers who priced with marketing contracts..998 1.46 1.47 1.253 1.599 13

Table 5: Estimated Cox proportional hazard models Daily Price Contracts (DPC) 25/6 26/7 27/8 28/9 coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) coef a exp(coef) GI b -1.264.283 4.344 77. 2.8 7.45 84.69 6.2e+36 (.) (.) (.) (.48) Spread c -.32.726 -.119.887 -.13.987 -.19.981 (.) (.) (.) (.) Trend d.156 1.16.79 1.83.9 1.1.61 1.63 (.349) (.) (.) (.) Volatility e -.281.755 -.48.619 -.23.977.214 1.239 (.) Last week f -23.94 (.98) Day dummies Tuesday.363 (.55) Wednesday -.32 (.87) Thursday -.54 (.786) Friday -.46 (.795) (.). -1.199 (.) 1.438 -.394 (.).726 -.249 (.).947 -.473 (.).955 -.234 (.) (.).31-18.67 (.941).674.26 (.).779.295 (.).622.85 (.119).791 -.222 (.) (.). -16.36 (.792) 1.229.841 (.) 1.343 1.214 (.) 1.89.676 (.119).81 -.615 (.5) Obs. g 438 2,826 4,5 1,55 R 2.945.465.597.831 LR test 1,267 1,765 3,638 1,875 Wald test 512.4 1,66 1,42 236.4 Score test 98.7 4,978 2,427 3,471 (a) p-values are presented in parentheses. (b) GI=gain indicator. Dummy variable equals 1 if current market price was above PRO price (benchmark) and otherwise. (c) Price spread was the average difference between futures price and PRO price (benchmark) during the 1-day period prior to the day when grain was priced. (d) Price trend was calculated as the difference between current market price on the day that grain was price and the average market price during the 1-day period prior to the day when grain was priced. (e) Volatility was calculated as the standard deviation of current market price during the 1-day period prior to the day when grain was priced. (f) Dummy variable which equals 1 when wheat was priced with DPC in the last 1 days of the marketing window. (g) Number of observations refers to quantity of transactions made during a marketing window, which is not equal to the number of producers who priced with marketing contracts.. 2.319 3.367 1.966.541 14

Estimated coefficients for the price spread were all negative for the DPC (Table 5), but mixed findings emerged for the other two contracts. For the FPC this variable had a positive sign in three years (24/5, 27/8 and 28/9) and a negative sign in two years (23/4 and 26/7), in addition to one year without statistical significance (Table 3). For the BPC the sign of the estimated coefficients for the spread were negative in three years (23/4, 26/7 and 27/8) and positive in two years (24/5 and 25/6), also in addition to one year when it was not statistically significant (Table 4). Since the spread reflects the difference between prices offered by the contracts and the price the CWB expects to pay the pool at the end of the crop year (PRO price), the impact of this variable on timing decisions may be interpreted as how much confidence producers have in the CWB forecast for the pool price. The negative sign in the estimated coefficients for the DPC indicates that larger positive spreads (current market price greater than PRO price) reduce the conditional probability of selling on a given day, suggesting that producers might not believe in the PRO price and thus expect the pool price to be greater than forecast by the CWB, choosing then to wait a while longer to sell. Alternatively, the negative sign can also indicate that larger negative spreads (current market price smaller than PRO price) increase the conditional probability of selling on a given day, suggesting that producers might also not believe in the PRO price and thus expect the pool price to be smaller than forecast by the CWB, opting then to sell soon at the current contract price. Even though findings appear to be mixed within the FPC and BPC models, they were actually consistent across the two contracts in 23/4 (negative sign) and 24/5 (positive sign), when the DPC had not yet been created. In the next four years results were not as consistent across contracts, which may just reflect their distinct marketing windows. For example, in 27/8 the sign was positive for the FPC and negative for the BPC and DPC. The FPC had the earliest and shortest marketing window, which ended before the large price spike that happened in that crop year. The BPC and DPC, on the other hand, had a longer window and most marketing with those contracts happened towards the end of the FPC window or even after it (Figures 1 to 3). Hence the change in sign for the estimated coefficients across contracts might imply changes in producers beliefs about the accuracy of the PRO price with new market developments. Results for the trend variable suggest a positive relationship with timing decisions. The majority of estimated coefficients for all contracts indicated an increase (decrease) in the conditional probability of selling wheat on a given day when there was an uptrend (downtrend) in the market. With respect to volatility, estimated coefficients were mostly negative for the BPC and DPC, suggesting a general risk-seeking behavior with these two contracts. Larger (smaller) price variability in the market would decrease (increase) the conditional probability of selling wheat on a given day, perhaps reflecting the notion that producers would wait and try to obtain higher prices in a more volatile market. On the other hand, results were mixed for the FPC, with a combination of positive and negative signs for this variable over the years (Table 3). Estimated coefficients on dummy variables for days of the week were generally statistically significant, but there appears to be no clear pattern of behavior with respect to pricing on specific days of the week. The exception may be the DPC, for which producers seemed more likely to price on Tuesdays and less likely to price on Fridays during the four years of the contract (Table 5).

Finally, producers using the DPC know that they have to price a certain quantity that was committed before the beginning of the marketing window. In this arrangement it was possible that producers would hold their wheat too long because of market conditions and then approach the end of the marketing window with the obligation to price the grain regardless what was happening in the market. An extra dummy variable was included in the DPC model to account for this possibility. This dummy variable takes a value of one if producers used the DPC in the last 1 days of the marketing window. As can be seen in Table 5, this variable was statistically significant in only one year and exhibited a negative sign. CONCLUSION This research investigated the timing of marketing decisions in the Canadian wheat market. Cox proportional hazard models were estimated to explore how market-based variables affected the timing of producers decisions. This method provides a way to interpret the conditional probability of selling wheat and how this probability changes due to changes in the independent variables. Four market-based variables were used in the analysis: an indicator showing whether current prices were above the producers benchmark on a given day (gain indicator), 1-day average spread between current prices and producers benchmark, 1-day price trend and price volatility over 1 days. Data were provided by the CWB and included all producers who grew CWRS wheat from 23/4 through 28/9, but the sample used in this study only included producers who grew CWRS wheat in at least one of the six crop years and marketed their wheat using at least one marketing contracts. The sample that meets these criteria contains 17,338 producers who executed 59,184 transactions. Overall results show that all market-based variables were statistically significant across contracts, indicating that they all affected timing decisions in producers marketing choices. However, the signs of the estimated coefficients tended to vary across contracts and across years, suggesting that producers could change their pricing behavior over time and response to the covariates could also depend on characteristics of the contracts and how they relate to producers marketing strategies. Further research can explore other benchmarks used to determine the gain indicator and the price spread. The present study assumes that producers would focus on the expected pool price (PRO price) when comparing current market prices, but there can also be other reference prices. In addition, the price spread, trend and volatility were calculated over a 1-day period prior to the day when a producer priced his grain. Other time horizons can also be explored. 16

REFERENCES Anderson, K.B. and B.W. Brorsen (25). Marketing Performance of Oklahoma Farmers. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 87, 1265-127. Cabrini de Colonna, S.M. (26). Three essays on performance and behavior of agricultural market advisory services in corn and soybeans. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, United States - Illinois. Coval, J.D. and T. Shumway (25). Do Behavioral Biases Affect Prices? The Journal of Finance 6, 1-34. Dorfman, J.H. and B. Karali (21). Do Farmers Hedge Optimally or by Habit? A Bayesian Partial-Adjustment Model of Farmer Hedging. Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 42: 791-83. Feng, L. And M.S. Seasholes (25). Do Investor Sophistication and Trading Experience Eliminate Behavioral Biases in Financial Markets? Review of Finance 9, 35-351. Hagedorn, L.A., S.H. Irwin, D.L. Good and E.V. Colino (25). Does the Performance of Illinois Corn and Soybean Farmers Lag the Market? American Journal of Agricultural Economics 87: 1271-1279. Isengildina, O. and M.D. Hudson (21). Factors Affecting Hedging Decisions Using Evidence from the Cotton Industry. Paper presented at the NCR-134 Conference on Applied Commodity Price Analysis, Forecasting, and Market Risk Management, St. Louis, Missouri, April 23-24, 21. McNew, K. and W.N. Musser (22). Farmer Forward Pricing Behavior: Evidence from Marketing Clubs. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 31: 2-21. Meulenberg, MT.G. and J.M.E. Pennings (22). A Marketing Approach to Commodity Futures Exchanges: A Case Study of the Dutch Hog Industry. Journal of Agricultural Economics 53: 51-64. Seru, A., T. Shumway and N. Stoffman (21). Learning by Trading. The Review of Financial Studies 23, 75-739. 17